AN EMPIRICAL STUDY ON THE EXPECTATIONS HYPOTHESIS OF THE PHILIPPINE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES, THE BOND RISK PREMIUM, AND ITS MACROECONOMIC DETERMINANTS A Thesis Presented to the Faculty of the School of Economics University of Asia and the Pacific In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Master of Science in Industrial Economics By Ivy T. Zuñiga April 2015 © Ivy T. Zuñiga. 2015. All Rights Reserved. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS These words will never be enough to express my gratitude to the people who made this accomplishment worth remembering. This page is not a simple list of persons who are very dear to me, but a note for others to know how kindhearted and selfless these people are. They are my true inspirations. Above all, I humbly offer this work to our Lord. This is His more than mine. If not for His continuous graces and guidance, I would not have survived every trial and handled every success that came my way. He is the real source of my strength. To my adviser who (discreetly) treats me as his favorite student, Dr. Victor Abola, thank you for greatly believing in me. I’ve never felt so appreciated by a professor until you came along. You did not only share your academic expertise, but you taught me that hard work really does pay off. To the ever diligent and genuine Mr. Edwin Pineda, thank you for taking time to read and study my thesis. I know that you’ve had a hard time understanding my seemingly “abstract” topic, but your eagerness and enthusiasm towards my work encouraged me to keep the discussion simple and sweet. I have learned from you that equations will be senseless if their worth are not explicitly explained. To my patient and cheerful external reader, Mr. Reynaldo Montalbo, Jr., thank you for imparting your expertise as a practitioner in the field. I am grateful for the persistent effort to improve my work by allowing me to present the thesis to the FMIC traders. That opportunity was a memorable one, and I will forever be thankful for introducing me to the “real world”. To Ms. Jovi Dacanay, my professional mentor, even though we rarely had our mentoring sessions in my last year in the University, I have always kept your pieces of advice close to my heart. Your motherly instincts toward us are wellvalued because we have understood that you only want what’s best for us and for the Industrial Economics Program. To the most loved fathers of the School of Economics: Dr. U, Dr. Terosa, Dr. Manzano, and Sir Perry, thank you for taking good care of the Industrial Economics Program. You are living proofs that the School of Economics is, indeed, the best choice we’ve ever made. Your simple “How are you?” and support to our education mean so much to us. To the other Industrial Economics Program Staff and School of Economics Faculty, thank you for sharing your warm greetings and sweet smiles whenever we enter the SEC Faculty room. Even though we, thesis writers, take up your working space and add unnecessary noise in the office, especially during break times, we are still thankful for the service you provide us and for facilitating things well for the students of IEP. You are the reasons why the SEC continues to prosper all these years. To my best friends, the IEP fifths, namely: Chela, Jose, Rey, Mon, Keren, Sarmie, Apple, Jo, Rige, Keng, Francis, Mar, German, Rose, Althea, Raf, Rap, and Lyndon, you are the best reasons why I cherished my college life. I look forward to each day, not to solely work on my thesis, but to see you, listen to your unique stories, and just laugh to even the pettiest things. You bring out the cheerfulness and optimism in me (even though I was sometimes rude to you, guys… Sorrryyy). As we part ways, let’s not forget each other and always try our best to catch up. I will surely miss you and our bonding moments, but I shall look forward to the day we meet each other again – with our dreams with us. To my Chocoholics family back in Naga: Meg, Charm, Micah, Jenoi, Beno, Camcam, Lala, Nille, Cathoi, and Rizza, you did not cease to be my constant confidants even though I am 8 hours away from you. I always get touched when you tell me you’re excited to see me in our reunions and anniversaries, and I always get crushed inside when I tell you I can’t be there because of school requirements. But now, I shall make it a point to spend my vacation with you, guys. We shall have our legendary hang outs – like in our high school days. To my family and relatives, thank you for being there no matter what. I would not be the person that I am if not for the upbringing you provided me. Remember that all of the fruits of my labor are because of you and for you. To my second family, my Balanghai and Capinpin friends, you are the best favors I received from God. You have been my closest sisters – my home away from home – and I will always be grateful for the love and concern. Thank you for watching over me and making sure that I always have that smile on my face. Your overflowing prayers lifted me up but your sincerity kept my feet on the ground. And lastly, to my UA&P friends: Sabio, Peer Facilitators, University Student Government (USG) 2013-2014, and the Business Economics Association (BEA), thank you for making my stay in the University the best so far. I have always told others that my best decision yet was to go to UA&P, but I think that you made my decision even more fulfilling. Your friendships kept me sane amidst the tons of academic work. I have learned so much from you and our experiences together will forever stay in my heart. All I can say is, I am blessed to have met all of you. For all of these, I could not ask for more. Indeed, this thesis is an answered prayer. The experience was heaven sent – just like the people in these pages. TABLE OF CONTENTS Page Acknowledgments List of Tables List of Figures Executive Summary x xi xii CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION A. Background of the Study B. Statement of the Problem C. Objectives of the Study D. Significance of the Study E. Scope and Limitations F. Definition of Terms 1 1 7 8 8 10 11 II REVIEW OF RELATED LITERATURE A. The Expectations Hypothesis 1. Term Spread Regression Models a) Derivation of Term Spread Regression Model for Projection of Long Rates b) Derivation of Term Spread Regression Model for Projection of Short Rates 2. Forward Spread Regression Models B. Empirical Tests of the Expectations Hypothesis 1. Term Spread Regression Results 2. Forward Spread Regression Results 3. Why the Expectations Hypothesis Tests Failed C. Bond Risk Premium 1. Estimating the Bond Risk Premium a) Observable Proxy for the BRP b) Term Premium Specification Based on a Term Structure Model D. Macroeconomic Variables and the Bond Risk Premium 21 21 24 III THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK AND METHODOLOGY A. Theoretical Framework 1. Term Spread Model for Predicting Changes in the Short Rate 2. Term Spread Model for Predicting Changes in the Long Rate 24 25 26 27 28 31 34 36 38 38 40 42 46 46 48 49 IV V 3. Model for Predicting Excess Holding Period Returns 4. Bond Risk Premium 5. Macroeconomic Factors and the Bond Risk Premium B. Conceptual Framework C. Empirical Methodology D. Data Requirements 50 52 53 63 63 72 RESULTS AND DISCUSSION A. Preliminary Analysis of Data B. Current Developments of the Philippine Bond Market 1. Size and Composition 2. Liquidity C. Expectations Hypothesis Testing using Term Spread Models D. Expectations Hypothesis Testing using Forward Spread Models E. Estimation of the Bond Risk Premium F. Macroeconomic Variables and the Bond Risk Premium 1. Whole Sample Test 2. Periodical Sample Test (Crisis and Post-Crisis Periods) 3. Short Rate Bond Risk Premium and Macroeconomic Variables 4. Long Rate Bond Risk Premium and Macroeconomic Variables G. Economic Implications of Macro-BRP Relationship 74 74 80 80 85 SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS, AND RECOMMENDATIONS A. Summary of Results and Conclusions B. Limits of the Study and Recommendations 89 94 97 105 107 108 110 112 116 124 124 131 APPENDIX A. Zero Coupon Bond Yields Obtained from the Bloomberg Terminal B. Data for Two-Period Case C. Data for N-Period Case D. Two-Period Case Term Spread Regression Model Results using HAC Newey-West Test E. N-Period Case Term Spread Regression Model Results using HAC Newey-West Test F. Computed Excess Holding Returns of Bond Yields under the Two-Period Case G. Computed Excess Holding Returns of Bond Yields under the N-Period Case 133 142 146 150 152 154 158 H. Term Spread Regression Model Results of Predicting Excess Bond Returns using HAC Newey-West Test (Two-Period and N-Period Case) I. Two-Period Case Forward Spread Regression Model Results using HAC Newey-West Test J. N-Period Case Forward Spread Regression Model Results using HAC Newey-West Test K. Forward Spread Regression Model Results of Predicting Excess Bond Returns using HAC Newey-West Test (Two-Period and N-Period Case) L. Term Spread Regression Model with Moving Average Bond Risk Premium Results using HAC Newey-West Test (Two-Period and N-Period Case) M. Term Spread Regression Model with Squared Excess Returns Bond Risk Premium Results using HAC NeweyWest Test (Two-Period and N-Period Case) N. Term Spread Regression Model with GARCHGenerated Standard Deviation Bond Risk Premium Results using HAC Newey-West Test (Two-Period and N-Period Case) O. Term Spread Regression Model with GARCHGenerated Variance Bond Risk Premium Results using HAC Newey-West Test (Two-Period and N-Period Case) P. Macroeconomic Variables for the Panel Regression Q. Results of the Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Whole Sample Case (All Variables & Selected Variables) R. Results of the Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Periodical Case (2006 to 2010 & 2011 to 2014) (All Variables & Selected Variables) S. Results of the Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Short Rate BRP and Long Rate BRP (2006 to 2014) (All Variables & Selected Variables) T. Results of the Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Short Rate BRP with Periodical Tests (All Variables & Selected Variables) U. Results of the Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Long Rate BRP with Periodical Tests (All Variables & Selected Variables) BIBLIOGRAPHY 162 165 167 169 172 175 178 181 184 188 189 191 193 195 197 LIST OF TABLES Table 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 Page McCallum’s Collection of Empirical Results, Change in Long Rates McCallum’s Collection of Empirical Results, Change in Short Rates Regressions of Change in the Spot Rate on the Forward Rate Spread Regressions of Change in the Spot Rate on Adjacent Forward Rates Explanatory Variables, Definitions, and Expected Relationship with BRP Correlations of Bond Yields Statistical Details of Bond Yields (Whole Sample & Subsamples) Term Spread Prediction of Future Changes in the Short Rate Term Spread Prediction of Future Changes in the Long Rate Term Spread Prediction of Excess Returns Forward Spread Prediction of Changes in Short Rate and Long Rate Forward Spread Prediction of Excess Returns Term Spread Prediction of Future Changes in the Short Rate with Bond Risk Premium Term Spread Prediction of Future Changes in the Long Rate with Bond Risk Premium Regression Results of Whole Sample Regression Results of Periodical Sample Regression Results of Short Rates (2006 to 2014) Regression Results of Short Rates (2006 to 2010 and 2011 to 2014) Regression Results of Long Rates (2006 to 2014) Regression Results of Long Rates (2006 to 2010 and 2011 to 2014) Summary of Macro-BRP Regressions x 29 31 32 33 61 75 77 91 92 93 95 96 101 103 108 110 111 112 114 116 123 LIST OF FIGURES Figure 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 Page Federal Funds Rates vs. 10-year Bond Yield During the Interest Rate Conundrum Decomposition of the 10-Year US Treasury Yield Philippine 91-Day T-Bills and 10-Year T-Bonds Risk & Return Tradeoff Principle Supply and Demand in the Money Market Framework for Real and Financial Markets Relationship of Macroeconomic Determinants of the Bond Risk Premium Conceptual Framework of the Study Summary of Methodologies of the Study 3-month to 10-year Monthly Bond Yields (2006 to 2014) Philippine Yield Curve (2006 to 2014) 3-month vs. 10-year Yield Spread (Yearly Average) Size of Philippine Bond Market in LCY Billions Size of Philippine Bond Market (% of GDP) Outstanding Bonds in Foreign Currency (Local Sources) Size of Bond Market of ASEAN +1 (% of GDP) (as of December 2014) Bills-to-Bond Ratio of the Philippines Bills-to-Bonds Ratio of ASEAN +3 (as of December 2014) Trading Volume of Philippine Government Bonds (2013 Average) Trading Volume of Government Bonds in the ASEAN Market +3 (2013 Average) Turnover Ratio of Philippine Government Bonds (Yearly Average) Bonds Turnover Ratio in ASEAN Market +4 (as of June 2013) Estimated Bond Risk Premium Using Moving Average Method Estimated Bond Risk Premium Using Squared Excess Returns Conditional Standard Deviation of Excess Returns from GARCH (1,1) Conditional Variance of Excess Returns from GARCH (1,1) xi 2 4 5 55 56 59 60 65 73 74 79 80 81 81 82 83 84 85 87 87 88 88 99 99 100 100 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY The Expectations Hypothesis (EH) is one of the main theories that explain the term structure of interest rates. It postulates that the yield curve is formed through investors’ expectations – such that the long rate is the simple average of the current short rate, the expected future short rates over the life of the long bond, and a risk premium. The traditional form of the EH assumes that the bond risk premium is constant or zero, making long-term rates purely based on the outlook of rational investors. Hence, the Expectations Hypothesis is also known as the Pure Expectations Hypothesis (PEH), Traditional Expectations Hypothesis (TEH), or the Rational Expectations Hypothesis (REH). More than a theoretical concept, the EH is a helpful framework used by academics, researchers, and financial analysts in further investigating the condition of a country’s interest rates. Common empirical tests are called term spread regression models, where the term spread (the difference between the long rate and the short rate) are used to predict changes in the short rates and long rates. A 𝛽 coefficient of 1 is required to confirm that a 1% change in the term spread would induce short rates and long rates to change by an equal magnitude. However, empirical tests performed by various authors (using data abroad), found out that the strict or pure form of the Expectations Hypothesis did not hold true. The resulting 𝛽 coefficients did not achieve the required values. For the short rates, 𝛽 values were significantly lower than 1, which implies that a 1% change in the term spread translates to a “less-than-1” change in the short rates. For the long rates, 𝛽 coefficients were significantly greater than 1 while some even reached xii negative values. This implies that a 1% change in the term spread induces long rates to increase by more than 1 or to decline. These results gained mixed explanations from authors. Some say that the errors came from inaccurate econometric treatments, while others comment that it is due to the overreaction of long rates to the current short rates. Among these explanations, the reason that gained the most attention from researchers is the exclusion of the bond risk premium (BRP) in the estimation of the EH. For them, the bond risk premium should not be zero or constant, but present and time-varying. Since the BRP is unobservable and cannot be directly measured, several studies have focused on various ways of estimating it, and then inputting these estimates into the EH regression tests to see if the results would improve. Due to the limited number of researches done on the Philippine term structure of interest rates, this thesis aimed to provide a benchmark study about the condition of the country’s interest rates in conformity with the requirements of the Expectations Hypothesis. This study is also motivated by the developing government debt market in the country, the growing importance of interest rates in investment and trading decisions, and the flourishing potential of the EH as a framework for monitoring interest rates. For the empirical tests, calculated Philippine zero coupon yields were used. The tests were divided into two based on McCallum’s study: the two-period case (which involves one-period bonds and two-period bonds) and the n-period case (which includes one-period bonds and bonds with maturities more than twoperiods). Term spread regression models were employed to test if Philippine bond xiii yields will satisfy the following conditions: 1) The term spread must perfectly predict changes in short rates; 2) The term spread must perfectly predict changes in long rates; and 3) The term spread must not forecast excess bond returns (as we are assuming a zero/constant bond risk premium). All of these will be achieved if the value of the 𝛽 coefficients appeared to be 1 for the first and second condition, and 0 for the third. Results of the tests show that Philippine bond yields do not conform to the implications of the Expectations Hypothesis. This is because the term spread did not “perfectly” forecast changes in the short rates and in the long rates. For the short rates, the term spread only predicted up to 52% of the changes in the short rate – such that for every 1% change in the term spread, short rates may only change by 0.52%. The tests on the long rates, on the other hand, produced negative 𝛽 values, signaling a fall on the long rates when the term spread increases. Moreover, the term spread was able to predict excess bond returns (as the 𝛽 values were not zero). This suggests that the bond risk premium may not really be zero (as required by the EH). All of these findings point to the rejection of the Expectations Hypothesis. Due to the failure of the EH tests, this study readily assumed (as suggested also by various literature) that the distortion came from the exclusion of a timevarying bond risk premium in the term spread regression models. Hence, the bond risk premium for the Philippine bond yields was estimated. The BRP can be modeled using proxies for risk, and to represent risk, interest rate volatility was measured. Three different measures of volatility were obtained as adopted from the study of Boero and Torricelli (2000). These are the: 1) moving average of absolute xiv changes in the short rate over the previous six periods; 2) square of expected excess holding period return; and estimates of conditional standard deviations and variances from the univariate GARCH (Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity) (1,1) model. The BRP values obtained from each estimation technique were inputted into the term spread regression models and their effects were evaluated using goodnessof-fit tests by Gujarati (2011). These are the Adjusted R2, F-statistic, Akaike Information Criterion (AIC), and Schwarz Information Criterion (SIC). The Adjusted R2 and F-statistic must have large values for they are measuring the significance of the variables in explaining the dependent variable, whereas the AIC and SIC represent estimates of information loss so lower values are needed. The improvement of the 𝛽 coefficients were also considered. From the three proxies of the BRP, the GARCH-generated conditional variances were deemed to be the best BRP estimates for the short rates, while the GARCH-generated conditional standard deviations best fitted the BRP of the long rates. This is because of the large Adjusted R2 and F-statistic values and the least AIC and SIC values they generated from the regression tests. For the short rates, the GARCH-generated conditional variances increased the 𝛽 values of the term spread by a couple of points while improving the predictive power of the model. For the long rates, the GARCH-generated standard deviations made the 𝛽 coefficients positive (from their previously negative values) and the model’s predictive power also increased. Even though the 𝛽 values were not exactly 1, the resulting 𝛽 coefficients from the regression tests still signify that the term xv spread can be a powerful tool in forecasting changes in interest rates. The resulting positive 𝛽 values from the regression tests signal increases of interest rates for an increase in the term spread. Hence, it would be safe to assume that when long rates rise, short rates may also increase; and short rates may fall when long rates decline. The next objective of the study is to identify the various macroeconomic variables that significantly influence the estimated BRP. Several economic data and some yield indicators were used as explanatory variables of the BRP. These were the: Meralco sales (as a proxy for economic growth), Philippine inflation, pesodollar rate, money supply (M2), OFW remittances, BSP policy rate, US inflation, gross international reserves, federal funds rate, budget deficit as a percent of GDP, government debt as a percent of GDP, Philippine Stock Exchange Index, lagged values of the bond risk premium, and the spread of the bond pairs. The analyses was divided into crisis (2006 to 2010) and post-crisis (2011 to 2014) periods for both the short rate BRP and long rate BRP. Results show that world macroeconomic factors had more dominant effects on the BRP during the crisis periods. This finding highlights the vulnerability of the country’s financial system to global shocks during the global financial crisis. Some of these foreign variables are the gross international reserves, US inflation, and peso-dollar exchange rate. On one hand, for the post-crisis periods (2011 to 2014), the effect of foreign economic variables have died down and only domestic factors were observed to significantly influence the estimated BRPs. This only confirms the country’s increased resiliency against global shocks after the 2008 financial crisis. This may xvi be due to the intensified macroprudential measures implemented by the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP), so that players in the financial system may be cautious when undergoing risky deals. Large domestic savings from overseas Filipino workers (OFW) and business process outsourcing (BPO) remittances also fortified the country from external shocks. Additionally, it was also observed that among the explanatory variables, the most persistent predictors of the BRP are its lagged values (𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1)) and the bond spread. This denotes that investors or traders are highly sensitive to the past condition of bond rates and the relationship of long-term yields with short-term yields, more than economic factors. Investors closely watch the situation of the financial market in requiring respective BRPs, thus exhibiting the so called adaptive expectations (AE). This behavior hypothesizes that people form their current decisions from the direction of past data. Overall, the findings of the macro-BRP relationship tests imply that the country’s bond market have gained sufficient resistance from external shocks after the global financial crisis. The country has learned a lesson from its past, and in order to prevent any mistakes, it is doing its best to build up its defenses. A factor that may have contributed to this is the fact that the Philippine bond market is still relatively small and young compared to other developing nations. The government debt market is also less integrated into the international scene making it less affected by global macroeconomic variables. xvii Furthermore, it is noticed that unlike the interest rates of some developed countries such as the US, Philippine interest rates are very hard to predict. This observation strengthens the idea that that Philippine bond yields (especially, the short rates) are not yet strongly anchored on macroeconomic variables. This is the reason why the country must intensify researches about Philippine interest rates to develop an appropriate framework that investors and policymakers can rely on. Such effort would make interest-rate monitoring easier and estimation of interest rates and of the bond risk premium possible. Even though Philippine bond yields rejected the implications of the Expectations Hypothesis, the term spread regression tests still suggest that the slope of the yield curve may be an effective predictor of changes in short-term and longterm bond yields. Moreover, despite the fact that the relationship of the BRP and macroeconomic variables were not consistent through time, the tests still show that the estimated bond risk premium of the Philippines is, one way or another, related to some macroeconomic data. This is a good indication that the debt market is gradually being characterized by rational investor decisions. Thus, as the country’s bond market moves towards advancements and increased participation in the international arena, we can only hope for a more competitive and efficient debt system. xviii CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION A. Background of the Study The Expectations Hypothesis (EH) is one of the most explored theories when studying the term structure of interest rates. Basically, the EH asserts that long-term rates are determined by the movement of short-term rates, and vice-versa via expectations. This theory, therefore, suggests that investors cannot profitably exploit arbitrage opportunities between short rates and long rates because long rates and short rates are perfect substitutes. Academics and researchers have been very interested in the dynamics of the EH as evidenced by the numerous studies done on data abroad. Most of these studies came from developed countries such as US, Canada, UK, Germany, etc. This is because the study of the EH tells a lot about the real conditions of the financial market. One concrete phenomenon where the study of the EH proved most useful was during the advent of the so-called “interest rate conundrum” or “Greenspan’s conundrum” in the US from 2004 to 2006, which appears to be bothering the US economy at present. The interest rate conundrum pertains to the strange and unexpected plunge of long-term interest rates despite the increase of the Federal Funds Rate and improving economic conditions in the US. This occurrence baffled the economy because it went against one implication of the EH, which is the no-arbitrage principle. According to theory, an upward-sloping yield curve (i.e., long-term rates 1 are greater than short-term rates) must induce expected future short-term rates to rise in order to produce equal returns. Unfortunately, when the Fed (under the supervision of Alan Greenspan) increased its federal funds rate in 2004 from 1.0% to 5.25%, long maturity rates eventually fell.1 It was on August 2006 that 10-year bond yields at 4.88% were outperformed by the federal funds rate (which stayed at 5.25% for quite some time). With this, Greenspan failed to tighten credit and restrain excesses that contributed to the global financial crisis. 7 6 Percent 5 4 3 2 1 2000-01 2000-07 2001-01 2001-07 2002-01 2002-07 2003-01 2003-07 2004-01 2004-07 2005-01 2005-07 2006-01 2006-07 2007-01 2007-07 2008-01 2008-07 2009-01 2009-07 2010-01 2010-07 2011-01 2011-07 2012-01 2012-07 2013-01 2013-07 2014-01 2014-07 2015-01 0 Federal Funds Rate 10-Year Bond Yield Figure 1. Federal Funds Rates vs. 10-year Bond Yield During the Interest Rate Conundrum Source of Basic Data: Federal Reserve Bank of New York This might have arrived as a surprise to policymakers, but to some financial researchers and academics who have been studying the EH, the conundrum might have been predicted to happen soon. Earlier studies observed that real data did not conform to the empirical tests of the EH theory. Historical bond rates proved that Roger Craine and Vance Martin, “Interest Rate Conundrum” Coleman Fung Risk Management Research Center Working Papers 2 (2009): 1. 1 2 long rates are not purely the average of expected short rates. Hence, a rise in the long rates may not prompt an equal increase in future short rates, and vice-versa. Some studies even found out that the relationship can be negative at times – which implies a fall in the expected short rates even though the long rates are rising, and vice-versa. Findings of these papers showed that there is some distortion present in the data that needs to be incorporated into financial models to accurately satisfy the hypothesis. Several experimental methods have emerged to solve this puzzle, but most of them point to the distortion caused by the so-called bond risk premium (BRP). Ben Bernanke, in his speech in the Annual Monetary/Macroeconomics Conference in March 2013, pointed out that “the largest portion of the downward move in long-term interest rates since 2010 is due to a fall in the term premium”.2 Figure 2 shows that the BRP/term premium fell dramatically during the conundrum and even reaching negative after 2011. This may indicate that investors are confident enough that bonds would not be too vulnerable to interest rate risks. Bernanke enumerated two factors that may have contributed to the general downward trend of the term premium. These are the: 1) decline in the volatility of Treasury yields because of the zero-interest rate policy (and still expected to remain there for some time); and the 2) increasing negative correlation of bonds and stocks Ben Bernanke, “Long-Term Interest Rates” (online copy of speech, Annual Monetary/ Macroeconomics Conference: The Past and Future Monetary Policy, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, San Francisco, California, March 1, 2013) http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20130301a.htm (accessed April 4, 2015). 2 3 implying that bonds have become more valuable as a safe-haven instrument against risks than other assets. Figure 2. Decomposition of the 10-Year US Treasury Yield Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Why is a conundrum dangerous in the first place? Since short rates are difficult to manage there can be a possibility that an inverted yield curve may appear, such that the returns of short-term bonds exceed those of long-term bonds – which is a conventional indicator of a recession. An inverted yield curve suggests that market players are more willing to buy long-term instruments even if they receive a lower yield. Investors find the short-term state of the economy too risky to make investments, prompting a rise in the short-term rate due to increased inflation or increased term premium.3 According to an article, inverse Treasury yield curves had forecasted the recessions of 1981, 1991, 2000, and even the 2008 Gary North, “The Yield Curve: The Best Recession Forecasting Tool” Gary North’s Specific Answers, http://www.garynorth.com/public/department81.cfm (accessed April 4, 2015) 3 4 financial crisis.4 Because of such forecasting power, the yield curve and its underlying assumptions must be studied and closely monitored so that anomalies (or even recessions at worst) in the financial market may be prevented. In the case of the Philippine interest rates, an interest rate conundrum has not happened yet. Figure 3 shows that since 1991, long-term bonds are still greater than short-term bonds. Moreover, yield curves are still concave upwards. All of these still point to a relatively healthy and normal financial system. 20 18 16 Percent 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 1999M01 1999M08 2000M03 2000M10 2001M05 2001M12 2002M07 2003M02 2003M09 2004M04 2004M11 2005M06 2006M01 2006M08 2007M03 2007M10 2008M05 2008M12 2009M07 2010M02 2010M09 2011M04 2011M11 2012M06 2013M01 2013M08 2014M03 2014M10 0 91-Day T-Bills 10-Year T-Bonds Figure 3. Philippine 91-Day T-Bills and 10-Year T-Bonds Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, Philippine Dealing Systems (PDS) Nonetheless, the “normality” of the movement of interest rates should not be a reason for researchers and policymakers to become complacent about the market. Besides, the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP) has not been very detailed about its framework when it comes to monitoring the rates of the debt market since it is highly focused on inflation targeting. Hence, the BSP may not have the Kimberly Amadeo, “How an Inverted Yield Curve Predicts a Recession,” about news, http://useconomy.about.com/od/glossary/g/Inverted_yield.htm (accessed April 4, 2015). 4 5 appropriate paradigm to tackle interest rate gyrations since the country has not experienced an interest rate conundrum. But, what if an interest rate conundrum in the Philippines happens? How would the BSP, the market participants, and the overall financial market reach to it? In the first place, are Philippine interest rates even vulnerable to such a conundrum? For us to find out, empirical tests on the term structure of interest rates must primarily be done, specifically anchored on a theory that explains the relationship of short rates and long rates or perhaps a framework that incorporates the estimation of the bond risk premium. The theory that has the implications closest to these topics is the Expectations Hypothesis (EH). However, the abundance of literature on the empirical tests of the EH on data abroad comes in stark contrast with the Philippine case. As far as the EH is concerned, no basic and focused studies have been done yet on the Philippine term structure of interest rates. Perhaps, the value of doing a study on the EH has not been emphasized yet for developing countries like ours. Nevertheless, it is worth noting that a study on the EH is not only useful to policymakers as a framework for monitoring the condition of the domestic interest rates, but also to investors as a guide for making the right decisions when trading in the free market. On this ground, it is essential to provide a benchmark study using Philippine data that other researchers can develop on. This thesis, therefore, aims to perform the basic econometric tests of the Expectations Hypothesis on Philippine domestic interest rates using bond rates. Knowing that the financial market is not frictionless, and that the Philippine bond 6 market is not as efficient as in developed countries, it is hypothesized in this study that distortions would be present. This would allow empirics to dissatisfy the theory and thus, an estimation of the bond risk premium is necessary. The same tests are replicated to assess if the BRP indeed plays a major role in the relationship of the EH and the term structure of interest rates. Lastly, macroeconomic factors affecting the BRP are identified to highlight the interconnectedness of elements within the financial system. But beyond all these, this study ultimately hopes to explore the implications of the results and findings on the bond market and interest rates of the country. B. Statement of the Problem Due to the abundance of literature on the Expectations Hypothesis (EH) of bond yields gained from developed countries, this study replicates the basic empirical studies of the EH using Philippine data. In order to learn more about the condition of the Philippine domestic interest rates with respect to the EH, the existence of the bond risk premium and its macroeconomic determinants, and their implications on the financial market, this research aims to answer the main question: 1. Do Philippine bond yields conform to the Expectations Hypothesis (EH) with the inclusion of an estimated bond risk premium (BRP)? 