Different transition paths to low carbon power: Germany, UK, EU Volkmar.Lauber@sbg.ac.at University of Salzburg, Austria Carleton University, 1-2 October 2015 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 1 Clarifications on low/zero carbon • Only renewable power is carbon-free • • • German FIT only supports renewable power UK FIT with CfD supports “low carbon”, i.e. Renewable power (zero carbon) Nuclear power is “low carbon”, not C-free CCS (low carbon - a share of CO2 is emitted) Current EU policy closer to that of UK 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 2 Different evolution of power mix in Germany and UK • In 1990, both had mostly coal plants, supplemented by nuclear power • UK started replacing sizeable part of coal by gas starting in 1990s, followed by contraction of gas in 2010s; 65 TWh of renewable power by 2014 (slide) • Germany:decline of hard coal + nuclear from 2007 onwards; less gas; steady growth of renewable power to 160 TWh in 2014 (slide) 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 3 Electricity generation in the United Kingdom by fuel source/technology, 1980-2014 Source: Department of Energy & Climate Change (2015) Digest of United Kingdom Energy Statistics. Infographics, p.7, https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/449434/DUKES_2015_Infog raphics.pdf. 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 4 Electricity generation in Germany by fuel source/technology, 1990-2014 700 Other energy sources 600 500 Photovoltaics Biomass Wind power in TWh 400 Household waste Hydro power 300 Petroleum products 200 Natural gas Hard coal 100 Nuclear 0 Source: Adapted from AGEB (Arbeitsgemeinschaft Energiebilanzen) (2015) Bruttostromerzeugung in Deutschland nach Energieträgern, as of 27 Feb 2015. 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada Lignite 5 Table of contents: Politics and policy of transition 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 22.03.2016 Germany 2000-2010 UK 2000-2008 Germany 2010-2015 UK 2008-2015 EU late 1990s-2015 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 6 Part 1: Germany, 2000-2010 Intention and first implementation of the Renewable Energy Act of 2000 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 7 The origins of Germany’s Renewable Energy Act of 2000 • Precursor (Feed-In Law of 1990) designed by Conservative Party, pro-renewable power MPs responding to civil society pressure. In 2000 with red-green MPs. • Rejecting/defeating support schemes pushed by Econ. Affairs Ministry and European Commission • Recurring battles with European Comm. until 2014 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 8 Purposes of Renewable Energy Act 2000 (by red-green government) Enable full transition from nuclear (phase-out by about 2022) and fossil to renewable power by • Creating steady demand for renewable power (RP) equipment by reducing risk for small and (unlike utilities) motivated investors • Supporting rise of RP equipment industry to drive down prices through steady innovation • Creating new industry, jobs, exports 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 9 Instruments of EEG 2000 Priority access for all renewable power tendered to utilities (solar PV only after 2003) Principle of full cost payments to generators (all investment costs plus small profit for well-run facilities – about 6% then) Guaranteed 20 year payments, degressive and differentiated by technology All technologies supported in parallel (unlike UK) 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 10 Implementation of EEG 2000 • At first, resistance by European Commission (see below), but big success for about 10 ys: • rapid deployment (beating minimum targets), • creation of equip. industry, jobs, exports, • big investments despite restive incumbents, • comparatively low cost (3 slides) • highly popular exc. with Liberal party leaders + Conservative business leaders 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 11 Renewable power generation by energy source in Germany, 1990-2014 180 160 140 Photovoltaics 120 TWh 100 Biomass 80 Wind power 60 40 Household waste 20 Hydro power 0 Source: Adapted from AGEB (Arbeitsgemeinschaft Energiebilanzen) (2015) Bruttostromerzeugung in Deutschland nach Energieträgern, as of 27 Feb 2015. 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 12 Minimum targets regularly overachieved/ moved upwards till 2010 • EEG 2000: 12% by 2010 achieved in 2005 (5 ys early) • EEG 2004: 20% by 2020 achieved in 2011 (9 ys early) • EEG 2008: 30% by 2020 probably achieved in 2015 (5 ys) • NREAP 2009: 38.6% by 2020 ________________________________ • Energiekonzept2010/EEG 2011/EEG 2014: 35%-2020 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 13 Germany: Renewable energy sector job growth, 1998-2011 Source: Unendlich viel Energie (2012): Arbeitsmarkt Erneuerbare Energien. Available on http://www.unendlich-viel-energie.de/de/wirtschaft/arbeitsplaetze-erneuerbarekarriere/arbeitsmarkt-erneuerbare-energien.html, 08.01.2013. 