Assessment Submission Form – HRM 20030 Student Name Colin Ratcliffe Student Number 11362941 Assessment Title Do 'free' labour markets yield better jobs? Module Title People at Work Module Co-ordinator Professor John Geary Date Submitted 05-10-12 Declaration of Authorship I declare that all material in this assessment is my own work except where there is clear acknowledgement and appropriate reference to the work of others. A COPY OF THIS FORM MUST ACCOMPANY ALL SUBMISSIONS FOR ASSESSMENT. STUDENTS SHOULD KEEP COPIES OF ALL WORK SUBMITTED. Procedures for Submission and Late Submission There are penalties for the late submission of assessments. For further information please see the University’s Policy on Late Submission of Coursework in the “Start Here” section of this course on Blackboard. By submitting this form, you declare that you are the sole author of this assignment and that all material from other sources is acknowledged. Plagiarism: the unacknowledged inclusion of another person’s writings or ideas or works, in any formally presented work (including essays, examinations, projects, laboratory reports or presentations). The penalties associated with plagiarism designed to impose sanctions that reflect the seriousness of University’s commitment to academic integrity. Ensure that you have read the University’s Briefing for Students on Academic Integrity and Plagiarism and the UCD Plagiarism Statement, Plagiarism Policy and Procedures. Do 'free' labour markets yield better jobs? In ‘Work In the New Economy’, Chris Benner defines labour market flexibility as the speed with which labour markets adapt to fluctuations in society, the economy and/or production. Economists consider a labour market flexible when wages are set by the forces of supply and demand, and not by non-market factors (such as pressure from unions, minimum wage laws etc). Standard neo-classical economists believe high European unemployment rates are due to labour market rigidity; the price of labour cannot adapt to economic shocks. They believe in reducing the power of trade unions, having fewer rules that protect labour and lowering minimum wages. The improved mobility of labour leads to lower unemployment. The economy becomes more attractive to inward investment and can respond more effectively and efficiently to economic shocks. The labour market becomes more flexible. Countries with flexible market economies like this include USA, Canada, Ireland, Great Britain and Australia. However, flexible market economies have their disadvantages. Short-term employment contracts lead to job insecurity. Employees may have less confidence in their employers. Short-term contracts may also lead to a lack of training for employees. Perhaps more worryingly, some studies show that flexible labour markets may be linked to the growth of poverty rates and the reduction of labour productivity growth. In contrast with free labour markets, co-ordinated market economies protect labour and promote employment security through channels such as giving more power to trade unions and regulating minimum wages. So what constitutes a ‘good’ job and do free labour market yield better jobs than coordinated market economies? In ‘Job Security and Job Protection (2005), Andrew Clark and Fabien Postel-Vinay argue that job security is seen to be one of the key determinants in job quality. The flexible labour market system often depends on rapid adjustments to the size of the workforce meaning job security is low. In contrast, CMEs depend on a specifically trained workforce and place an emphasis on labour retention meaning job security is high. Similarly, the process of ‘up-skilling’ is essential to job quality. Workers who feel like they are constantly learning new skills are more content in their jobs than workers who do not. In flexible labour markets, employees are often over-skilled due to the generalisation of work. In CMEs however, the industry-specific and knowledge-specific nature of work means employees improve their skills on a continual basis. Job control is another essential element of job quality. Workers who have more control and responsibility will, on average, be more content than those who do not. The skill-based work more common to CMEs is more difficult for management to monitor or direct so employees are generally entrusted with more control and management take a ‘laissez-faire’ approach. The generalised work in flexible labour markets is much easier to supervise and employees have much less responsibility. Alfred Kleinknecht, Professor of Economics of Innovation at TU Delft conducted a study in his native Netherlands on the link between the use of flexible labour and labour productivity growth. He found that more ‘flexible’ firms (with many temporary contracts, manpower agency workers or a high labour turnover) pay, on average, lower wages. Moreover, flexible workers earn lower hourly wages. When all elements are taken into account, I believe that ‘free’ labour markets do not yield better jobs than co-ordinated market economies. The features of work I have listed throughout this essay are some of the main factors to be considered when measuring job quality and what makes a ‘good’ job. The CME approach seems to satisfy each of these factors more readily than its flexible labour market counterpart and thus yields better jobs. References: Benner, C. ‘Work in the New Economy: Flexible Labour Markets in Silicon Valley’ (2002), Los Angeles: Wiley-Blackwell Clark, A., Postel-Vinay, F: ‘Job Security and Job Protection’ (2005) Germany: IZA Kleinknecht, A., R.M. Oostendorp, M.P. Pradhan & C.W.M. Naastepad: 'Flexible labour, firm performance and the Dutch job creation miracle', in: International Review of Applied Economics, Vol. 20 (2006), pp. 171-187