7 C. Objectives of the Study In order to answer the principal question of this study, the following objectives must be satisfied: 1. To empirically test the validity of the Expectations Hypothesis using Philippine bond yields; 2. To estimate the bond risk premium in the term structure of Philippine bond yields; 3. To assess if an estimated bond risk premium improves or does not improve the empirical tests done on the Expectations Hypothesis; 4. To identify the macroeconomic variables that influence the estimated bond risk premium; and 5. To determine the implications of the study’s findings on the Philippine bond market. D. Significance of the Study There are several reasons why this study should done. First and foremost, the Expectations Hypothesis (EH) can be cited as one of the core theories that explain the structure of interest rates. If there has been a limited study done on the Philippine term structure of interest rates and the EH, it is possible that the market’s knowledge about interest rates can still be inadequate. The findings of this study can, thus, shed light to new information on how Philippine interest rates perform under the assumptions of a theory. If the empirics were to reject the hypothesis, then sources of distortions can be identified from where recommendations or possible solutions can be aimed at. 8 Secondly, a deeper analysis of the Philippine bond rates can be useful from the perspective of policy-making or regulations when it comes to interest ratetargeting. In the case of the US, during the interest rate conundrum, the Federal Reserve did not expect that the strong link between the Federal Funds rate has apparently weakened, therefore failing to manipulate long-term rates via short-term nominal rates. If only researchers were able to communicate their findings that long-term rates were not as reactive to short-term rates or that the relationship of the two are negative, the Fed could have mitigated the effects of the conundrum and helped save the financial system during the global crisis. In the same way, the EH can be a promising framework that the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP) or the Philippine Dealing Systems (PDS) Group can use when monitoring the movement of short rates and long rates or when utilizing monetary policy facilities. The outcomes of this study can signal any irregularity in the system that the BSP or PDS Group can consider to implement the optimal response needed. Lastly, the findings concerning the bond risk premium shall have substantial informational value to bond investors and traders. Results of the study can show if interest rates are only driven by market sentiment or if they move along other macroeconomic variables as stated by theory. Hence, investors and traders can be better informed whether they can use the EH as a model in taking their respective positions in the market whenever new macroeconomic data have surfaced. 9 E. Scope and Limitations This study aims to test the Expectations Hypothesis (EH) based on one of the widely used empirical methods. These are the term spread regression models. Forward spread regression models were also done to validate the results. Advanced studies have featured several versions of these models but due to the limited tenors of interest rates data we have in the Philippines, only McCallum’s (1994) EH models are considered.5 In the estimation of the bond risk premium (BRP), only interest rate volatility shall be considered as a proxy measure, as this thesis only aims to establish a baseline study of the theory. Volatility was estimated in three ways, which are the: 1) moving average of the short rate, 2) square of excess returns, and 3) simple univariate GARCH (1,1) model6 as replicated from the study of Boero and Torricelli (2000). The value estimates gained from the three methods shall represent the BRP for the respective long-term rates. Each of the estimated BRP were plugged into the term spread regression models and goodness-of-fit criteria were used to select the best BRP proxy. Several macroeconomic variables that are hypothesized to affect the BRP were also be included in the analysis to pinpoint which macroeconomic data have significant (positive or negative) relationships with the BRP. These are electricity sales (as a proxy for economic growth), inflation, peso-dollar exchange rate, excess liquidity, OFW remittances, monetary stance, federal funds rate, budget deficit (as 5 See Chapter 2 and Chapter 3 for further elaboration about the models used in the study. See Definition of Terms and Chapter 3 for an elaboration of the univariate GARCH (1,1) method. 6 10 % of GDP), government debt (as % of GDP), stock market activity, and gross international reserves. The lagged values of the estimated bond risk premium were also included, along with the bond spread. To simplify the testing of the EH, monthly yields of zero coupon bonds from 2006 to 2014 would be used for the tests and analyses of the study. Since the Philippines does not issue zero coupon bonds anymore, bond yields stripped off their coupon effects were obtained using Bloomberg’s time series of calculated zero coupon bond yields.7 The following bond tenors that will be included are: 3-month, 6-month, 1-year, 2-year, 3-year, 5-year, and 10-year. F. Definition of Terms ARIMA-GARCH ARIMA-GARCH stands for Autoregressive Integrated Moving Average – Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity, which is a combination of ARIMA process of data and GARCH model. A time series data is considered ARIMA (𝑝,𝑑,𝑞) when it has to be differenced 𝑑 times and then the ARMA (Autoregressive and Moving Average) model is applied to it – where 𝑝 denotes the number of autoregressive (AR) terms, 𝑑 denotes the number of times the series has to be differenced before it becomes stationary, and 𝑝 is the number of moving average (MA) terms. Thus, an ARIMA (2,1,2) time series has to be differenced once (𝑑 = 1) before it becomes stationary and the first-differenced stationary time series 7 Coupon bond yields can be manually stripped off their coupon effects using a method called bootstrapping. 11 can be modeled as an ARMA (2,2) process, that is, it has two AR terms and two MA terms.8 GARCH enters the picture when the error variance of the time series data is related to the squared error terms several periods in the past. This model can have the GARCH (𝑝,𝑞) model in which there are 𝑝 lagged terms in the squared error term and 𝑞 terms of the lagged conditional variances.9 Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) Test ADF is a test for unit root in a time series data. This is also a statistical test for the stationarity or non-stationarity of the data. The usual rule is, if the probability value obtained from the test is less than 0.05, the null hypothesis (i.e., the data has unit root) must be rejected. Otherwise, the null hypothesis must be accepted. Bills-to-Bonds Ratio This measure was used by the Asian Development Bank (ADB) as an indicator of bond market size. This is calculated as: 𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝐵𝑖𝑙𝑙𝑠 𝑡𝑜 𝐵𝑜𝑛𝑑𝑠 𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜 = 𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝑂𝑢𝑡𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔 𝐺𝑜𝑣𝑒𝑟𝑛𝑚𝑒𝑛𝑡 𝐵𝑖𝑙𝑙𝑠 𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝑂𝑢𝑡𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔 𝐺𝑜𝑣𝑒𝑟𝑛𝑚𝑒𝑛𝑡 𝐵𝑜𝑛𝑑𝑠 where bills pertain to government securities of 1 year or less in maturity while bonds pertain to government securities of more than 1 year in 8 Damodar Gujarati, Basic Econometrics: International Edition (New York: McGraw-Hill, 2003), 840. 9 Damodar Gujarati, Basic Econometrics: International Edition (New York: McGraw-Hill, 2003), 862. 12 maturity. This also gives a hint if a country’s bond market is characterized by short maturity bonds or long maturity bonds.10 Bond Pairs This pertains to the pairing of a short rate and a long rate for the regression models of the Expectations Hypothesis. The following bond pairs are as follows: 3-month and 6-month bonds, 6-month and 1-year bonds, 1-year and 2-year bonds, 1-year and 3-year bonds, 1-year and 5-year bonds, and 1year and 10-year bonds. Bond Risk Premium (BRP) According to Ilmanen (2012), the bond risk premium refers to the return advantage of long-term bonds over short-term bonds. It is also known as the compensation for risk that investors require in investing in long-term bonds than short-term bonds. In this study, the bond risk premium was measured by using the volatility of interest rates as a proxy. This implies that the more volatile a certain bond is, the riskier it is, hence, a higher risk premium is needed. Alternatively, the less volatile a certain bond is, the less risky it is, hence, a lower risk premium is required. Three measures of bond risk premium were done in this paper. These are the: 1) moving average of the 1) moving average of the short rate, 2) square of excess returns, and 3) univariate GARCH (1,1) generated measures of “Bills-to-Bonds Ratio,” Asian Bonds Online, http://asianbondsonline.adb.org/philippines/data/bondmarket.php?code=Bills_Bonds_Ratio_Total (accessed April 5, 2015). 10 13 conditional standard deviations and conditional variances from the study of Boero and Torricelli (2000). Bond Turnover Ratio This measure was used as an indicator of liquidity in the bond market by the ADB. This is computed using the formula: 𝐵𝑜𝑛𝑑𝑠 𝑇𝑢𝑟𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑒𝑟 𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜 = 𝑉𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒 𝑜𝑓 𝑏𝑜𝑛𝑑𝑠 𝑡𝑟𝑎𝑑𝑒𝑑 𝐴𝑣𝑒𝑟𝑎𝑔𝑒 𝑎𝑚𝑜𝑢𝑛𝑡 𝑜𝑓 𝑜𝑢𝑡𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑠𝑖𝑛𝑔 𝑏𝑜𝑛𝑑𝑠 The average amount of outstanding bonds is equal to the average amount at the end of the previous and current quarters. The higher the turnover ratio, the higher is the liquidity of the secondary bonds market.11 Bond Yields/Bond Returns This figure refers to the return that an investor gets on a bond which usually refers to yield-to-maturity, or the total return that one will receive if the bond is held to maturity. In this study, however, zero-coupon bond yields were used. The term “bond yield” was used interchangeably with “bond return” in this study. Correlogram Specification This is a graphical and numerical display of autocorrelation statistics of time series data. It is also a diagnostic test to determine if a certain time series data has unit root or are non-stationary. It is also known as Autocorrelation Function (ACF). If the ACF value is within the 95% confidence interval, then there is sufficient statistical evidence for the null hypothesis to be “Bonds Turnover Ratio,” Asian Bonds Online, http://asianbondsonline.adb.org/philippines/data/bondmarket.php?code=Bond_turn_ratio (accessed April 5, 2015). 11 14 rejected. This means that the data do not have unit root or are stationary. Otherwise, the data are non-stationary. Covariance This is a measure of co-movement between two variables. A positive covariance means that two variables move together while a negative covariance means that the variables move in opposite directions. The formula for covariance is:12 ∑𝑛𝑖=1(𝑥𝑖 − 𝑥̅ )(𝑦𝑖 − 𝑦̅) 𝐶𝑂𝑉(𝑥, 𝑦) = 𝑛−1 where: 𝑦 = dependent variable 𝑥 = independent variable 𝑛 = number of data points in the sample 𝑦̅ = mean of dependent variable 𝑦 𝑥̅ = mean of independent variable 𝑥 Excess Bond Returns/Excess Holding Period Returns Excess bond returns pertains to the return on a long-term bond relative to the return on a short-term bond (risk-free investment). This paper adopted the definition of excess bond returns or excess holding return by Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller (1986). The excess bond returns is expressed as: 𝐸𝐻𝑅 = 𝐻𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡 “Statistical Sampling and Regression: Covariance and Correlation,” PreMBA Analytical Methods, https://www0.gsb.columbia.edu/premba/analytical/s7/s7_5.cfm (accessed April 17, 2015). 12 15 where: 𝑟𝑡 ≡ short-term bond yield 𝐻𝑡 ≡ holding period return 𝐻𝑡 was calculated as: 𝐻𝑡 ≈ 𝑅𝑡 − 𝑅𝑡+1 − 𝑅𝑡 𝜕 where: 𝑅𝑡 ≡ long-term bond yield at the current period 𝑅𝑡+1 ≡ long-term bond yield at the next period 𝜕 ≡ constant equal to the average long-term yield Fixed Effects Panel Regression Fixed effects is one of the specifications used when doing a panel regression. A panel dataset contains observations on multiple entities (individuals), wherein each entity is observed at two or more pints in time.13 This was used in the regression tests for the macroeconomic determinants of the BRP. The fixed effects method was used, as opposed to the random effects model, because we would want to take into account the time-variant nature of the explanatory variables. The random effects specification is used only when the effects of time-invariant variables should be included. Forward Rates Forward rates are the rates applicable to a financial transaction that will happen in the future. In the context of bonds, they are calculated to “Regression with Panel Data” http://www.econ.brown.edu/fac/Frank_Kleibergen/ec163/ch10_slides_1.pdf (accessed April 25, 2015). 13 16 determine future yields. For example, an investor can either purchase a oneyear Treasury bill and hold it to maturity, or purchase a six-month T-bill and buy another six-month bill once the former matures. Under the principle of no-arbitrage, the investor will be indifferent between the two choices. The spot rate of the one-year and six-month bonds will be known, but the value of the six-month bill purchased six months from now shall be unknown. Given the six-month and 1-year spot rates though, the forward rate on a six-month bill can be computed. It is the rate that equalizes the return between two types of investment tenors.14 Forward Spread This refers to the difference between the forward rate of a long rate and the forward rate of a short rate used for the forward spread regression models – an alternative test of the Expectations Hypothesis done to validate and compare with the results of the term spread regression models. Kurtosis This is a statistical measure that describes the variability of data around the mean. A high kurtosis depicts a graph with fat tails signifying an even-out data distribution, whereas a low kurtosis portrays a graph with skinny tails indicating that the distribution is concentrated around the mean. It is also called as the “volatility of volatility”.15 Kurtosis, in this study, was used to describe the condition of the bond yields before, during, and after the global “Forward Rate” Investopedia, http://www.investopedia.com/terms/f/forwardrate.asp (accessed April 4, 2015). 15 “Kurtosis,” Investopedia, http://www.investopedia.com/terms/k/kurtosis.asp (accessed April 5, 2015). 14 17 financial crisis. Conventionally, higher kurtosis values appeared during the crisis years signifying the high level of volatility and risk present. N-Period Case This pertains to the term spread regression model done by McCallum (1994) on bonds with maturities more than two periods. The following bond pairs were used for the n-period case regression tests: 1-year and 3-year, 1-year and 5-year, and 1-year and 10-year. One-Period Bond This refers to the yield of a bond held for one period. In this study, the following bond tenors were considered under the classification of a oneperiod bond: 3-month bond, 6-month bond, and 1-year bond. Skewness Skewness is also a statistical measure that describes the location of data, which can be symmetrical or non-symmetrical. In the case of investment returns, non-symmetrical or skewed distributions are more common – which can be positively skewed or negatively skewed. Positively skewed distributions (or long right tails) meant frequent small losses and a few extreme gains or that extremely bad scenarios are unlikely to happen. Negatively skewed distributions (or long left tails), on the other hand, meant frequent small gains and a few extreme losses or greater chance for extremely negative outcomes.16 “Quantitative Methods – Skew and Kurtosis,” Investopedia, http://www.investopedia.com/exam-guide/cfa-level-1/quantitative-methods/statistical-skewkurtosis.asp (accessed April 5, 2015). 16 18 Term Spread This refers to the difference between the bond pairs or the difference between a long rate and a short rate used for the term spread regression models in testing the Expectations Hypothesis. Trading Volume This was also used as an indicator of bond market liquidity by the ADB. This pertains to the total traded value of local government bonds in the secondary market in US dollars.17 Two-Period Bond This refers to the yield of a bond held for two periods, which is usually twice that of the period of one-period bonds. Hence, two-period bonds in this study are the 6-month bond, 1-year bond, and 2-year bond. Two-Period Case This pertains to the term spread regression models done by McCallum (1994) on one-period bonds and two-period bonds. The following bond pairs were used for the two-period case regression tests: 3-month and 6month, 6-month and 1-year, and 1-year and 2-year. Univariate GARCH (1,1) Model GARCH stands for Generalized AutoRegressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity. This econometric technique is commonly used to model the volatility of some financial time series data. GARCH assumes that the “Trading Volume,” Asian Bonds Online, http://asianbondsonline.adb.org/philippines/data/bondmarket.php?code=Trading_Volume (accessed April 5, 2015). 17 19 variance of the error term (residual) is affected by its past values. Furthermore, the GARCH specification asserts that the best predictor of the variance in the next period is a weighted average of the long-run average variance, the variance predicted for this period, and the new information in this period that is captured by the most recent squared residual. Such an updating rule is a simple description of adaptive or learning behavior.18 For this study, the volatility of excess returns was estimated using the GARCH (1,1) model. This signifies that the excess returns might possess an ARCH (1) effect (current volatility of the residuals is affected by the previous residual) and a GARCH (1) effect (current volatility of the residuals is affected by its previous volatility). Zero Coupon Bonds These are also called pure discount bonds which are bonds that have been stripped off their coupons. They do not pay an interest during the life the bond but the payment of the interest and principal happens at the end of the bond’s maturity. According to some studies about the Expectations Hypothesis (EH), zero coupon bonds are used to simplify the testing of the term spread regression models. If zero coupon bonds are not available in one’s financial market, coupon bonds can be converted to zero coupon bonds via a process called bootstrapping. In this study, zero coupon Philippine bonds with different tenors were directly obtained using the Bloomberg terminal. Robert Engle, “GARCH 101: The Use of ARCH/GARCH Models in Econometrics”, Journal of Economic Perspectives 15 (2001), 159. 18 20 CHAPTER II REVIEW OF RELATED LITERATURE A. The Expectations Hypothesis The Expectations Hypothesis (EH) is one among the three major theories that try to explain the term structure of interest rates.19 The key assumption of this theory is that bonds, despite having different maturities, are “perfect substitutes”; hence, bonds’ expected returns are equal. In practice, “the expectations theory postulates that an investor can earn the same amount of interest by investing in a one-year bond today and rolling that investment into a new one-year bond after a year compared to buying a two-year bond today”.20 Munasib provided the following example to illustrate the no-arbitrage assumption of the EH:21 1. Buy $1 one-year bond (short bond) and buy another one-year bond upon maturity (also known as the Rolling Strategy) 2. Buy $1 of two-year bond and hold it (also known as the Maturity Strategy) 19 The term structure of interest rates shows the relationship of yields across various maturities. The graphical representation of it is called the yield curve. The two other theories that attempt to describe the yield curve are the Liquidity Preference Theory and Market Segmentation Theory which shall not be discussed in this paper. 20 “Expectations Theory,” Investopedia. http://www.investopedia.com/terms/e/expectationstheory.asp (accessed September 26, 2014) 21 Abdul Munasib, “Term Structure of Interest Rates: The Theories”, Econ 3313 – Handout 03, Middle Tennessee State University, http://raptor1.bizlab.mtsu.edu/sdrive/FMICHELLO/Fin%204910%20Options,%20Futures%20and %20other%20Derivatives/Extra%20Readings/Term%20structure%20of%20interest%20rates.pdf (accessed December 26, 2014). 21 For the EH, to hold true, Investment Strategy 1 must have an equal return with Investment Strategy 2. Consider the following notations: 𝐸𝑅1 ≡ expected return for Investment Strategy 1 or the Rolling Strategy 𝐸𝑅2 ≡ expected return for Investment Strategy 2 or the Maturity Strategy 𝑖𝑡 ≡ interest rate of a one-period bond at time t 𝑒 𝑖𝑖+1 ≡ expected interest rate of a one-period bond at time t+1 𝑖2𝑡 ≡ interest rate of a two-period bond at time t For Investment Strategy 1 (Rolling Strategy), the expected return is: 𝑒 𝐸𝑅1 = [(1 + 𝑖𝑡 ) + (1 + 𝑖𝑡 )𝑖𝑖+1 ]−1 𝑒 𝑒 𝐸𝑅1 = 𝑖𝑡 + 𝑖𝑖+1 + 𝑖𝑡 (𝑖𝑡+1 ) 𝑒 𝐸𝑅1 ≈ 𝑖𝑡 + 𝑖𝑖+1 𝑒 ) since 𝑖𝑡 (𝑖𝑡+1 ≅0 For Investment Strategy 2 (Maturity Strategy), the expected return is: 𝐸𝑅2 = [(1 + 𝑖2𝑡 ) + (1 + 𝑖2𝑡 )𝑖2𝑡 ] − 1 𝐸𝑅2 = 𝑖𝑡 + (𝑖2𝑡 )2 𝐸𝑅2 ≈ 2𝑖2𝑡 since (𝑖2𝑡 )2 ≅ 0 By EH, 𝑒 𝑖𝑡 + 𝑖𝑖+1 = 2𝑖2𝑡 𝑖2𝑡 = 𝑒 𝑖𝑡 + 𝑖𝑡+1 2 (Eq. 1) Equation 1 shows that the two-period interest rate must equal the average of the current short-term rate and the future short-term rate expected to hold over the two-period horizon. The same follows for a bond that is more than two-years in maturity, as shown in Equation 2. 22 𝑖𝑛𝑡 = 𝑒 𝑒 𝑒 𝑖𝑡 + 𝑖𝑡+1 + 𝑖𝑡+2 +⋯+ 𝑖𝑡+(𝑛−1) 𝑛 . (Eq. 2) Therefore, if the current short-term rate changes, so will the long-term rates. Thus, the EH also posits that “interest rates for different maturities tend to move together over time”.22 In summary, the EH asserts that 1 𝑚 𝑛,𝑚 𝑟𝑡𝑛 = ( ) ∑𝑘−1 𝑖=0 𝐸𝑡 𝑟𝑡+𝑚𝑖 + 𝜃 𝑘 (Eq. 3) where: 𝑟𝑡𝑛 ≡ long-term (n-period) rate 𝑟 𝑚 ≡ short-term (m-period) rate 𝑛 𝑘 = 𝑚 ≡ is an integer 𝜃 𝑛,𝑚 ≡ term-specific but constant risk premium Similar to Equation 1, Equation 3 states that the long rate is the simple average of the current short rate and expected future short rates up to n-m periods in the future. 𝜃 𝑛,𝑚 is the predictable excess return on the n-period bond over the mperiod bond. The term-specific premium may vary with m and n but is assumed to be constant through time.23 The relationship between the n and m period rates in Equation 3 implies that an upward-sloping yield curve predicts an increase in short rates and consequently in long rates, and vice-versa. In order to investigate this, Abdul Munasib, “Term Structure of Interest Rates: The Theories”, Econ 3313 – Handout 03, Middle Tennessee State University. An empirical study on the Philippine term structure of interest rates by Diaz (2012) confirmed this claim via cointegration tests between the benchmark 91-day and 10-year rates. 23 Campbell & Shiller (1991) put the risk premium to be constant through time, but the stricter version of the EH (known as the Pure Expectations Hypothesis) assumes that the term premium is null or zero. This is because the PEH posits that interest rates are established strictly on the basis of expectations about future rates. Secondly, the theory assumes that market players are riskneutral (i.e. indifferent to maturity because they do not view long-term bonds as being riskier than short-term bonds). In this study, however, we shall test if the term premium of Philippine bond rates is indeed zero or not. 22 23 various approaches have been developed. Two common methods are the term spread regression models and the forward spread regression models. 1. Term Spread Regression Models The term spread regression models aim to use the difference between the long rate and the short rate (term spread) as a predictor of two outcomes: a) future changes in the long rate and b) future changes in the short rate. The studies of Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller (1986), Campbell and Shiller (1991), Campbell (1995), Tzavalis and Wickens (1997), Dai and Singleton (2002), and many others, have used the term spread regression models to test the EH. Equation 3 can be transformed into a regression model to investigate these two assumptions. a. Derivation of Term Spread Regression Model for Projection of Long Rates The first approach starts from the assumption that the one-period return on an n-period bond must be equal to the one-period short rate and a disturbance term known as the risk premium (Equation 4). Following Geiger’s (2011) notations, the derivation is as follows: 𝐸𝑡 (𝑟𝑛,𝑡+1 ) = 𝑖1,𝑡 + 𝑥𝑟𝑛 (Eq. 4) [𝑖𝑛,𝑡 − (𝑛 − 1)][𝐸𝑡 (𝑖𝑛−1,𝑡+1 )] − 𝑖𝑛,𝑡 = 𝑖1,𝑡 + 𝑥𝑟𝑛 (Eq. 5) [𝐸𝑡 (𝑖𝑛−1,𝑡+1 )] − 𝑖𝑛,𝑡 = (𝑖𝑛,𝑡 − 𝑖1,𝑡 ) (𝑛−1) 𝑖𝑛−1,𝑡+1 − 𝑖𝑛,𝑡 = 𝛼1,𝑛 + 𝛽1,𝑛 − 𝑥𝑟𝑛 (𝑛−1) (𝑖𝑛,𝑡 − 𝑖1,𝑡 ) (𝑛−1) + 𝜃𝑛,𝑡 (Eq. 6) (Eq. 7) 24 where Equation 6 tells us that the expected one-period change in the long rate, [𝐸𝑡 (𝑖𝑛−1,𝑡+1 )] − 𝑖𝑛,𝑡 , is equal to the average term spread over the remaining periods (n-1), (𝑖𝑛,𝑡 − 𝑖1,𝑡 ) (𝑛−1) , minus the average term premium over 𝑥𝑟 𝑛 the remaining periods, (𝑛−1) . Equation 7 transforms Equation 6 into a directly testable regression model that can be consistently tested via ordinary least squares. This is because the term premium, 𝜃𝑛,𝑡 , or the forecast error, under rational expectations, is assumed to be orthogonal or uncorrelated to the current information at time t. In this way, the term spread shall be uncorrelated also with the errors. To satisfy the EH, the projection of the changes in the long rate (left-hand side) onto the slope of the yield curve (right-hand side) should give an 𝛼1,𝑛 coefficient of zero, and a 𝛽1,𝑛 coefficient of one.24 b. Derivation of Term Spread Regression Model for Projection of Short Rates Alternatively, Equation 3 can also be used to derive the formula for testing if the term spread is able to predict expected changes in the short rate. From the basic assumption that the long rate is a simple average of the current short rate and the expected short rates in the future, plus an assumed constant risk premium, as shown in Equation 8: Felix Geiger, “The Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates,” in the The Yield Curve and Financial Risk Premia, (Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 2011), 69-70. 24 25 𝑖𝑛,𝑡 = 1 𝑦 ∑𝑛−1 𝐸 (𝑖 ) + ∅ 𝑡 1,𝑡+𝑗 𝑗=0 𝑛, 𝑛 (Eq. 8) the short rate can be subtracted from both sides of the equation to achieve the term spread regression model. 1 𝑛 1 𝑛 𝑦 ∑𝑛−1 𝑗=0 [𝐸𝑡 (𝑖1,𝑡+𝑗 ) − 𝑖1,𝑡 ] = 𝑖𝑛,𝑡 − 𝑖1,𝑡 − ∅𝑛 (Eq. 9) ∑𝑛−1 𝑗=0 (𝑖1,𝑡+𝑗 − 𝑖1,𝑡 ) = 𝛼2,𝑛 + 𝛽2,𝑛 (𝑖𝑛,𝑡 − 𝑖1,𝑡 ) + 𝜀𝑛,𝑡 (Eq. 10) Equation 10 implies that the yield spread, (𝑖𝑛,𝑡 − 𝑖1,𝑡 ), predicts the expected changes in the short rate, specifically the weighted cumulative expected change in the short rate over the life of the long rate, 1 𝑛 ∑𝑛−1 𝑗=0 (𝑖1,𝑡+𝑗 − 𝑖1,𝑡 ). Based on the EH, the expression above also suggests that whenever the long-term yield exceeds the current short-term yield (or a rise in the term spread), future short rates are expected to rise so that the returns between the two are equal. Similar to Equation 7, if the EH holds, 𝛼2,𝑛 must approach zero and 𝛽2,𝑛 should converge to unity so that an observed positive term spread is associated with increasing future shortterm rates.25 2. Forward Spread Regression Models Other studies have also explored the usefulness of forward rates26 in investigating the EH. Some of these are Fama and Bliss (1987) and Felix Geiger, “The Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates,” in the The Yield Curve and Financial Risk Premia, (Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 2011), 69-70. 26 Walsh introduced forward rates as an equal measure of the expected one-period ahead rates under the EH. He defined it in the case of a two-period bond and a one-period bond as: 𝑓𝑡1 = 25 (1+𝐼𝑡 )2 (1+𝑖𝑡 ) − 1. 26 Cochrane and Piazessi (2002). Geiger called this the “unbiased test of the EH” since under the assumptions of the EH, forward rates proxy as unbiased and optimal predictors of future interest rates”.27 Hence, current forward rates should appropriately predict future short rates.28 The forward spread regression model came from Equation 7 as a predictor of future short rate changes: 𝑖1,𝑡+𝑛 − 𝑖1,𝑡 = 𝛼3,𝑛 + 𝛽3,𝑛 (𝑓𝑛,𝑛+1 − 𝑖1,𝑡 ) + 𝜀𝑛,𝑡 (Eq. 11) where: 𝑖1,𝑡 ≡ interest rate of a one-period bond at time t 𝑖1,𝑡+𝑛 ≡ interest rate of a one-period bond during the life of the nperiod bond 𝑓𝑛,𝑛+1 ≡ forward rate that equalizes the returns of the one-period bond and n-period bond 𝜀𝑛,𝑡 ≡ disturbance term/risk premium If the EH holds, Equation 11 implies that 𝛼3,𝑛 must have a coefficient of zero and a 𝛽3,𝑛 coefficient of one. B. Empirical Tests of the Expectations Hypothesis A multitude of studies have tested the EH’s empirical validity. Majority of them used US bonds data while covered the term structure of other OECD29 and Carl Walsh, “The Term Structure of Interest Rates,” in the Monetary Theory and Policy, (Massachusetts: The MIT Press, 2010), 467. 28 Felix Geiger, “The Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates,” in the The Yield Curve and Financial Risk Premia, 70. 29 Frederic Mishkin, “A Multi-Country Study of the Information in the Term Structure about Future Inflation,” National Bureau of Economic Research (1989). 27 27 G730 countries. However, almost all of the basic empirical tests failed to satisfy the EH with 𝛽 coefficients significantly different from one. For some, the 𝛽 coefficients were even significantly less than zero. The collection of literature on the EH tests assembled by McCallum (1994) are shown in Tables 1 and 2. 1. Term Spread Regression Results McCallum segregated the results for the change in short rates and change in long rates.31 Table 1 shows the slope coefficients for the model that predicts changes in long rates. Results of the regression tests show that almost all of the 𝛽 coefficients were significantly below zero. The absolute value of the slopes also increase with the maturity of the bond.32 The same results were also arrived at by Hardouvelis (1994) for the study on G7 countries which analyzed the behavior of the 10-year and 3-month government bond yields between the periods of 1968-1992. He found out that the long rates move contrary to that implied by theory.33 The negative coefficients from the term spread models of the long rates imply that as the yield spread increases, the long yield has the tendency to fall. Campbell (1995) argued that when the long yields fall the short rates have the tendency to decline even more (if the EH is followed), thereby Gikas Hardouvelis, “The term structure spread and future changes in long and short rates in the G7 countries: Is there a puzzle?,” Journal of Monetary Economics (1993). 31 Empirical tests for the term spread as a predictor of change in short rates was called the twoperiod case by McCallum, while testing the changes in long rates was called the n-period case. The two-period case pertains to the relationship between yields on one-period and two-period bonds, whereas the n-period case covers bonds with maturities of more than two periods. 32 Bennett McCallum, “Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates” NBER Working Paper 4938 (1994), 4, 10. 33 The same results were also achieved by Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller (1986). 30 28 resulting to a greater yield difference between the short rate and the long rate. The EH, however, requires the future change in long yields to increase to offset the corresponding rising of the yield curve.34 On the other hand, some EH tests produced results consistent with theory. An example of which is the study on the German term structure of interest rates by Boero and Torricelli (2000). Nearly all pairs of maturities had coefficient estimates that were consistently positive, although not always significantly so. For the authors, their results suggest that “it is easier to predict changes in interest rates over longer horizons”. Boero and Torricelli, nevertheless, overruled the previous statement after having very low R2 values, indicating that the term spread has poor predictive content for changes in the long rate.35 Table 1. McCallum’s Collection of Empirical Results, Change in Long Rates Slope Coefficient Evans & Lewis (1994) 1964-1988 1 mo. 2 -0.17 Evans & Lewis (1994) 1964-1988 1 mo. 4 -0.70 Evans & Lewis (1994) 1964-1988 1 mo. 6 -1.27 Evans & Lewis (1994) 1964-1988 1 mo. 8 -1.52 Evans & Lewis (1994) 1964-1988 1 mo. 10 -1.89 Campbell & Shiller (1991) 1952-1987 1 mo. 2 0.00 Campbell & Shiller (1991) 1952-1987 1 mo. 4 -0.44 Campbell & Shiller (1991) 1952-1987 1 mo. 6 -1.03 Campbell & Shiller (1991) 1952-1987 1 mo. 12 -1.38 Campbell & Shiller (1991) 1952-1987 1 mo. 24 -1.81 Campbell & Shiller (1991) 1952-1987 1 mo. 48 -2.66 Campbell & Shiller (1991) 1952-1987 1 mo. 60 -3.10 Campbell & Shiller (1991) 1952-1987 1 mo. 120 -5.02 Hardouvelis (1994) 1954-1992 3 mo. 120 -2.90 Source: Bennett McCallum, “Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates” NBER Working Paper 4938 (1994). Study Sample Period Short Rate N+1 John Campbell, “Some Lessons from the Yield Curve,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 5, no. 3 (1995), http://www.jstor.org/stable/2138430. 35 Gianna Boero and Costanza Torricelli, “The Information in the Term Structure of German Interest Rates” (2000). 34 29 Table 2 also shows McCallum’s collection of literature that tested the term spread on future changes in the short rate. Similar to the results from the long rates, majority of the 𝛽s were significantly different from the desired coefficient of one. Some were greatly below than 1, negative at times, and for some highly exceeding one. These results suggest various implications for the relationship of the term spread and the future changes of short rates. If 𝛽s are significantly below 1, increases in the term spread may not be well-translated in the changes of short rates. If 𝛽s are significantly negative, just like the case of the long rate regression results, increases in the term spread will cause short rates to fall; and if 𝛽s significantly exceed one, any increase in the term spread will result to an overreaction of future short rates.36 Nevertheless, compared to the widely contradicting results for changes in long rates, findings of the regression tests for predicting short rate changes have been more unified and consistent. Most of the results gathered by Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller (1986), Boero and Torricelli (2000), and Campbell and Shiller (1991), produced 𝛽 coefficients which are positive (consistent with the relationship dictated by the EH theory), with some closely approaching one. Additionally, some of the regressions, such as in Germany’s case, showed higher information content (higher R2 values) than for longer bond tenors. These findings support the claim that the term 36 The overreaction of long rates to short rates have been studied by Mankiw and Summers (1984) in their paper entitled “Do Long-Term Interest Rates Overreact to Short-Term Interest Rates?”. 30 spread has greater ability in predicting future changes of short rates than long rates. Table 2. McCallum’s Collection of Empirical Results, Change in Short Rates Study Sample Period Short Rate Slope Coefficient 1959-1979 0.23 Mankiw & Miron (1986) 3 mo. 1951-1958 -0.33 Mankiw & Miron (1986) 3 mo. 1934-1951 -0.25 Mankiw & Miron (1986) 3 mo. 1915-1933 0.42 Mankiw & Miron (1986) 3 mo. 1890-1914 0.76 Mankiw & Miron (1986) 3 mo. 1964-1988 0.42 Evans & Lewis (1994) 1 mo. 1952-1987 0.50 Campbell & Shiller (1991) 1 mo. 1952-1987 0.19 Campbell & Shiller (1991) 2 mo. 1952-1987 -0.15 Campbell & Shiller (1991) 3 mo. 1952-1987 0.04 Campbell & Shiller (1991) 6 mo. 1952-1987 -0.02 Campbell & Shiller (1991) 12 mo. 1952-1987 0.14 Campbell & Shiller (1991) 36 mo. 1952-1987 2.79 Campbell & Shiller (1991) 60 mo. 1959-1982 0.46 Fama (1984) 1 mo. 1984-1991 -0.01 Roberds, Runkle, & Whiteman (1993) 3 mo. 1979-1982 0.19 Roberds, Runkle, & Whiteman (1993) 3 mo. 1975-1979 0.43 Roberds, Runkle, & Whiteman (1993) 3 mo. Source: Bennett McCallum, “Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates” NBER Working Paper 4938 (1994). 2. Forward Spread Regression Results Apart from the tests done on the term spread models, several authors have also investigated the EH using the forward spread method. Some of these authors are Fama and Bliss (1987), Mishkin (1988)37, Cochrane and Piazessi (2005), Fama (2006), and Bulkley, Harris, and Nawosah (2008). Mishkin (1988), for example, had two kinds of tests using forward rates. First, he investigated the relationship between the expected changes in the spot rate (current short rate) and the forward rate-spot rate spread.38 Mishkin’s paper is a refinement of Fama’s (1984) study. 