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 14 Figure 1. Ownership structure in 2010 of renewable electricity installations in Germany (not including pumped storage) (Total installed capacity: 53,0 GW) Adapted from: trend:research (2011) p.45. 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 15 Payment for Wind Energy in Europe 2011 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 16 Price ranges (average to minimum support) for direct support of onshore wind in EU27 (average tariffs are indicative) compared to long-term marginal costs (minimum to average costs). Support schemes are normalised to 15 years. CEC:Commission Staff Working Paper SEC(2008)57, The support of electricity from renewable energy sources, pp. 25- 26 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 17 Historically observed efficiency of support for onshore wind: Effectiveness indicator compared to expected profit in 2006. CEC:Commission Staff Working Paper SEC(2008)57, The support of electricity from renewable energy sources, p.32 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 18 Part 2: UK 2000-2008 • Intentions and first implementation of Renewables Obligation (RO) 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 19 Origins and Purpose • Designed by Treasury (NFFO model) and DTI with minimal role for UK Parliament (Westminster model…); Thatcherist economics • Bring down price of renewable power by competition (DE: also technological learning) • Supports market creation only for the currently cheapest technologies (not all simultaneously, as in Germany); windfalls if new tech. with higher prices is needed 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 20 The instruments of the RO • Requires utilities to hand in renewable energy certificates for a set (and annually increasing) percentage of their sales (quota), from own generation or bought from outside (traded) • Generators get market price + certif. price • Certificates are traded -> volatility (“cliff”?) • Volatility eliminates SME participation (high risk) and deters rise of equipment industry 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 21 Impact of RO • Purpose of RO 2002 was to drive down prices for renewable power -> diffusion • In practice, RO (and similar schemes in Italy, Belgium, Poland…) led to highest prices in EU • By excluding small investors, it also freed incumbents largely from competition and deployment pressures -> slow deployment • Led to little technological learning, little participation in RP industry 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 22 Renewable power generation by energy sources in the United Kingdom, 1990-2014 10000 in thousand tonnes of oil equivalent 9000 Photovoltaics 8000 7000 Offshore wind 6000 5000 Onshore wind 4000 3000 Bioenergy 2000 1000 Hydro 0 Source: Department of Energy & Climate Change (2015) Digest of United Kingdom Energy Statistics, https://www.gov.uk/government/statistics/renewable-sources-of-energy-chapter-6-digest-of-united-kingdomenergy-statistics-dukes. 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 23 Part 3. Germany 2010-2014: Dismantling EEG? • By its old opponents: Econ. Aff. Ministry, big incumbents, Liberal leaders, Business wing of Conservative Party • New opponents: other Conservatives, since 2013 also key Social Democratic leaders • Interestingly, this is hardly reflected in public support– overwhelming approval rates for “citizen Energiewende” even in 2014 (EMNID) 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 24 Arguments for holding down renewable power growth • Excessive support due to lacking competition • Leads to market creation for technologies which are not yet market ready (PV?) • Excessive growth of RP means high consumer cost and danger to competitiveness of German industry… deindustrialisation? 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 25 Arguments of Critics • Excessively rapid deployment of technologies • Excessive support for technologies which are not market ready (particularly PV, which surged in 2009-2012) • Lack of direct price competition among generators (all get the FIT) • High consumer costs • Loss of competitiveness of German industry, deindustrialisation at end of the road 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 26 Background: Acceleration of RP growth (Source: AGEB, 2015) Year Total generation in TWh 1990 19.7 Annual increase in period Average 1 TWh/year 1999 29.1 Average 5.5 TWh/year 2004 56.6 Average 7.6 TWh/year 2009 94.9 Average 13 TWh/year 2014 22.03.2016 160,6 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 27 Germany: PV growth: Installed capacity (in MW) and energy supply (in GWh) from photovoltaic installations, 1990-2011 (cumulative) Adapted from: Federal Ministry for the Environment, Nature Conservation and Nuclear Safety 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada (2012). 28 Other reasons for changing attitudes among political leaders Perceived need to help the ailing big four electricity incumbents suffering from • problematic take-overs after liberalisation, • nuclear phase-out zig-zag (Con.