MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 COVERED STRATEGIES: Take a position in the option and the underlying stock. SPREAD STRATEGIES: Take a position in 2 or more options of the same type (A spread). COMBINATION STRATEGIES: Take a position in a mixture of calls and puts. MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 STANDARD SYMBOLS: STAKES: ◦ C = current call price, P = current put price ◦ S0 = current stock price, ST = stock price at time T ◦ T = time to maturity ◦ X = exercise price (or K in some books) ◦ P = profit from strategy ◦ NC = number of calls ◦ NP = number of puts ◦ NS = number of shares of stock MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 These symbols imply the following: ◦ NC or NP or NS > 0 implies buying (going long) ◦ NC or NP or NS < 0 implies selling (going short) Recall the PROFIT EQUATIONS ◦ Profit equation for calls held to expiration P = NC[Max(0,ST - X) – Cexp(rT)] For buyer of one call (NC = 1) this implies P = Max(0,ST - X) - Cexp(rT) For seller of one call (NC = -1) this implies P = -Max(0,ST - X) + Cexp(rT) MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 The Profit Equations (continued) Profit equation for puts held to expiration P = NP[Max(0,X - ST) - Pexp(rT)] For buyer of one put (NP = 1) this implies P = Max(0,X - ST) - Pexp(rT) For seller of one put (NP = -1) this implies P = -Max(0,X - ST) + Pexp(rT) MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 The Profit Equations (continued) ◦ Profit equation for stock P = NS[ST - S0] For buyer of one share (NS = 1) this implies P = ST - S0 For short seller of one share (NS = -1) this implies P = -ST + S0 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Profit Profit K K ST ST (a) (b) Profit Profit K ST (c) K (d) MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 ST Bull Spread Using Calls: Buying a call option on a stock with a particular strike price and selling a call option on the same stock with a higher strike price. Payoff from a Bull Spread: Stock price Range Payoff from Long Call Option Payoff from Short Call Option Total Payoff ST ≥ K2 K1 < ST < K2 ST ≤ K1 ST - K1 ST - K1 0 K2 - ST 0 0 K2 - K1 ST ≥ K2 0 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA - AUGUST 2010 Ex: An investor buys $3 a call with a strike price of $30 and sells for $1 a call with a strike price of $35. Payoff from a Bull Spread: Stock price Range Payoff from Long Call Option Payoff from Short Call Option Total Payoff ST ≥ $35 $30 < ST < $35 ST ≤ $30 ST - $30 - $3 ST - $30 -$3 0 - $3 $35 - ST +$1 0+$1 0+$1 $3 ST - $32 -$2 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA - AUGUST 2010 Profit ST K1 K2 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Profit K1 K2 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 ST Profit K1 K2 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 ST Bear Spread: Buying a call option on a stock with a particular strike price and selling a call option on the same stock with a lower strike price. Stock price Range Payoff from Long Call Option Payoff from Short Call Option Total Payoff ST ≥ K2 K1 < ST < K2 ST ≤ K1 ST - K2 0 0 K1 - ST K1 - ST 0 -(K2 - K1) -(ST ≥ K1) 0 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA - AUGUST 2010 Example: An investor buys a call for $1 with a strike price of $35 and sells for $3 a call with a strike price of $30. Stock price Range Payoff from Long Call Option Payoff from Short Call Option Total Payoff ST ≥ $35 $30 < ST < $35 ST ≤ $30 ST - $35 0 0 $30 - ST $30 - ST 0 -($35 - $30) -(ST ≥ $30) 0 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA - AUGUST 2010 Profi t K1 K2 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 ST A combination of a bull call spread and a bear put spread If all options are European a box spread is worth the present value of the difference between the strike prices If they are American this is not necessarily so. MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Butterfly Spread: buying a call option with a relative low strike price, K1,, buying a call option with a relative high strike price. K3, and selling two call options with a strike price halfway in between, K2. Stock price Range Payoff from First Long Call Option Payoff from Second Long Call Option Payoff from Short Calls Total Payoff ST ≥ K3 K2 < ST < K3 K2 < ST < K3 ST ≤ K1 ST - K1 ST - K1 ST - K1 0 ST - K3 0 0 0 -2(ST - K2) -2(ST - K2) 0 0 0 K3 - ST ST - K1 0 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA - AUGUST 2010 Example: Call option prices on a $61 stock are: $10 for a $55 strike, $7 for a $60 strike, and $5 for a $65 strike. The investor could create a butterfly spread by buying one call with $55 strike price, buying a call with a $65 strike price, and selling two calls with a $60 strike price. Stock price Range Payoff from First Long Call Option Payoff from Second Long Call Option Payoff from Short Calls Total Payoff ST ≥ $65 $60 < ST <$65 $55 < ST <$60 ST ≤ $55 ST - $55 ST - $55 ST - $55 0 ST - $65 0 0 0 -2(ST - $60) -2(ST - $60) 0 0 0 $65 - ST ST -$55 0 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA - AUGUST 2010 Profit K1 K2 K3 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 ST Profit K1 K2 K3 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 ST Profit ST K MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Profit ST K MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Straddle: Buying a call and a put with the same strike price and expiration Date. Stock price Range Payoff from Call Payoff from Put Total Payoff ST ≥ K ST < K ST – K 0 0 K - ST ST - K K - ST MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA - AUGUST 2010 Example: An investor buying a call and a put with a strike price of $70 and an expiration date in 3 months. Suppose the call costs $4 and the put $3. Stock price Range Payoff from Call Payoff from Put Total Payoff ST ≥ $70 ST < $70 ST – $70 -$4 0 - $4 0 -$3 $70 - ST - $3 ST - $77 $63 - ST MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA - AUGUST 2010 Profit K MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 ST Profit Profit K Strip ST K Strap MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 ST Profit K1 K2 ST MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 A stock price is currently $20 In three months it will be either $22 or $18 Stock Price = $22 Stock price = $20 Stock Price = $18 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 A 3-month call option on the stock has a strike price of 21. Stock Price = $22 Option Price = $1 Stock price = $20 Option Price=? Stock Price = $18 Option Price = $0 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Consider the Portfolio: long D shares short 1 call option 22D – 1 18D Portfolio is riskless when 22D – 1 = 18D or D = 0.25 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 The riskless portfolio is: long 0.25 shares short 1 call option The value of the portfolio in 3 months is 22 0.25 – 1 = 4.50 The value of the portfolio today is 4.5e – 0.120.25 = 4.3670 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 The portfolio that is long 0.25 shares short 1 option is worth 4.367 The value of the shares is 5.000 (= 0.25 20 ) The value of the option is therefore 0.633 (= 5.000 – 4.367 ) MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 A derivative lasts for time T and is dependent on a stock S ƒ S(1+a)=Su ƒu S(1-a)=Sd ƒd MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Consider the portfolio that is long D shares and short 1 derivative SuD – ƒu SdD – ƒd The portfolio is riskless when SuD – ƒu = Sd D – ƒd or ƒu f d D Su Sd MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Value of the portfolio at time T is Su D – ƒu Value of the portfolio today is (Su D – ƒu )e–rT Another expression for the portfolio value today is S D – f Hence ƒ = S D – (Su D – ƒu )e–rT MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Substituting for D we obtain ƒ = [ p ƒu + (1 – p )ƒd ]e–rT where p e rT 1 a 2a MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 ƒ = [ p ƒu + (1 – p )ƒd ]e-rT The variables p and (1 – p ) can be interpreted as the risk-neutral probabilities of up and down movements The value of a derivative is its expected payoff in a risk-neutral world discounted at the riskfree rate Su S ƒ ƒu Sd ƒd MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Su = 22 ƒu = 1 S ƒ Sd = 18 ƒd = 0 Since p is a risk-neutral probability 20e0.12 0.25 = 22p + 18(1 – p ); p = 0.6523 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Su = 22 ƒu = 1 S ƒ Sd = 18 ƒd = 0 The value of the option is e–0.120.25 [0.65231 + 0.34770] = 0.633 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 One way of matching the volatility is to set e rT 1 a p 2a s ae Dt 1 where s is the volatility and Dt is the length of the time step. This is the approach used by Cox, Ross, and Rubinstein MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 24.2 22 19.8 20 18 Each time step is 3 months K=21, r=12% MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 16.2 D 22 20 1.2823 A B 2.0257 18 E F 19.8 0.0 C 0.0 24.2 3.2 16.2 0.0 Value at node B = e–0.120.25(0.65233.2 + 0.34770) = 2.0257 Value at node A = e–0.120.25(0.65232.0257 + 0.34770) = 1.2823 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 K = 52, Dt = 1yr r = 5% D 60 50 4.1923 A B 1.4147 40 72 0 48 4 E C 9.4636 F MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 32 20 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Discrete time; discrete variable Discrete time; continuous variable Continuous time; discrete variable Continuous time; continuous variable MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 We can use any of the four types of stochastic processes to model stock prices The continuous time, continuous variable process proves to be the most useful for the purposes of valuing derivative securities MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 In a Markov process future movements in a variable depend only on where we are, not the history of how we got where we are We will assume that stock prices follow Markov processes MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 The assertion is that it is impossible to produce consistently superior returns with a trading rule based on the past history of stock prices. In other words technical analysis does not work. A Markov process for stock prices is clearly consistent with weak-form market efficiency MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 A stock price is currently at $40 At the end of 1 year it is considered that it will have a probability distribution of (40,10) where f(m,s) is a normal distribution with mean m and standard deviation s. MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 What is