𝜏 Mishkin’s first regression model is: 𝑅𝑡+𝜏 − 𝑅𝑡+1 = 𝛼1 + 𝛽1 (𝐹𝜏𝑡 − 𝑅𝑡+1 ) + 𝜂𝑡+𝜏−1 ; and the 𝜏 second one is: 𝑅𝑡+𝜏 − 𝑅𝑡+𝜏−1 = 𝛼2 + 𝛽2 (𝐹𝜏𝑡 − 𝐹(𝑡 − 1)𝑡 ) + 𝜂𝑡+𝜏−1 , where 𝑅𝑡+𝜏 is the one37 38 31 Secondly, he examined the relationship between the change in the spot rate and the difference between two adjacent forward rates. Mishkin used Treasury bills with tenors from one month up to six months for his data. The results are shown in Tables 3 and 4, respectively. For Mishkin’s results in Table 3, he concluded that “the forward rate-spot rate differential for the 1-month ahead, 𝐹2𝑡 − 𝑅𝑡+1 , has significant predictive power and significant explanatory power for the change in the spot rate one month ahead, 𝑅𝑡+2 − 𝑅𝑡+1 ”.39 It can be observed, however, that the forward spread’s predictive power decreases as the predictive horizon lengthens. Additionally, he noted that examining the results per subperiod is important because this affects the stochastic process of interest rates. Overall, Mishkin concluded for this first set of tests on US bonds that “the term structure has more predictive power for spot rates from October 1979 onwards”.40 Table 3. Regressions of Change in the Spot Rate on the Forward Rate Spread Sample Period 2/59 – 7/82 2/59 – 1/64 2/64 – 1/69 2/69 – 1/74 2/74 – 1/79 𝑹𝒕+𝟐 − 𝜷 0.41** (0.11) 0.44** (0.12) 0.52** (0.13) 0.32** (0.07) 0.69** (0.17) 𝑹𝒕+𝟏 R2 0.11 0.22 0.39 0.12 0.10 𝑹𝒕+𝟑 − 𝜷 0.27 (0.18) 0.34** (0.10) 0.40** (0.14) 0.17 (0.16) 0.10 (0.25) 𝑹𝒕+𝟏 R2 0.03 0.16 0.19 0.01 0.00 Dependent Variable 𝑹𝒕+𝟒 − 𝑹𝒕+𝟏 𝑹𝒕+𝟓 − 𝜷 R2 𝜷 0.25 0.01 0.21 (0.24) (0.15) 0.28 0.06 0.05 (0.16) (0.11) 0.22 0.04 0.32** (0.12) (0.09) 0.61** 0.13 0.07 (0.18) (0.17) 0.31 0.02 0.20 (0.29) (0.22) 𝑹𝒕+𝟏 R2 0.01 0.00 0.18 0.00 0.02 𝑹𝒕+𝟔 − 𝜷 0.16 (0.11) 0.06 (0.14) 0.26** (0.08) 0.15 (0.11) -0.12 (0.18) 𝑹𝒕+𝟏 R2 0.01 0.01 0.14 0.02 0.01 month rate observed at time 𝑡 + 𝜏 − 1 and 𝐹𝜏𝑡 is the forwad rate for month 𝑡 + 𝜏 observed at time 𝑡. 39 Frederic Mishkin, “The Information in the Term Structure,” National Bureau of Economic Research 2575 (1988): 8. 40 Frederic Mishkin, “The Information in the Term Structure,” National Bureau of Economic Research 2575 (1988): 9. 32 Table 3 continued 2/79 – 0.61** 0.15 0.43 0.04 0.29 0.01 0.43 0.03 0.50 0.03 7/82 (0.21) (0.32) (0.37) (0.33) (0.37) 1/59 – 0.40** 0.11 0.30* 0.04 0.34** 0.02 0.20 0.02 0.16 0.01 6/86 (0.09) (0.15) (0.10) (0.11) (0.10) 1/59 – 0.44** 0.14 0.25** 0.04 0.34** 0.05 0.12 0.01 0.05 0.00 9/79 (0.06) (0.08) (0.10) (0.09) (0.09) 10/79 – 0.71** 0.20 0.59 0.08 0.47 0.03 0.58 0.06 0.64* 0.07 9/82 (0.23) (0.33) (0.35) (0.31) (0.30) 10/82 – 0.51** 0.26 0.64** 0.23 0.61** 0.17 0.13 0.02 -0.03 0.00 6/86 (0.12) (0.15) (0.21) (0.17) (0.17) Source: Frederic Mishkin, “The Information in the Term Structure,” National Bureau of Economic Research 2575 (1988): 7. Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. * = significant at 5% level ** = significant at 1% level The results for the marginal predictive power of forward rates (i.e., forward rates with one period interval) on the monthly changes in future spot rates were slightly less favorable than the previous one. The last row of Table 4 shows that adjacent forward rates provide significant predictive power for the change in the spot rate up but only up to 3 months in the future. Moreover, when Mishkin further tested the robustness of the results of the two regressions, he concluded that there is more coefficient instability (thus, less robust) for the marginal prediction equations than there were for the forward rate-spot rate model.41 Table 4. Regressions of Change in the Spot Rate on Adjacent Forward Rates Sample Period 2/59 – 7/82 2/59 – 1/64 2/64 – 1/69 2/69 – 1/74 2/74 – 1/79 𝑹𝒕+𝟐 − 𝜷 0.41** (0.11) 0.44** (0.12) 0.52** (0.13) 0.32** (0.07) 0.69** (0.17) 𝑹𝒕+𝟏 R2 0.11 0.22 0.39 0.12 0.10 𝑹𝒕+𝟑 − 𝜷 -0.03 (0.12) 0.45** (0.10) 0.34** (0.12) 0.21 (0.12) -0.00 (0.23) 𝑹𝒕+𝟐 R2 0.00 0.21 0.21 0.06 0.00 Dependent Variable 𝑹𝒕+𝟒 − 𝑹𝒕+𝟑 𝑹𝒕+𝟓 − 𝜷 R2 𝜷 -0.02 0.00 0.04 (0.11) (0.08) 0.25* 0.07 0.11 (0.11) (0.09) 0.18 0.04 0.21 (0.14) (0.11) 0.16 0.04 -0.08 (0.09) (0.06) -0.55 0.10 -0.02 (0.49) (0.16) 𝑹𝒕+𝟒 R2 0.00 0.03 0.14 0.01 0.00 𝑹𝒕+𝟔 − 𝜷 0.00 (0.06) 0.19** (0.06) 0.12 (0.07) -0.08 (0.06) -0.09 (0.08) 𝑹𝒕+𝟓 R2 0.00 0.09 0.07 0.04 0.02 Frederic Mishkin, “The Information in the Term Structure,” National Bureau of Economic Research 2575 (1988): 10. 41 33 Table 4 continued 2/79 – 0.61** 0.15 -0.59* 0.07 -0.36 0.02 0.03 0.00 0.26 0.01 7/82 (0.21) (0.28) (0.29) (0.23) (0.37) 1/59 – 0.40** 0.11 0.03 0.00 0.07 0.00 0.05 0.00 0.02 0.00 6/86 (0.09) (0.11) (0.10) (0.07) (0.06) 1/59 – 0.44** 0.14 0.25** 0.06 0.06 0.00 0.02 0.00 -0.03 0.00 9/79 (0.06) (0.08) (0.11) (0.06) (0.05) 10/79 – 0.71** 0.20 -0.56* 0.07 -0.24 0.09 0.00 0.25 0.01 0.01 9/82 (0.23) (0.27) (0.27) (0.22) (0.34) 10/82 – 0.51** 0.26 0.42* 0.13 0.60** 0.28 0.14 0.03 0.06 0.00 6/86 (0.12) (0.17) (0.16) (0.12) (0.13) Source: Frederic Mishkin, “The Information in the Term Structure,” National Bureau of Economic Research 2575 (1988): 10. Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. * = significant at 5% level ** = significant at 1% level 3. Why the Expectations Hypothesis Tests Failed If we would look at the vast literature which attempted to study the Expectations Hypothesis (EH), majority of them arrived at the conclusion that empirical tests reject the EH in its constant term premium form. This observation remains true for both US data and data from European countries.42 Geiger (2011), nonetheless, argued that “this does imply that interest rate expectations are impossible to be inferred from the term structure, but rather reflects the insight that the EH and its single-equation representation only predicts future yield levels to a limited extent”. Still, it can be said that there is some element of truth in the EH. Several reasons have been put forth regarding the failure of the EH. The study of Campbell and Shiller (1991), that focused on measurement errors in modelling the EH, argued that the main failure of the EH was primarily caused by the overreaction of long rates to current short rates. This 42 Empirical support is only found at the short end of the yield curve (<1 year) for both US and European data. 34 excessive sensitivity of long rates to short rates have also been investigated by the study of Mankiw and Summers (1984). However, Mankiw and Summers, likewise, decisively rejected this claim. Campbell and Shiller, thus, suggested several econometric resolutions to compute for the EH more accurately.43 Campbell (1995) argued that the failure of the EH can be explained by biases in estimating the EH due to the variability of excess returns in long bonds. Since expected excess returns appear on both sides of the equation (Equation 7), they bias 𝛽1 down due to its negative effect on the dependent variable and positive effect on the regressor. On the other hand, excess returns also have the tendency to bias 𝛽2 up since changing expectations of excess returns only positively affect the right-hand side of the equation (Equation 10). Moreover, Mankiw and Miron (1986) considered the effect of monetary policy on the predictive power of the yield spread for future interest rate movements. They found out that there are only specific periods in which the EH fit the data, specifically before the founding of the Federal Reserve (Fed) since rates were more predictable that time. According to Geiger (2011), Mankiw and Miron’s finding suggest that “firstly, the predictive power of the EH changes across different monetary policy regimes, and secondly, a central bank that heavily manipulates interest rates John Campbell and Robert Shiller, “Yields Spreads and Interest Rate Movements: A Bird’s Eye View,” The Review of Economic Studies 58, no.3 (1991), http://www.jstor.org/stable/2298008 43 35 makes it harder for market participants to forecast future movement of interest rates if the short rate follows a random walk”.44 Finally, from the literature surveyed in this study, majority of the authors insisted that the error of the regression models primarily came from the omission of a time-varying term premium in the regressions that is correlated with the term spread.45 This was argued by Tzavalis and Wickens (1997), Balfoussia and Wickens (2007), and McCallum (1994) that recognized the need to incorporate the risk premium in the estimation of the EH via econometric adjustments. Geiger (2011) also posited that the underlying sources of risk and how they are translated into the variability of the term premia are important to explain the validity of the EH. The earlier studies of Fama (1984), Mankiw (1986), and Hardouvelis (1988), and McCallum (1994), on the other hand, argued in favor of the possibility of time variation in the term premium due to policy regime changes. C. Bond Risk Premium The bond risk premium (BRP) has been equally studied as the EH since academic researchers have identified it as the main candidate for why the yield spread is unable to forecast future interest rates correctly. As defined by Ilmanen (2012), the bond risk premium or the term premium46 is the “expected return Felix Geiger, “The Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates,” in the The Yield Curve and Financial Risk Premia, (Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 2011), 73. 45 Elias Tzavalis and Michael Wickens, “Explaining the Failures of the Term Spread Models of the Rational Expectations Hypothesis of the Term Structure,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 29, no. 3 (1997), http://www.jstor.org/stable/2953700 46 Bond risk premium and term premium is used interchangeably in this study. The terms bond risk premia and term premia may, at times, be mentioned. 44 36 advantage of long-duration bonds over short-term (one-period) bonds”.47 It is also known as the compensation for risk that investors demand for investing in longterm bonds than shorter ones, since it is presumed that time is associated with risks. Mathematically, the BRP was illustrated as 𝜃 𝑛,𝑚 in Equation 3. Nevertheless, unlike the previous assumption of the EH, it is anticipated that the BRP is no longer zero or constant but present and/or time-varying. In the case of the US, the identification of the bond term premia has been very significant especially during the interest rate conundrum in 2004 to 2005. Ben Bernanke, former Fed Chairman from 2006 to 2014, discussed in his speech last March 2013, that the biggest contributor to low rates during the conundrum, despite the Fed raising the federal funds, was the decline in the term premium. Some of the known causes of a very low or negative premium were central bank purchases of government debt, safe-asset demand, and lastly, the global savings glut (that resulted to some countries’ massive accumulation of foreign exchange reserves).48 From the US’ experience, estimating the bond risk premia can be used as a signaling tool for any anomaly in the market such as the interest rate conundrum. This is because the US conundrum suggested that the global monetary system is in bad shape. If the term premium could be estimated accurately monitored, economic and financial crises may effectively be prevented. 47 Antti Ilmanen, Expected Returns on Major Asset Classes (Research Foundation of CFA Institute: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 2012), 57. 48 “Conundrum: a glut-wrenching experience”, The Economist, November 20, 2014. http://www.economist.com/blogs/freeexchange/2014/11/conundrums. 37 1. Estimating the Bond Risk Premium Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller (1986), Tzavalis and Wickens (1997), Balfoussia and Wickens (2007), Boero and Torricelli (2000), and many other studies hypothesized that the failure of the EH was caused by the omission of the BRP in the regression tests. However, these studies also recognized that the BRP is not directly observable and not that easy to find a proxy for.49 Estimation procedures should, therefore, be done to incorporate the BRP into the regression equation. Nevertheless, Geiger (2011) noted that there is still no consensus on how to measure the term premia. Hence, researchers have experimented on a wide set of model specifications and estimation techniques to estimate the BRP. These methods are clustered into two general approaches by Balfoussia and Wickens (2007) into:50 a. Observable Proxy for the BRP The observable proxy method pertains to selecting a directly recognizable variable that may imitate the magnitude or behavior of the bond risk premium. It can also be a variable that is highly correlated to the excess returns or disturbance term of the term spread regression models. Putting an observable proxy for the term/risk premium was carried out differently by various studies. Shiller, Campbell, and Schoenholtz 49 Ilmanen (2012) also acknowledged that the BRP is unobservable hence, estimating techniques must be done. 50 Hiona Balfoussia and Mike Wickens, “Macroeconomic Sources of Risk in the Term Structure”, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 39, no. 1 (2007), http://www.jstor.org/stable/4123075 38 (1983), for example, used a measure of credit volume that measures the relative amount of activity in the short end of the market (than the long end) to predict risk premiums.51 They regressed excess returns on six-month bills on the previous quarter’s ratio of short borrowing (<1 year) to long (>1 year) financing by US corporations. They found out that the volume ratio is indeed a significant predictor of excess returns from 1959 to 1982. However, it is not significant over the shorter bonds in the earlier sample period from 1959 to 1979, while the volume ratio is only 10% significant in predicting excess returns on long-term bonds. Campbell (1987) used latent variables such as the expected returns on hedge portfolios on bills, bonds, and common stocks assumed to drive risk premia; however, data strongly rejected the latent variable models.52 Simon (1989), on the other hand, suggested that the term premium is proportional to the square of the excess holding period return.53 Furthermore, Tzavalis and Wickens (1997) argued that the ex-post holdingperiod return of one maturity can be used as a good BRP proxy of other maturities.54 Similarly, Cochrane and Piazzesi’s (2002) study supported Tzavalis and Wickens’ findings upon using a tent-shaped function of Robert Shiller, John Campbell, and Kermit Schoenholtz, “Forward Rates and Future Policy: Interpreting the Term Structure of Interest Rates”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1983, no.1 (1983), http://www.jstor.org/stable/2534355. 52 John Campbell, “Stock Returns and the Term Structure,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 1626 (1985), 7. 53 David Simon, “Expectations and Risk in the Treasury Bill Market,” The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 24, no. 3 (1989), http://www.jstor.org/stable/2330816. 54 Elias Tzavalis and Michael Wickens, “Explaining the Failures of the Term Spread Models of the Rational Expectations Hypothesis of the Term Structure,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 29, no. 3 (1997), http://www.jstor.org/stable/2953700. 51 39 forward rates as a single-factor representation of the BRP to predict oneyear excess holding-period returns.55 Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller (1986) and Boero and Torricelli (2000), used measures of volatility as a way to proxy for the BRP. Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller, assumed that the term premium is positively related to risk; thus, the riskier a certain investment instrument is, a higher term premium would be assigned by investors to it. They assumed that “substantial fluctuation in perceived risk could explain the rejection of the EH”. They used the following variables to inspect which highly affects excess returns: 1) interest rate volatility, 2) consumption, 3) stock market activity, and 4) change in asset supplies.56 In the same way, Boero and Torricelli directly used the following as proxies for excess returns/risk premium: 1) moving average of absolute changes in the short rate over the previous six periods; 2) expected square of excess holding period returns; and 3) estimates of conditional variances from GARCH models. b. Term Premium Specification Based on a Term Structure Model Other studies have also specified the term premium through latent affine stochastic discount factors (SDF). SDF models refer to “pricing an John Cochrane and Monika Piazzesi, “Decomposing the Yield Curve,” National Bureau of Economic Research (2008), http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/john.cochrane/research/papers/interest_rate_revised.pdf. 56 Gregory Mankiw, Stephen Goldfeld, and Robert Shiller, “The Term Structure of Interest Rates Revisited,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1986, no.1 (1986), http://www. jstor.org/stable/2534414. 55 40 asset as the expected discounted value of its pay-off next period”57 (see Cochrane (2000), Bolder (2001), Chib (2009), and Smith and Wickens (2003) for a more detailed discussion of SDF models). Balfoussia and Wickens (2007) posited that the risk premia obtained from an SDF model were derived from the conditional covariances of the excess return over the risk-free rate. Cochrane (2000) stated that there are two major approaches to asset pricing: 1) absolute asset pricing which involves pricing an asset with respect to its exposure to fundamental sources of macroeconomic risk; and 2) relative asset pricing which prices an asset with respect to the prices of other assets.58 Alternatively, Balfoussia and Wickens (2007) also discussed that SDF models can be single factor affine models (wherein all bond yields are a function of the short rate and with a fixed shape of the yield curve through time) or multifactor affine models (that is argued to be more flexible but over-constrained). With all of these information, Balfoussia and Wickens (2007), therefore, developed their methodology based on the SDF model to estimate the contribution of macroeconomic variables to the term premia.59 Ilmanen (2012) also suggested that another approach to estimate the BRP is through a survey. The survey is the most direct way of assessing the market’s expectations. Values can be obtained right away and by Hiona Balfoussia and Mike Wickens, “Macroeconomic Sources of Risk in the Term Structure,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 39, no. 1 (2007), http://www.jstor.org/stable/4123075. 58 Peter Smith and Michael Wickens, “Asset Pricing and Observable Stochastic Discount Factors,” Journal of Economic Surveys 16 (2002), 397-446. 59 Hiona Balfoussia and Mike Wickens, “Macroeconomic Sources of Risk in the Term Structure,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 39, no. 1 (2007), http://www.jstor.org/stable/4123075. 57 41 subtracting the measure from current long-term yield gives the estimate of the BRP. However, it is noted that academics have recently veered away from gathering data through surveys because of the tedious efforts associated to it. Likewise, the survey approach in this research shall not be given focus. This is because no such surveys have been done in the Philippines.60 D. Macroeconomic Variables and the Bond Risk Premium Due to the unobservable nature of the BRP, several studies have used macroeconomic variables or country data that may aid in estimating the term premium. Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller (1986), for example, associated excess returns with some common sources of risk such as interest rate volatility, consumption, and activity of the stock market, and changes in asset supplies (or the relative supply of long-term and short-term bonds). Unfortunately, none of these factors satisfactorily explained the large variation in the term premium, and thus lead to the failure of the EH.61 Balfoussia and Wickens (2007) also considered three observable macroeconomic factors to estimate the variability of the bond risk premia. These were consumption, output, and inflation. They used a multivariate GARCH (Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity) model with 60 Antti Ilmanen, Expected Returns on Major Asset Classes (Research Foundation of CFA Institute: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 2012), 56. 61 Gregory Mankiw, Stephen Goldfeld, and Robert Shiller, “The Term Structure of Interest Rates Revisited,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1986, no.1 (1986), http://www. jstor.org/stable/2534414. 42 conditional covariances in the mean of the excess holding-period returns. Balfoussia and Wickens found out that inflation was the main source of risk at all maturities, while consumption was a less important source of risk.62 Similarly, Lee (1995) used output and money supply as the sources of the time-varying risk premia in the term structure. Lee’s empirical tests were summarized by the ARIMAGARCH (Autoregressive Integrated Moving Average – Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity) model, and he found out that the uncertainties related to output (industrial production) and money supply (M1) were significant in all the risk premium equations and they showed explanatory power for the monthly excess returns.63 Ilmanen (2012), on the other hand, enumerated the four key drivers of the BRP. The first BRP driver was level-dependent inflation uncertainty, which was considered as the most important secular driver of required expected real bond yields and BRPs. The intuition is that, higher inflation levels are associated with greater inflation uncertainty, which warrants higher required premia for holding nominal bonds. The second BRP driver was the equity and/or recession-hedging ability or also known as the stock-bond correlation. Ilmanen argued that the stockbond correlation in the US reached negative levels around 1998, which reflected the government bond’s role as the ultimate safe-haven asset. Additionally, Ilmanen Hiona Balfoussia and Mike Wickens, “Macroeconomic Sources of Risk in the Term Structure,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 39, no. 1 (2007), http://www.jstor.org/stable/4123075. 63 Sang-Sub Lee, “Macroeconomic Sources of Time-Varying Risk Premia in the Term Structure of Interest Rates,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27, no. 2 (1995), http://www.jstor.org/stable/2077883. 62 43 posited that the stock-bond correlation is likely to be negative even with low and stable inflation expectations. The next BRP driver is the supply and demand factors which contribute to the time-varying nature of the risk premia. Some examples of these are the: 1) fiscal supply (maturity structure of government debt and public-debt-to-GDP ratio) since the impact on bond yields of high debts/deficits is greater when expected inflation is also high and initial fiscal conditions are poor; 2) regulatory effects and pension fund demand which allows the yield curve to be flat or inverted at long maturities; and 3) foreign flows which characterized the “savings glut” in 2004 to 2005. Lastly, Ilmanen stated that the shape of the yield curve is closely interrelated with various cycles in the economy which includes business cycles, credit cycles, and monetary policy cycles. Ilmanen found out that the yield curve of the BRP is distinctly countercyclical, which means that at periods near business cycle troughs, required term premium is high, while at periods near business cycle peaks, required term premium is low.64 Finally, Chantapacdepong (2007) examined the relationship of the risk premia on holding 6-month Treasury bills in 43 countries65 (as the dependent variable) with other macroeconomic variables (as the explanatory variables). These variables were classified as domestic economic variables (economic growth, inflation rate, and real effective exchange rate), government/fiscal variables (government debt as a percent of GDP and fiscal deficit as a percent of GDP), and 64 Antti Ilmanen, Expected Returns on Major Asset Classes (Research Foundation of CFA Institute: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 2012), 61-75. 65 Chantapacdepong has representative countries from developed, developing, and less developed countries around the world. 44 institutional variables (political constraints and political risk index). Chantapacdepong’s results showed that the risk premia were highly correlated with the political risk index (𝜌 = 0.63), political constraint index (𝜌 = 0.58), and inflation (𝜌 = 0.57). Other variables followed: real effective exchange rate (REER) (𝜌 = 0.50), economic growth (𝜌 = 0.43), and budget deficit as a percent of GDP (𝜌 = 0.17).66 Apart from the correlations, regression was also used to identify if these factors are significant predictors of the BRP. Chantapacdepong’s results showed that inflation (𝛽 = 1.41) and economic growth (𝛽 = -1.73) were significant predictors at the 5% level. Budget deficit as a percentage of GDP has a predictive power (𝛽 = 1.62) at the 10% level. Debt-to-GDP and the volatility of the REER were not significant at all, but also contains some degree of prediction at 𝛽 = 0.17 and 𝛽 = 0.22, respectively. When the political and institutional variables were added, the results did not change; inflation, deficit-to-GDP, and economic growth still showed strong predictive powers for the BRP. Chantapacdepong concluded that “the short run macroeconomic circumstances are the ones that highly explain the risk premia”; that is, higher inflation, lower growth, and higher government deficit all lead to a higher risk premia.67 Pornpinun Chantapacdepong “Determinants of the time varying risk premia,” (Discussion Paper No. 07/597, Department of Economics, University of Bristol, 2007), 18-34. 67 Pornpinun Chantapacdepong “Determinants of the time varying risk premia,” (Discussion Paper No. 07/597, Department of Economics, University of Bristol, 2007), 35-36. 66 45 CHAPTER III THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK AND METHODOLOGY This study aims to empirically test the applicability of the Expectations Hypothesis (EH) on Philippine bond yields. As a benchmark study, this paper shall be a basic development from the various research papers that investigated the EH. For the first objective, which is to empirically test the EH, the two-period case and n-period case models of McCallum (1994) would be employed. For the measurement of the bond risk premium (BRP), this study would use interest rate volatility as a proxy for risk. Finally, to identify relationships with macroeconomic variables, a mix of the experimental regressions done by Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller (1986), Chantapacdepong (2007), and Ilmanen (2012) would be used. A. Theoretical Framework This thesis study shall revolve around its main theoretical basis which is the Expectations Hypothesis (EH). The hypothesis is illustrated by Equation 3 which shows that the long rate is just the simple average of the current short rate and the expected future short rates over the life of the long rate. This implies that the movement of the long-term rate can be determined by the movement of the current and expected short-term rates, and vice-versa. Hence, this supports the claim that under the EH, long-term bonds and short-term bonds are perfect substitutes or applies the notion of the “no-arbitrage principle”. 1 𝑚 𝑛,𝑚 𝑟𝑡𝑛 = ( ) ∑𝑘−1 𝑖=0 𝐸𝑡 𝑟𝑡+𝑚𝑖 + 𝜃 𝑘 (from Eq. 3) 46 For investment instruments to be considered perfect substitutes, they must have inherent characteristics that goes in consonance with the implications of the theory. The EH, for instance, have the following implications:68 1. The term spread must predict expected changes in future short-term rates; 2. The term spread must predict expected changes in future long-term rates; and 3. The term premium must be constant or zero (which implies that the term spread must not forecast the excess holding returns on long-term rates). These assumptions are a set of criteria to say that a specific set of investment instruments or assets follow the EH rule. If one of these conditions is rejected, we can say that the EH does not hold anymore. Equation 3 can be used to derive the corresponding empirical equations to test the validity of the assumptions of the EH. These empirical equations are called term spread models. A wide set of literature developed on various term spread equations, however, this thesis searched for an appropriate model that would fit the availability of bond maturities in the Philippines. Thus, this study shall adopt McCallum’s (1994) EH models.69 McCallum classified the term spread models into two. These are the twoperiod case and the n-period case. This was done to allow for the unique properties of the bond maturities featured in his study. The two-period case is used to tackle the relationship between yields on one-period bonds and two-period bonds, while the n-period case is employed to test the relationship of one-period bonds and longterm rates with maturities of more than two periods. 68 69 This summary of EH assumptions came from Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller (1986). This part shall take up McCallum’s notations. 47 1. Term Spread Model for Predicting Changes in the Short Rate The EH posits that the long rate (𝑅𝑡 ) is related to the current short rate (𝑟𝑡 ) and the expected future short rates (𝐸𝑡 𝑟𝑡+1 ) as follows: 𝑅𝑡 = 0.5 (𝑟𝑡 + 𝐸𝑡 𝑟𝑡+1 ) + 𝜉𝑡 (Eq. 12) where 𝜉𝑡 is the term premium that is assumed constant.70 Defining the expectational error (or the error in forecasting future short rates) 𝜖𝑡+1 = 𝑟𝑡+1 − 𝐸𝑡 𝑟𝑡+1, Equation 12 implies 0.5 (𝑟𝑡+1 − 𝑟𝑡 ) = (𝑅𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡 ) − 𝜉𝑡 + 0.5𝜖𝑡+1 (Eq. 13) If a constant term premium is assumed, 𝜉𝑡 = 𝜉, and assuming rational expectations which makes the expectation error, 𝜖𝑡+1, orthogonal or uncorrelated with 𝑅𝑡 and 𝑟𝑡 , the constant coefficient 𝛼 and the slope coefficient 𝛽 in the regression model 0.5 (𝑟𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) = 𝛼 + 𝛽 (𝑅𝑡−1 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 (Eq. 14) should have probability limits of zero and one, respectively. Equation 13 tells us that the average change in the short rate, 0.5 (𝑟𝑡+1 − 𝑟𝑡 ), must be equal term spread, (𝑅𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡 ), less the term premium, 𝜉𝑡 , plus the average expectation error, 0.5𝜖𝑡+1 . In Equation 14, the 𝛼 coefficient indicates that with everything in the model held constant, the term spread will not be able to predict future changes in the short rate; whereas, the expected 𝛽 coefficient of one implies that the term spread can “perfectly” predict the changes in the short rate, such that every percentage change in the term spread translates to an equal 70 For now, this basic model of the EH shall assume a constant term premium. 48 percentage change in the short rate. A standard way of estimating Equation 14 is by using the ordinary-least squares (OLS) method. 2. Term Spread Model for Predicting Changes in the Long Rate For testing the relationship between the long rate and the term spread, McCallum used a different model called the n-period case. This model is made fit for bonds with a maturity of more than two periods. Following the same notations as in the two-period case, the EH relationship between the long rate and short rate can be expressed as 𝑅𝑡 − 𝑁𝐸𝑡 (𝑅𝑡+1 − 𝑅𝑡 ) = 𝑟𝑡 + 𝜉𝑡 , (Eq. 15) where 𝑁 + 1 is the measure of duration of the long rate (where for discount bonds or zero-coupon bonds, the duration is equal to its maturity). The lefthand side of the equation represents the one-period holding return on the long rate.71 Equation 15 means that the one-period holding return in any long period bond must be equal to the return of the current short rate plus the term premium. The empirical model becomes 𝑁(𝑅𝑡+1 − 𝑅𝑡 ) = (𝑅𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡 ) − 𝜉𝑡 + 𝑁𝜀𝑡+1 (Eq. 16) where 𝜀𝑡+1 = 𝑅𝑡+1 − 𝐸𝑡 𝑅𝑡+1 , or the expectational error that is made in forecasting future long rates. 𝜀𝑡+1 is also assumed to be orthogonal or uncorrelated with 𝑅𝑡 and 𝑟𝑡 . If the term premium, 𝜉𝑡 , is assumed to be constant, a regression in the form of: McCallum noted that 𝑁𝐸𝑡 (𝑅𝑡+1 − 𝑅𝑡 ) is only an approximation of the expected capital loss on the long bond. This has been adopted so that only two maturities will be involved in the model. Due to the limited type (maturities) of zero coupon bonds that the Philippines has, this was also chosen to be the empirical model for this thesis. 71 49 𝑁(𝑅𝑡 − 𝑅𝑡−1 ) = 𝛼 + 𝛽(𝑅𝑡−1 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 (Eq. 17) should have probability limits of zero for 𝛼 and one for 𝛽 after OLS estimation. The 𝛼 and 𝛽 coefficients of Equation 17 have the same implications as in Equation 16, but now changes in the long rate are the ones estimated by the term spread. 3. Model for Predicting Excess Holding Period Returns The EH also posits that the term premium, 𝜉𝑡 , is constant through time. Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller (1986) tested this assumption by combining it with another assumption that the expectation error, 𝜐𝑡+1,72 cannot be forecasted with information available at time t. This also implies that the excess holding return, 𝐻𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡 , cannot be forecasted using variables known at time t: 𝐻𝑡 73 − 𝑟𝑡 = 𝜉𝑡 + 𝜐𝑡+1 (Eq. 18) Equation 18 can be transformed into its regression form 𝐻𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽𝑋𝑡 + 𝜐𝑡+1 (Eq. 19) and can be estimated via OLS by regressing the excess return on any variable determined at time t. For the EH to hold, the 𝛽 coefficient must be zero. 72 This notation can be considered as a representation of the expectation errors for the term spread model for the short rate and the term spread model for the long rate. 73 The holding return, as defined by Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller (1986), can be expressed in 1+𝑃𝑡+1 − 𝑃𝑡 𝑅 −𝑅 terms of prices, 𝐻𝑡 ≡ , or yields, 𝐻𝑡 ≡ 𝑅𝑡 − 𝑡+1 𝑡. A linearized version of the holding 𝑃𝑡 return was also presented: 𝐻𝑡 ≈ 𝑅𝑡 − 𝑅𝑡+1 − 𝑅𝑡 𝜌 𝑅𝑡+1 , where 𝜌 is a constant equal to the average of the long rate. 50 Indeed, there can be a limitless number of variables available at time t that can be plugged in Equation 19, but Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller already suggested two specific variables to be tested. The first variable is the lagged values of the excess return. The excess return must not be forecasted by the lagged values of 𝜐𝑡+1. If by chance, the 𝛽 coefficient is not zero, it can be hypothesized that the excess returns and its lagged values are serially correlated thus, indicating the presence of a time-varying risk premium.74 The second variable is the spread between the long rate and the short rate (𝑅𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡 ). In order to satisfy the EH, the term spread must not forecast the excess holding period returns, which further supports the assumption that the term premium is zero. If it does, this can be another indication that a time-varying risk premium may be present.75 Previous studies done on the EH highlighted the importance of correcting the term spread models via econometric techniques to achieve unbiased estimates. Thus, diagnostic tests of the residuals and elements of the equation would be done to check for any errors such as serial correlation or heteroskedasticity.76 Gregory Mankiw, Stephen Goldfeld, and Robert Shiller, “The Term Structure of Interest Rates Revisited,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1986, no.1 (1986), http://www. jstor.org/stable/2534414. 75 Gregory Mankiw, Stephen Goldfeld, and Robert Shiller, “The Term Structure of Interest Rates Revisited,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1986, no.1 (1986), http://www. jstor.org/stable/2534414. 