-Lib. Govt) • neglecting renewable power investments • excessive new build of gas and coal plants at time of falling demand (since 2008) • Under the merit order, incumbents lose profitable peak load to PV and wind 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 29 Installed net capacity for electricity generation in Germany, 2002-2015 200 180 Solar 160 Wind offshore 140 Wind onshore GW 120 Hydro 100 Biomass 80 Natural gas 60 Nuclear 40 Lignite 20 Hard coal 0 Source: Adapted from Fraunhofer ISE (2015b); * first half of 2015 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 30 Weak government arguments • Cost to households grew also due to rapid growth of exemptions for big industry (€4bn) • Also because merit-order savings (PV + wind displace expensive fossil generation) were not passed on to households+SMEs. Paradox:Lower wholesale prices due to RP growth increase “extra cost” of RP to households, SMEs • Ignores external costs of and subsidies to conventional power (see next slide, also 2015 IMF study) 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 31 From Lauber and Jacobsson (2015) PV 2015 8-12 1.18 0.4 11.58 Figure: 1: German PV FITs from January 2004 to October 2013 Bernard Chabot (2013) Diversity in PV Systems Sizes and Market Deployment Management from Prices: Two Strategic Lessons from the German PV Policy and Measures. P. 1. Available at: http://cf01.erneuerbareenergien.schluetersche.de/files/smfiledata/3/0/3/4/9/9/TwoStrategicLessons. pdf, 09.09.2013. 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 33 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 34 Instruments for slowing growth, reducing costs and re-empowering corporate actors • EEG 2014: Reducing targets + tariffs, setting caps for each technology (flexible for PV since 2010; absolute by 2017 with tender system?) • By 2017: Change to new type of support system: tendering/bidding system, as in European Commission (2014) guidelines • Favours incumbents, other corporate actors 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 35 Goals nearly unchanged since 2010 (not increased as in past) • Goal: 80% renewable power by 2050, set in 2010 when nuclear phase-out was postponed. Then this was a minimum target; 2014 a cap • But at EU level, the German government presses for binding 2030 targets, though still modest ones (30% for all renewable energy) • Currently govt. hesitates to openly put coal phase-out on its agenda 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 36 Part 4: UK policies 2008-2015: Contradictory developments • 2008-10: Strong stimulation of RP growth by banded RO and “German-style” FITs, leads to near-tripling of RP generation in 2010-14 • Since 2010, Cameron govt. formulates new policy (CfD) to privilege nuclear power: Bidding for subsidies • Simultaneously, govt. plans to terminate banded RO and perhaps FIT by 2016 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 37 Britain 2008-2015 Zig-zag policies? • 2008-2010: Reforming RO and introducing FITs almost triples deployment in four years (slide), increases spending, raises ambitions (30% by 2030 • But more or less U-turn with Electricity Market Reform since 2011: Reform stretches FITs with Contracts for Difference (CfD), a method to allocate subsidies by auction for all “lowcarbon” - to support nuclear (Hinkley Pt C) and CCS generation. 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 38 End of RO in 2016. And also of FIT? • Banded RO is successful, achieves high growth; terminated “because too expensive” • FIT tariff benefits above all solar PV: About 8 GW installed by 3rd quarter of 2015 by some 800.000, mostly small investors. • In summer 2015, DECC announced the end of FITs for onshore wind and strong reductions for biomass and (by 60-70%) for PV by 2016 (new PV FIT: 1.03 to 1.63 pence) 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 39 UK position in EU with Cameron • UK reverts to its old position: At EU level, it opposes binding and ambitious (beyond 27%) 2030 targets for member states. Cost argument credible? (given special treatment for Hinkley Point C) • Allies with Poland, Czech Republic to hold down EU targets for renewables • Pleads for more use of gas (Shell intervention with EU in 2013), slowdown for renewables • CfD fit 2014 EU State aid guidelines for energy 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 40 Electricity generation from renewable sources in the United Kingdom, 2000-2014 Source: Department of Energy & Climate Change (2015) UK Energy in Brief 2015, p.30, https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/449067/UK_Energy_ in_Brief_2015.pdf. 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 41 Feed in Tariffs in the United Kingdom, 2011 to 2015 Source: Department of Energy & Climate Change (2015) UK Energy in Brief 2015, p.28, https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/449067/UK_Energy_in_Brief_2015.pdf. 