the probability distribution of the stock price at the end of 2 years? ½ years? ¼ years? Dt years? Taking limits we have defined a continuous variable, continuous time process MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 In Markov processes changes in successive periods of time are independent This means that variances are additive Standard deviations are not additive MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 In our example it is correct to say that the variance is 100 per year. It is strictly speaking not correct to say that the standard deviation is 10 per year. MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 We consider a variable z whose value changes continuously The change in a small interval of time Dt is Dz The variable follows a Wiener process if: 1. Dz Dt where is a random drawing from N(0,1) 2. The values of Dz for any 2 different (nonoverlapping) periods of time are independent MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Mean of [z (T ) – z (0)] is 0 Variance of [z (T ) – z (0)] is T Standard deviation of [z (T ) – z (0)] is MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 T What does an expression involving dz and dt mean? It should be interpreted as meaning that the corresponding expression involving Dz and Dt is true in the limit as Dt tends to zero In this respect, stochastic calculus is analogous to ordinary calculus MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 A Wiener process has a drift rate (ie average change per unit time) of 0 and a variance rate of 1 In a generalized Wiener process the drift rate & the variance rate can be set equal to any chosen constants MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 The variable x follows a generalized Wiener process with a drift rate of a & a variance rate of b2 if dx=adt+bdz MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Dx a Dt b Dt Mean change in x in time T is aT Variance of change in x in time T is b2T Standard deviation of change in x in time T is b T MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 A stock price starts at 40 & has a probability distribution of (40,10) at the end of the year If we assume the stochastic process is Markov with no drift then the process is dS = 10dz If the stock price were expected to grow by $8 on average during the year, so that the year-end distribution is (48,10), the process is dS = 8dt + 10dz MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 In an Ito process the drift rate and the variance rate are functions of time dx=a(x,t)dt+b(x,t)dz The discrete time equivalent Dx a ( x , t ) Dt b( x , t ) Dt is only true in the limit as Dt tends to zero MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 For a stock price we can conjecture that its expected proportional change in a short period of time remains constant not its expected absolute change in a short period of time We can also conjecture that our uncertainty as to the size of future stock price movements is proportional to the level of the stock price MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 dS mSdt sSdz where m is the expected return s is the volatility. The discrete time equivalent is DS mSDt sS Dt MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 We can sample random paths for the stock price by sampling values for Suppose m= 0.14, s= 0.20, and Dt = 0.01, then DS 0.0014 S 0.02 S MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Period Stock Price at Random Start of Period Sample for Change in Stock Price, DS 0 20.000 0.52 0.236 1 20.236 1.44 0.611 2 20.847 -0.86 -0.329 3 20.518 1.46 0.628 4 21.146 -0.69 -0.262 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 If we know the stochastic process followed by x, Ito’s lemma tells us the stochastic process followed by some function G (x, t ) Since a derivative security is a function of the price of the underlying & time, Ito’s lemma plays an important part in the analysis of derivative securities MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 A Taylor’s series expansion of G (x , t) gives G G G 2 DG Dx Dt ½ 2 Dx x t x 2G 2G 2 Dx Dt ½ 2 Dt xt t 2 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 In ordinary calculus we get G G DG Dx Dt x t In stochastic calculus we get G G 2G 2 DG D x Dt ½ D x x t x2 because Dx has a component which is of order Dt MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Suppose dx a( x, t )dt b( x, t )dz so that Dx = a Dt + b Dt Then ignoring terms of higher order than Dt G G 2G 2 2 DG Dx Dt ½ b Dt 2 x t x MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Since N (0,1), E ( ) 0 E ( ) [ E ( )] 1 2 2 E ( ) 1 2 It follows that E ( 2 Dt ) Dt The variance of Dt is proportion al to Dt 2 and can be ignored. Hence G G 1 G 2 DG Dx Dt b Dt 2 x t 2 x 2 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 Taking limits G G 2G 2 dG dx dt ½ 2 b dt x t x Substituting dx a dt b dz We obtain G G 2G 2 G dG a ½ 2 b dt b dz t x x x This is Ito's Lemma MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 The stock price process is d S m S dt s S d z For a function G of S & t G G 2G 2 2 G dG mS ½ s S dz 2 s S dt t S S S MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010 1. The forward price of a stock for a contract maturing at time T G S er ( T t ) dG (m r )G dt sG dz 2. G ln S s2 dG m dt s dz 2 MILJAN KNEŽEVIĆ, BANJA LUKA AUGUST 2010