76 Elias Tzavalis and Michael Wickens, “Explaining the Failures of the Term Spread Models of the Rational Expectations Hypothesis of the Term Structure,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 29, no. 3 (1997), http://www.jstor.org/stable/2953700 74 51 4. Bond Risk Premium In this thesis, it is considered that the rejection of any or all assumptions of the EH signals for the presence of a bond risk premium (BRP), specifically, a time-varying risk premium. Thus, to deeply examine the effect of the BRP on the EH tests, the BRP must be measured. For this study to be established as a startup study about the EH of the term structure, simple measurement methods such as observable proxies for the BRP would be employed. Among the different observable proxies suggested by relevant literature, this thesis considered the estimations of Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller (1986), and Boero and Torricelli (2000). They measured the BRP using proxies of risk. Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller associated the term premium as the measure for risk associated with holding a long-term bond, 𝜉𝑡 𝑅𝐼𝑆𝐾𝑡 (Eq. 20) which is positively related with each other. Risk, on the other hand, is also unobservable, but imperfect proxies for it can be obtained. For this study, various measures of interest rate volatility are employed, with the assumption that volatility is directly proportional to risk, 𝑅𝐼𝑆𝐾𝑡 𝑉𝑂𝐿𝑡 . (Eq. 21) From the definition of term premium as an investor’s compensation for risk, assuming risk-averse investors, the required expected return for holding long-term bonds must rise when they are riskier. Consequently, if 52 long-term bonds are less risky, the required compensation of investors must also fall. It can, thus, be said that greater interest rate volatility is also associated with a greater term premium, and reduced interest rate volatility with a smaller term premium.77 Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller (1986) also considered a plausible model of volatility as a proxy for risk, which is expected volatility, 𝑅𝐼𝑆𝐾𝑡 𝐸𝑡 (𝑉𝑂𝐿𝑡 ) (Eq. 22) which is also positively related to risk. However, expected volatility is also unobservable hence, actual volatility was adopted as an imperfect proxy for expected volatility. It also follows from the EH that the measurement error between actual and expected volatility is uncorrelated with the term spread at time t.78 5. Macroeconomic Factors and the Bond Risk Premium Several studies on the EH have cited the relevance of macroeconomic factors that affect or are related to the BRP. One of which was Chantapacdepong (2007) who examined the determinants of the timevarying risk premia. Chantapacdepong used three classifications of macroeconomic variables which are the domestic and foreign economic variables, government/fiscal variables, and institutional variables, and used Gregory Mankiw, Stephen Goldfeld, and Robert Shiller, “The Term Structure of Interest Rates Revisited,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1986, no.1 (1986), http://www. jstor.org/stable/2534414. 78 Gregory Mankiw, Stephen Goldfeld, and Robert Shiller, “The Term Structure of Interest Rates Revisited,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1986, no.1 (1986), http://www. jstor.org/stable/2534414. 77 53 cross sectional regressions to identify the relationship of these data to the estimated BRP. Since studies on the BRP of the Philippines have been very limited and they have not identified the corresponding correlations and/or expected relationship of the BRP with various macroeconomic variables, this thesis would rely on a new framework. This new basis is a combination of three well-known frameworks which are the Risk-Return Tradeoff Principle, the Supply and Demand Framework in the Money Market, and the Framework for Real and Financial Markets. In this study, it shall be considered that factors contributing to higher bond returns (either coming from the supply or demand side of Treasury funds) shall be associated with higher risk and hence, higher BRP. Consequently, factors that contribute to lower bond returns shall be associated with lower risk and thus, lower BRP. Figure 4 shows the simple and straightforward relationship between risk and return. The Risk-Return Tradeoff Principle primarily asserts that risk and investment returns have a direct positive relationship. Potential return rises with increased risk, while low potential returns are associated with lower risk. On the other hand, Figure 5 illustrates the interaction of the supply of money and demand for money that determines the level of interest rates. Money supply (MS) is considered fixed in the long-run that explains the vertical line graph, while money demand (MD) is comparable to the appearance of aggregate demand (i.e. downward sloping). The initial 54 equilibrium point (point A) is where MS1 and MD1 intersects. An increase in money supply (MS1 to MS2), with money demand held constant (at MD1), shall induce interest rates to fall (from r1 to r2) at equilibrium point B. The opposite shall happen if a decrease in money supply happens, ceteris paribus. On the other hand, when there is an increase in money demand (MD1 to MD2), with money supply held constant (at MS1), will cause interest rates to increase (r1 to r3) and equilibrium point will be at point C. If a decrease in money demand happens, interest rates shall decrease, ceteris Return paribus. Risk Figure 4. Risk & Return Tradeoff Principle Source: “Risk-Return Tradeoff”, Investopedia, http://www.investopedia.com/terms/r/riskreturntradeoff.asp 55 Figure 5. Supply and Demand in the Money Market Source: Mankiw, Gregory. Macroeconomics. 5th edition. New York: Worth Publishers, 2003. The next step is to find out the factors affecting money supply and money demand in the Philippines that contribute to the rise and fall of domestic interest rates. For this, we shall rely on the framework of Abola (2014) below which highlights the underlying relationships between domestic interest rates and macroeconomic variables (both domestic and foreign). Figure 6 shows that domestic interest rates are directly influenced by foreign interest rates. As explained by Abola (2014), foreign interest rates (especially US) have a positive relationship with domestic interest rates. Higher interest rates in the US would allow capital flight from Philippine assets. This lessens the supply of funds available locally. Ceteris paribus, a decrease in supply will result to an increase in domestic interest 56 rates. Hence, an increase in US interest rates also prompts an increase in Philippine interest rates. However, Abola argued that the transmission of a change in foreign interest rates is not 1-for-1 but only 1/3 o3 33%.79 Furthermore, interest rates are also determined by the domestic supply of funds and demand for funds. The funds supply and demand, in turn, are affected by domestic macroeconomic variables. Demand for funds is influenced by: 1) the demand of private firms, 2) demand of the public sector or the National Government (NG); 3) additional demand resulting from inflation; and 4) sometimes, output or gross domestic product (GDP). The supply of funds, on the other hand, is determined by income measured by GDP and OFW remittances (which becomes Gross National Product (GNP)) in the form of savings. The impact of GNP growth, in turn, is affected by the foreign exchange rate. BSP’s monetary stance is also a determinant of the supply of funds.80 Combining the three frameworks, a diagram of macroeconomic determinants of the bond risk premium is demonstrated in Figure 7. Figure 7 shows that the bond risk premium (BRP) is directly associated to risk, that is, higher risk means a higher BRP and lower risk needs a lower BRP. Risk, on the other hand, is directly associated to bond returns such that increased bond returns entails higher risk, while lower bond returns involves lower Victor Abola, “Domestic Interest Rates: After disasters, a downward trend”, Recent Economic Indicators, November 2014. 80 Victor Abola, “Domestic Interest Rates: After disasters, a downward trend”, Recent Economic Indicators, November 2014. 79 57 risk. This encapsulates the risk-return tradeoff principle exemplified by Figure 4. The third level of the diagram pertains to the relationship of bond returns with the supply and demand of funds. Basically, higher bond returns are produced when money demand is high while money supply is held constant. The outcome is the same when money supply is low while money demand is held constant. Thus, factors that positively affect money demand (or negatively affect money supply) are considered to be the variables which contribute to a higher BRP. On the other hand, lower bond returns are produced when money supply is high while money demand is held constant (or when money demand is high while money supply is held constant). Hence, factors that positively affect money supply (or negatively affect money demand) are considered to contribute to a lower BRP. The main macroeconomic variables that affect the supply of and demand for Treasury funds are also enumerated in Figure 7, as compiled from the framework of real and financial markets by Abola (2014).81 These macroeconomic variables are to be supplemented by some factors used by Bico (2010). Some of these factors are the bond spread and the lagged values of the dependent variable.82 Additionally, although Abola classified monetary policy under the factors that inversely affect the BRP, this study shall adopt the finding of Bico that bond yields are positively related to 81 M2 (broad money) or M3 was also included by Abola in one of the interest rate frameworks that he developed. M2 or M3 82 C. Bico, “Estimating and Forecasting the Philippines Zero-Coupon Yield Curve: A Multimethod Approach” (Thesis, University of Asia and the Pacific, 2010), 64-71. 58 BSP’s monetary stance and thus, contributes to higher risk and a higher BRP. This assertion is also confirmed by the finding of Ireland (2015) that a “monetary policy tightening increases the [bond risk] premia while monetary policy easing works to decrease them”.83 Stock market activity was also included as suggested by the study of Ilmanen (2012) which has a positive effect on BRP. US and Global Environment World Economic Growth World Financial Markets Foreign Interest Rates/FX Rates Stocks Bonds Commodities OFW P/$ Rate BSP Supply of Funds PSEi Domestic Interest Rates T-Bonds Inflation Demand for Funds Fiscal Balance Savings For Production GNP Growth Figure 6. Framework for Real and Financial Markets Source: Abola, Victor. “Domestic Interest Rates: After disasters, a downward trend.” Recent Economic Indicators, November 2014. Peter Ireland, “Monetary Policy, Bond Risk Premia, and the Economy,” National Bureau of Economic Research (2015): 28. 83 59 High Bond Risk Premium Low Bond Risk Premium High Risk = High Bond Returns Low Risk = Low Bond Returns Increase in Money Demand Increase in Money Supply (with Money Supply held constant) (with Money Demand held constant) Private sector demand Public sector demand (i.e., National Government) Domestic Inflation Peso-Dollar Rate Foreign variables (US Inflation and US Treasury Rates) Gross Domestic Product (GDP) Gross National Product (GNP) or OFW Remittances Gross International Reserves (GIR) Foreign Investments M2 or M3 BSP’s Monetary Policy Figure 7. Relationship of Macroeconomic Determinants of the Bond Risk Premium Source of Macroeconomic Concepts: Abola, Victor. “Domestic Interest Rates: After disasters, a downward trend.” Recent Economic Indicators, November 2014. To uncover the underlying effects of these explanatory variables to the BRP, the estimated risk premium shall be regressed against the mentioned macroeconomic variables. In this way, researchers, policymakers, and investors shall know what factors to focus on when monitoring the country’s interest rates. The macroeconomic variables, their definitions, and corresponding expected signs are summarized in the table below: 60 Table 5. Explanatory Variables, Definitions, and Expected Relationship with BRP Variable Notation Definition Domestic and Foreign Economic Variables In order to fit the frequency of the data, monthly sales GDP growth of Meralco (Economic 𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠 (electricity sales) can be Growth) used as a proxy for economic growth. This pertains to the year-onyear growth of the Price 𝑔𝑖𝑛𝑓 Consumer Price Index (CPI) with a monthly frequency. This refers to the average monthly peso-dollar Peso-Dollar exchange rate. To remove 𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥 Rate the general trend of the peso, the growth rate was used. M2 is the measure of broad money available in the financial system. This includes the currency in Excess Liquidity 𝑔𝑚2 circulation, peso demand deposits, peso savings, and time deposits. Monthly growth rate was used. This pertains to the monthly OFW OFW remittances in dollars. 𝑔𝑜𝑓𝑤𝑟𝑒𝑚 Remittances Growth rate was also used to remove the trend. This is the overnight policy rate or the reverse repurchase rate used by the Monetary Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas 𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝 Stance (BSP). The monthly growth rates were used to achieve robust results. This pertains to the monthly US Prices growth of inflation in the 𝑔𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖 US. This refers to the average monthly overnight policy Federal Funds rate in the US. Growth rate 𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒 Rate was used to remove the trend. Expected Relationship with BRP – + + – – + + + 61 Gross International Reserves 𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟 These are the foreign assets readily controlled by the BSP for financing and managing imbalances. They are used as indicators of the country’s liquidity and ability to pay imports and foreign obligations. Growth rates were used to remove the trend in the data. – Government/Fiscal Variables Budget Deficit 𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑖𝑐𝑖𝑡 Government Debt 𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑏𝑡 This refers to the monthly budget deficit of the government as a percentage of GDP, measured using net domestic financing. Growth rate was used to remove the underlying trend. This refers to the monthly growth rate of the debt of the government as a percentage of GDP. + + Institutional Variables Stock Market Index 𝑔𝑝𝑠𝑒𝑖 This represents the monthly performance of the stock market. The growth rate of the index was used to remove the trend. + Additional Variables Lag of Bond Risk Premium 𝑏𝑟𝑝𝑙𝑎𝑔 Bond Spread 𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑 This pertains to the lagged value of the estimated bond risk premium per bond pair. With this, we can check if the present value of the BRP is highly affected by its past value. This pertains to the slope of the yield curve, or simply the difference between two certain maturities which are the bond pairs. + + Source: Abola (2014), Chantapacdepong (2007), Bico (2010), and Ilmanen (2012) 62 B. Conceptual Framework The framework below illustrates the relationships of the major concepts discussed in this research. Figure 8 shows that the Expectations Hypothesis (EH) assuming a constant term premium holds true if standard tests satisfy three specific implications which are: 1) The term spread must predict future changes in the short rates; 2) The term spread must predict future changes in the long rate; and 3) The term spread must not predict the excess returns. If any of these assumptions is rejected, it can be said there is some disturbance affecting the EH model. In this study, this disturbance is readily assumed to be the bond risk premium (BRP). Since the BRP is unobservable, estimation techniques must be done to measure it. An estimated BRP can be plugged in into the EH model but now assuming a time-varying risk premium. The conditions of the former EH model must still hold hence, diagnostic tests would be required to inspect if the standard regression method improved the previous results or not. Finally, to deepen the discussion about the estimated BRP, macroeconomic variables affecting it or highly correlated to it would be examined. C. Empirical Methodology The methodologies used in this study were made to correspond to each research objective. The first objective, which is to empirically test the validity of the assumptions of the Expectations Hypothesis (EH) on Philippine bond yields, shall be achieved by applying the bond yields into the term spread models and excess returns model. 63 The first term spread model shall forecast future changes in the short rate denoted by 0.5 (𝑟𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) = 𝛼1 + 𝛽1 (𝑅𝑡−1 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚, (from Eq. 14) while the second version of the EH model shall relate the term spread model to future changes in the long rate, that is 𝑁(𝑅𝑡 − 𝑅𝑡−1 ) = 𝛼2 + 𝛽2 (𝑅𝑡−1 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚. (from Eq. 15) For the EH to be satisfied, the coefficients of 𝛼1 and 𝛼2 must approach zero while the coefficients of 𝛽1 and 𝛽2 must equal unity or one by estimating the two models via ordinary least squares (OLS). To test the third assumption of the EH, which is that excess returns must not predict excess returns, Equation 19 would be tested via OLS. 𝐻𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽𝑋𝑡 + 𝜐𝑡+1 (from Eq. 19) using the variables recommended by Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller (1986) which should produce 𝛽 coefficients of zero. These variables are the lagged values of the excess returns 𝐻𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽 (𝐸𝑅𝑙𝑎𝑔𝑔𝑒𝑑 ) + 𝜐𝑡+1 (Eq. 23) and the term spread 𝐻𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽 (𝑅𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡 ) + 𝜐𝑡+1 . (Eq. 24) Diagnostic tests of the residuals for Equations 15, 18, and 20 would be performed to consistently estimate the equation and achieve unbiased results. Corresponding corrective econometric techniques would be applied if signs of serial correlation or conditional heteroskedasticity are present. 64 Expectations Hypothesis with constant bond risk premium changes in short rate otherwise must changes in predict long rate re-testing excess returns must not Expectations Hypothesis with timevarying bond risk premium Bond Risk Premium Macroeconomic Factors Figure 8. Conceptual Framework of the Study The next research objective aims to estimate the bond risk premium for the respective bond maturities of the Philippines. To fulfill this, several measures of the BRP would be done, specifically following the proxies of Boero and Torricelli (2000). Boero and Torricelli took off from the assumption of Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller’s (1986) that the term premium can be modeled using proxies for risk; and to represent risk, interest rate volatility can be measured. Boero and Torriceli used three alternative measures for volatility. These are the: 65 1. moving average of absolute changes in the short rate computed over the previous 6 periods84 𝐵𝑅𝑃𝑀𝐴,𝑡 = 𝑚 𝑚 ∑5𝑖=0 |𝑅𝑡−𝑖 − 𝑅𝑡−𝑖−1 | 6 ; (Eq. 25) 2. square of expected excess holding period return 𝐵𝑅𝑃(𝐸𝑅)2 ,𝑡 = 𝐸𝑡 (𝐻𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡 )2 ; and (Eq. 26) 3. estimates of conditional standard deviations and variances from the univariate GARCH model 𝐵𝑅𝑃𝐺𝐴𝑅𝐶𝐻 = ℎ𝑡 , (Eq. 27) specifically, the lag structure GARCH (1,1), where: 2 ℎ𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽1 𝜀𝑡−1 + 𝛽2 ℎ𝑡−1 . (Eq. 28) Boero and Torricelli (2000) adopted these three measures from various researches as well. The first measure was used by Fama (1976), Jones and Roley (1983), and Simon (1989). The second one was used by Simon (1989) and Harris (1998). Lastly, the third measure was adopted from the initial works of Engle, Lilien, and Robins (1987) which also used ARCH-in-mean (Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity-in-mean) models, and subsequently developed into GARCH models. Once the BRP has been estimated, they will be individually plugged into the extended versions of the regression Equations 14 (for the short rate) and 15 (for the long rate), as follows: 84 Since the same short rates are used for the long rate case (or the n-period case), the moving average of the change in the long rates would be considered. 66 Moving Average: 0.5 (𝑟𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) = 𝛼1 + 𝛽1 (𝑅𝑡−1 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) + 𝛾𝐵𝑅𝑃𝑀𝐴,𝑡 + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 (Eq. 29) 𝑁(𝑅𝑡 − 𝑅𝑡−1 ) = 𝛼2 + 𝛽2 (𝑅𝑡−1 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) + 𝛾𝐵𝑅𝑃𝑀𝐴,𝑡 + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 (Eq. 30) Square of Excess Returns: 0.5 (𝑟𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) = 𝛼1 + 𝛽1 (𝑅𝑡−1 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) + 𝛾𝐵𝑅𝑃(𝐸𝑅)2,𝑡 + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 (Eq. 31) 𝑁(𝑅𝑡 − 𝑅𝑡−1 ) = 𝛼2 + 𝛽2 (𝑅𝑡−1 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) + 𝛾𝐵𝑅𝑃(𝐸𝑅)2,𝑡 + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 (Eq. 32) GARCH (1,1) 0.5 (𝑟𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) = 𝛼1 + 𝛽1 (𝑅𝑡−1 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) + 𝛾𝐵𝑅𝑃𝐺𝐴𝑅𝐶𝐻 + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 (Eq. 31) 𝑁(𝑅𝑡 − 𝑅𝑡−1 ) = 𝛼2 + 𝛽2 (𝑅𝑡−1 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) + 𝛾𝐵𝑅𝑃𝐺𝐴𝑅𝐶𝐻 + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 (Eq. 32) These models shall accomplish the third objective. To evaluate the said BRP proxies, goodness of fit evaluations were done. This study used the four criteria of Gujarati (2011), which are the Adjusted R2, F-statistic, Akaike Information Criterion (AIC), and Schwarz Information Criterion (SIC).85 Adjusted R2 The Adjusted R2, similar to the R2, captures the proportion of variation in the dependent variable accounted by the independent variables. The adjusted R2, nonetheless, adjusts for the number of terms in a model, thus, the adjusted R2 only improves if the added explanatory value is considered significant (or has a significant t-stat value).86 C. Bico, “Estimating and Forecasting the Philippine Zero-Coupon Yield Curve: A Multimethod Approach” (Thesis, University of Asia and the Pacific, 2010), 45-46. 86 J. Bico, “Estimating and Forecasting the Philippine Zero-Coupon Yield Curve: A Multimethod Approach” (Thesis, University of Asia and the Pacific, 2010), 46. 85 67 F-Statistic This tests the overall significance of a set of variables in explaining the dependent variable (Wooldridge, 2009). The F-test assesses the validity of the null hypothesis that is, the coefficients of the explanatory variables are zero (thus, does not have an effect on the dependent variable). The desired result for this study is for the null to be rejected. To achieve this, a higher the value of the F-statistic is needed or a probability value of less than 0.05.87 Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) The AIC is commonly used in selecting the best regression model. The AIC puts a harsher penalty (equivalent to 2𝑘 𝑛 , where k is the number of regressors and n is the number of observations) for adding more variables into the model just like the adjusted R2. It rewards goodness of fit but includes a penalty for overfitting (or increasing the number of parameters to improve a model). The AIC represents an estimate of information loss to minimize the uncertainty that a model is close to the true model. Hence, the model with the lowest AIC is the most efficient.88 Schwarz Information Criterion (SIC) The SIC (also known as Schwarz’ Bayesian Information Criterion) is an alternative to the AIC which imposes a harsher penalty factor (equal “The F-test,” The F-Test for Linear Regression, http://facweb.cs.depaul.edu/sjost/csc423/documents/f-test-reg.htm (accessed April 15, 2015). 88 “Akaike Information Criterion,” Wikipedia, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Akaike_information_criterion (accessed April 15, 2015). 87 68 𝑘 to [𝑛 ln 𝑛]) . Similarly, the model with the lowest SIC is the most efficient. The SIC also mitigates the risk of overfitting to filter the unnecessary complicated models. Because of its harsher penalty, SIC prefers simpler models than the AIC.89 Apart from the four criteria, the improvement of the 𝛼 and 𝛽 coefficients were also considered. The fourth objective, which is to identify the macroeconomic variables that highly affect the estimated BRP, would be achieved via a panel regression model where the dependent variables are the estimated BRP. The fixed effects specification was used as we are interested in analyzing the impact of the explanatory variables which are time-varying.90 Different variations of tests would be done – whole sample test, short rate tests, long rate tests, and analysis according to two periods (2006 to 2010 and 2011 to 2014) for both the short rate and long rate. The division of the periods was done to compare the condition of interest rates during the crisis and after the crisis. They are denoted as follows: Model 1: Whole Sample 𝐵𝑅𝑃𝑖𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽𝑏𝑟𝑝(−1)𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚2𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑜𝑓𝑤𝑟𝑒𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑖𝑐𝑖𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑏𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑝𝑠𝑒𝑖𝑖𝑡 (Eq. 33) where: 𝑖 = whole sample (for both short rates and long rates) 𝑡 = 2006 to 2014 “Bayesian Information Criterion,” Statistical & Financial Consulting by Stanford PhD, http://stanfordphd.com/BIC.html (accessed April 15, 2015). 90 On the contrary, the random effects specification is used when the effect of time-invariant variables (such as gender, culture, religion, etc.) wants to be investigated. 89 69 Model 2: Short Rate 𝐵𝑅𝑃𝑖𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽𝑏𝑟𝑝(−1)𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚2𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑜𝑓𝑤𝑟𝑒𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑖𝑐𝑖𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑏𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑝𝑠𝑒𝑖𝑖𝑡 (Eq. 34) where: 𝑖 = short rate sample (BRP for 3-month and 6-month, 6-month and 1year, and 1-year and 2-year) 𝑡 = 2006 to 2014 Model 3: Long Rate 𝐵𝑅𝑃𝑖𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽𝑏𝑟𝑝(−1)𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚2𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑜𝑓𝑤𝑟𝑒𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑖𝑐𝑖𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑏𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑝𝑠𝑒𝑖𝑖𝑡 (Eq. 35) where: 𝑖 = long rate sample (BRP for 1-year and 3-year, 1-year and 5-year, and 1-year and 10-year) 𝑡 = 2006 to 2014 Model 4: 2006 to 2010 𝐵𝑅𝑃𝑖𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽𝑏𝑟𝑝(−1)𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚2𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑜𝑓𝑤𝑟𝑒𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑖𝑐𝑖𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑏𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑝𝑠𝑒𝑖𝑖𝑡 (Eq. 36) where: 𝑖 = whole sample (for both short rates and long rates) 𝑡 = 2006 to 2010 Model 5: 2011 to 2014 𝐵𝑅𝑃𝑖𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽𝑏𝑟𝑝(−1)𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚2𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑜𝑓𝑤𝑟𝑒𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑖𝑐𝑖𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑏𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑝𝑠𝑒𝑖𝑖𝑡 (Eq. 37) where: 𝑖 = whole sample (for both short rates and long rates) 𝑡 = 2011 to 2014 Model 6: Short Rate (2006 to 2010) 𝐵𝑅𝑃𝑖𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽𝑏𝑟𝑝(−1)𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚2𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑜𝑓𝑤𝑟𝑒𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑖𝑐𝑖𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑏𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑝𝑠𝑒𝑖𝑖𝑡 (Eq. 38) where: 𝑖 = short rate sample (BRP for 3-month and 6-month, 6-month and 1-year, and 1-year and 2-year) 𝑡 = 2006 to 2010 70 Model 7: Long Rate (2006 to 2010) 𝐵𝑅𝑃𝑖𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽𝑏𝑟𝑝(−1)𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚2𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑜𝑓𝑤𝑟𝑒𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑖𝑐𝑖𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑏𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑝𝑠𝑒𝑖𝑖𝑡 (Eq. 39) where: 𝑖 = long rate sample (BRP for 1-year and 3-year, 1-year and 5-year, and 1-year and 10-year) 𝑡 = 2006 to 2010 Model 8: Short Rate (2011 to 2014) 𝐵𝑅𝑃𝑖𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽𝑏𝑟𝑝(−1)𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚2𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑜𝑓𝑤𝑟𝑒𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑖𝑐𝑖𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑏𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑝𝑠𝑒𝑖𝑖𝑡 (Eq. 40) where: 𝑖 = short rate sample (BRP for 3-month and 6-month, 6-month and 1-year, and 1-year and 2-year) 𝑡 = 2011 to 2014 Model 9: Long Rate (2011 to 2014) 𝐵𝑅𝑃𝑖𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽𝑏𝑟𝑝(−1)𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑚2𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑜𝑓𝑤𝑟𝑒𝑚𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑖𝑐𝑖𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑑𝑒𝑏𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽𝑔𝑝𝑠𝑒𝑖𝑖𝑡 (Eq. 41) where: 𝑖 = long rate sample (BRP for 1-year and 3-year, 1-year and 5-year, and 1-year and 10-year) 𝑡 = 2011 to 2014 Corresponding relationships (whether positively related or negatively related) would be verified while the impact of each variable shall be indicated by the 𝛽 coefficients. Lastly, implications of the study on the bond market shall be formulated by compiling and summarizing the findings of the various tests. Recommendations regarding the implications of the study will also be enumerated to benefit the sectors to which this thesis is aimed at. 71 To summarize, all of the empirical methodologies discussed above are shown in Figure 9. D. Data Requirements For the tests of the Expectations Hypothesis (EH), monthly zero-coupon government bond yields from 2006 to 2014 are used. Since the country no longer issues zero coupon bonds, theoretical bond yields computed via bootstrapping obtained through the Bloomberg terminal are employed in the models. The bond yields that are going to be examined have the following tenors: 3month, 6-month, 1-year, 2-year, 3-year, 5-year, and 10-year. For the two-period case of the EH tests, the tenors included are the: 1) 3-month and 6-month bonds, 2) 6-month and 1-year bonds, and the 3) 1-year and 2-year bonds. For the n-period case, the short rate, 𝑟𝑡 , shall be the 1-year bonds and the following long rates are the 3-year, 5-year, and 10-year bonds. The estimation of the bond risk premium (BRP) would also make use of the same bond yield pairs. The macroeconomic variables needed for the tests of correlation and predictive power are the monthly growth rates of the following: Meralco sales (proxy for GDP/economic growth), Philippine inflation, peso-dollar rate, money supply (M2), OFW remittances, BSP policy rate, US inflation, gross international reserves, federal funds rate, budget deficit as a percent of GDP, government debt as a percent of GDP, Philippine Stock Exchange Index, lagged values of the bond risk premium, and the spread of the bond pairs. 72 Empirical Test of the EH on Philippine Bond Yields Methodologies: * Estimation of the term spread models of the EH using OLS * Applicaion of corrective econometric techniques for serial correlation and/or conditional heteroskedasticity Estimation of the Bond Risk Premium Methodologies: * Estimation of the risk premium using various observable proxies of volatility * Selection of one best BRP proxy Empirical Test of the EH with Bond Risk Premium Methodologies: * Replication of the Term Spread Models of the EH using OLS including a time-varying risk premium * Applicaion of corrective econometric techniques for serial correlation and/or conditional heteroskedasticity Macroeconomic Variables and the BRP Methodologies: * Evaluate the impact of various macroecoomic variables to the estimated BRP via regression. Figure 9. Summary of Methodologies of the Study 73 CHAPTER IV RESULTS AND DISCUSSION A. Preliminary Analysis of Data Figure 10 illustrates the movement of bond yields through time. It is observed that bond yields had been gradually falling from 2006 to 2014. By inference also, it shows that interest rates of short-term bonds are greater than longterm bonds. This is an indication of the possibility that long-term rates differ from short-term rates via a factor (cited as the term premium), thereby diverging from the assumption of the Pure Expectations Hypothesis (PEH) that the bond risk premium is zero.91 12.0000 10.0000 PERCENT 8.0000 6.0000 4.0000 2.0000 2006M01 2006M05 2006M09 2007M01 2007M05 2007M09 2008M01 2008M05 2008M09 2009M01 2009M05 2009M09 2010M01 2010M05 2010M09 2011M01 2011M05 2011M09 2012M01 2012M05 2012M09 2013M01 2013M05 2013M09 2014M01 2014M05 2014M09 0.0000 3mo 6mo 1y 2y 3y 5y 10y Figure 10. 3-month to 10-year Monthly Bond Yields (2006 to 2014) Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC) 91 The traditional version of the Pure Expectations Hypothesis asserts that the bond risk premium is zero, while the modified form known as the Expectations Hypothesis (EH) asserts that the bond risk premium is constant. 74 Simple correlations among the bond yields were also explored. Table 6 shows that correlation is high among neighboring tenors. Consequently, as one tenor moves farther away from another, its correlation coefficient weakens. This observation can be compared to the thesis results of Diaz (2012) that confirmed the possible long run equilibrium relationship among adjacent bond yields (such as between the 91-day and 182-day, 364-day, and 10-year rates, and between 10-year rates and 91-day, 182-day, 364-day, 2-year, and 5-year rates) using the Johansen Cointegration test from 2005 to 2011.92 Table 6. Correlations of Bond Yields m3 m6 y1 y2 y3 y5 y10 m3 1.00 0.97 0.97 0.93 0.91 0.90 0.88 m6 0.97 1.00 0.98 0.94 0.92 0.89 0.85 y1 0.97 0.98 1.00 0.97 0.95 0.92 0.88 y2 0.93 0.94 0.97 1.00 0.97 0.93 0.88 y3 0.91 0.92 0.95 0.97 1.00 0.95 0.90 y5 0.90 0.89 0.92 0.93 0.95 1.00 0.94 0.88 0.85 0.88 0.88 0.90 0.94 1.00 y10 Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC) The statistical details of the bond yields are shown in Table 7, for both the whole sample and the two subsamples classified into the global financial crisis period (2006 to 2011)93 and the post-crisis period (2012 to 2014). Undoubtedly, the bond returns at the advent and during the turmoil of the global financial crisis were much higher than the whole sample and the post-crisis period with a mean of 4.63% for the 3-month bonds to 8.14% for the 10-year bonds. J. Diaz, “The Philippine Term Structure of Interest Rates: An Empirical Analysis” (Thesis, University of Asia and the Pacific, 2012), 87. 93 This division was based on several written articles (such as in The Economist and The Guardian) that traced the timeline of the Global Financial Crisis. 92 75 Standard deviation of the bond yields were also higher when compared to the postcrisis results, signaling the elevated volatility of rates before and during the crisis. The kurtosis of the bond yields during the crisis also indicate that yields were very volatile as they were too scattered from the mean. Moreover, the measure of skewness signified that there were more chances for negative outcomes at the shortend of the yield curve than the long-end. This might have signaled that a crisis was about to happen soon as short-term instruments were viewed to be riskier than longterm bonds. Even though the financial sector was cited to be “fairly stable” when the crisis hit, adverse macroeconomic consequences (weak economic growth, high unemployment rates, tight credit availability abroad, weak consumer spending, risk averse market, etc.) and uncertainties present during the financial collapse caused the market to demand higher returns. 