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 42 Part 5: European Union politics and policy on renewable power • Political controversy extended above all to definition of “renewable energy” (nuclear? waste?), targets, support schemes, and state aid guidelines • Outcomes are codified in -Renewable Energy Directive 2001/77/EC, -Renewable Energy Directive 2009/28/EC, -State aid guidelines on environment/energy, most recently from 2014 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 43 Transformation in EU-28 is much slower than in UK or Germany • Renewable power generation doubled between 2002 and 2012 (next slide) • Phase-out of generation from fuel oil, coal and nuclear started (upcoming slide), but fossil/nuclear resistance hardened since 2010 • Post-2010 EU policy is to go slow on renewables deployment (“Europe alone cannot save the world” – Oettinger) 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 44 Share of renewable electricity in EU-28, 2002-2012 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 22.03.2016 45 Source: SolarPower Europe Global Market Outlook (2015), http://www.solarpowereurope.org/fileadmin/user_upload/documents/Publications/Global_Market_Outlook_2015_-2019 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 46 Biggest controversies over choice of support instruments and targets • Before first (2001) RP Directive: Effort by European Commission to push through quota cum tradable certificate scheme (such as RO)and to ban FITs; founders in Parl. and Council • Before 2nd (2009) RP Directive: Similar Commission effort, fails again • 2013-14: Similar Commission effort to phase out FITs by backdoor of state aid guidelines; legality still controversial (is before Court) 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 47 Different philosophies and interests • Stimulate RP growth via “competition by incumbents” (UK most of the time, EU Commission, EURELECTRIC) or via supporting technological learning and innovation? • Rapid shift to RP power to limit global warming (Denmark, Germany,…) or slow shift nursing existing fossil and nuclear generation (UK most years, power incumbents, Poland, Czech Rep., some other Eastern Europeans) • Physical trade of RP or just certificate trade? 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 48 Conflict over Dir. 2001/77/EC • Energy Commissioner Papoutsis tried to push through a quota cum tradable certificates model, similar to later RO. Sends emissaries to EU capitals (governments, utilities). Supports lawsuit challenging German FIT. • Met with strong resistance from renewable power assoc. (exc. British and Danish wind power), Parliament, German and Spanish governments 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 49 …2001/77/EC • Commission resigns, de Palacio is new energy commissioner. Submits a draft proposal (=bill) that leaves choice of support up to member states (“subsidiarity”), but they respect state aid and internal market provisions - opens back door challenge to FIT • However, Court in PreussenElektra vs. Schleswag rejects COM argument that FIT are state aid or violating internal market 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 50 Conflict over Dir. 2009/28/EC … • Comparative studies of quota systems (UK, IT, BE, PL) and FIT (most other member states) show greater efficiency and effectiveness of FIT – issue appears settled in favour of free choice of support system by member states • But in 2007 attempt by certificate trading advocates in COM (=neoliberals, UK) to introduce a trading mechanism “so that small states” (UK?) “can meet now binding quotas” 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 51 … Dir. 2009/28/EC … • Renew. power stakeholders claim this would destroy FITs, energy commissioner Piebalgs grants them a hearing • Result: Opt-outs from trading mechanism are introduced into proposal • Legal experts “discover” that opt-outs would not hold up in Court • Certificate trading advocates concede defeat 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 52 …Dir. 2009/28/EC • Commissioner Piebalgs stands by as Parliam. and Council negotiate a new version (unusual given the Commission’s exclusive right to legislative initative). • Green MEP Turmes and Council led by core group formed by UK(!) /Poland /Germany negotiate new bill: free choice of support system plus ”non-trading flexibility” to satisfy target fulfilment anxieties of small countries • 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 53 Commission (2014) guidelines on state aid to energy – new attempt • These guidelines require bidding, ban FIT from future support schemes except for small installations (1 MW for PV, 6MW for wind), • This will inhibit decentralised energy transition by motivated citizens, many SMEs • Likely to give electr. incumbents and other corporate actors a new chance to take over the renewables business – and to keep it small 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 54 2014 state aid guidelines • European Renewable Energy Foundation has challenged