94 After the crisis, the Federal Reserve and other large countries and institutions joined forces to inject enough liquidity for the global economy to recover.95 The global market has been doubly cautious about the financial system that financial institutions have tried to protect themselves from external shocks by stocking up big reserves. The Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP) also bulked itself with great dollar reserves and implemented precautionary measures for banks. Josef Yap, Celia Reyes, and Janet Cuenca, “Impact of the Global Financial and Economic Crisis on the Philippines,” Philippine Institute for Development Studies (2009): 1-9. 95 Larry Elliot, Global financial crisis: five key stages (2007-2011), in The Guardian, http://www.theguardian.com/business/2011/aug/07/global-financial-crisis-key-stages (accessed March 19, 2015). 94 76 Bond markets, thus, rallied, bringing yields to their record lows until the present amidst the increased liquidity built over the years. This is confirmed by the post-crisis bond returns which were well below the whole sample mean with an average difference of 184 basis points (bps) across all maturities. Volatility of bond returns also tempered after the crisis periods, with standard deviations below 1% (except for the 2-year bond) and kurtosis levels lower than during the crisis period. Table 7. Statistical Details of Bond Yields (Whole Sample & Subsamples) Mean Whole Sample Risk Free Bond Yields Median Max. Min. Std. Dev. Skewness m3 3.17 3.69 8.91 0.10 1.95 m6 3.45 4.03 8.69 0.18 2.04 y1 3.87 4.40 7.79 0.41 2.06 y2 4.60 4.74 10.24 1.93 1.97 y3 4.99 5.22 10.72 1.98 1.91 y5 5.65 5.89 11.42 2.16 1.81 y10 6.70 6.99 10.69 2.91 2.01 2006-2010 (Financial Crisis Period) Risk Free m3 4.63 4.31 8.91 1.20 1.21 Bond Returns m6 5.00 4.78 8.69 1.47 1.22 y1 5.45 5.22 7.79 2.55 1.17 y2 6.05 5.66 10.24 3.56 1.32 y3 6.34 5.90 10.72 4.24 1.31 y5 6.90 6.55 11.42 4.78 1.22 y10 8.14 8.37 10.69 5.91 1.14 2011-2014 (Post-Financial Crisis Period) Risk Free m3 1.32 1.30 3.20 0.10 0.79 Bond Returns m6 1.48 1.54 3.22 0.18 0.76 y1 1.85 1.90 3.81 0.41 0.77 y2 2.74 2.55 4.74 1.93 0.69 y3 3.26 3.22 5.43 1.98 0.86 y5 4.05 3.90 6.49 2.16 0.98 y10 4.85 4.45 7.55 2.91 1.20 Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC) Kurtosis 0.19 0.14 0.09 0.41 0.41 0.29 -0.11 2.24 1.98 1.77 2.25 2.62 2.94 2.00 0.39 0.12 0.05 0.72 1.01 1.18 0.19 5.34 4.28 2.65 3.26 3.76 5.04 2.66 0.27 0.01 0.26 1.60 0.76 0.18 0.44 2.39 2.32 2.79 4.97 3.10 2.42 2.17 The movement of the bond yields can also be analyzed using yield curves. The yield curves of the sample are plotted in Figure 11 by taking the yearly average of the 3-month to 10-year bonds. It can be observed that Philippine yield curves are most of the time increasing and concave. Again, from visual inspection, we notice 77 a substantial flattening of the yield curve from 2006 to 2014. Highest yields were obtained in 2006 while the lowest ones were in 2013. However, further slicing into the periods would reveal how the yield curves behaved amidst the financial crisis affecting countries abroad. Before the bursting of the housing bubble, around 2006 to 2007, yield curves shifted downwards, indicative of lower bond yields across maturities. The bond market was at a rally point, unaware of what could happen next. When the crisis started in 2008, the yield curve began to shift up. This economic shock quaked the bond market and made the investors more cautious. Due to heightened uncertainties in the long run, market demand diverted its focus on the short rates that plunged by 160 bps, while long rates did not budge at all. As the crisis normalized in 2010, regained market sentiment pushed the yield curve downwards. From 2011, continuous flattening of the yield curve was experienced up until yields reached record lows in 2013. 2014, was then again, characterized by an increase in yields after the termination of the Fed’s stimulus package in October 2014 that raised expectations for an increase in US interest rates. Bond yield spreads also highlight the condition of bonds during the crisis years and post-crisis years. Yield spreads are defined as the difference between the quoted rates of two investment maturities. Usually, yield spreads are used as measures of “risk” because a higher absolute value of the spread indicates a steeper yield curve. A steeper yield curve signals the market’s risk aversion for long maturities and great demand for short maturities. It is measured in basis points where 1% is equal to 100 basis points (bps). 78 Figure 12 clearly shows that average yield spreads were more elevated during the crisis years (2009 to 2011), indicative of the heightened risk aversion for long term investments of the market players. This finding also indicates that East Asian countries were still vulnerable to external shocks due to the increased financial market integration. Since non-residents still have a great hold of the country’s dollar-denominated bonds (ROPs) at a share of 58% as of end-2008, effects of the crisis have been more pronounced.96 Nonetheless, after the crisis years, we can see that spreads have returned to their pre-crisis levels, now below the nine-year spread average of 351 bps. 10.00 9.00 PERCENT 8.00 2006 7.00 2007 6.00 2008 5.00 2009 2010 4.00 2011 3.00 2012 2.00 2013 1.00 2014 0.00 m3 m6 y1 y2 y3 y5 y10 BOND TENORS Figure 11. Philippine Yield Curve (2006 to 2014) Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC) Diwa Guinigundo, The impact of the global financial crisis on the Philippines financial system – an assessment, BIS no. 54, http://www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap54s.pdf (accessed March 19, 2015). 96 79 500 450 400 Basis Points (bps) 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 Figure 12. 3-month vs. 10-year Yield Spread (Yearly Average) Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC) B. Current Developments of the Philippine Bond Market 1. Size and Composition Since 2006, the size of the Philippine bond market in terms of local currency value has been growing at a steady pace. Figure 13 shows that as of December 2014, the total peso value of the bond market already reached P4.6 T, a 107% improvement from the bond market size in 2006. Nevertheless, the share-to-GDP of government bonds is seen to be gradually declining as the size of the corporate bond market has been accelerating (in Figure 14). From government securities’ (GS) GDP share at 37.9 % in 2006, it has fallen to 30.8% in December 2014. On the contrary, from corporate bonds’ meager share-to-GDP at 0.81% in 2006, it has grown to 6.0% at present. This demonstrates the increasing ability of corporations to finance their activities with debt – that may indicate increased liquidity or cash position of private industries. 80 The outstanding amount of foreign-denominated bonds of the Philippines (also known as ROPs) is also expanding. It has reached US $34.9 as of December 2014, from its 2006 volume at US $25.4. Currently, 76.9% of total ROPs are government securities, while the rest are corporate bonds (19.4%) and bonds from banks and financial institutions (3.6%). 5000 4500 Government Corporate 4000 in LCY Billions 3500 3000 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 0 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 Figure 13. Size of Philippine Bond Market in LCY Billions Source of Basic Data: Asian Development Bank, Asian Bonds Online 45 Government Corporate 40 35 % of GDP 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 Figure 14. Size of Philippine Bond Market (% of GDP) Source of Basic Data: Asian Development Bank, Asian Bonds Online 81 However, the country’s bond market still lags behind its ASEAN neighbors. The government securities debt market of China, Malaysia, Singapore, and Thailand outperforms the volume of the Philippines at 30.8% of GDP – but the Philippines’ is way better than the bond markets of Vietnam and Indonesia. In terms of corporate bonds, the country’s volume is slowly catching up with the rest. Corporate bonds are still bigger than Indonesia’s and Vietnam’s. 50 45 40 in USD Billions 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 2006 2007 Government 2008 2009 2010 2011 Banks and Financial Institutions 2012 2013 2014 Other Corporates Figure 15. Outstanding Bonds in Foreign Currency (Local Sources) Source of Basic Data: Asian Development Bank, Asian Bonds Online In terms of composition, the bills-to-bonds ratio is a good indicator to look at. This tells us if the country’s bond market is greatly composed of either short-term debts (bills less than or equal to one year in maturity) or long-term debts (bonds more than one year in maturity). The ratio is calculated by diving the total outstanding government bills to the total outstanding government bonds. 82 80.0 Government 70.0 Corporate 60.5 57.3 60.0 49.8 % of GDP 50.0 42.7 40.0 32.5 32.1 30.8 30.0 20.0 19.0 18.1 21.7 13.0 10.0 6.0 2.2 0.3 0.0 CN ID MY PH SG TH VN Figure 16. Size of Bond Market of ASEAN +1 (% of GDP) (as of December 2014) Source of Basic Data: Asian Development Bank, Asian Bonds Online Figure 17 shows that from 2006, the composition of the Philippine debt market has transitioned from being prominently composed of bills to having an increasing share of long-term bonds. The decline specifically happened amidst the global financial crisis in 2009. This may imply that through time (or after the crisis), the Bureau of the Treasury (BTr) has opted to supply long-term bonds than short-term ones as a way of managing its liabilities. Recently, the BTr and the Department of Finance (DOF) expressively launched its domestic liability management program in August 2014, by re-issuing more than P140 B worth of 10-year benchmark bonds97, “The Republic of the Philippines Announced the Results of its Domestic Liability Management Program”, Bureau of the Treasury, http://www.treasury.gov.ph/wpcontent/uploads/2014/08/Results-Announcement.pdf (accessed April 6, 2015). 97 83 as a way of “rebalancing its debt portfolio, fostering efficient pricing of GS, and enhancing trading of GS”.98 0.6 Bills-to-Bonds Ratio 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 Dec-14 Jul-14 Feb-14 Sep-13 Apr-13 Jun-12 Nov-12 Jan-12 Aug-11 Oct-10 Mar-11 May-10 Jul-09 Dec-09 Feb-09 Sep-08 Apr-08 Nov-07 Jun-07 Jan-07 Aug-06 Mar-06 0 Figure 17. Bills-to-Bond Ratio of the Philippines Source of Basic Data: Asian Development Bank, Asian Bonds Online Relative to the bills-to-bonds ratio of its ASEAN neighbors, the Philippines appears to be at par with the rest. All the countries, except for Hong Kong and Singapore, have debt markets heavily characterized by long-term bonds. Indonesia, Korea, and Philippines have comparatively similar bills-to-bonds ratio at 0.1, with total outstanding bonds larger than bills. In the case of the Philippines, the size of total bonds is 12.5 times greater than the size of bills, while Indonesia and Korea have long-term debts 10.6 times and 7.8 times larger than their bills market, respectively. Japan’s total outstanding bonds is 29.8 times its bills, thus having a 0.03 ratio. Hong Kong and Singapore, on the other hand, have debt markets “Republic of the Philippines Launches Domestic Liability Management Exercise”, Bureau of the Treasury, http://www.treasury.gov.ph/wp-content/uploads/2014/08/press-release.pdf (accessed April 6, 2015). 98 84 immensely composed of bills than bonds. This may imply that the two countries are contemporaneously liquid to have financed a big volume of short-term debts. 5.0 4.1 Bills-toBonds Ratio 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.2 1.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 ID JP KR 0.2 0.1 0.3 0.3 TH VN 0.0 CN* HK MY PH SG Figure 18. Bills-to-Bonds Ratio of ASEAN +3 (as of December 2014) Source of Basic Data: Asian Development Bank, Asian Bonds Online Note: Latest data for China is as of June 2014 2. Liquidity Two indicators are used to measure the liquidity of a country’s debt market. These are the trading volume and the bonds turnover ratio. The trading volume pertains to the degree of market activity in a country using the value of local currency government bonds traded in the secondary market, while the bonds turnover ratio also indicates the extent of trading in the secondary market but relative to the amount of outstanding bonds. Figure 19 shows that the growth of the average value of government bonds being transacted in the secondary market has been accelerating since 2006. As of June 2013, the average trading in the secondary market already 85 reached US $59.8 B. Compared to the ASEAN +3 market, the country still has one of the smallest secondary bond markets with a volume slightly higher than Indonesia, but trails behind the rest of its neighbors (as seen in Figure 20). The largest secondary bond markets can be found in China and Korea with an average value reaching US $1.2 T and US $652.3 B, respectively. For the bonds turnover ratio, Figure 21 illustrates that the share of the traded bonds in the secondary market is increasing, thereby signaling increased liquidity throughout the years. However, the market liquidity of the country is still behind other ASEAN countries. The Philippines, with a turnover ratio of 0.49, is way behind the liquidity of six other ASEAN neighbors (Hong Kong, Japan, Korea, Malaysia, Singapore, and Thailand) with Hong Kong leading the pack with a turnover ratio at 1.46 (which further justifies Hong Kong’s heightened bills-to-bonds ratio). The liquidity of the country, nevertheless, still performs better than China and Indonesia, signifying increased efforts to improve the country’s bond trading activities. 86 70.00 59.80 60.00 50.00 38.95 37.14 40.00 33.40 30.00 20.00 19.08 17.32 16.90 15.77 2006 2007 2008 10.00 0.00 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Figure 19. Trading Volume of Philippine Government Bonds (2013 Average) Source of Basic Data: Asian Development Bank, Asian Bonds Online 1400.0 1228.2 Government Bonds 1200.0 in USD Billions 1000.0 800.0 652.3 600.0 400.0 193.0 151.3 200.0 123.0 23.7 59.8 73.6 PH SG 0.0 CN HK ID KR MY TH Figure 20. Trading Volume of Government Bonds in the ASEAN Market +3 (2013 Average) Source of Basic Data: Asian Development Bank, Asian Bonds Online 87 0.80 0.73 Government Bonds 0.70 0.64 Bonds Turnover Ratio 0.60 0.54 0.53 2011 2012 0.50 0.41 0.40 0.38 0.35 0.31 0.30 0.20 0.10 0.00 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2013 Figure 21. Turnover Ratio of Philippine Government Bonds (Yearly Average) Source of Basic Data: Asian Development Bank, Asian Bonds Online 1.60 1.46 Government Bonds 1.40 1.25 1.27 Bonds Turnover Ratio 1.20 1.00 0.84 0.80 0.70 0.60 0.40 0.70 0.49 0.31 0.30 0.20 0.00 CN HK ID JP KR MY PH SG TH Figure 22. Bonds Turnover Ratio in ASEAN Market +4 (as of June 2013) Source of Basic Data: Asian Development Bank, Asian Bonds Online In terms of liquidity, the Philippines seems to be improving its stand among its peers with the gradual acceleration of its bonds turnover ratio. It 88 is also worth noting that the country is working its way to expand the debt market and enhance its pricing efficiency as evidenced by its liability management programs. The country also aspires to increase its participation in the world capital markets as demonstrated by its successful issuance of US $2 B worth of 25-year dollar-denominated bonds (ROPs) last January 2015.99 These initiatives only reflect the strength of the country’s economy that allowed the bond market to gain a strong reputation in the international scene. With these, we cannot but hope for bigger and better developments in the bond market in the near future. Overall, it can be inferred that relative to its ASEAN neighbors, the debt market of the Philippines is still part of the emerging ones because of its relatively small yet growing bond market, both for government securities and corporate bonds. In terms of size and composition, the country generally lags behind the GS volumes of other countries, but at par with the rest as it is characterized by longterm debts than short-term bills. C. Expectations Hypothesis Tests using Term Spread Models Empirical data must satisfy three specific assumptions under the Expectations Hypothesis (EH) for the theory to hold. The first assumption is: The term spread model must predict future changes in the short rate. The second one is: “Republic of the Philippines Starts Year Blazing a Trail in International Capital Markets”, Bureau of the Treasury, http://www.treasury.gov.ph/wp-content/uploads/2015/01/Press-ReleaseRP-Starts-Year-Blazing-a-Trail-in-Intl-Capital-Markets.pdf (accessed April 6, 2015). 99 89 The term spread must predict future changes in the long rate; and lastly: The term spread must not predict excess bond returns. For the first assumption, three pairs of short rates and long rates were tested which were the 3-month and 6-month bond yields, 6-month and 1-year bond yields, and 1-year and 2-year bond yields. This employed McCallum’s two-period case method. For the second assumption, this study considered the 1-year bond yields as the short rate, while the 2-year, 5-year and 10-year bonds yields were the long rates. All of the bond yields were tested for unit root using the Correlogram Specification and Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) Tests. Results showed that the elements used for all the term spread regressions (both the left-hand side and righthand side of the equations) did not possess any unit root, signifying that the data distribution are stationary. Stationary data are necessary to avoid spurious regressions, and thus, the estimates obtained from the regressions can be considered correct and valid. Additionally, due unstable/auto-correlated nature of the residuals of the regressors, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent (HAC) Newey-West Test was employed instead of using the ordinary least squares (OLS) method. Table 8 shows the test results for the first assumption using McCallum’s two-period case model. For the EH to hold, the 𝛼 coefficient must have a value of zero while the 𝛽 coefficient must have a value of one. The test results show that the 𝛼 coefficients were all significantly negative, while the 𝛽 coefficients were significantly below unity. 90 The pair that were closest to the ideal results was the 6-month and 1-year bonds, with a 𝛽 coefficient at 0.46 and a relatively high predictive power (R2 = 25%). The results for the 3-month and 6-month and 1-year and 2-year, on the other hand, were significantly different from the desired results with very low predictive powers. These findings suggest that a one percentage point increase in the spread between the short rate and the long rate raises the short rate by less than one percentage point. This result implies that the spread does not provide a “perfect” forecast of the change in the short rates. Nevertheless, as theory suggests, the term spread still signaled increases in the short rate, as denoted by the positive 𝛽 coefficients. Table 8. Term Spread Prediction of Future Changes in the Short Rate Regression Model: 0.5 (𝑟𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) = 𝛼 + 𝛽 (𝑅𝑡−1 − Short Rate Long Rate Period α (𝒓𝒕 ) (𝑹𝒕 ) -0.09*** 3-month 6-month 2006 – 2014 (0.03) -0.22*** 6-month 1-year 2006 – 2014 (0.05) -0.13*** 1-year 2-year 2006 – 2014 (0.04) 𝑟𝑡−1 ) + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 β 0.21*** (0.07) 0.46*** (0.11) 0.14*** (0.05) R2 DW 0.06 2.28 0.25 1.96 0.07 1.84 Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC) Notes: Standard errors are placed in parentheses. * = significant at 10% level ** = significant at 5% level *** = significant at 1% level To test the second assumption, McCallum’s n-period case applied using the following pairs: 1-year and 3-year, 1-year and 5-year, and 1-year and 10-year bond yields. In a similar way, for the EH to hold, the 𝛼 coefficient must have a value of zero while the 𝛽 coefficient must have a value of one. 91 Table 9 shows that the term spread tests for changes in future long rates also did not produce the desired results as theory suggested. The 𝛼 coefficients, compared to the two-period case, are now positively related to the term spread with values reaching as high as 2.08 percentage points. The 𝛽 results, on the other hand, show significantly negative coefficients which suggests that the term spread forecasts the long rate in the opposite direction. The same results were also experienced by Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller (1986), McCallum (1994), Campbell (1997), Dai and Singleton (2002), and several others. Geiger (2011) asserted that the change in the long rates fall (or become more negative) monotonically with the maturity of the bond which indicates a strong positive relationship between yield spreads and excess returns on long-term bonds.100 This can also be said for the Philippine case, since the term spread and the changes in the long rate have an inverse relationship. In order to verify this conclusion, the relationship between excess returns and the term spread must be tested as the EH’s third assumption. Table 9. Term Spread Prediction of Future Changes in the Long Rate Regression Model: 𝑁(𝑅𝑡 − 𝑅𝑡−1 ) = 𝛼 + 𝛽(𝑅𝑡−1 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 Short Rate Long Rate Period α β R2 DW (𝒓𝒕 ) (𝑹𝒕 ) 0.61* -0.71*** 1-year 3-year 2006 – 2014 0.06 2.04 (0.37) (0.34) 2.08*** -1.34*** 1-year 5-year 2006 – 2014 0.09 2.13 (0.70) (0.33) 1.90 -0.88** 1-year 10-year 2006 – 2014 0.02 1.74 (1.45) (0.44) Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC) Notes: Standard errors are placed in parentheses. * = significant at 10% level ** = significant at 5% level *** = significant at 1% level Felix Geiger, “The Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates,” in the The Yield Curve and Financial Risk Premia, (Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 2011), 70. 100 92 The third assumption of the EH asserts that the term spread must not predict the excess bond returns to verify that the term premium is indeed zero. Thus, the expected value for the coefficient of the term spread must be zero. Excess returns were calculated using Mankiw, Goldfeld, and Shiller’s (1986) formula and were regressed against the yield spread for both the two-period case and n-period case. However, contrary to what the EH says, the results suggest that for the twoperiod and n-period case, the excess returns can be clearly predicted by the term spread. The 𝛽 coefficients are significantly greater than zero and are noticeably increasing as the predictive horizon lengthens. The estimated R2 also escalates, signaling the increased power of the term spread to predict excess returns as bond maturity increases. This finding confirms Geiger’s (2011) assertion that the term spread is unable to predict changes in the long rate due to the strong positive relationship of the term spread with excess returns. Table 10. Term Spread Prediction of Excess Returns Regression Model: 𝐸𝐻𝑅𝑟,𝑅 = 𝛼 + 𝛽(𝑅𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡 ) + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 Two-Period Case Short Rate Long Rate Period α β R2 (𝒓𝒕 ) (𝑹𝒕 ) 0.27*** 0.07 3-month 6-month 2006 – 2014 0.00 (0.02) (0.02) 0.34*** 0.22* 6-month 1-year 2006 – 2014 0.04 (0.04) (0.12) 0.43*** 0.42*** 1-year 2-year 2006 – 2014 0.16 (0.13) (0.16) N-Period Case Short Rate Long Rate Period α β R2 (𝒓𝒕 ) (𝑹𝒕 ) 0.42*** 0.63*** 1-year 3-year 2006 – 2014 0.35 (0.12) (0.11) 0.64*** 0.65*** 1-year 5-year 2006 – 2014 0.37 (0.22) (0.13) 0.50*** 0.83*** 1-year 10-year 2006 – 2014 0.67 (0.18) (0.05) DW 2.18 2.00 2.44 DW 2.35 2.35 2.08 Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC) Notes: Standard errors are placed in parentheses. 93 * = significant at 10% level ** = significant at 5% level *** = significant at 1% level D. Expectations Hypothesis Tests using Forward Spread Models Apart from using the yield/term spread, the Expectations Hypothesis can also be tested using forward spreads. To verify and to compare the results obtained from the term spread models, forward spread models were also done for forecasting changes in the short rate, in the long rate, and of excess returns. Results showed that the forward rates’ predictions for changes in the short were closely at par with the results from the term spread model. The 𝛼 coefficients were significantly and consistently zero compared to negative results of the term spread regressions. The 𝛽 coefficients were also significant and consistent with the results of the term spread regressions (with a slight 1% difference from the 𝛽 coefficient of the 6-month and 1-year bond pair. Nonetheless, all estimates were still far below the desired 𝛽 coefficient of one. The predictive power of the term spread indicated by the R2 were also similar to the results of the term spread tests. In contrast, the results for the changes in the long rate show that forward spreads are very poor predictors compared to term spread models. The 𝛼 and 𝛽 coefficients were consistently and significantly zero across the samples. This stark difference suggests that forward rates work as best predictors of interest rates for very short horizons, specifically, less than one year. For longer horizons, the predictive power of forward spreads already deteriorates. This assertion can also be confirmed by the results of Mishkin (1988) in Table 3. 94 Table 11. Forward Spread Prediction of Changes in Short Rate and Long Rate Regression Model: (𝑟𝑡+1 − 𝑟𝑡 ) = 𝛼 + 𝛽 (𝑓𝑟→𝑅 − Two-Period Case Short Rate Long Rate Period α (𝒓𝒕 ) (𝑹𝒕 ) 0.00*** 3-month 6-month 2006 – 2014 (0.00) 0.00*** 6-month 1-year 2006 – 2014 (0.00) 0.00*** 1-year 2-year 2006 – 2014 (0.00) Regression Model: (𝑅𝑡+1 − 𝑅𝑡 ) = 𝛼 + 𝛽(𝑓𝑟→𝑅 − N-Period Case Short Rate Long Rate Period α (𝒓𝒕 ) (𝑹𝒕 ) 0.00 1-year 3-year 2006 – 2014 (0.00) 0.00 1-year 5-year 2006 – 2014 (0.00) 0.00 1-year 10-year 2006 – 2014 (0.00) 𝑟𝑡 ) + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 β R2 DW 0.20*** 0.06 2.28 (0.09) 0.46*** 0.25 1.95 (0.11) 0.14*** 0.07 1.84 (0.05) 𝑟𝑡 ) + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 β 0.00 (0.01) -0.01 (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) R2 DW 0.00 1.97 0.00 1.97 0.01 1.96 Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC) Notes: Standard errors are placed in parentheses. * = significant at 10% level ** = significant at 5% level *** = significant at 1% level Excess returns as a function of forward spreads were also tested. If the latter predicts the former, then it would be a clear rejection of the EH. Results in Table 12 show that, indeed, excess returns can be predicted by the forward rate spread, especially for the short rates. The 𝛽 coefficients under the two-period case, along with the R2, signal the potential forecasting power of the forward spread. For the nperiod case, on the other hand, only the 1-year and 3-year bonds showed that the forward spread can forecast excess returns. The rest of the n-period case sample results can be considered negligible. In any case, however, we can declare that the third assumption of the EH was not fulfilled, as well, using forward spreads. 95 Table 12. Forward Spread Prediction of Excess Returns Regression Model: 𝐸𝐻𝑅𝑟,𝑅 = 𝛼 + 𝛽(𝑓𝑟→𝑅 − 𝑟𝑡 ) + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 Two-Period Case Short Rate Long Rate Period α β R2 (𝒓𝒕 ) (𝑹𝒕 ) 0.27*** 3.47 3-month 6-month 2006 – 2014 0.00 (0.04) (3.83) 0.34*** 10.80* 6-month 1-year 2006 – 2014 0.04 (0.04) (5.96) 0.43*** 20.89*** 1-year 2-year 2006 – 2014 0.16 (0.13) (8.07) N-Period Case Short Rate Long rate Period α β R2 (𝒓𝒕 ) (𝑹𝒕 ) 0.74*** 5.08*** 1-year 3-year 2006 – 2014 0.03 (0.17) (2.50) 1.95*** -0.66 1-year 5-year 2006 – 2014 0.00 (0.40) (1.36) 2.31*** 0.64 1-year 10-year 2006 – 2014 0.04 (0.40) (0.51) DW 2.18 2.00 2.44 DW 1.11 0.92 0.46 Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC) Notes: Standard errors are placed in parentheses. * = significant at 10% level ** = significant at 5% level *** = significant at 1% level From all the term spread models and forward spread models used to test the EH, we can conclude that the three assumptions were hardly satisfied. The term spread and forward spread models in predicting future short rates had positive 𝛽 coefficients, suggesting that yield spreads can capture the movement of the short rates. However, when it comes to the prediction of long rates, results showed zero to negative 𝛽 coefficients, suggesting that an increase in the term spread has no effect at all or portends a fall in the long rates – a big contrast from what theory says. Lastly, instead of losing explanatory powers, test results showed that the term spread can somehow predict excess returns. This also goes against the third assumption of the EH. 96 Hence, we can conclude that the EH was not empirically verified using Philippine bond yields. From the vast literature surveyed in this study, the failure of the EH does not mean that future interest rates cannot be inferred from the term structure. The inference power is present but still poor. It should be noted that we are just tackling interest rates via one approach – the expectations approach. This rather reflects that the EH can only predict future yield levels up to a limited extent.101 The failure of the EH, however, can be remedied; and from the vast literature explored in this study, the distortion of empirical tests point to the failure of including a bond risk premium (BRP), or more specifically, a time-varying risk premium. Thus, a major assumption made in this study was that the failure of the EH is attributed to the omission of the BRP. We, therefore, need to measure the BRP and redo the EH term spread tests to see if the models can improve or not. In any case, the estimation of the BRP for Philippine bond yields may have very informative implications about the bond market helpful for investors, policymakers, and researchers, alike. E. Estimation of the Bond Risk Premium For the estimation of the bond risk premium (BRP), this study adopted the methodologies of Boero and Torricelli (2000). The main assumption made was that a higher BRP is associated with higher risk, and risk was represented by higher interest rate volatility. Interest rate volatility was, therefore, measured using three Felix Geiger, “The Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates,” in the The Yield Curve and Financial Risk Premia, (Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 2011), 71. 101 97 different estimation methods. These are the: 1) moving average of absolute changes of the short rates computed over the previous 6 periods; 2) square of the expected excess holding period return; and 3) estimates of conditional variances and conditional standard deviations from the univariate GARCH (1,1) model. The following BRP estimates are shown in the figures below. Using the moving average method, it can be observed that the estimated bond risk premium for all bond pairs are time-varying. The BRP of the short rate pairs are greater than and more volatile than the long rate pairs – which is consistent with the increased volatility observed from Philippine short-term bonds than longterm ones. Long rate BRP are more stable, nonetheless. The mean BRP for the short rates was at 0.16% while the long rate BRP averages to 0.03%. This method may imply that investors are more reactive and demand more compensation for risk in the short run. The squared excess returns method also shows a time-varying risk premium; but, in contrast with moving average estimates, this method implies that investors required a greater bond risk premium as maturity increases. The mean of the squared excess returns for the 3-month and 6-month, 6-month and 1-year, and 1-year and 2-year were 0.40%, 0.35%, ad 0.82%, respectively. For the long rates, the 1-year and 3-year bonds had a mean of squared excess returns of 1.70%, 3.89% for the 1-year and 5-year bonds, and 9.02% for the 1-year and 10-year bonds. From the bond risk premium estimated via univariate GARCH (1,1), two kinds of estimates can be used to improve the EH tests – the conditional standard deviations and the conditional variances (which are just squared values of the 98 conditional standard deviations). These measures pertain to the volatility of the excess returns of the bond pairs. Both Figure 9 and 10 show that the bond risk premium estimates and its volatility increase with maturity. Similar to the results of the squares excess returns, this suggests that investors require more cushion for risk as the investment horizon lengthens. 0.80 0.70 PERCENT 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 2006M01 2006M05 2006M09 2007M01 2007M05 2007M09 2008M01 2008M05 2008M09 2009M01 2009M05 2009M09 2010M01 2010M05 2010M09 2011M01 2011M05 2011M09 2012M01 2012M05 2012M09 2013M01 2013M05 2013M09 2014M01 2014M05 2014M09 0.00 m3m6 m6my1 y1y2 y1y3 y1y5 y1y10 Figure 23. Estimated Bond Risk Premium Using Moving Average Method Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC) 30.00 25.00 15.00 10.00 5.00 0.00 2006M01 2006M05 2006M09 2007M01 2007M05 2007M09 2008M01 2008M05 2008M09 2009M01 2009M05 2009M09 2010M01 2010M05 2010M09 2011M01 2011M05 2011M09 2012M01 2012M05 2012M09 2013M01 2013M05 2013M09 2014M01 2014M05 2014M09 PERCENT 20.00 m3m6 m6y1 y1y2 y1y3 y1y5 y1y10 Figure 24. Estimated Bond Risk Premium Using Squared Excess Returns Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC) 99 5.0 4.5 4.0 PERCENT 3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 2006M01 2006M05 2006M09 2007M01 2007M05 2007M09 2008M01 2008M05 2008M09 2009M01 2009M05 2009M09 2010M01 2010M05 2010M09 2011M01 2011M05 2011M09 2012M01 2012M05 2012M09 2013M01 2013M05 2013M09 2014M01 2014M05 2014M09 0.0 m3m6 m6my1 y1y2 y1y3 y1y5 y1y10 Figure 25. Conditional Standard Deviation of Excess Returns from GARCH (1,1) Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC) 25.0 PERCENT 20.0 15.0 10.0 5.0 2006M01 2006M05 2006M09 2007M01 2007M05 2007M09 2008M01 2008M05 2008M09 2009M01 2009M05 2009M09 2010M01 2010M05 2010M09 2011M01 2011M05 2011M09 2012M01 2012M05 2012M09 2013M01 2013M05 2013M09 2014M01 2014M05 2014M09 0.0 m3m6 m6my1 y1y2 y1y3 y1y5 y1y10 Figure 26. Conditional Variance of Excess Returns from GARCH (1,1) Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC) These BRP measures were inserted into the term spread models to identify which estimate went closest to the desired results. In order to select the best BRP proxy, goodness of fit evaluations were done. This study adopted the four criteria suggested by Gujarati (2011) and used by Bico (2010) which are the Adjusted R2, 100 F-statistic, Akaike Information Criterion (AIC), and Schwarz Information Criterion (SIC). The improvement of the 𝛼 and 𝛽 coefficients were also considered. For the short rate regressions, the conditional variance estimation of the BRP outperformed the rest of the estimates. This was shown in the minimal 1% to 2% change in the Adjusted R2, in the high F-Statistic values, and in the smaller AIC and SIC values. The 𝛼 and 𝛽 coefficients also improved and were all statistically significant from the previous HAC Newey-West tests. Table 13. Term Spread Prediction of Future Changes in the Short Rate with Bond Risk Premium Short Rate Regression: 0.5 (𝑟𝑡 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) = 𝛼1 + 𝛽1 (𝑅𝑡−1 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) + 𝛾𝐵𝑅𝑃 + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 3-month and 6-month OLS (HAC NeweyWest Test) 𝛽1 -0.09*** (0.03) 0.21*** (0.07) 𝛾 -- 𝛼1 R2 0.06 DW 2.28 Adjusted R2 -F-Statistic -AIC -SIC -6-month and 1-year -0.22*** 𝛼1 (0.05) 0.46*** 𝛽1 (0.11) Square of Excess Returns BRP Conditional Variance -0.04 (0.05) 0.20*** (0.08) -0.27 (0.33) 0.07 2.99 0.05 3.72 0.98 1.06 -0.09*** (0.02) 0.21*** (0.05) 0.00 (0.01) 0.06 2.28 0.04 3.16 1.00 1.07 -0.06 (0.03) 0.24*** (0.05) -0.13*** (0.04) 0.08 2.36 0.06 4.62 0.98 1.05 Conditional Standard Deviation 0.00 (0.03) 0.24*** (0.06) -0.20*** (0.06) 0.08 2.33 0.06 4.20 0.98 1.06 -0.21*** (0.03) 0.52*** (0.04) -0.12 (0.08) 0.28 2.07 0.27 20.26 0.57 0.65 -0.13*** (0.03) 0.50*** (0.03) -0.29*** (0.05) 0.29 1.92 0.28 21.41 0.56 0.64 0.00 (0.05) 0.52*** (0.03) -0.44*** (0.08) 0.30 1.92 0.28 21.87 0.56 0.63 -0.13*** (0.04) -0.11*** (0.04) 0.06 (0.07) R DW Adjusted R2 F-Statistic AIC SIC 0.25 1.96 ----- -0.13*** (0.06) 0.46*** (0.08) -0.55 (0.41) 0.29 2.01 0.28 21.29 0.56 0.63 𝛼1 -0.13*** (0.04) -0.07 (0.04) 𝛾 2 -- GARCH (1,1) BRP Moving Average BRP 101 0.15*** 0.14*** 0.27*** 0.28*** (0.04) (0.05) (0.07) (0.07) -0.34*** -0.46 0.00 -0.14*** -𝛾 (0.11) (0.22)** (0.04) (0.05) R2 0.07 0.12 0.07 0.11 0.12 DW 1.84 1.89 1.84 1.79 1.81 0.11 Adjusted R2 -0.10 0.05 0.09 7.19 F-Statistic -6.77 3.77 6.33 0.12 AIC -0.12 0.18 0.14 0.20 SIC -0.20 0.25 0.21 Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC), Author’s computations Notes: Standard errors are placed in parentheses. * = significant at 10% level ** = significant at 5% level *** = significant at 1% level 𝛽1 0.14*** (0.05) Table 13, on the other hand, shows that the conditional standard deviation from the univariate GARCH (1,1) model dominated the other BRP proxies for the long rate regressions. The Adjusted R2 barely differed from their original R2, FStatistic values were also greater than the rest, and the AIC and SIC criteria were the lowest. Majority of the 𝛼 and 𝛽 coefficients, however, did not show the desired results under the EH’s assumption. Instead of converging to zero, the 𝛼 values became higher and more positive. The 𝛽 coefficients barely improved as well, as they did not converge to unity but sky-rocketed to as high as 31.38 points (for 1year and 10-year bonds). Although 1-year and 3-year and the 1-year and 10-year bonds now have positive 𝛽 coefficients, the 𝛽 of the 1-year and 5-year bonds was left at the negative territory. 