guidelines in Court for violating renewable energy directive 2009/28/EC, which is valid until 2020 • But no political resistance from member state governments so far since Germany accepted Commission view (this was different with similar, earlier COM efforts) 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 55 Legal nature of guidelines • In theory, these guidelines only inform on criteria that Commission will apply when accepting/rejecting national support schemes (not a legislative document) • In practice, they influence the formulation of national support schemes -> deter FITs and thus small investors and SMEs, the most motivated group so far and favouring decentralised transition 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 56 EU falling behind on renewables and climate action? • Europe has played a big role in promoting renewable power until 2010, building up the first renewable energy industry • But COM unable (unwilling?) to build a truly European RP sector, preferring liberalisation • Since 2010, resistance from fossil/nuclear incumbents slows deployment dynamic • COM accepted their claims that renewables are competitive already and that high costs of support endangers EU competitiveness 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 57 EU now falling behind on renewables and climate action (2) • That is likely result of the 2014 COM guidelines on state aid to energy • Renewable power now does better in highgrowth developing countries without entrenched fossil/nuclear incumbents and without an Emissions Trading System (which in the EU practically ignores climate costs – lately €5-10/t of CO2 instead of about €80 – UBA estimate 2012, Alberici et al., 2014. 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 58 WWF/Lichtblick (2015) Megatrends der globalen Energiewende, http://www.energiewendebeschleunigen.de/fileadmin/fm-wwf/lichtblick/Megatrends-der-globalen-Energiewende.pdf 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 59 Current policy intensifying upcoming shocks? The likely result of EU slowdown for RP and its protection of fossil power:: • Higher impact on climate –more costs borne by future generations (Stern report) • EU may lose /has lost its leadership in RP industry - China and other regions caught up • Even bigger shock likely to hit EU’s big utilities once cheaper+cleaner+simpler sources defeat utilities’ efforts at holding them at bay. Will incumbents survive that? 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 60 Merit order effects explained by sfv (Solarenergieförderverein) • The following slides (62 to 73) are taken from a presentation by SFV (updated versions can be found on its homepage: www.sfv.de) 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 61 HowEs wind-generated gibt im electricity reduces theviel price of Binnenland mehr Flächen für power at the electricity die Windenergie exchange als notwendig! 62 62 Price per kWh 32 cent Different generators have different costs, are dispatched in merit order (lowest cost first) until demand is satisfied. Red line shows where demand is cut off 27 cent 18 cent 11 cent 3 cent 3,5 cent Demand 4 cent Volume of electricity generated 63 63 Not sold Price 18 cent volume demand 64 64 Price Price of the electricity exchange applies to all 18 Profit 15 cent 3 cent volume Demand 65 65 Price 18 cent Profits of onventional z.B. für electricity Atomgenerators kraftwerk Price bids of generators volume Demand 66 66 Preis Purchasing price of suppliers Strommenge Nachfrage 67 67 price Wind power fed into grid reduces demand for conventional electricity 18 Profits of conventional generators volume demand Wind power 68 68 price What has to be paid for wind power? 18 Feed-in tariff 4 volume Demand Wind power 69 69 price 18 4 Purchasing price for conv. electricity Plus cost for wind power Feed-in tariff volume Demand Windpower 70 70 price 18 Savings from wind power= lower profits of conventional generators 4 Purchasing price of convent. plectr. Plus costs for wind power Feed-in tariff volume Demand Wind power 71 71 price 18 4 Savings due to wind power Savings of suppliers= lost profits for conven-tional Cost of generators price conventional gen. wind power volume Demand Wind power 72 72 Result: Conventional generators do not like wind generators 73 73 Main references • Jacobsson and Lauber (2006) on Germany: The politics and policy of energy system transformation, Energy Policy 34:3, 256-276 • Lauber and Jacobsson (2015) on Germany: The politics and economics of constructing, contesting and restricting sociopolitical space for renewables, Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions, in press. • Lauber and Schenner (2011) on EU: The struggle over support schemes for renewable electricity in the EU, Environmental Politics 20:4, 508-527. • Lauber (2012) on UK-Germany comparison: Wind Power Policy in Germany and the UK, in Szarka et al., Learning from Wind Power, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. 22.03.2016 Volkmar Lauber/Canada 74