102 Table 14. Term Spread Prediction of Future Changes in the Long Rate with Bond Risk Premium Long Rate Regression 𝑁(𝑅𝑡 − 𝑅𝑡−1 ) = 𝛼2 + 𝛽2 (𝑅𝑡−1 − 𝑟𝑡−1 ) + 𝛾𝐵𝑅𝑃 + 𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚 1-year and 3-year OLS GARCH (1,1) BRP Moving Square of (HAC Conditional Average Excess Newey-West Conditional Standard BRP Returns BRP Test) Variance Deviation 0.61 0.97*** 0.79*** 0.00 5.44*** 𝛼2 (0.37) (0.39) (0.31) (0.32) (1.21) -0.71*** -0.77** -1.56*** 2.69*** 3.92*** 𝛽2 (0.34) (0.39) (0.46) (0.60) (0.63) -11.49*** 0.46*** -1.85*** -7.95*** -𝛾 (3.81) (0.11) (0.40) (1.40) R2 0.06 0.08 0.29 0.31 0.33 DW 2.04 2.10 1.59 2.11 2.30 Adjusted R2 -0.07 0.27 0.30 0.32 F-Statistic -4.81 20.78 23.49 25.68 AIC -4.02 3.77 3.73 3.71 SIC -4.09 3.84 3.77 3.78 1-year and 5-year 2.08*** 4.20*** 2.39** 2.02 3.76* 𝛼2 (0.70) (0.78) (1.23) (1.55) (1.94) -1.34*** -1.69*** -2.98*** 0.04 -0.37 𝛽2 (0.33) (0.33) (0.88) (0.68) (1.04) -56.19*** 0.67*** -0.61*** -1.77*** -𝛾 (12.63) (0.14) (0.28) (0.89) R2 0.09 0.25 0.42 0.12 0.10 DW 2.13 2.05 1.51 2.18 2.18 Adjusted R2 -0.24 0.40 0.10 0.09 F-Statistic -17.74 36.93 7.04 5.88 AIC -5.13 4.89 5.31 5.33 SIC -5.21 4.96 5.34 5.40 1-year and 10-year 1.90 4.22*** 5.93*** -4.63 44.48*** 𝛼2 (1.45) (1.61) (2.01) (3.38) (6.37) -0.88** -1.32*** -5.10*** 8.62*** 31.38*** 𝛽2 (0.44) (0.45) (1.40) (3.00) (4.64) -36.36** 0.88*** -2.26*** -45.95*** -𝛾 (15.34) (0.28) (0.65) (6.64) 2 0.40 R 0.02 0.05 0.28 0.12 DW 1.74 1.75 1.57 1.59 1.35 Adjusted R2 -0.03 0.26 0.10 0.39 F-Statistic -2.67 19.92 6.88 35.02 AIC -6.46 6.19 6.39 6.00 SIC -6.54 6.26 6.47 6.03 Source of Basic Data: Bloomberg, First Metro Investment Corporation (FMIC), Author’s computations Notes: Standard errors are placed in parentheses. * = significant at 10% level ** = significant at 5% level *** = significant at 1% level 103 The option of the conditional variance values as the bond risk premium for the short rate regressions and the conditional standard deviation for the long rate regressions just confirms that short-term yields are more volatile than long-term yields. Due to the “squared” nature of the conditional variance, it better captures the volatility or variance of the excess returns among the short rates. The conditional standard deviation, on the other hand, is a toned down measure of the conditional variance (as it is just the square root of the conditional variance); and since long-term rates are less volatile, the conditional standard deviations were enough in grasping the long rates’ excess returns volatility. However, we cannot say that the BRP proxies of the univariate GARCH model are the best estimates that improved the term spread models of the EH tests. The results of the GARCH model, especially for the long rate regressions, were still far from the desired 𝛼 and 𝛽 values. The rejection of the EH, even after including the best BRP proxy among the estimates done in this study, does not mean that the Philippine term spread is useless in predicting future movements of interest rates. The direction and magnitude of the 𝛽 coefficients, for both short rates and long rates, still have some important implications. One implication is that the term spread is able to positively portend future changes in interest rates to a limited extent. The bond risk premium proxies for the short rates also improved the EH tests, implying that the GARCH estimation is consistent enough to capture the volatility of the short rates’ excess returns. For the long rates, on the other hand, the conditional standard deviations of the excess 104 returns were able to reverse the negative signs of the 𝛽 coefficients, making it consistent with theory. The 𝛽 coefficient for the 1-year and 5-year may still be negative, but this result can still be discounted since it is not considered statistically significant. F. Macroeconomic Variables and the Bond Risk Premium The fourth objective in this study is to identify certain macroeconomic variables that highly influence the estimated bond risk premium. To achieve this, a panel regression model, with the BRP as the dependent variable, was done. Fixed effects specification of the panel regression was employed to consider the effects of the explanatory variables that are time-varying. From the results of the BRP tests, the selected BRP proxies for the twoperiod case (i.e., between one-period and two-period bonds) are the GARCHgenerated measures of conditional variances, while the best BRP proxies for the nperiod case (i.e., between one-period and n-period bonds) are the GARCHgenerated measures of conditional standard deviations. These BRP measures proved to be the best among the three methods presented, as shown in the improvement of the goodness-of-fit evaluations and term spread regression coefficients. The analysis have the following variations – whole sample test, short rate tests, long rate tests, and analysis according to two periods (2006 – 2010 and 2011 – 2014) for both the short rate and long rate. 105 The whole sample test includes the bond risk premium estimates for both the two-period case (which are the BRPs for the 3-month and 6-month, 6-month and 1-year, and 1-year and 2-year bonds) and the n-period case (which are the 1year and 3-year, 1-year and 5-year, and 1-year and 10-year bonds) as the dependent variables, together with all of the 12 macroeconomic variables with the lagged values of the BRP and the bond spread as the explanatory variables. All of the data are transformed to monthly growth rates from 2006 to 2014. The short rate tests, on the other hand, only include the BRPs estimated under the two-period case (which are the BRPs for the 3-month and 6-month, 6month and 1-year, and 1-year and 2-year bonds) as the dependent variables, together with all of the 12 macroeconomic variables with the lagged values of the BRP and the bond spread as the explanatory variables. All of the data are transformed to monthly growth rates from 2006 to 2014. The long rate tests, in the same way, include BRPs estimated under the nperiod case (which are the 1-year and 3-year, 1-year and 5-year, and 1-year and 10year bonds) as the dependent variables, with all of the 12 macroeconomic variables, the lagged values of the BRP, and the bond spread as explanatory variables. All of the data are transformed to monthly growth rates from 2006 to 2014. For the periodical analysis, the data sample will be divided into two subperiods: 2006 to 2010 and 2011 to 2014. 106 1. Whole Sample Test The whole sample test (which includes both the short rate and long rate bond risk premium with all the macroeconomic variables from 2006 to 2014) show that four variables out of the 12 regressors significantly affect the bond risk premium. The most significant of them is the lagged values of the BRP, with a minimal standard error, and a p-value nearly zero. An increase in the lagged BRP by 1% or 100 basis points (bps) would induce the current BRP to increase by 77 bps. Among the macroeconomic variables, Meralco sales (𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠) (as a proxy for economic growth) and the lagged values of the growth rate of the federal funds rate (𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒(−1)) are observed to be the most significant determinants of the BRP, having one of the highest t-statistics at 2.83 and 2.63, respectively. The impact of Meralco sales, however, is very minimal at -0.7 bps, compared to federal funds rate at 21 bps. This signifies that for every 100 bps change in economic growth and in the past growth rate of monetary policy in the US, the BRP will change by -0.7 bps and 21 bps, respectively. Excess liquidity (𝑔𝑚2) and the lagged values of the growth rate of foreign exchange rate (𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥(−1)) followed suit as important determinants of the BRP. Similarly, the former seems to have a very small impact to the BRP at -0.3 bps than the relatively larger effect of foreign exchange rate at 171 bps. With the latter’s standard error at ±79 bps, the effect of the foreign exchange rate on the BRP can fluctuate from 92 bps to 250 bps, which can be quite volatile than the rest. 107 As we can see, the impact of the domestic variables are overpowered by the large 𝛽 coefficients of the lagged values of the world macroeconomic factors. The minute effects of economic growth (𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠) and excess liquidity (𝑔𝑚2) seem negligible compared to the immense impacts of the lagged values of the foreign exchange rate (𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥(−1)) and the Fed’s policy rate (𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒(−1)). The observed significance of the current domestic data than the one-period lag in foreign factors signify that information delay could exist. Thus, the effects of the past peso-dollar exchange rate and the federal funds rate may ensue until the present. Table 15. Regression Results of Whole Sample Variable Coefficient Standard Error 0.37 0.04 𝑐 0.77 0.02 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) -0.007 0.002 𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠 1.71 0.79 𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥(−1) -0.003 0.001 𝑔𝑚2 0.21 0.08 𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒(−1) 2 R = 0.920823 DW = 2.075503, Durbin’s h = -1.182402 t-Statistic 8.44*** 32.12*** 2.83*** 2.15** 1.95** 2.63*** (no serial correlation among the variables) Source of Basic Data: Author’s computations Notes: * = significant at 10% level ** = significant at 5% level *** = significant at 1% level 2. Periodical Sample Test (Crisis and Post-Crisis Periods) A periodical analysis was also done to observe the behavior of the BRP and its interaction with macroeconomic variables during and after the global financial crisis. Results show that during the crisis period, from 2006 to 2010, the most important determinants of the BRP are its lagged values (𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1)), the bond 108 spread (𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑), the growth rate of the gross international reserves (𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟), and the growth rate of the US inflation (𝑔𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖). We can see here that the country’s BRP is prominently affected by world macroeconomic variables (such as the gross international reserves and the US inflation) than domestic factors. This suggests that despite our known resilience during the global financial crisis, investors still took into consideration the possible consequences of the crisis to the country’s financial market. The effect of GIR on BRP, however, is relatively small (at 0.2 bps) compared to the immense effect of US inflation – such that for every 1% change in the growth rate of US inflation, the BRP may change by 202 bps. The latter, nevertheless, should be considered with caution due to its relatively high standard error (at ±92 bps). The finding that the lagged values of the BRP and the current bond spread are among the most important determinants of the BRP only shows the great relationship between the past values of the BRP and the slope of the yield curve to the current BRP. This also signals the great relevance of these factors to the current condition of interest rates. This may imply that investors were already watchful about the movement of interest rates during the crisis, taking into account the direction of past data and direction of long-term interest rates relative to the shortterm rates. For the periods after the financial crisis, it can be observed that the world macroeconomic effects have died down, and domestic factors took the role. These country variables are the lagged values of the BRP (𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1)), lagged values of the bond spread (𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑(−1)), and the growth rate of BSP’s monetary stance 109 (𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝). Among these, BSP’s policy rate has the highest impact on BRP at 129 bps (with a standard error of ±53 bps). This highlights the increased importance of the reverse repurchase rate (𝑟𝑟𝑝) at present as the primary reference for interest rates monitored by investors. This finding also suggests that the BSP must remain attentive to the effects of its monetary policy rate decisions as the BRP is shown to be very reactive to the 𝑟𝑟𝑝’s movements. Table 16. Regression Results of Periodical Sample 2006 to 2010 2011 to 2014 Variable Coefficient Standard Error tStatistic Variable Coefficient Standard Error tStatistic 𝑐 0.20 0.05 3.93*** 𝑐 0.32 0.05 5.91*** 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) 0.52 0.03 17.24*** 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) 0.58 0.08 7.50*** 𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑 0.36 0.02 14.98*** 𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑(−1) 0.18 0.06 3.22*** 𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝 1.29 0.53 2.43** 𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟 𝑔𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖 -0.002 0.001 1.70* 2.02 0.92 2.19** R2 = 0.923858 DW = 2.064108, Durbin’s h = -0.731383 (no serial correlation among the variables) Source of Basic Data: Author’s computations Notes: * = significant at 10% level ** = significant at 5% level *** = significant at 1% level R2 = 0.953200 DW = 1.829008, Durbin’s h = 1.760418 (no serial correlation among the variables) 3. Short Rate Bond Risk Premium and Macroeconomic Variables The effect of macroeconomic variables on the short rate BRP (3-month and 6-month, 6-month and 1-year, and 1-year and 2-year bonds) were also studied, along with some periodical analyses. Using the whole sample period (2006 to 2014), it is observed none of the 12 macroeconomic variables was significant at the 95% and 90% confidence level. The only factors that proved to be significant are the lagged values of the BRP (𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1)) and the bond spread (𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑). This finding may suggest that when 110 investors trade short-term investment instruments, they tend to focus more on the available information in the bond market than consider other macroeconomic variables in their decision-making process. The results are a sign that investors may base their current decisions on the outcome of past data. This may also explain why volatility clustering is present, especially in short rates – where periods of high volatility are followed by periods of high volatility, and periods of low volatility are trailed by periods of low volatility. Table 17. Regression Results of Short Rates (2006 to 2014) Variable Coefficient Standard Error t-Statistic 0.03 0.02 1.52 𝑐 0.72 0.03 24.07*** 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) 0.20 0.03 6.57*** 𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑 2 R = 0.793214 DW = 2.181456 , Durbin’s h = -1.900565 (no serial correlation among the variables) Source of Basic Data: Author’s computations Notes: * = significant at 10% level ** = significant at 5% level *** = significant at 1% level When the sample was divided into two time periods, 2006 to 2010 and 2011 to 2014, the BRP determinants has been clear cut. Apart from the usual determinant of the BRP (which is the lagged values of BRP), US inflation (𝑔𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖) prevailed over the rest and is deemed statistically significant in affecting the BRP. A 100 bps change in the growth rate of US inflation may induce an increase in the BRP by 208 bps. Inflationary pressures abroad may have heavily affected the decision of domestic investors to increase their short-term BRP outlook due to the worsening US economy when the crisis hit. We should note here that none of the domestic variables heavily affected the BRP of the short rates during the crisis period. 111 But now, after the crisis years, it is observed that the short BRP have become highly relevant to a domestic factor, which is the economic growth indicator (𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠). The effect on BRP, however, is very minimal at -0.7 bps for every 100 bps change in the growth rate of Meralco sales. This suggests that investors who are heavily invested in short maturity debt instruments may immediately decide based on the current performance of the economy. Hence, the announcement of the quarterly GDP figures may be crucial to the bond market. Of course, the lagged values of the BRP (𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1)) and lagged values of the bond spread (𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑(−1)) still prevailed to be significant indicators due to their high correlation with the estimates of BRP. Table 18. Regression Results of Short Rates (2006 to 2010 and 2011 to 2014) Variable 𝑐 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) 𝑔𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖 2006 to 2010 Standard Coefficient Error 0.07 0.04 0.73 0.04 2.08 1.25 tStatistic 1.98** 16.49*** 1.67* R2 = 0.681370 DW = 2.191396, Durbin’s h = -1.571606 (no serial correlation among the variables) Variable 𝑐 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) 𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑(−1) 𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠 2011 to 2014 Standard Coefficient Error 0.10 0.03 0.71 0.06 0.14 0.05 -0.007 0.003 R2 = 0.906905 tStatistic 2.92*** 11.64*** 2.90*** 2.26** DW = 1.90551, Durbin’s h = 0.789445 (no serial correlation among the variables) Source of Basic Data: Author’s computations Notes: * = significant at 10% level ** = significant at 5% level *** = significant at 1% level 4. Long Rate Bond Risk Premium and Macroeconomic Variables For the tests of the BRP of the long rates from 2006 to 2014, results show there are five factors (that is, a mixture of domestic and world macroeconomic variables) highly affecting the BRP (apart from the lagged values of the BRP). These are Meralco sales (𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠), the growth rate of the foreign exchange rate 112 (𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥), excess liquidity (𝑔𝑚2), the lagged values of the growth rate of the federal funds rate (𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒(−1)), and the growth rate of the Philippine Stock Exchange index (𝑔𝑝𝑠𝑒𝑖). All of them are statistically significant at the 5% to 1% significance level. The effect, however, of excess liquidity and economic growth on BRP are very minimal at -0.5 bps and -0.8 bps, respectively for every 100 bps change of the two variables. Investors, nevertheless, are more reactive when foreign exchange rate, the lagged values of the federal funds rate, and the Philippine Stock Exchange index grow. For every 100 bps change in the growth rate of these variables, investors may increase the BRP by 269 bps, 26 bps, and 85 bps, respectively. It can also be noticed that more macroeconomic variables significantly affect the long rate BRP than the short rate BRP. Additionally, the factors that significantly affect the BRP of the whole sample data (2006 to 2014) are greatly similar to the variables that affect the long rate BRP. This signifies that the effect of macroeconomic variables on the long rate BRP prevail over their effect on the short rate BRP. Furthermore, this gives us the impression that long maturity rates are more rooted on macroeconomic conditions than short rates. Remember that only the past values of the BRP and the bond spread affect the current BRP of the short rates. This may suggest that when it comes to trading short maturity bonds, investors are more adaptive or backward-looking. Thus, the outcome of the past BRP values may heavily influence investors’ current BRP decision. 113 Table 19. Regression Results of Long Rates (2006 to 2014) Variable Coefficient Standard Error t-Statistic 0.62 0.09 6.56*** 𝑐 0.75 0.04 19.94*** 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) -0.008 0.004 2.12*** 𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠 2.69 1.36 1.98** 𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥 -0.005 0.002 2.13*** 𝑔𝑚2 0.26 0.13 2.00** 𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒(−1) 0.85 0.37 2.29*** 𝑔𝑝𝑠𝑒𝑖 R2 = 0.850545 DW = 2.003696, Durbin’s h = -0.134421 (no serial correlation among the variables) Source of Basic Data: Author’s computations Notes: * = significant at 10% level ** = significant at 5% level *** = significant at 1% level On the other hand, the results for the sample during the crisis period show that the most significant determinants of BRP are dominated by world macroeconomic factors (similar to the case of the whole sample and short rate BRP). These variables are the growth of gross international reserves (𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟) and the lagged values the foreign exchange rate (𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥(−1)). A 1% or 100 bps change in the growth rate of the GIR may induce investors to change their BRP by -0.7 bps, while the peso-dollar rate may prompt the BRP to change by as much as 322 bps. It can be noticed that the effect of the exchange rate has been relatively high throughout the other sample regressions at levels reaching more than 170 bps, and now reaching as high as 300 bps for the long rate BRP during the crisis years. This observation may highlight the big impact of peso appreciation or depreciation to the country’s bond market as the size of foreigncurrency bonds have been growing until now. 114 The growth of inflation followed suit as the next significant factor in determining the BRP with an impact of 91 bps. This figure may still fluctuate from 38 bps to 144 bps which can be quite volatile and risky. Also, we can notice that Philippine inflation took over the role of US inflation from the whole sample and short rate regressions. Hence, we can say that Philippine economic data has become more relevant for the long-end during the crisis years. Investors were already wary about the increased risk from inflation, as price uncertainties also heightened during the global financial crisis. It is, therefore, noticed that not only world macroeconomic conditions significantly affected investment decisions during the crisis periods, but also domestic factors such as the country’s elevated inflation that may have readily provoked investors to require higher BRP returns. For the post-crisis years, the relationship between the estimated BRP and macroeconomic variables suddenly paint a unique picture. The whole sample and short rate BRP regressions show that the BSP’s policy rate (𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝) and economic growth (𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠), respectively, emerged to be the only variables affecting the BRP. For the long rate BRP, however, both the reverse repurchase rate (𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝) and the excess liquidity (𝑔𝑚2) proved to be the most relevant variables. The effect of the former is quite large than the latter – such that for every 100 bps or 1% change in the growth of BSP’s policy rate, the BRP may change by 236 bps (and this may still fluctuate between 142 bps and 330 bps given its standard error). On the other hand, the effect of excess liquidity on the BRP seems to be more subdued at only 0.8 bps, but statistically, excess liquidity is a better BRP predictor than the reverse repurchase rate. 115 Moreover, compared to the post-crisis regressions of the whole sample and short rate BRP data, which required the lagged values of the bond spread, long rates demanded future values of the bond spread. To prevent serial correlation among the variables in the regression, the “one-period ahead” figure of the bond spread (𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑 (+1)) must be inputted into the model. This result implies that there is a possibility that investors now rely on the expected movement of the slope of the yield curve when trading long-term debt instruments. Table 20. Regression Results of Long Rates (2006 – 2010 and 2011 – 2014) 2006 to 2010 Standard tVariable Coefficient Error Statistic 0.79 0.14 5.46*** 𝑐 0.65 0.06 11.40*** 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) -0.007 0.003 2.31** 𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟 0.91 0.53 1.72* 𝑔𝑖𝑛𝑓 3.22 1.61 2.00** 𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥(−1) R2 = 0.835654 DW = 2.154323, Durbin’s h = -1.581699 (no serial correlation among the variables) Source of Basic Data: Author’s computations Notes: * = significant at 10% level ** = significant at 5% level *** = significant at 1% level 2011 to 2014 Standard tVariable Coefficient Error Statistic 0.76 0.17 4.39*** 𝑐 0.69 0.06 11.04*** 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) 0.15 0.07 2.15** 𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑(+1) 2.36 0.94 2.52** 𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝 -0.008 0.003 2.85*** 𝑔𝑚2 R2 = 0.874554 DW = 1.769473, Durbin’s h = 1.939539 (no serial correlation among the variables) G. Economic Implications of Macro-BRP Relationship The tests regarding the relationship of macroeconomic variables on the BRP showed that a varied set of macroeconomic variables highly affect the estimated BRP, and these relationships change through time. Based on the estimation methods for the bond risk premium of different maturities (short rate or long rate), the most persistent and highly significant variable that is consistent through time is the lagged values of the BRP. For every 100 bps change in the lagged values of the estimated BRP, current BRP may change 116 by 52 bps (from the 2006 to 2010 regressions of the whole sample data) to as high as 77 bps (from the 2006 to 2014 regressions of the whole sample data). This indicator of interest rates heavily affects both the BRP of the short rates and the BRP of the long rates – but the impact is more distinct for the short rates. This denotes that investors, especially those in the short-term debt market, are highly sensitive to the past condition of bond rates and not on economic factors; thus, explaining the more volatile nature of short-term bonds than long-term bonds. Investors closely watch the situation of the financial market in requiring respective BRPs. This behavior is highlighted by the so called adaptive expectations, which states that people form their current decisions from the direction of past data.102 The bond spread or the slope of the yield curve was also used as one of the basic indicators of the estimated BRP. Regression results show that the bond spread was only relevant in the periodical analysis. The current spread was a good predictor of the BRP during the crisis years, specifically for the short rate BRP; but the lagged values of the spread were more effective during the post-global financial crisis, especially for the long rate BRP. This finding implies that the relationship of short-term rates and long-term rates may be one of the factors that investors consider when assigning respective risk premiums for their bonds. Even though the movement of the long rates did not perfectly translate to the changes of the short rates, the large effect of the bond spread on the BRP indicates that the slope of the yield curve can be a good predictor of the BRP when properly used in regression tests. “Adaptive Expectations Hypothesis,” Investopedia, http://www.investopedia.com/terms/a/adaptiveexpthyp.asp (accessed April 20, 2015). 102 117 The macro-BRP relationship tests done, however, did not produce conclusive and consistent results. Various macroeconomic variables affect the estimated BRP differently according to maturity and time. Several variables, however, proved to be recurring than the rest. These factors are summarized in the whole sample results. Using the data from 2006 to 2014, the most persistent factors are the annual growth rate of Meralco sales (𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠, an indicator of economic growth), excess liquidity (𝑔𝑚2), foreign exchange rate (𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥 (−1) or simply 𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥), and the federal funds rate (𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒(−1) or 𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒). We can notice that these are a mixture of both domestic and world macroeconomic variables. The impact of the foreign factors, however, have exceeded the effect of the domestic factors. This may signify that even after the global financial crisis, the country is still vulnerable to impacts abroad. Hence, the Philippine bond market’s move towards global integration and increased participation in the international market must be closely supervised and monitored, as any global shock may cause immense changes to the country’s financial system. Additionally, it is observed that the whole sample results (from 2006 to 2014) resemble the results of the long rate tests (from 2006 to 2014). This tells us that the long rate BRPs may be more grounded on macroeconomic data than short rates, and the effect of these macroeconomic variables last through the crisis and post-crisis years. This inference is also confirmed by the results for the short rate BRP – which shows that the only persistent predictors of the short rate BRP are its lagged values and the bond spread. 118 The effect of these world macroeconomic variables also varies through time. For instance, the effect of the foreign exchange rate has been more prominent from 2006 to 2010. Additionally, Bico (2010) noted that since short-term maturity bonds (such as the 91-day T-Bill) do not have a dollar substitutes compared to longterm bonds, they are not sensitive to changes in the peso-dollar exchange rate.103 Hence, the exchange rate remains to be one of the strongest determinants of longterm yields and consequently of long rate BRPs. In contrast to exchange rate, the effect of the federal funds rate was only evident through the crisis and post-crisis periods (2006 to 2014). However, contrary to conventional thinking, the impact of the federal funds rate is observed to be more evident on the long rate BRP than the short rate BRP. The same situation applies for BSP’s monetary stance. It is seen that the reverse repurchase facility and the federal funds rate have been more effective in determining the BRP of long-term bonds than short-term ones, especially during the post-crisis periods. These findings may suggest that long-term bond yields are more sensitive to changes in the domestic and foreign factors, giving policymakers a possible strategy when they want to influence the long end of the country’s yield curve. Meralco sales (𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠, as a proxy for productivity) and excess liquidity (𝑚2), nevertheless, are also significant determinants of the BRP, but only have very small impacts on it. The former seems to be more relevant to the short-term BRP than the latter (which affects the long rate BRP more). This finding implies that short-term investors can be more reactive to the regular announcement of the C. Bico, “Estimating and Forecasting the Philippines Zero-Coupon Yield Curve: A Multimethod Approach” (Thesis, University of Asia and the Pacific, 2010), 75-76. 103 119 country’s GDP figures in making their short-term investment decisions. One factor that may have invited this behavior is the fact that the country’s economic growth is readily publicized for the financial market to consider. The quarterly announcement of the GDP figures are much anticipated for compared to the measure of the country’s broad money – which can only be relevant on the part of policymakers. When the analysis was divided into crisis and post-crisis periods, the effect of the macroeconomic variables have been more distinct. For the periods 2006 to 2010, world factors dominated the effect of domestic factors on the estimated BRP. For the short rate, US inflation was the only statistically significant variable; while for the long rate, gross international reserves and the peso-dollar rate prevailed among the rest. These results imply that bond yields were more sensitive to global jolts during the crisis. Despite reports saying that the country was not badly hit during the global financial crisis, the findings of this study shows that the Philippine bond market has been greatly affected as well, to a limited extent (as the effects did not ensue anymore to the present). This is not to forget, however, that domestic inflation was also one of the factors that highly influence the BRP. Obviously, price anxieties abroad shook domestic prices, as supplies abroad suffered from the tight financial system in the US. Another noticeable finding from the crisis period results is that, money demand variables (inflation and foreign exchange rate) are more dominant than money supply variables (gross international reserves). This simply confirms that, 120 when the crisis hit, the financial market’s appetite has been distressed. The market’s momentum halted thereby encouraging investors to put a higher risk premium on their debt instruments. On the other hand, the results for the post-crisis periods show that the influence of world macroeconomic variables have gradually receded and domestic factors have become more effective. It can be noticed in the short rate results, Meralco sales (𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠) emerged to be the only effective factor while for the long rate, BSP’s monetary policy (𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝) and excess liquidity (𝑔𝑚2) were the most significant predictors. Among these variables, the impact of BSP’s reverse repurchase rate (rrp) dominated in the whole sample results. The effect of BSP’s rrp on the BRP can range from 129 bps (in the whole sample results) to 236 bps (in the long rate results). The result for the long rate BRP are very similar to the whole sample results except for an addition. The condition of the Philippine Stock exchange index is also observed to be one of the most significant determinants of the long rate BRP. This means that when stock returns are higher, bond investors would expected a higher compensation for the risk of shifting investment markets. This is due to the observed negative correlation of stock and bond returns, making government bonds the “ultimate safe-haven assets”.104 Overall, these findings imply that the Philippine BRP, both short rates and long rates, is mostly dependent on domestic short-term indicators than world macroeconomic variables. This is perhaps because of the increased resiliency of the 104 Antti Ilmanen, Expected Returns on Major Asset Classes (Research Foundation of CFA Institute: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 2012), 68. 121 country’s financial markets from external shocks and persistent economic growth brought about by the large domestic savings from OFW and BPO remittances. Macroprudential measures have been strictly put in place so that risks may be mitigated. Another reason that may have added to the protection of the bond market is its innate characteristic itself. The Philippine bond market is still relatively small and young compared to its neighboring countries. The government debt market is also less integrated into the international arena, making it more “resistant” and less affected by external macroeconomic events and shocks. And unlike the interest rates of developed markets, Philippine interest rates (especially at the short-end) dramatically fluctuate, and hence, very hard to predict. This observation further supports the implication of this study – that Philippine bond yields (especially, the short rates) are not yet strongly anchored on macroeconomic variables relative to the bond markets of developed countries. The Philippine bond market, however, is gradually growing and is slowly tapping the international market, so developments in the future must be closely monitored. These advancements must translate to a more efficient bond market and must result to well-anchored trading decisions to facilitate predictability of the bond risk premium. 122 Table 21. Summary of Macro-BRP Regressions Whole Sample 20062010 20112014 𝑐 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) 𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠 𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥(−1) 𝑔𝑚2 𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒(−1) 𝑐 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) 𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑 𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟 𝑔𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖 𝑐 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) 𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑(−1) 𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝 Short Rate (20062014) Short Rate (20062010) Short Rate (20112014) 𝑐 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) 𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑 𝑐 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) 𝑢𝑠𝑐𝑝𝑖 𝑐 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) 𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑(−1) 𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠 Long Rate (20062010) Long Rate (20112014) 𝑐 𝑐 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) 𝑔𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑠𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠 𝑔𝑔𝑖𝑟 𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥 𝑔𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑥(−1) 𝑔𝑚2 𝑔𝑖𝑛𝑓 𝑔𝑓𝑒𝑑𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒(−1) 𝑔𝑝𝑠𝑒𝑖 𝑐 𝐵𝑅𝑃(−1) 𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑(+1) 𝑔𝑟𝑟𝑝 𝑔𝑚2 Long Rate (2006-2014) Source: Author’s compilation 123 CHAPTER V SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS, AND RECOMMENDATIONS This study aims to test the correspondence of Philippine bond yields to the Expectations Hypothesis (EH), and consequently measure the bond risk premium of Philippine bond rates. This study is motivated by the developing government debt market in the country, the growing importance of term spreads in investment and trading decisions, and the flourishing potential of the EH as a framework in monitoring interest rates. This study has five major objectives to fulfill. These are: 1) to empirically test the validity of the Expectations Hypothesis via term spread models; 2) to estimate the bond risk premium (BRP) of Philippine bond yields; 3) to test again the EH using the term spread models with the estimated BRP; 4) to identify the macroeconomic variables that highly affect the estimated the BRP; and 5) to explain the implications of the findings of the study on the Philippine bond market. A. Summary of Results and Conclusions Results are discussed according to the objectives posed in this study: The first objective is to empirically test the validity of the assumptions under the Expectations Hypothesis (EH) via term spread models using the Philippine bond yields. To do this, the future changes in the short-term yields, future changes in the long-term yields, and excess returns were regressed against their corresponding term spreads. The discussion was divided into the two-period 124 case (3-month and 6-month, 6-month and 1-year, and 1-year and 2-year bond yields) and the n-period case (1-year and 3-year, 1-year and 5-year, and 1-year and 10-year bond yields). The desired 𝛼 coefficient must be zero and the 𝛽 coefficient must be one. The results of the term spread regression models highly affirm the rejection of the assumptions of the Expectations Hypothesis (EH). Firstly, the term spread models did not “perfectly” forecast the future changes in the short rate. The 𝛼 coefficients were below zero while the 𝛽 coefficients were far from unity – although the direction of the forecast was right (positive). Secondly, the term spread did not “perfectly” forecast the future changes in the long rate, and the results showed that the 𝛼 coefficients were highly positive while the direction of the forecast was contrary to theory as the 𝛽 coefficients were significantly negative. Lastly, the term spread models were able to positively, consistently (across all maturities), and strongly (high 𝛽 coefficients) forecast the excess returns of bond rates, which it was not supposed to do. The additional tests using forward spread models also confirmed that the EH did not hold true for Philippine bond yields. Due to the failure of the assumptions of the EH, this study assumed right away that the rejection of the tests was due to the omission for the bond risk premium (BRP) as suggested by various literature. Hence, the second objective was to have an estimate of the bond risk premium to be plugged in into the term spread models. 125 In this study, the BRP was associated with interest rate volatility. Three measures of volatility were obtained. These were the: 1) moving average of the absolute changes in the short rate and long rate computed over the previous six periods; 2) square of the expected excess holding period return; and the estimates of conditional standard deviations and variances from the univariate GARCH (1,1) model. To select which BRP estimate is the best, each of them were inputted into the term spread models and improvement indicators were monitored as indicated by the third objective. These indicators are the: 1) Adjusted R2 which must not be far away from the original R2; 2) F-statistic which must have a large value; 3) Akaike Information Criterion; and the 4) Schwarz Information Criterion (SIC) which should both be at a minimum value. The improvement of the 𝛼 and 𝛽 coefficients were also considered. From the criteria above, the best BRP proxy estimates were obtained from the GARCH (1,1) model that measured the volatility of the monthly excess returns of bond yields. Based on the assessment, the best BRP for the short rates were the conditional variances, while the best BRP for the long rates were the conditional standard deviations. This only affirms that the short rates are more volatile than the long rates; hence, variances must be used for the former, while a more stable proxy can be used to capture the volatility of the latter. Nevertheless, despite producing the best BRP estimates among the methods tested, the conditional standard deviations and conditional variances did not achieve the theoretical values of the 𝛼 and 𝛽 coefficients. In the case of the short 126 rates, the conditional variances enhanced the 𝛼 coefficients by making it less negative than the original test, and by adding more points to the 𝛽 coefficient making it closer to one. This implies that the conditional variances are good proxies for the BRP, making them close to the real BRP required by investors in the Philippine bond market. In the case of the long rate regressions, the conditional standard deviations somehow improved the results of the tests, although still far from the desired results. The 𝛼 coefficients had large positive values which were still far away from zero. The 𝛽 coefficients, on the other hand, now became positive which is big change from the negative 𝛽s in the original term spread model. With this, empirical results already correspond to what theory says – an increase in the term spread does signal a positive change of future long rates. From these findings, we can say that the BRP estimates from the univariate GARCH (1,1) model are still good BRP proxies. However, the estimation model can be further improved to achieve the desired 𝛼 and 𝛽 coefficients. Now that the BRP proxy has been selected and tested, the fourth objective of this study was to identify the various macroeconomic variables that highly affect the BRP. To achieve this, a fixed effects panel regression model was used to test the relationship of 14 macroeconomic variables (independent variables), together with the lagged values of the BRP and the bond spread, and the estimated BRP (dependent variable), both for the short rate and the long rate. The following variables are classified into macroeconomic variables, government/fiscal variables, institutional variables, and additional variables derived from the yield 127 curve. They are as follows: annual growth rate of Meralco sales (as a proxy for economic growth), inflation, peso-dollar rate, excess liquidity, OFW remittances, BSP monetary stance, US prices, federal funds rate, gross international reserves, budget deficit as a percent of GDP, government debt as a percent of GDP, Philippines stock market index, the lagged values of the BRP, and the bond spread. Periodical analyses were also done to deepen the discussion of the results. The regression results showed that the various macroeconomic variables affect the estimated BRP differently according to maturity and time. It was, therefore, hard to pinpoint which variables consistently and significantly affect the estimated BRP. The most persistent factor throughout the tests, however, was the lagged values of the BRP and the bond spread. This implies that investors highly rely on the past conditions of the market and the movement of long-term rates relative to the short-term rates to peg their assigned BRP. They closely watch the movement of interest rates to make their next trading or investment move. This behavior suggests that investors follow more the assumptions of the Adaptive Expectations Hypothesis (AEH) (i.e., being more backward-looking) than the Rational Expectations Hypothesis (REH) (i.e., being more forward-looking). For the macroeconomic variables, the most insistent and statistically significant factors were shown in the whole sample results which were which were the annual growth rate of Meralco sales, excess liquidity, peso-dollar exchange rate, and the federal funds rate. Other variables not in the whole sample results, such as BSP’s monetary stance and the growth rate of the Philippine Stock Exchange index, were also observed to be some of the most important determinants of the BRP. This 128 finding suggests that investors also take into account the effect of various macroeconomic variables on their investment instruments. Among these macroeconomic variables, the short rate BRP is observed to be more responsive to the lagged values of the BRP, while the long rate is observed to be more anchored on economic factors, both domestic and foreign variables. This finding confirms that expectations of investors in the short-term debt market may still be based on adaptive sentiments (i.e., on what they feel or believe will happen based on the previous direction of the data). Hence, trading decisions may be temporary and fleeting – giving the BSP and the PDS Group more ways to deviate or correct the market’s prospects. The long rate BRP, on the other hand, are more grounded on economic variables and their effects have been varied. Meralco sales (as a proxy for economic growth) and excess liquidity, for instance, have very minute yet significant effects on BRP. The financial market may, therefore, expect small impacts on the BRP when measures of economic growth and liquidity change. On the other hand, when shocks to the peso-dollar rate, BSP’s policy rate, federal funds rate, and stock market activity transpire, the bond market can expect the BRP and, consequently, yields to strongly react. Hence, these macroeconomic variables must be closely monitored to maintain stability of long-term maturity bonds. As a response to the fifth objective, the findings of the study has several implications especially about the bond market of the country. First and foremost, the Philippine bond market is still young and small, compared to the government debt market of other developing countries (especially, its ASEAN 129 neighbors), which still needs a lot of improvement in terms of efficiency. The bond market is not yet very competitive enough to meet the rigid assumptions of the Expectations Hypothesis (EH). This just shows that our country’s interest rates are not purely dependent on the expectations of investors as theory dictates, but also on other factors. The nature of these factors that significantly affect the BRP and, consequently, the bond yields, confirm the country’s resistance to external shocks after the crisis period; hence, pointing our direction to domestic economic variables as reliable predictors of the current BRP and bond yields. Secondly, the lack of studies about frameworks regarding the term structure of interest rates only highlights the fact that the market is not yet well-structured enough. The academe nor financial analysts are not yet deep into analyzing the motivations behind the movements of interest rates. This makes investment or trading decisions loosely grounded on macroeconomic activities and more rooted on sentiments or mere expectations. Unlike in developed countries, several studies have been done already to estimate interest rate expectations and the BRP so that forecasts may have a framework. In the Philippines, however, decisions are not yet well-supported by macroeconomic forces and policymakers do not have yet a concrete framework to follow when it comes to interest-rate monitoring, making it hard to predict the movement of interest rates and the BRP. Nevertheless, the macro-BRP relationship tests done in this study show that the estimated BRP of the Philippines is, in one way or another, related to various macroeconomic variables. This is a good indication that the debt market is 130 gradually being characterized by rational market players as decisions are becoming more based on analyzed facts and more informed choices. Furthermore, as the Philippine bond market moves towards advancements, corresponding developments may translate to a more competitive and efficient debt market. A more feasible interest rate framework is, therefore, not too distant to be achieved. B. Limits of the Study and Recommendations Future researchers can explore more on the limitations of this study. Since this study only discussed the single-equation approach in the empirical testing of the Expectations Hypothesis, other estimation methods can be done. One example is the affine term structure representations, which includes the Stochastic Discount Factor (SDF) model or the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). Other studies may also extend the bond maturities of this study by computing for the zero-coupon bonds of consecutive tenors via bootstrapping. It is also suggested to make use of benchmark bonds – bonds that are actively traded in the secondary market and proven to be more liquid. This is because the yields of these bonds efficiently reflect the true yields made by the market; hence, benchmark bonds will serve as more accurate indicators of Philippine’s interest rates. There are also a number of ways to estimate the bond risk premium (BRP) as discussed in the related literature of this study. Instead of using the observable proxy method, the term premium specification model from the SDF and CAPM methods can used. The survey method can also be done if possible. 131 Lastly, since this study only analyzed the relationship of the estimated BRP with a limited number of macroeconomic variables, more econometric models can be developed and more macroeconomic variables can be added to come up with a very robust model useful for forecasting. With this, the BRP can be efficiently predicted that may be helpful for investors and policymakers. 132 APPENDIX A: ZERO COUPON BOND YIELDS OBTAINED FROM THE BLOOMBERG TERMINAL (TENORS: 3-MONTH, 6-MONTH, 1-YEAR, 2-YEAR, 3-YEAR, 5-YEAR, AND 10-YEAR) PHP Philippine Government Zero Coupon Yield 3 Month Security Start Date End Date Period Currency Date 11/30/2014 10/31/2014 9/30/2014 8/29/2014 7/31/2014 6/30/2014 5/30/2014 4/30/2014 3/31/2014 2/28/2014 1/31/2014 12/31/2013 11/29/2013 10/31/2013 9/30/2013 8/30/2013 7/31/2013 6/28/2013 5/31/2013 4/30/2013 I10503M Index 2/26/2004 12/30/2014 M PHP PX_LAST 1.5 1.4 1.5 1.25 1.375 1.15 1.07 1.3 1.5 1 1.2 0.325 0.175 0.095 0.476 1.25 1.049 1.75 2 0.2 PHP Philippine Government Zero Coupon Yield 6 Month Security Start Date End Date Period Currency Date 11/30/2014 10/31/2014 9/30/2014 8/29/2014 7/31/2014 6/30/2014 5/30/2014 4/30/2014 3/31/2014 2/28/2014 1/31/2014 12/31/2013 11/29/2013 10/31/2013 9/30/2013 8/30/2013 7/31/2013 6/28/2013 5/31/2013 4/30/2013 I10506M Index 2/26/2004 12/30/2014 M PHP PX_LAST 1.738 1.464 1.737 1.613 1.663 1.29 1.789 1.96 1.321 1.481 1.947 0.425 0.299 0.184 0.896 1.35 0.847 1.802 2.025 0.3 PHP Philippine Government Zero Coupon Yield 1 Year Security Start Date End Date Period Currency Date 11/30/2014 10/31/2014 9/30/2014 8/29/2014 7/31/2014 6/30/2014 5/30/2014 4/30/2014 3/31/2014 2/28/2014 1/31/2014 12/31/2013 11/29/2013 10/31/2013 9/30/2013 8/30/2013 7/31/2013 6/28/2013 5/31/2013 4/30/2013 I10501Y Index 2/26/2004 12/30/2014 M PHP PX_LAST 2.033 1.742 1.754 1.9 1.92 1.753 2 2.255 1.399 1.923 2.044 0.922 0.754 0.409 1.077 1.573 1.422 2.037 2.016 0.454 133 3/29/2013 2/28/2013 1/31/2013 12/31/2012 11/30/2012 10/31/2012 9/28/2012 8/31/2012 7/31/2012 6/29/2012 5/31/2012 4/30/2012 3/30/2012 2/29/2012 1/31/2012 12/30/2011 11/30/2011 10/31/2011 9/30/2011 8/31/2011 7/29/2011 6/30/2011 5/31/2011 4/29/2011 3/31/2011 2/28/2011 1/31/2011 12/31/2010 11/30/2010 10/29/2010 9/30/2010 8/31/2010 7/30/2010 6/30/2010 5/31/2010 0.25 0.35 0.151 0.3 0.611 0.3 0.625 1.382 1.84 2.195 2.2 2.15 2.3 1.889 1.625 1.375 2.165 1.115 2.745 0.951 2.425 2.852 2.189 0.607 1.042 1.65 3.2 1.195 1.5 3.749 4.103 4.1 4.066 3.951 4.15 3/29/2013 2/28/2013 1/31/2013 12/31/2012 11/30/2012 10/31/2012 9/28/2012 8/31/2012 7/31/2012 6/29/2012 5/31/2012 4/30/2012 3/30/2012 2/29/2012 1/31/2012 12/30/2011 11/30/2011 10/31/2011 9/30/2011 8/31/2011 7/29/2011 6/30/2011 5/31/2011 4/29/2011 3/31/2011 2/28/2011 1/31/2011 12/31/2010 11/30/2010 10/29/2010 9/30/2010 8/31/2010 7/30/2010 6/30/2010 5/31/2010 0.321 0.35 0.387 0.575 0.646 0.488 0.973 1.669 2.091 2.277 2.321 2.162 2.313 2.31 1.786 1.536 1.51 1.445 2.039 0.992 2.63 2.982 2.376 0.882 1.215 2.062 3.218 1.465 1.82 4.055 4.313 4.306 4.249 4.226 4.332 3/29/2013 2/28/2013 1/31/2013 12/31/2012 11/30/2012 10/31/2012 9/28/2012 8/31/2012 7/31/2012 6/29/2012 5/31/2012 4/30/2012 3/30/2012 2/29/2012 1/31/2012 12/30/2011 11/30/2011 10/31/2011 9/30/2011 8/31/2011 7/29/2011 6/30/2011 5/31/2011 4/29/2011 3/31/2011 2/28/2011 1/31/2011 12/31/2010 11/30/2010 10/29/2010 9/30/2010 8/31/2010 7/30/2010 6/30/2010 5/31/2010 0.822 1.034 1.245 0.929 0.754 0.83 1.475 2.114 2.297 2.457 2.579 2.556 2.999 2.563 2.232 1.678 1.613 1.607 1.531 1.576 3.1 3.131 2.809 2.18 2.305 3.34 3.807 2.548 2.555 4.129 4.568 4.54 4.609 4.607 4.625 134 4/30/2010 3/31/2010 2/26/2010 1/29/2010 12/31/2009 11/30/2009 10/30/2009 9/30/2009 8/31/2009 7/31/2009 6/30/2009 5/29/2009 4/30/2009 3/31/2009 2/27/2009 1/30/2009 12/31/2008 11/28/2008 10/31/2008 9/30/2008 8/29/2008 7/31/2008 6/30/2008 5/30/2008 4/30/2008 3/31/2008 2/29/2008 1/31/2008 12/31/2007 11/30/2007 10/31/2007 9/28/2007 8/31/2007 7/31/2007 6/29/2007 4.056 3.9 4.015 3.805 4.067 3.647 4.005 4.052 3.751 3.688 4.319 4.355 4.353 4.293 4.556 4.282 5.626 6.375 6.75 6.5 6.185 6.082 5.116 6.061 5.087 4.375 4.6 4 4.22 4.022 4 4.062 4.525 4.25 4.66 4/30/2010 3/31/2010 2/26/2010 1/29/2010 12/31/2009 11/30/2009 10/30/2009 9/30/2009 8/31/2009 7/31/2009 6/30/2009 5/29/2009 4/30/2009 3/31/2009 2/27/2009 1/30/2009 12/31/2008 11/28/2008 10/31/2008 9/30/2008 8/29/2008 7/31/2008 6/30/2008 5/30/2008 4/30/2008 3/31/2008 2/29/2008 1/31/2008 12/31/2007 11/30/2007 10/31/2007 9/28/2007 8/31/2007 7/31/2007 6/29/2007 4.16 4.028 4.139 4.243 4.314 4.142 4.191 4.17 3.997 3.828 4.567 4.552 4.586 4.462 4.777 4.511 6.002 6.426 6.971 6.222 6.781 6.049 5.558 5.842 6.172 5.129 5.424 4.819 4.835 4.844 4.733 4.813 5.503 4.944 4.784 4/30/2010 3/31/2010 2/26/2010 1/29/2010 12/31/2009 11/30/2009 10/30/2009 9/30/2009 8/31/2009 7/31/2009 6/30/2009 5/29/2009 4/30/2009 3/31/2009 2/27/2009 1/30/2009 12/31/2008 11/28/2008 10/31/2008 9/30/2008 8/29/2008 7/31/2008 6/30/2008 5/30/2008 4/30/2008 3/31/2008 2/29/2008 1/31/2008 12/31/2007 11/30/2007 10/31/2007 9/28/2007 8/31/2007 7/31/2007 6/29/2007 4.514 4.414 4.393 4.773 4.791 4.53 4.454 4.399 4.434 4.252 4.792 4.665 4.757 4.787 4.943 4.637 6.083 6.839 7.227 6.503 6.657 7.269 6.709 6.824 6.595 5.521 5.906 5.21 5.595 5.652 5.72 5.717 5.742 5.716 5.296 135 5/31/2007 4/30/2007 3/30/2007 2/28/2007 1/31/2007 12/29/2006 11/30/2006 10/31/2006 9/29/2006 8/31/2006 7/31/2006 6/30/2006 5/31/2006 4/28/2006 3/31/2006 2/28/2006 1/31/2006 12/30/2005 11/30/2005 10/31/2005 9/30/2005 8/31/2005 7/29/2005 6/30/2005 5/31/2005 4/29/2005 3/31/2005 2/28/2005 1/31/2005 12/31/2004 11/30/2004 10/29/2004 9/30/2004 8/31/2004 7/30/2004 4.567 3 4.023 3.538 3.643 4.885 5.212 5.725 5.724 5.917 6.332 8.906 5.736 5.058 5.389 5.756 5.732 7.769 5.878 6.265 6.259 6.08 6.041 6.216 5.946 6.591 6.694 7.497 8.008 8.084 8.002 7.978 7.821 7.561 7.33 5/31/2007 4/30/2007 3/30/2007 2/28/2007 1/31/2007 12/29/2006 11/30/2006 10/31/2006 9/29/2006 8/31/2006 7/31/2006 6/30/2006 5/31/2006 4/28/2006 3/31/2006 2/28/2006 1/31/2006 12/30/2005 11/30/2005 10/31/2005 9/30/2005 8/31/2005 7/29/2005 6/30/2005 5/31/2005 4/29/2005 3/31/2005 2/28/2005 1/31/2005 12/31/2004 11/30/2004 10/29/2004 9/30/2004 8/31/2004 7/30/2004 4.1 3.839 4.307 3.926 4.271 4.885 5.219 6.238 6.282 6.383 6.883 7.161 6.173 5.499 8.692 6.359 6.329 8.295 7.64 7.953 8.05 7.635 7.413 6.983 6.87 7.659 7.789 7.497 8.008 9.17 8.916 9.107 8.605 8.428 8.258 5/31/2007 4/30/2007 3/30/2007 2/28/2007 1/31/2007 12/29/2006 11/30/2006 10/31/2006 9/29/2006 8/31/2006 7/31/2006 6/30/2006 5/31/2006 4/28/2006 3/31/2006 2/28/2006 1/31/2006 12/30/2005 11/30/2005 10/31/2005 9/30/2005 8/31/2005 7/29/2005 6/30/2005 5/31/2005 4/29/2005 3/31/2005 2/28/2005 1/31/2005 12/31/2004 11/30/2004 10/29/2004 9/30/2004 8/31/2004 7/30/2004 5.131 5.029 4.763 4.382 4.572 5.23 5.366 6.798 6.652 7.322 7.371 7.794 6.97 5.935 6.647 7.315 7.304 8.236 8.175 8.99 9.059 8.65 8.409 8.193 7.99 8.559 8.752 8.345 8.682 10.081 9.803 9.715 9.718 9.801 9.386 136 6/30/2004 5/31/2004 4/30/2004 3/31/2004 2/27/2004 7.437 7.141 7.126 7.994 6.483 6/30/2004 5/31/2004 4/30/2004 3/31/2004 2/27/2004 PHP Philippine Government Zero Coupon Yield 2 Year Security Start Date End Date Period Currency Date 11/30/2014 10/31/2014 9/30/2014 8/29/2014 7/31/2014 6/30/2014 5/30/2014 4/30/2014 3/31/2014 2/28/2014 1/31/2014 12/31/2013 11/29/2013 10/31/2013 9/30/2013 8/30/2013 7/31/2013 6/28/2013 I10502Y Index 2/26/2004 12/30/2014 M PHP PX_LAST 2.508 2.321 2.145 2.455 2.497 2.378 2.346 2.727 2.404 2.247 2.705 2.151 1.925 1.953 2.045 2.647 2.267 2.553 8.603 8.505 8.093 8.742 7.925 6/30/2004 5/31/2004 4/30/2004 3/31/2004 2/27/2004 PHP Philippine Government Zero Coupon Yield 3 Year Security Start Date End Date Period Currency Date 11/30/2014 10/31/2014 9/30/2014 8/29/2014 7/31/2014 6/30/2014 5/30/2014 4/30/2014 3/31/2014 2/28/2014 1/31/2014 12/31/2013 11/29/2013 10/31/2013 9/30/2013 8/30/2013 7/31/2013 6/28/2013 I10503Y Index 2/26/2004 12/30/2014 M PHP PX_LAST 2.829 2.442 2.672 2.66 2.751 2.685 2.671 2.954 2.932 2.663 2.935 2.264 2.111 2.021 2.356 2.438 2.135 2.883 9.613 9.125 8.835 9.647 9.182 PHP Philippine Government Zero Coupon Yield 5 Year Security Start Date End Date Period Currency Date 11/30/2014 10/31/2014 9/30/2014 8/29/2014 7/31/2014 6/30/2014 5/30/2014 4/30/2014 3/31/2014 2/28/2014 1/31/2014 12/31/2013 11/29/2013 10/31/2013 9/30/2013 8/30/2013 7/31/2013 6/28/2013 I10505Y Index 2/26/2004 12/30/2014 M PHP PX_LAST 3.331 3.599 4.153 3.873 3.596 3.606 3.337 3.901 3.463 3.593 3.414 3 2.786 2.898 3.115 2.841 2.504 2.875 137 5/31/2013 4/30/2013 3/29/2013 2/28/2013 1/31/2013 12/31/2012 11/30/2012 10/31/2012 9/28/2012 8/31/2012 7/31/2012 6/29/2012 5/31/2012 4/30/2012 3/30/2012 2/29/2012 1/31/2012 12/30/2011 11/30/2011 10/31/2011 9/30/2011 8/31/2011 7/29/2011 6/30/2011 5/31/2011 4/29/2011 3/31/2011 2/28/2011 1/31/2011 12/31/2010 11/30/2010 10/29/2010 9/30/2010 8/31/2010 7/30/2010 2.266 2.02 2.186 2.338 2.64 2.864 2.452 2.698 2.299 2.658 2.674 3.085 2.987 2.907 3.197 3.07 2.788 2.362 2.431 2.483 2.622 2.643 3.572 3.914 4.419 3.272 4.28 4.74 4.719 3.564 3.834 4.434 5.015 5.105 5.164 5/31/2013 4/30/2013 3/29/2013 2/28/2013 1/31/2013 12/31/2012 11/30/2012 10/31/2012 9/28/2012 8/31/2012 7/31/2012 6/29/2012 5/31/2012 4/30/2012 3/30/2012 2/29/2012 1/31/2012 12/30/2011 11/30/2011 10/31/2011 9/30/2011 8/31/2011 7/29/2011 6/30/2011 5/31/2011 4/29/2011 3/31/2011 2/28/2011 1/31/2011 12/31/2010 11/30/2010 10/29/2010 9/30/2010 8/31/2010 7/30/2010 2.289 1.978 2.537 2.791 3.206 3.285 3.413 3.683 3.281 3.828 3.609 3.654 3.588 3.749 3.613 3.509 3.758 3.432 3.517 3.757 3.308 3.224 3.963 4.486 5.082 4.643 5.197 5.433 4.951 4.237 4.337 4.534 5.098 5.123 5.373 5/31/2013 4/30/2013 3/29/2013 2/28/2013 1/31/2013 12/31/2012 11/30/2012 10/31/2012 9/28/2012 8/31/2012 7/31/2012 6/29/2012 5/31/2012 4/30/2012 3/30/2012 2/29/2012 1/31/2012 12/30/2011 11/30/2011 10/31/2011 9/30/2011 8/31/2011 7/29/2011 6/30/2011 5/31/2011 4/29/2011 3/31/2011 2/28/2011 1/31/2011 12/31/2010 11/30/2010 10/29/2010 9/30/2010 8/31/2010 7/30/2010 2.163 2.448 2.974 3.318 3.459 3.798 3.844 4.323 4.524 4.558 4.617 4.883 4.975 4.888 4.606 4.406 4.403 4.367 4.981 4.764 5.25 4.598 4.947 5.129 5.436 5.03 5.887 6.486 5.486 4.926 4.836 4.782 5.397 5.585 6.328 138 6/30/2010 5/31/2010 4/30/2010 3/31/2010 2/26/2010 1/29/2010 12/31/2009 11/30/2009 10/30/2009 9/30/2009 8/31/2009 7/31/2009 6/30/2009 5/29/2009 4/30/2009 3/31/2009 2/27/2009 1/30/2009 12/31/2008 11/28/2008 10/31/2008 9/30/2008 8/29/2008 7/31/2008 6/30/2008 5/30/2008 4/30/2008 3/31/2008 2/29/2008 1/31/2008 12/31/2007 11/30/2007 10/31/2007 9/28/2007 8/31/2007 5.208 5.195 4.898 4.848 4.672 5.019 5.352 4.672 4.658 4.795 4.743 4.722 5.296 4.941 4.984 5.232 5.405 5.561 6.592 7.674 7.672 7.464 7.163 7.137 7.146 7.679 7.528 6.202 6.099 5.43 5.713 6.22 6.243 6.265 6.581 6/30/2010 5/31/2010 4/30/2010 3/31/2010 2/26/2010 1/29/2010 12/31/2009 11/30/2009 10/30/2009 9/30/2009 8/31/2009 7/31/2009 6/30/2009 5/29/2009 4/30/2009 3/31/2009 2/27/2009 1/30/2009 12/31/2008 11/28/2008 10/31/2008 9/30/2008 8/29/2008 7/31/2008 6/30/2008 5/30/2008 4/30/2008 3/31/2008 2/29/2008 1/31/2008 12/31/2007 11/30/2007 10/31/2007 9/28/2007 8/31/2007 5.356 5.362 5.45 5.181 5.423 5.419 5.673 5.38 5.436 5.261 5.421 5.222 5.504 5.151 5.395 5.881 5.772 5.927 6.252 7.98 7.777 7.009 7.038 7.831 8.225 8.27 7.663 6.347 6.371 5.487 5.698 6.314 6.39 6.427 7.031 6/30/2010 5/31/2010 4/30/2010 3/31/2010 2/26/2010 1/29/2010 12/31/2009 11/30/2009 10/30/2009 9/30/2009 8/31/2009 7/31/2009 6/30/2009 5/29/2009 4/30/2009 3/31/2009 2/27/2009 1/30/2009 12/31/2008 11/28/2008 10/31/2008 9/30/2008 8/29/2008 7/31/2008 6/30/2008 5/30/2008 4/30/2008 3/31/2008 2/29/2008 1/31/2008 12/31/2007 11/30/2007 10/31/2007 9/28/2007 8/31/2007 6.522 6.61 6.67 6.509 6.483 6.624 6.553 6.542 6.567 6.432 6.546 6.49 6.526 6.261 6.426 6.545 6.541 6.295 6.704 8.54 7.864 7.673 7.354 8.526 8.955 8.631 8.153 6.56 6.554 5.603 5.814 6.48 6.552 6.661 7.305 139 7/31/2007 6/29/2007 5/31/2007 4/30/2007 3/30/2007 2/28/2007 1/31/2007 12/29/2006 11/30/2006 10/31/2006 9/29/2006 8/31/2006 7/31/2006 6/30/2006 5/31/2006 4/28/2006 3/31/2006 2/28/2006 1/31/2006 12/30/2005 11/30/2005 10/31/2005 9/30/2005 8/31/2005 7/29/2005 6/30/2005 5/31/2005 4/29/2005 3/31/2005 2/28/2005 1/31/2005 12/31/2004 11/30/2004 10/29/2004 9/30/2004 6.781 6.158 5.864 5.614 5.295 5.173 5.418 5.56 5.793 7.003 7.489 7.78 8.359 8.551 10.242 6.314 7.079 8.067 8.349 10.038 9.27 9.786 9.7 9.586 9.582 9.343 9.289 9.784 10.091 10.106 10.077 11.532 11 10.425 10.94 7/31/2007 6/29/2007 5/31/2007 4/30/2007 3/30/2007 2/28/2007 1/31/2007 12/29/2006 11/30/2006 10/31/2006 9/29/2006 8/31/2006 7/31/2006 6/30/2006 5/31/2006 4/28/2006 3/31/2006 2/28/2006 1/31/2006 12/30/2005 11/30/2005 10/31/2005 9/30/2005 8/31/2005 7/29/2005 6/30/2005 5/31/2005 4/29/2005 3/31/2005 2/28/2005 1/31/2005 12/31/2004 11/30/2004 10/29/2004 9/30/2004 6.907 6.555 5.913 5.784 5.541 5.355 5.671 5.707 5.912 7.073 7.491 10.724 8.681 9.205 8.52 6.478 7.133 8.232 8.601 9.549 9.736 10.304 10.221 10.22 10.144 9.899 9.907 10.703 10.724 10.731 10.404 11.951 11.53 11.586 11.422 7/31/2007 6/29/2007 5/31/2007 4/30/2007 3/30/2007 2/28/2007 1/31/2007 12/29/2006 11/30/2006 10/31/2006 9/29/2006 8/31/2006 7/31/2006 6/30/2006 5/31/2006 4/28/2006 3/31/2006 2/28/2006 1/31/2006 12/30/2005 11/30/2005 10/31/2005 9/30/2005 8/31/2005 7/29/2005 6/30/2005 5/31/2005 4/29/2005 3/31/2005 2/28/2005 1/31/2005 12/31/2004 11/30/2004 10/29/2004 9/30/2004 7.175 6.92 6.152 6.149 6.036 5.743 6.123 5.89 6.094 7.259 7.687 8.137 9.248 9.766 8.772 6.745 7.289 11.418 8.674 9.705 10.13 11.05 11.14 11.138 11.128 11.268 11.052 11.659 11.472 11.592 11.436 13.124 12.846 12.837 12.526 140 8/31/2004 7/30/2004 6/30/2004 5/31/2004 4/30/2004 3/31/2004 2/27/2004 10.73 10.29 10.486 10.261 9.878 10.795 10.869 8/31/2004 7/30/2004 6/30/2004 5/31/2004 4/30/2004 3/31/2004 2/27/2004 11.611 11.033 11.223 11.011 10.478 11.555 11.518 8/31/2004 7/30/2004 6/30/2004 5/31/2004 4/30/2004 3/31/2004 2/27/2004 12.818 11.51 12.394 12.045 11.015 12.296 12.501 PHP Philippine Government Zero Coupon Yield 10 Year Security Index Date 11/30/2014 10/31/2014 9/30/2014 8/29/2014 7/31/2014 6/30/2014 5/30/2014 4/30/2014 3/31/2014 2/28/2014 1/31/2014 12/31/2013 11/29/2013 10/31/2013 9/30/2013 8/30/2013 7/31/2013 6/28/2013 5/31/2013 4/30/2013 3/29/2013 2/28/2013 PX_LAST 3.851 4.157 4.361 4.306 4.195 4.043 4.118 4.36 4.454 4.182 4.296 3.73 3.544 3.499 3.608 3.498 3.375 3.856 3.369 2.905 3.024 3.607 I10510Y Index Date 1/31/2013 12/31/2012 11/30/2012 10/31/2012 9/28/2012 8/31/2012 7/31/2012 6/29/2012 5/31/2012 4/30/2012 3/30/2012 2/29/2012 1/31/2012 12/30/2011 11/30/2011 10/31/2011 9/30/2011 8/31/2011 7/29/2011 6/30/2011 5/31/2011 4/29/2011 PX_LAST 4.072 4.299 4.604 4.877 4.841 5.038 5.12 5.529 5.838 5.523 5.599 5.179 5.393 5.355 6.044 5.973 6.346 6.246 6.555 6.77 6.624 6.518 Date 3/31/2011 2/28/2011 1/31/2011 12/31/2010 11/30/2010 10/29/2010 9/30/2010 8/31/2010 7/30/2010 6/30/2010 5/31/2010 4/30/2010 3/31/2010 2/26/2010 1/29/2010 12/31/2009 11/30/2009 10/30/2009 9/30/2009 8/31/2009 7/31/2009 6/30/2009 PX_LAST 7.293 7.551 6.563 6.326 6.17 5.913 6.346 7.042 8.168 8.288 8.568 8.628 8.735 8.447 8.515 8.654 8.567 8.627 8.762 8.514 8.538 8.774 Start Date Period Date 5/29/2009 4/30/2009 3/31/2009 2/27/2009 1/30/2009 12/31/2008 11/28/2008 10/31/2008 9/30/2008 8/29/2008 7/31/2008 6/30/2008 5/30/2008 4/30/2008 3/31/2008 2/29/2008 1/31/2008 12/31/2007 11/30/2007 10/31/2007 9/28/2007 8/31/2007 2/26/2004 M PX_LAST 8.272 8.953 8.509 8.652 7.957 7.614 9.138 10.202 8.502 8.535 10.236 9.69 9.302 8.621 7.546 7.254 6.136 6.723 7.242 7.281 7.372 8.123 Date 7/31/2007 6/29/2007 5/31/2007 4/30/2007 3/30/2007 2/28/2007 1/31/2007 12/29/2006 11/30/2006 10/31/2006 9/29/2006 8/31/2006 7/31/2006 6/30/2006 5/31/2006 4/28/2006 3/31/2006 2/28/2006 1/31/2006 12/30/2005 11/30/2005 10/31/2005 End Date Currency PX_LAST 7.456 7.195 7.298 7.495 7.396 7.197 6.991 6.498 6.641 7.883 8.549 9.171 10.57 10.692 10.396 7.35 7.704 8.682 9.838 10.061 11.915 12.672 12/30/2014 PHP Date 9/30/2005 8/31/2005 7/29/2005 6/30/2005 5/31/2005 4/29/2005 3/31/2005 2/28/2005 1/31/2005 12/31/2004 11/30/2004 10/29/2004 9/30/2004 8/31/2004 7/30/2004 6/30/2004 5/31/2004 4/30/2004 3/31/2004 2/27/2004 PX_LAST 12.69 12.823 13.118 12.71 12.628 12.631 12.932 13.278 13.214 14.533 14.431 14.283 13.764 13.863 13.316 13.025 13.06 12.524 12.991 13.471 141 APPENDIX B: DATA FOR TWO-PERIOD CASE m3 m6 m3m3 2005M11 5.87800 2005M12 7.76900 2006M01 5.73200 6.32900 -1.01850 2006M02 5.75600 6.35900 2006M03 5.38900 2006M04 m3m6 m6 y1 m6m6 m6y1 y1 y2 y1y1 y1y2 7.64000 7.64000 8.17500 8.17500 9.27000 8.29500 8.29500 8.23600 8.23600 10.03800 0.52600 6.32900 7.30400 -0.98300 -0.05900 7.30400 8.34900 -0.46600 1.80200 0.01200 0.59700 6.35900 7.31500 0.01500 0.97500 7.31500 8.06700 0.00550 1.04500 8.69200 -0.18350 0.60300 8.69200 6.64700 1.16650 0.95600 6.64700 7.07900 -0.33400 0.75200 5.05800 5.49900 -0.16550 3.30300 5.49900 5.93500 -1.59650 -2.04500 5.93500 6.31400 -0.35600 0.43200 2006M05 5.73600 6.17300 0.33900 0.44100 6.17300 6.97000 0.33700 0.43600 6.97000 10.24200 0.51750 0.37900 2006M06 8.90600 7.16100 1.58500 0.43700 7.16100 7.79400 0.49400 0.79700 7.79400 8.55100 0.41200 3.27200 2006M07 6.33200 6.88300 -1.28700 2006M08 5.91700 6.38300 -0.20750 -1.74500 6.88300 7.37100 -0.13900 0.63300 7.37100 8.35900 -0.21150 0.75700 0.55100 6.38300 7.32200 -0.25000 0.48800 7.32200 7.78000 -0.02450 0.98800 2006M09 5.72400 6.28200 -0.09650 0.46600 6.28200 6.65200 -0.05050 0.93900 6.65200 7.48900 -0.33500 0.45800 2006M10 5.72500 6.23800 0.00050 0.55800 6.23800 6.79800 -0.02200 0.37000 6.79800 7.00300 0.07300 0.83700 2006M11 5.21200 5.21900 -0.25650 0.51300 5.21900 5.36600 -0.50950 0.56000 5.36600 5.79300 -0.71600 0.20500 2006M12 4.88500 4.88500 -0.16350 0.00700 4.88500 5.23000 -0.16700 0.14700 5.23000 5.56000 -0.06800 0.42700 2007M01 3.64300 4.27100 -0.62100 0.00000 4.27100 4.57200 -0.30700 0.34500 4.57200 5.41800 -0.32900 0.33000 2007M02 3.53800 3.92600 -0.05250 0.62800 3.92600 4.38200 -0.17250 0.30100 4.38200 5.17300 -0.09500 0.84600 2007M03 4.02300 4.30700 0.24250 0.38800 4.30700 4.76300 0.19050 0.45600 4.76300 5.29500 0.19050 0.79100 2007M04 3.00000 3.83900 -0.51150 0.28400 3.83900 5.02900 -0.23400 0.45600 5.02900 5.61400 0.13300 0.53200 2007M05 4.56700 4.10000 0.78350 0.83900 4.10000 5.13100 0.13050 1.19000 5.13100 5.86400 0.05100 0.58500 2007M06 4.66000 4.78400 0.04650 -0.46700 4.78400 5.29600 0.34200 1.03100 5.29600 6.15800 0.08250 0.73300 2007M07 4.25000 4.94400 -0.20500 0.12400 4.94400 5.71600 0.08000 0.51200 5.71600 6.78100 0.21000 0.86200 2007M08 4.52500 5.50300 0.13750 0.69400 5.50300 5.74200 0.27950 0.77200 5.74200 6.58100 0.01300 1.06500 2007M09 4.06200 4.81300 -0.23150 0.97800 4.81300 5.71700 -0.34500 0.23900 5.71700 6.26500 -0.01250 0.83900 2007M10 4.00000 4.73300 -0.03100 0.75100 4.73300 5.72000 -0.04000 0.90400 5.72000 6.24300 0.00150 0.54800 2007M11 4.02200 4.84400 0.01100 0.73300 4.84400 5.65200 0.05550 0.98700 5.65200 6.22000 -0.03400 0.52300 2007M12 4.22000 4.83500 0.09900 0.82200 4.83500 5.59500 -0.00450 0.80800 5.59500 5.71300 -0.02850 0.56800 142 2008M01 4.00000 4.81900 -0.11000 0.61500 4.81900 5.21000 -0.00800 0.76000 5.21000 5.43000 -0.19250 0.11800 2008M02 4.60000 5.42400 0.30000 0.81900 5.42400 5.90600 0.30250 0.39100 5.90600 6.09900 0.34800 0.22000 2008M03 4.37500 5.12900 -0.11250 0.82400 5.12900 5.52100 -0.14750 0.48200 5.52100 6.20200 -0.19250 0.19300 2008M04 5.08700 6.17200 0.35600 0.75400 6.17200 6.59500 0.52150 0.39200 6.59500 7.52800 0.53700 0.68100 2008M05 6.06100 5.84200 0.48700 1.08500 5.84200 6.82400 -0.16500 0.42300 6.82400 7.67900 0.11450 0.93300 2008M06 5.11600 5.55800 -0.47250 -0.21900 5.55800 6.70900 -0.14200 0.98200 6.70900 7.14600 -0.05750 0.85500 2008M07 6.08200 6.04900 0.48300 0.44200 6.04900 7.26900 0.24550 1.15100 7.26900 7.13700 0.28000 0.43700 2008M08 6.18500 6.78100 0.05150 -0.03300 6.78100 6.65700 0.36600 1.22000 6.65700 7.16300 -0.30600 -0.13200 2008M09 6.50000 6.22200 0.15750 0.59600 6.22200 6.50300 -0.27950 -0.12400 6.50300 7.46400 -0.07700 0.50600 2008M10 6.75000 6.97100 0.12500 -0.27800 6.97100 7.22700 0.37450 0.28100 7.22700 7.67200 0.36200 0.96100 2008M11 6.37500 6.42600 -0.18750 0.22100 6.42600 6.83900 -0.27250 0.25600 6.83900 7.67400 -0.19400 0.44500 2008M12 5.62600 6.00200 -0.37450 0.05100 6.00200 6.08300 -0.21200 0.41300 6.08300 6.59200 -0.37800 0.83500 2009M01 4.28200 4.51100 -0.67200 0.37600 4.51100 4.63700 -0.74550 0.08100 4.63700 5.56100 -0.72300 0.50900 2009M02 4.55600 4.77700 0.13700 0.22900 4.77700 4.94300 0.13300 0.12600 4.94300 5.40500 0.15300 0.92400 2009M03 4.29300 4.46200 -0.13150 0.22100 4.46200 4.78700 -0.15750 0.16600 4.78700 5.23200 -0.07800 0.46200 2009M04 4.35300 4.58600 0.03000 0.16900 4.58600 4.75700 0.06200 0.32500 4.75700 4.98400 -0.01500 0.44500 2009M05 4.35500 4.55200 0.00100 0.23300 4.55200 4.66500 -0.01700 0.17100 4.66500 4.94100 -0.04600 0.22700 2009M06 4.31900 4.56700 -0.01800 0.19700 4.56700 4.79200 0.00750 0.11300 4.79200 5.29600 0.06350 0.27600 2009M07 3.68800 3.82800 -0.31550 0.24800 3.82800 4.25200 -0.36950 0.22500 4.25200 4.72200 -0.27000 0.50400 2009M08 3.75100 3.99700 0.03150 0.14000 3.99700 4.43400 0.08450 0.42400 4.43400 4.74300 0.09100 0.47000 2009M09 4.05200 4.17000 0.15050 0.24600 4.17000 4.39900 0.08650 0.43700 4.39900 4.79500 -0.01750 0.30900 2009M10 4.00500 4.19100 -0.02350 0.11800 4.19100 4.45400 0.01050 0.22900 4.45400 4.65800 0.02750 0.39600 2009M11 3.64700 4.14200 -0.17900 0.18600 4.14200 4.53000 -0.02450 0.26300 4.53000 4.67200 0.03800 0.20400 2009M12 4.06700 4.31400 0.21000 0.49500 4.31400 4.79100 0.08600 0.38800 4.79100 5.35200 0.13050 0.14200 2010M01 3.80500 4.24300 -0.13100 0.24700 4.24300 4.77300 -0.03550 0.47700 4.77300 5.01900 -0.00900 0.56100 2010M02 4.01500 4.13900 0.10500 0.43800 4.13900 4.39300 -0.05200 0.53000 4.39300 4.67200 -0.19000 0.24600 2010M03 3.90000 4.02800 -0.05750 0.12400 4.02800 4.41400 -0.05550 0.25400 4.41400 4.84800 0.01050 0.27900 2010M04 4.05600 4.16000 0.07800 0.12800 4.16000 4.51400 0.06600 0.38600 4.51400 4.89800 0.05000 0.43400 2010M05 4.15000 4.33200 0.04700 0.10400 4.33200 4.62500 0.08600 0.35400 4.62500 5.19500 0.05550 0.38400 2010M06 3.95100 4.22600 -0.09950 0.18200 4.22600 4.60700 -0.05300 0.29300 4.60700 5.20800 -0.00900 0.57000 143 2010M07 4.06600 4.24900 0.05750 0.27500 4.24900 4.60900 0.01150 0.38100 4.60900 5.16400 0.00100 0.60100 2010M08 4.10000 4.30600 0.01700 0.18300 4.30600 4.54000 0.02850 0.36000 4.54000 5.10500 -0.03450 0.55500 2010M09 4.10300 4.31300 0.00150 0.20600 4.31300 4.56800 0.00350 0.23400 4.56800 5.01500 0.01400 0.56500 2010M10 3.74900 4.05500 -0.17700 0.21000 4.05500 4.12900 -0.12900 0.25500 4.12900 4.43400 -0.21950 0.44700 2010M11 1.50000 1.82000 -1.12450 0.30600 1.82000 2.55500 -1.11750 0.07400 2.55500 3.83400 -0.78700 0.30500 2010M12 1.19500 1.46500 -0.15250 0.32000 1.46500 2.54800 -0.17750 0.73500 2.54800 3.56400 -0.00350 1.27900 2011M01 3.20000 3.21800 1.00250 0.27000 3.21800 3.80700 0.87650 1.08300 3.80700 4.71900 0.62950 1.01600 2011M02 1.65000 2.06200 -0.77500 0.01800 2.06200 3.34000 -0.57800 0.58900 3.34000 4.74000 -0.23350 0.91200 2011M03 1.04200 1.21500 -0.30400 0.41200 1.21500 2.30500 -0.42350 1.27800 2.30500 4.28000 -0.51750 1.40000 2011M04 0.60700 0.88200 -0.21750 0.17300 0.88200 2.18000 -0.16650 1.09000 2.18000 3.27200 -0.06250 1.97500 2011M05 2.18900 2.37600 0.79100 0.27500 2.37600 2.80900 0.74700 1.29800 2.80900 4.41900 0.31450 1.09200 2011M06 2.85200 2.98200 0.33150 0.18700 2.98200 3.13100 0.30300 0.43300 3.13100 3.91400 0.16100 1.61000 2011M07 2.42500 2.63000 -0.21350 0.13000 2.63000 3.10000 -0.17600 0.14900 3.10000 3.57200 -0.01550 0.78300 2011M08 0.95100 0.99200 -0.73700 0.20500 0.99200 1.57600 -0.81900 0.47000 1.57600 2.64300 -0.76200 0.47200 2011M09 2.74500 2.03900 0.89700 0.04100 2.03900 1.53100 0.52350 0.58400 1.53100 2.62200 -0.02250 1.06700 2011M10 1.11500 1.44500 -0.81500 -0.70600 1.44500 1.60700 -0.29700 -0.50800 1.60700 2.48300 0.03800 1.09100 2011M11 2.16500 1.51000 0.52500 0.33000 1.51000 1.61300 0.03250 0.16200 1.61300 2.43100 0.00300 0.87600 2011M12 1.37500 1.53600 -0.39500 -0.65500 1.53600 1.67800 0.01300 0.10300 1.67800 2.36200 0.03250 0.81800 2012M01 1.62500 1.78600 0.12500 0.16100 1.78600 2.23200 0.12500 0.14200 2.23200 2.78800 0.27700 0.68400 2012M02 1.88900 2.31000 0.13200 0.16100 2.31000 2.56300 0.26200 0.44600 2.56300 3.07000 0.16550 0.55600 2012M03 2.30000 2.31300 0.20550 0.42100 2.31300 2.99900 0.00150 0.25300 2.99900 3.19700 0.21800 0.50700 2012M04 2.15000 2.16200 -0.07500 0.01300 2.16200 2.55600 -0.07550 0.68600 2.55600 2.90700 -0.22150 0.19800 2012M05 2.20000 2.32100 0.02500 0.01200 2.32100 2.57900 0.07950 0.39400 2.57900 2.98700 0.01150 0.35100 2012M06 2.19500 2.27700 -0.00250 0.12100 2.27700 2.45700 -0.02200 0.25800 2.45700 3.08500 -0.06100 0.40800 2012M07 1.84000 2.09100 -0.17750 0.08200 2.09100 2.29700 -0.09300 0.18000 2.29700 2.67400 -0.08000 0.62800 2012M08 1.38200 1.66900 -0.22900 0.25100 1.66900 2.11400 -0.21100 0.20600 2.11400 2.65800 -0.09150 0.37700 2012M09 0.62500 0.97300 -0.37850 0.28700 0.97300 1.47500 -0.34800 0.44500 1.47500 2.29900 -0.31950 0.54400 2012M10 0.30000 0.48800 -0.16250 0.34800 0.48800 0.83000 -0.24250 0.50200 0.83000 2.69800 -0.32250 0.82400 2012M11 0.61100 0.64600 0.15550 0.18800 0.64600 0.75400 0.07900 0.34200 0.75400 2.45200 -0.03800 1.86800 2012M12 0.30000 0.57500 -0.15550 0.03500 0.57500 0.92900 -0.03550 0.10800 0.92900 2.86400 0.08750 1.69800 144 2013M01 0.15100 0.38700 -0.07450 0.27500 0.38700 1.24500 -0.09400 0.35400 1.24500 2.64000 0.15800 1.93500 2013M02 0.35000 0.35000 0.09950 0.23600 0.35000 1.03400 -0.01850 0.85800 1.03400 2.33800 -0.10550 1.39500 2013M03 0.25000 0.32100 -0.05000 0.00000 0.32100 0.82200 -0.01450 0.68400 0.82200 2.18600 -0.10600 1.30400 2013M04 0.20000 0.30000 -0.02500 0.07100 0.30000 0.45400 -0.01050 0.50100 0.45400 2.02000 -0.18400 1.36400 2013M05 2.00000 2.02500 0.90000 0.10000 2.02500 2.01600 0.86250 0.15400 2.01600 2.26600 0.78100 1.56600 2013M06 1.75000 1.80200 -0.12500 0.02500 1.80200 2.03700 -0.11150 -0.00900 2.03700 2.55300 0.01050 0.25000 2013M07 1.04900 0.84700 -0.35050 0.05200 0.84700 1.42200 -0.47750 0.23500 1.42200 2.26700 -0.30750 0.51600 2013M08 1.25000 1.35000 0.10050 -0.20200 1.35000 1.57300 0.25150 0.57500 1.57300 2.64700 0.07550 0.84500 2013M09 0.47600 0.89600 -0.38700 0.10000 0.89600 1.07700 -0.22700 0.22300 1.07700 2.04500 -0.24800 1.07400 2013M10 0.09500 0.18400 -0.19050 0.42000 0.18400 0.40900 -0.35600 0.18100 0.40900 1.95300 -0.33400 0.96800 2013M11 0.17500 0.29900 0.04000 0.08900 0.29900 0.75400 0.05750 0.22500 0.75400 1.92500 0.17250 1.54400 2013M12 0.32500 0.42500 0.07500 0.12400 0.42500 0.92200 0.06300 0.45500 0.92200 2.15100 0.08400 1.17100 2014M01 1.20000 1.94700 0.43750 0.10000 1.94700 2.04400 0.76100 0.49700 2.04400 2.70500 0.56100 1.22900 2014M02 1.00000 1.48100 -0.10000 0.74700 1.48100 1.92300 -0.23300 0.09700 1.92300 2.24700 -0.06050 0.66100 2014M03 1.50000 1.32100 0.25000 0.48100 1.32100 1.39900 -0.08000 0.44200 1.39900 2.40400 -0.26200 0.32400 2014M04 1.30000 1.96000 -0.10000 -0.17900 1.96000 2.25500 0.31950 0.07800 2.25500 2.72700 0.42800 1.00500 2014M05 1.07000 1.78900 -0.11500 0.66000 1.78900 2.00000 -0.08550 0.29500 2.00000 2.34600 -0.12750 0.47200 2014M06 1.15000 1.29000 0.04000 0.71900 1.29000 1.75300 -0.24950 0.21100 1.75300 2.37800 -0.12350 0.34600 2014M07 1.37500 1.66300 0.11250 0.14000 1.66300 1.92000 0.18650 0.46300 1.92000 2.49700 0.08350 0.62500 2014M08 1.25000 1.61300 -0.06250 0.28800 1.61300 1.90000 -0.02500 0.25700 1.90000 2.45500 -0.01000 0.57700 2014M09 1.50000 1.73700 0.12500 0.36300 1.73700 1.75400 0.06200 0.28700 1.75400 2.14500 -0.07300 0.55500 2014M10 1.40000 1.46400 -0.05000 0.23700 1.46400 1.74200 -0.13650 0.01700 1.74200 2.32100 -0.00600 0.39100 2014M11 1.50000 1.73800 0.05000 0.06400 1.73800 2.03300 0.13700 0.27800 2.03300 2.50800 0.14550 0.57900 where: m3 = 3-month bond yield, m6 = 6-month bond yield, y1 = 1-year bond yield, y2 = 2-year bond yield m3m3 = average change in 3-month bond yield, m6m6 = average change in 6-month bond yield, y1y1 = average change in 1-year bond yield m3m6 = 3-month & 6-month bond spread, m6y1= 6-month & 1-year bond spread, y1y2 = 1-year & 2-year bond spread 145 APPENDIX C: DATA FOR N-PERIOD CASE y1 y3 y3y3 2005M11 8.17500 2005M12 8.23600 2006M01 7.30400 8.60100 -2.84400 2006M02 7.31500 8.23200 2006M03 6.64700 2006M04 y1y3 y1 y5 y5y5 9.73600 8.17500 9.54900 8.23600 1.31300 7.30400 8.67400 -5.15500 -1.10700 1.29700 7.31500 11.41800 7.13300 -3.29700 0.91700 6.64700 5.93500 6.47800 -1.96500 0.48600 2006M05 6.97000 8.52000 6.12600 2006M06 7.79400 9.20500 2006M07 7.37100 2006M08 7.32200 2006M09 6.65200 2006M10 y1y5 y1 y10 y10y10 y1y10 10.13000 8.17500 11.91500 9.70500 8.23600 10.06100 1.46900 7.30400 9.83800 -2.23000 1.82500 13.72000 1.37000 7.31500 8.68200 -11.56000 2.53400 7.28900 -20.64500 4.10300 6.64700 7.70400 -9.78000 1.36700 5.93500 6.74500 -2.72000 0.64200 5.93500 7.35000 -3.54000 1.05700 0.54300 6.97000 8.77200 10.13500 0.81000 6.97000 10.39600 30.46000 1.41500 2.05500 1.55000 7.79400 9.76600 4.97000 1.80200 7.79400 10.69200 2.96000 3.42600 8.68100 -1.57200 10.72400 6.12900 1.41100 7.37100 9.24800 -2.59000 1.97200 7.37100 10.57000 -1.22000 2.89800 1.31000 7.32200 8.13700 -5.55500 1.87700 7.32200 9.17100 -13.99000 3.19900 7.49100 -9.69900 3.40200 6.65200 7.68700 -2.25000 0.81500 6.65200 8.54900 -6.22000 1.84900 6.79800 7.07300 -1.25400 0.83900 6.79800 7.25900 -2.14000 1.03500 6.79800 7.88300 -6.66000 1.89700 2006M11 5.36600 5.91200 -3.48300 0.27500 5.36600 6.09400 -5.82500 0.46100 5.36600 6.64100 -12.42000 1.08500 2006M12 5.23000 5.70700 -0.61500 0.54600 5.23000 5.89000 -1.02000 0.72800 5.23000 6.49800 -1.43000 1.27500 2007M01 4.57200 5.67100 -0.10800 0.47700 4.57200 6.12300 1.16500 0.66000 4.57200 6.99100 4.93000 1.26800 2007M02 4.38200 5.35500 -0.94800 1.09900 4.38200 5.74300 -1.90000 1.55100 4.38200 7.19700 2.06000 2.41900 2007M03 4.76300 5.54100 0.55800 0.97300 4.76300 6.03600 1.46500 1.36100 4.76300 7.39600 1.99000 2.81500 2007M04 5.02900 5.78400 0.72900 0.77800 5.02900 6.14900 0.56500 1.27300 5.02900 7.49500 0.99000 2.63300 2007M05 5.13100 5.91300 0.38700 0.75500 5.13100 6.15200 0.01500 1.12000 5.13100 7.29800 -1.97000 2.46600 2007M06 5.29600 6.55500 1.92600 0.78200 5.29600 6.92000 3.84000 1.02100 5.29600 7.19500 -1.03000 2.16700 2007M07 5.71600 6.90700 1.05600 1.25900 5.71600 7.17500 1.27500 1.62400 5.71600 7.45600 2.61000 1.89900 2007M08 5.74200 7.03100 0.37200 1.19100 5.74200 7.30500 0.65000 1.45900 5.74200 8.12300 6.67000 1.74000 2007M09 5.71700 6.42700 -1.81200 1.28900 5.71700 6.66100 -3.22000 1.56300 5.71700 7.37200 -7.51000 2.38100 2007M10 5.72000 6.39000 -0.11100 0.71000 5.72000 6.55200 -0.54500 0.94400 5.72000 7.28100 -0.91000 1.65500 2007M11 5.65200 6.31400 -0.22800 0.67000 5.65200 6.48000 -0.36000 0.83200 5.65200 7.24200 -0.39000 1.56100 2007M12 5.59500 5.69800 -1.84800 0.66200 5.59500 5.81400 -3.33000 0.82800 5.59500 6.72300 -5.19000 1.59000 146 2008M01 5.21000 5.48700 -0.63300 0.10300 5.21000 5.60300 -1.05500 0.21900 5.21000 6.13600 -5.87000 1.12800 2008M02 5.90600 6.37100 2.65200 0.27700 5.90600 6.55400 4.75500 0.39300 5.90600 7.25400 11.18000 0.92600 2008M03 5.52100 6.34700 -0.07200 0.46500 5.52100 6.56000 0.03000 0.64800 5.52100 7.54600 2.92000 1.34800 2008M04 6.59500 7.66300 3.94800 0.82600 6.59500 8.15300 7.96500 1.03900 6.59500 8.62100 10.75000 2.02500 2008M05 6.82400 8.27000 1.82100 1.06800 6.82400 8.63100 2.39000 1.55800 6.82400 9.30200 6.81000 2.02600 2008M06 6.70900 8.22500 -0.13500 1.44600 6.70900 8.95500 1.62000 1.80700 6.70900 9.69000 3.88000 2.47800 2008M07 7.26900 7.83100 -1.18200 1.51600 7.26900 8.52600 -2.14500 2.24600 7.26900 10.23600 5.46000 2.98100 2008M08 6.65700 7.03800 -2.37900 0.56200 6.65700 7.35400 -5.86000 1.25700 6.65700 8.53500 -17.01000 2.96700 2008M09 6.50300 7.00900 -0.08700 0.38100 6.50300 7.67300 1.59500 0.69700 6.50300 8.50200 -0.33000 1.87800 2008M10 7.22700 7.77700 2.30400 0.50600 7.22700 7.86400 0.95500 1.17000 7.22700 10.20200 17.00000 1.99900 2008M11 6.83900 7.98000 0.60900 0.55000 6.83900 8.54000 3.38000 0.63700 6.83900 9.13800 -10.64000 2.97500 2008M12 6.08300 6.25200 -5.18400 1.14100 6.08300 6.70400 -9.18000 1.70100 6.08300 7.61400 -15.24000 2.29900 2009M01 4.63700 5.92700 -0.97500 0.16900 4.63700 6.29500 -2.04500 0.62100 4.63700 7.95700 3.43000 1.53100 2009M02 4.94300 5.77200 -0.46500 1.29000 4.94300 6.54100 1.23000 1.65800 4.94300 8.65200 6.95000 3.32000 2009M03 4.78700 5.88100 0.32700 0.82900 4.78700 6.54500 0.02000 1.59800 4.78700 8.50900 -1.43000 3.70900 2009M04 4.75700 5.39500 -1.45800 1.09400 4.75700 6.42600 -0.59500 1.75800 4.75700 8.95300 4.44000 3.72200 2009M05 4.66500 5.15100 -0.73200 0.63800 4.66500 6.26100 -0.82500 1.66900 4.66500 8.27200 -6.81000 4.19600 2009M06 4.79200 5.50400 1.05900 0.48600 4.79200 6.52600 1.32500 1.59600 4.79200 8.77400 5.02000 3.60700 2009M07 4.25200 5.22200 -0.84600 0.71200 4.25200 6.49000 -0.18000 1.73400 4.25200 8.53800 -2.36000 3.98200 2009M08 4.43400 5.42100 0.59700 0.97000 4.43400 6.54600 0.28000 2.23800 4.43400 8.51400 -0.24000 4.28600 2009M09 4.39900 5.26100 -0.48000 0.98700 4.39900 6.43200 -0.57000 2.11200 4.39900 8.76200 2.48000 4.08000 2009M10 4.45400 5.43600 0.52500 0.86200 4.45400 6.56700 0.67500 2.03300 4.45400 8.62700 -1.35000 4.36300 2009M11 4.53000 5.38000 -0.16800 0.98200 4.53000 6.54200 -0.12500 2.11300 4.53000 8.56700 -0.60000 4.17300 2009M12 4.79100 5.67300 0.87900 0.85000 4.79100 6.55300 0.05500 2.01200 4.79100 8.65400 0.87000 4.03700 2010M01 4.77300 5.41900 -0.76200 0.88200 4.77300 6.62400 0.35500 1.76200 4.77300 8.51500 -1.39000 3.86300 2010M02 4.39300 5.42300 0.01200 0.64600 4.39300 6.48300 -0.70500 1.85100 4.39300 8.44700 -0.68000 3.74200 2010M03 4.41400 5.18100 -0.72600 1.03000 4.41400 6.50900 0.13000 2.09000 4.41400 8.73500 2.88000 4.05400 2010M04 4.51400 5.45000 0.80700 0.76700 4.51400 6.67000 0.80500 2.09500 4.51400 8.62800 -1.07000 4.32100 2010M05 4.62500 5.36200 -0.26400 0.93600 4.62500 6.61000 -0.30000 2.15600 4.62500 8.56800 -0.60000 4.11400 2010M06 4.60700 5.35600 -0.01800 0.73700 4.60700 6.52200 -0.44000 1.98500 4.60700 8.28800 -2.80000 3.94300 147 2010M07 4.60900 5.37300 0.05100 0.74900 4.60900 6.32800 -0.97000 1.91500 4.60900 8.16800 -1.20000 3.68100 2010M08 4.54000 5.12300 -0.75000 0.76400 4.54000 5.58500 -3.71500 1.71900 4.54000 7.04200 -11.26000 3.55900 2010M09 4.56800 5.09800 -0.07500 0.58300 4.56800 5.39700 -0.94000 1.04500 4.56800 6.34600 -6.96000 2.50200 2010M10 4.12900 4.53400 -1.69200 0.53000 4.12900 4.78200 -3.07500 0.82900 4.12900 5.91300 -4.33000 1.77800 2010M11 2.55500 4.33700 -0.59100 0.40500 2.55500 4.83600 0.27000 0.65300 2.55500 6.17000 2.57000 1.78400 2010M12 2.54800 4.23700 -0.30000 1.78200 2.54800 4.92600 0.45000 2.28100 2.54800 6.32600 1.56000 3.61500 2011M01 3.80700 4.95100 2.14200 1.68900 3.80700 5.48600 2.80000 2.37800 3.80700 6.56300 2.37000 3.77800 2011M02 3.34000 5.43300 1.44600 1.14400 3.34000 6.48600 5.00000 1.67900 3.34000 7.55100 9.88000 2.75600 2011M03 2.30500 5.19700 -0.70800 2.09300 2.30500 5.88700 -2.99500 3.14600 2.30500 7.29300 -2.58000 4.21100 2011M04 2.18000 4.64300 -1.66200 2.89200 2.18000 5.03000 -4.28500 3.58200 2.18000 6.51800 -7.75000 4.98800 2011M05 2.80900 5.08200 1.31700 2.46300 2.80900 5.43600 2.03000 2.85000 2.80900 6.62400 1.06000 4.33800 2011M06 3.13100 4.48600 -1.78800 2.27300 3.13100 5.12900 -1.53500 2.62700 3.13100 6.77000 1.46000 3.81500 2011M07 3.10000 3.96300 -1.56900 1.35500 3.10000 4.94700 -0.91000 1.99800 3.10000 6.55500 -2.15000 3.63900 2011M08 1.57600 3.22400 -2.21700 0.86300 1.57600 4.59800 -1.74500 1.84700 1.57600 6.24600 -3.09000 3.45500 2011M09 1.53100 3.30800 0.25200 1.64800 1.53100 5.25000 3.26000 3.02200 1.53100 6.34600 1.00000 4.67000 2011M10 1.60700 3.75700 1.34700 1.77700 1.60700 4.76400 -2.43000 3.71900 1.60700 5.97300 -3.73000 4.81500 2011M11 1.61300 3.51700 -0.72000 2.15000 1.61300 4.98100 1.08500 3.15700 1.61300 6.04400 0.71000 4.36600 2011M12 1.67800 3.43200 -0.25500 1.90400 1.67800 4.36700 -3.07000 3.36800 1.67800 5.35500 -6.89000 4.43100 2012M01 2.23200 3.75800 0.97800 1.75400 2.23200 4.40300 0.18000 2.68900 2.23200 5.39300 0.38000 3.67700 2012M02 2.56300 3.50900 -0.74700 1.52600 2.56300 4.40600 0.01500 2.17100 2.56300 5.17900 -2.14000 3.16100 2012M03 2.99900 3.61300 0.31200 0.94600 2.99900 4.60600 1.00000 1.84300 2.99900 5.59900 4.20000 2.61600 2012M04 2.55600 3.74900 0.40800 0.61400 2.55600 4.88800 1.41000 1.60700 2.55600 5.52300 -0.76000 2.60000 2012M05 2.57900 3.58800 -0.48300 1.19300 2.57900 4.97500 0.43500 2.33200 2.57900 5.83800 3.15000 2.96700 2012M06 2.45700 3.65400 0.19800 1.00900 2.45700 4.88300 -0.46000 2.39600 2.45700 5.52900 -3.09000 3.25900 2012M07 2.29700 3.60900 -0.13500 1.19700 2.29700 4.61700 -1.33000 2.42600 2.29700 5.12000 -4.09000 3.07200 2012M08 2.11400 3.82800 0.65700 1.31200 2.11400 4.55800 -0.29500 2.32000 2.11400 5.03800 -0.82000 2.82300 2012M09 1.47500 3.28100 -1.64100 1.71400 1.47500 4.52400 -0.17000 2.44400 1.47500 4.84100 -1.97000 2.92400 2012M10 0.83000 3.68300 1.20600 1.80600 0.83000 4.32300 -1.00500 3.04900 0.83000 4.87700 0.36000 3.36600 2012M11 0.75400 3.41300 -0.81000 2.85300 0.75400 3.84400 -2.39500 3.49300 0.75400 4.60400 -2.73000 4.04700 2012M12 0.92900 3.28500 -0.38400 2.65900 0.92900 3.79800 -0.23000 3.09000 0.92900 4.29900 -3.05000 3.85000 148 2013M01 1.24500 3.20600 -0.23700 2.35600 1.24500 3.45900 -1.69500 2.86900 1.24500 4.07200 -2.27000 3.37000 2013M02 1.03400 2.79100 -1.24500 1.96100 1.03400 3.31800 -0.70500 2.21400 1.03400 3.60700 -4.65000 2.82700 2013M03 0.82200 2.53700 -0.76200 1.75700 0.82200 2.97400 -1.72000 2.28400 0.82200 3.02400 -5.83000 2.57300 2013M04 0.45400 1.97800 -1.67700 1.71500 0.45400 2.44800 -2.63000 2.15200 0.45400 2.90500 -1.19000 2.20200 2013M05 2.01600 2.28900 0.93300 1.52400 2.01600 2.16300 -1.42500 1.99400 2.01600 3.36900 4.64000 2.45100 2013M06 2.03700 2.88300 1.78200 0.27300 2.03700 2.87500 3.56000 0.14700 2.03700 3.85600 4.87000 1.35300 2013M07 1.42200 2.13500 -2.24400 0.84600 1.42200 2.50400 -1.85500 0.83800 1.42200 3.37500 -4.81000 1.81900 2013M08 1.57300 2.43800 0.90900 0.71300 1.57300 2.84100 1.68500 1.08200 1.57300 3.49800 1.23000 1.95300 2013M09 1.07700 2.35600 -0.24600 0.86500 1.07700 3.11500 1.37000 1.26800 1.07700 3.60800 1.10000 1.92500 2013M10 0.40900 2.02100 -1.00500 1.27900 0.40900 2.89800 -1.08500 2.03800 0.40900 3.49900 -1.09000 2.53100 2013M11 0.75400 2.11100 0.27000 1.61200 0.75400 2.78600 -0.56000 2.48900 0.75400 3.54400 0.45000 3.09000 2013M12 0.92200 2.26400 0.45900 1.35700 0.92200 3.00000 1.07000 2.03200 0.92200 3.73000 1.86000 2.79000 2014M01 2.04400 2.93500 2.01300 1.34200 2.04400 3.41400 2.07000 2.07800 2.04400 4.29600 5.66000 2.80800 2014M02 1.92300 2.66300 -0.81600 0.89100 1.92300 3.59300 0.89500 1.37000 1.92300 4.18200 -1.14000 2.25200 2014M03 1.39900 2.93200 0.80700 0.74000 1.39900 3.46300 -0.65000 1.67000 1.39900 4.45400 2.72000 2.25900 2014M04 2.25500 2.95400 0.06600 1.53300 2.25500 3.90100 2.19000 2.06400 2.25500 4.36000 -0.94000 3.05500 2014M05 2.00000 2.67100 -0.84900 0.69900 2.00000 3.33700 -2.82000 1.64600 2.00000 4.11800 -2.42000 2.10500 2014M06 1.75300 2.68500 0.04200 0.67100 1.75300 3.60600 1.34500 1.33700 1.75300 4.04300 -0.75000 2.11800 2014M07 1.92000 2.75100 0.19800 0.93200 1.92000 3.59600 -0.05000 1.85300 1.92000 4.19500 1.52000 2.29000 2014M08 1.90000 2.66000 -0.27300 0.83100 1.90000 3.87300 1.38500 1.67600 1.90000 4.30600 1.11000 2.27500 2014M09 1.75400 2.67200 0.03600 0.76000 1.75400 4.15300 1.40000 1.97300 1.75400 4.36100 0.55000 2.40600 2014M10 1.74200 2.44200 -0.69000 0.91800 1.74200 3.59900 -2.77000 2.39900 1.74200 4.15700 -2.04000 2.60700 2014M11 2.03300 2.82900 1.16100 0.70000 2.03300 3.33100 -1.34000 1.85700 2.03300 3.85100 -3.06000 2.41500 where: y1 = 1-year bond yield, y3 = 3-year bond yield, y5 = 5-year bond yield, y10 = 10-year bond yield y3y3 = maturity times change in 3-year bond yield, y5y5 = maturity times change in 5-year bond yield, y10y10 = maturity times change in 10year bond yield y1y3 = 1-year & 3-year bond spread, y1y5 = 1-year & 5-year bond spread, y1y10 = 1-year & 10-year bond spread 149 APPENDIX D: TWO-PERIOD CASE TERM SPREAD REGRESSION MODEL RESULTS USING HETEROSKEDASTICITY-AUTOCORRELATION CONSISTENT (HAC) NEWEY-WEST TEST 3-month & 6-month Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 6-month & 1-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: M3M3 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Dependent Variable: M6M6 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C M3M6SPREAD -0.0872 0.2056 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0572 0.0482 0.3901 15.9808 -50.0992 6.3700 0.0131 0.0037 Std. Error 0.0272 0.0693 t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient -3.2043 2.9664 0.0018 0.0037 C M6Y1SPREAD -0.2213 0.4621 -0.0293 0.3999 0.9738 1.0238 0.9941 2.2792 8.7997 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.2538 0.2467 0.3221 10.8947 -29.6030 35.7208 0.0000 0.0001 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Std. Error 0.0512 0.1113 t-Statistic Prob. -4.3199 4.1521 0.0000 0.0001 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.0306 0.3711 0.5907 0.6407 0.6110 1.9555 17.2399 150 1-year & 2-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y1Y1 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C Y1Y2SPREAD -0.1327 0.1402 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0673 0.0584 0.2594 7.0629 -6.4148 7.5769 0.0070 0.0048 Std. Error 0.0441 0.0487 t-Statistic Prob. -3.0078 2.8790 0.0033 0.0048 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.0290 0.2673 0.1573 0.2072 0.1775 1.8412 8.2889 151 APPENDIX E: N-PERIOD CASE TERM SPREAD REGRESSION MODEL RESULTS USING HETEROSKEDASTICITY-AUTOCORRELATION CONSISTENT (HAC) NEWEY-WEST TEST 1-year & 3-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 1-year & 5-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y3Y3 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Dependent Variable: Y5Y5 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C Y1Y3 0.6128 -0.7134 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0572 0.0482 1.7964 338.8351 -213.4951 6.3698 0.0131 0.0391 Std. Error 0.3741 0.3414 t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient 1.6380 -2.0896 0.1044 0.0391 C Y1Y5 2.0837 -1.3357 -0.1884 1.8413 4.0279 4.0779 4.0482 2.0380 4.3666 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0883 0.0796 3.4193 1227.6010 -282.3658 10.1682 0.0019 0.0001 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Std. Error 0.7031 0.3277 t-Statistic Prob. 2.9636 -4.0757 0.0038 0.0001 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.2979 3.5641 5.3152 5.3652 5.3355 2.1337 16.6113 152 1-year & 10-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y10Y10 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C Y1Y5 1.8975 -0.8764 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0201 0.0107 6.0973 3903.6240 -344.2569 2.1516 0.1454 0.0471 Std. Error 1.4491 0.4362 t-Statistic Prob. 1.3094 -2.0091 0.1933 0.0471 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.5804 6.1304 6.4721 6.5221 6.4923 1.7391 4.0366 153 APPENDIX F: COMPUTED EXCESS HOLDING RETURNS OF BOND YIELDS UNDER THE TWO-PERIOD CASE m3 m6 m3m6hr m3m6ehr m6 y1 m6y1hr m6y1ehr y1 y2 y1y2hr y1y2ehr 2006M01 5.73200 6.32900 6.32031 0.58831 6.32900 7.3040 7.30116 0.97216 7.3040 8.3490 8.41034 1.10634 2006M02 5.75600 6.35900 5.68344 -0.07256 6.35900 7.3150 7.48764 1.12864 7.3150 8.0670 8.28192 0.96692 2006M03 5.38900 8.69200 9.61659 4.22759 8.69200 6.6470 6.83101 -1.86099 6.6470 7.0790 7.24541 0.59841 2006M04 5.05800 5.49900 5.30383 0.24583 5.49900 5.9350 5.66752 0.16852 5.9350 6.3140 5.45952 -0.47548 2006M05 5.73600 6.17300 5.88691 0.15091 6.17300 6.9700 6.75705 0.58405 6.9700 10.2420 10.60985 3.63985 2006M06 8.90600 7.16100 7.24150 -1.66450 7.16100 7.7940 7.90332 0.74232 7.7940 8.5510 8.59277 0.79877 2006M07 6.33200 6.88300 7.02778 0.69578 6.88300 7.3710 7.38366 0.50066 7.3710 8.3590 8.48495 1.11395 2006M08 5.91700 6.38300 6.41225 0.49525 6.38300 7.3220 7.49515 1.11215 7.3220 7.7800 7.84330 0.52130 2006M09 5.72400 6.28200 6.29474 0.57074 6.28200 6.6520 6.61427 0.33227 6.6520 7.4890 7.59472 0.94272 2006M10 5.72500 6.23800 6.53307 0.80807 6.23800 6.7980 7.16808 0.93008 6.7980 7.0030 7.26622 0.46822 2006M11 5.21200 5.21900 5.31572 0.10372 5.21900 5.3660 5.40115 0.18215 5.3660 5.7930 5.84369 0.47769 2006M12 4.88500 4.88500 5.06279 0.17779 4.88500 5.2300 5.40005 0.51505 5.2300 5.5600 5.59089 0.36089 2007M01 3.64300 4.27100 4.37090 0.72790 4.27100 4.5720 4.62110 0.35010 4.5720 5.4180 5.47130 0.89930 2007M02 3.53800 3.92600 3.81567 0.27767 3.92600 4.3820 4.28354 0.35754 4.3820 5.1730 5.14646 0.76446 2007M03 4.02300 4.30700 4.44252 0.41952 4.30700 4.7630 4.69426 0.38726 4.7630 5.2950 5.22561 0.46261 2007M04 3.00000 3.83900 3.76342 0.76342 3.83900 5.0290 5.00264 1.16364 5.0290 5.6140 5.55962 0.53062 2007M05 4.56700 4.10000 3.90194 -0.66506 4.10000 5.1310 5.08836 0.98836 5.1310 5.8640 5.80004 0.66904 2007M06 4.66000 4.78400 4.73767 0.07767 4.78400 5.2960 5.18746 0.40346 5.2960 6.1580 6.02248 0.72648 2007M07 4.25000 4.94400 4.78213 0.53213 4.94400 5.7160 5.70928 0.76528 5.7160 6.7810 6.82451 1.10851 2007M08 4.52500 5.50300 5.70280 1.17780 5.50300 5.7420 5.74846 0.24546 5.7420 6.5810 6.64974 0.90774 2007M09 4.06200 4.81300 4.83617 0.77417 4.81300 5.7170 5.71622 0.90322 5.7170 6.2650 6.26979 0.55279 2007M10 4.00000 4.73300 4.70086 0.70086 4.73300 5.7200 5.73757 1.00457 5.7200 6.2430 6.24800 0.52800 2007M11 4.02200 4.84400 4.84661 0.82461 4.84400 5.6520 5.66673 0.82273 5.6520 6.2200 6.33029 0.67829 2007M12 4.22000 4.83500 4.83963 0.61963 4.83500 5.5950 5.69450 0.85950 5.5950 5.7130 5.77456 0.17956 2008M01 4.00000 4.81900 4.64381 0.64381 4.81900 5.2100 5.03013 0.21113 5.2100 5.4300 5.28447 0.07447 2008M02 4.60000 5.42400 5.50942 0.90942 5.42400 5.9060 6.00550 0.58150 5.9060 6.0990 6.07659 0.17059 154 2008M03 4.37500 5.12900 4.82698 0.45198 5.12900 5.5210 5.24344 0.11444 5.5210 6.2020 5.91355 0.39255 2008M04 5.08700 6.17200 6.26756 1.18056 6.17200 6.5950 6.53582 0.36382 6.5950 7.5280 7.49515 0.90015 2008M05 6.06100 5.84200 5.92424 -0.13676 5.84200 6.8240 6.85372 1.01172 6.8240 7.6790 7.79495 0.97095 2008M06 5.11600 5.55800 5.41582 0.29982 5.55800 6.7090 6.56428 1.00628 6.7090 7.1460 7.14796 0.43896 2008M07 6.08200 6.04900 5.83704 -0.24496 6.04900 7.2690 7.42716 1.37816 7.2690 7.1370 7.13134 -0.13766 2008M08 6.18500 6.78100 6.94287 0.75787 6.78100 6.6570 6.69680 -0.08420 6.6570 7.1630 7.09752 0.44052 2008M09 6.50000 6.22200 6.00511 -0.49489 6.22200 6.5030 6.31589 0.09389 6.5030 7.4640 7.41875 0.91575 2008M10 6.75000 6.97100 7.12881 0.37881 6.97100 7.2270 7.32727 0.35627 7.2270 7.6720 7.67156 0.44456 2008M11 6.37500 6.42600 6.54878 0.17378 6.42600 6.8390 7.03438 0.60838 6.8390 7.6740 7.90937 1.07037 2008M12 5.62600 6.00200 6.43374 0.80774 6.00200 6.0830 6.45670 0.45470 6.0830 6.5920 6.81628 0.73328 2009M01 4.28200 4.51100 4.43398 0.15198 4.51100 4.6370 4.55792 0.04692 4.6370 5.5610 5.59494 0.95794 2009M02 4.55600 4.77700 4.86821 0.31221 4.77700 4.9430 4.98332 0.20632 4.9430 5.4050 5.44263 0.49963 2009M03 4.29300 4.46200 4.42609 0.13309 4.46200 4.7870 4.79475 0.33275 4.7870 5.2320 5.28595 0.49895 2009M04 4.35300 4.58600 4.59585 0.24285 4.58600 4.7570 4.78078 0.19478 4.7570 4.9840 4.99335 0.23635 2009M05 4.35500 4.55200 4.54766 0.19266 4.55200 4.6650 4.63218 0.08018 4.6650 4.9410 4.86377 0.19877 2009M06 4.31900 4.56700 4.78099 0.46199 4.56700 4.7920 4.93156 0.36456 4.7920 5.2960 5.42087 0.62887 2009M07 3.68800 3.82800 3.77906 0.09106 3.82800 4.2520 4.20496 0.37696 4.2520 4.7220 4.71743 0.46543 2009M08 3.75100 3.99700 3.94690 0.19590 3.99700 4.4340 4.44305 0.44605 4.4340 4.7430 4.73169 0.29769 2009M09 4.05200 4.17000 4.16392 0.11192 4.17000 4.3990 4.38479 0.21479 4.3990 4.7950 4.82480 0.42580 2009M10 4.00500 4.19100 4.20519 0.20019 4.19100 4.4540 4.43436 0.24336 4.4540 4.6580 4.65495 0.20095 2009M11 3.64700 4.14200 4.09219 0.44519 4.14200 4.5300 4.46255 0.32055 4.5300 4.6720 4.52408 -0.00592 2009M12 4.06700 4.31400 4.33456 0.26756 4.31400 4.7910 4.79565 0.48165 4.7910 5.3520 5.42444 0.63344 2010M01 3.80500 4.24300 4.27311 0.46811 4.24300 4.7730 4.87121 0.62821 4.7730 5.0190 5.09448 0.32148 2010M02 4.01500 4.13900 4.17114 0.15614 4.13900 4.3930 4.38757 0.24857 4.3930 4.6720 4.63371 0.24071 2010M03 3.90000 4.02800 3.98978 0.08978 4.02800 4.4140 4.38816 0.36016 4.4140 4.8480 4.83712 0.42312 2010M04 4.05600 4.16000 4.11019 0.05419 4.16000 4.5140 4.48531 0.32531 4.5140 4.8980 4.83339 0.31939 2010M05 4.15000 4.33200 4.36269 0.21269 4.33200 4.6250 4.62965 0.29765 4.6250 5.1950 5.19217 0.56717 2010M06 3.95100 4.22600 4.21934 0.26834 4.22600 4.6070 4.60648 0.38048 4.6070 5.2080 5.21757 0.61057 2010M07 4.06600 4.24900 4.23249 0.16649 4.24900 4.6090 4.62683 0.37783 4.6090 5.1640 5.17683 0.56783 2010M08 4.10000 4.30600 4.30397 0.20397 4.30600 4.5400 4.53276 0.22676 4.5400 5.1050 5.12458 0.58458 155 2010M09 4.10300 4.31300 4.38771 0.28471 4.31300 4.5680 4.68145 0.36845 4.5680 5.0150 5.14139 0.57339 2010M10 3.74900 4.05500 4.70218 0.95318 4.05500 4.1290 4.53578 0.48078 4.1290 4.4340 4.56452 0.43552 2010M11 1.50000 1.82000 1.92280 0.42280 1.82000 2.5550 2.55681 0.73681 2.5550 3.8340 3.89273 1.33773 2010M12 1.19500 1.46500 0.95739 -0.23761 1.46500 2.5480 2.22263 0.75763 2.5480 3.5640 3.31275 0.76475 2011M01 3.20000 3.21800 3.55274 0.35274 3.21800 3.8070 3.92769 0.70969 3.8070 4.7190 4.71443 0.90743 2011M02 1.65000 2.06200 2.30726 0.65726 2.06200 3.3400 3.60748 1.54548 3.3400 4.7400 4.84007 1.50007 2011M03 1.04200 1.21500 1.31143 0.26943 1.21500 2.3050 2.33730 1.12230 2.3050 4.2800 4.49928 2.19428 2011M04 0.60700 0.88200 0.44939 -0.15761 0.88200 2.1800 2.01744 1.13544 2.1800 3.2720 3.02249 0.84249 2011M05 2.18900 2.37600 2.20052 0.01152 2.37600 2.8090 2.72578 0.34978 2.8090 4.4190 4.52886 1.71986 2011M06 2.85200 2.98200 3.08393 0.23193 2.98200 3.1310 3.13901 0.15701 3.1310 3.9140 3.98840 0.85740 2011M07 2.42500 2.63000 3.10431 0.67931 2.63000 3.1000 3.49386 0.86386 3.1000 3.5720 3.77409 0.67409 2011M08 0.95100 0.99200 0.68882 -0.26218 0.99200 1.5760 1.58763 0.59563 1.5760 2.6430 2.64757 1.07157 2011M09 2.74500 2.03900 2.21100 -0.53400 2.03900 1.5310 1.51136 -0.52764 1.5310 2.6220 2.65224 1.12124 2011M10 1.11500 1.44500 1.42618 0.31118 1.44500 1.6070 1.60545 0.16045 1.6070 2.4830 2.49431 0.88731 2011M11 2.16500 1.51000 1.50247 -0.66253 1.51000 1.6130 1.59620 0.08620 1.6130 2.4310 2.44601 0.83301 2011M12 1.37500 1.53600 1.46361 0.08861 1.53600 1.6780 1.53483 -0.00117 1.6780 2.3620 2.26933 0.59133 2012M01 1.62500 1.78600 1.63427 0.00927 1.78600 2.2320 2.14646 0.36046 2.2320 2.7880 2.72666 0.49466 2012M02 1.88900 2.31000 2.30913 0.42013 2.31000 2.5630 2.45032 0.14032 2.5630 3.0700 3.04237 0.47937 2012M03 2.30000 2.31300 2.35672 0.05672 2.31300 2.9990 3.11349 0.80049 2.9990 3.1970 3.26009 0.26109 2012M04 2.15000 2.16200 2.11596 -0.03404 2.16200 2.5560 2.55006 0.38806 2.5560 2.9070 2.88960 0.33360 2012M05 2.20000 2.32100 2.33374 0.13374 2.32100 2.5790 2.61053 0.28953 2.5790 2.9870 2.96568 0.38668 2012M06 2.19500 2.27700 2.33086 0.13586 2.27700 2.4570 2.49835 0.22135 2.4570 3.0850 3.17441 0.71741 2012M07 1.84000 2.09100 2.21320 0.37320 2.09100 2.2970 2.34429 0.25329 2.2970 2.6740 2.67748 0.38048 2012M08 1.38200 1.66900 1.87054 0.48854 1.66900 2.1140 2.27914 0.61014 2.1140 2.6580 2.73610 0.62210 2012M09 0.62500 0.97300 1.11344 0.48844 0.97300 1.4750 1.64169 0.66869 1.4750 2.2990 2.21220 0.73720 2012M10 0.30000 0.48800 0.44225 0.14225 0.48800 0.8300 0.84964 0.36164 0.8300 2.6980 2.75151 1.92151 2012M11 0.61100 0.64600 0.66656 0.05556 0.64600 0.7540 0.70877 0.06277 0.7540 2.4520 2.36238 1.60838 2012M12 0.30000 0.57500 0.62944 0.32944 0.57500 0.9290 0.84733 0.27233 0.9290 2.8640 2.91273 1.98373 2013M01 0.15100 0.38700 0.39771 0.24671 0.38700 1.2450 1.29953 0.91253 1.2450 2.6400 2.70570 1.46070 2013M02 0.35000 0.35000 0.35840 0.00840 0.35000 1.0340 1.08879 0.73879 1.0340 2.3380 2.37107 1.33707 156 2013M03 0.25000 0.32100 0.32708 0.07708 0.32100 0.8220 0.91710 0.59610 0.8220 2.1860 2.22211 1.40011 2013M04 0.20000 0.30000 -0.19950 -0.39950 0.30000 0.4540 0.05032 -0.24968 0.4540 2.0200 1.96649 1.51249 2013M05 2.00000 2.02500 2.08957 0.08957 2.02500 2.0160 2.01057 -0.01443 2.0160 2.2660 2.20357 0.18757 2013M06 1.75000 1.80200 2.07854 0.32854 1.80200 2.0370 2.19594 0.39394 2.0370 2.5530 2.61522 0.57822 2013M07 1.04900 0.84700 0.70135 -0.34765 0.84700 1.4220 1.38298 0.53598 1.4220 2.2670 2.18434 0.76234 2013M08 1.25000 1.35000 1.48146 0.23146 1.35000 1.5730 1.70118 0.35118 1.5730 2.6470 2.77796 1.20496 2013M09 0.47600 0.89600 1.10217 0.62617 0.89600 1.0770 1.24964 0.35364 1.0770 2.0450 2.06501 0.98801 2013M10 0.09500 0.18400 0.15070 0.05570 0.18400 0.4090 0.31984 0.13584 0.4090 1.9530 1.95909 1.55009 2013M11 0.17500 0.29900 0.26251 0.08751 0.29900 0.7540 0.71058 0.41158 0.7540 1.9250 1.87584 1.12184 2013M12 0.32500 0.42500 -0.01572 -0.34072 0.42500 0.9220 0.63203 0.20703 0.9220 2.1510 2.03049 1.10849 2014M01 1.20000 1.94700 2.08194 0.88194 1.94700 2.0440 2.07527 0.12827 2.0440 2.7050 2.80463 0.76063 2014M02 1.00000 1.48100 1.52733 0.52733 1.48100 1.9230 2.05842 0.57742 1.9230 2.2470 2.21285 0.28985 2014M03 1.50000 1.32100 1.13597 -0.36403 1.32100 1.3990 1.17778 -0.14322 1.3990 2.4040 2.33374 0.93474 2014M04 1.30000 1.96000 2.00952 0.70952 1.96000 2.2550 2.32090 0.36090 2.2550 2.7270 2.80988 0.55488 2014M05 1.07000 1.78900 1.93349 0.86349 1.78900 2.0000 2.06383 0.27483 2.0000 2.3460 2.33904 0.33904 2014M06 1.15000 1.29000 1.18199 0.03199 1.29000 1.7530 1.70984 0.41984 1.7530 2.3780 2.35211 0.59911 2014M07 1.37500 1.66300 1.67748 0.30248 1.66300 1.9200 1.92517 0.26217 1.9200 2.4970 2.50614 0.58614 2014M08 1.25000 1.61300 1.57709 0.32709 1.61300 1.9000 1.93773 0.32473 1.9000 2.4550 2.52244 0.62244 2014M09 1.50000 1.73700 1.81605 0.31605 1.73700 1.7540 1.75710 0.02010 1.7540 2.1450 2.10671 0.35271 2014M10 1.40000 1.46400 1.38466 -0.01534 1.46400 1.7420 1.66679 0.20279 1.7420 2.3210 2.28032 0.53832 2014M11 1.50000 1.73800 1.73800 2.0330 2.0330 2.5080 where: m3 = 3-month bond yield, m6 = 6-month bond yield, y1 = 1-year bond yield, y2 = 2-year bond yield m3m6hr = holding return of 6-month bonds over 3-month bonds, m6y1hr = holding return of 1-year bonds over 6-month bonds, y1y2hr = holding return of 2-year bonds over 1-year bonds m3m6ehr = excess holding return of 6-month bonds over 3-month bonds, m6y1ehr = excess holding return of 1-year bonds over 6-month bonds, y1y2ehr = excess holding return of 2-year bonds over 1-year bonds 157 APPENDIX G: COMPUTED EXCESS HOLDING RETURNS OF BOND YIELDS UNDER THE N-PERIOD CASE y1 y3 y1y3hr y1y3ehr y1 y5 y1y5hr y1y5ehr y1 y10 y1y10hr y1y10ehr 2006M01 7.3040 8.6010 8.67498 1.37098 7.3040 8.6740 8.18840 0.88440 7.3040 9.8380 10.01063 2.70663 2006M02 7.3150 8.2320 8.45235 1.13735 7.3150 11.4180 12.14869 4.83369 7.3150 8.6820 8.82805 1.51305 2006M03 6.6470 7.1330 7.26433 0.61733 6.6470 7.2890 7.38527 0.73827 6.6470 7.7040 7.75686 1.10986 2006M04 5.9350 6.4780 6.06859 0.13359 5.9350 6.7450 6.38629 0.45129 5.9350 7.3500 6.89514 0.96014 2006M05 6.9700 8.5200 8.38266 1.41266 6.9700 8.7720 8.59610 1.62610 6.9700 10.3960 10.35180 3.38180 2006M06 7.7940 9.2050 9.31006 1.51606 7.7940 9.7660 9.85767 2.06367 7.7940 10.6920 10.71022 2.91622 2006M07 7.3710 8.6810 8.27139 0.90039 7.3710 9.2480 9.44461 2.07361 7.3710 10.5700 10.77891 3.40791 2006M08 7.3220 10.7240 11.37221 4.05021 7.3220 8.1370 8.21663 0.89463 7.3220 9.1710 9.26388 1.94188 2006M09 6.6520 7.4910 7.57481 0.92281 6.6520 7.6870 7.76274 1.11074 6.6520 8.5490 8.64845 1.99645 2006M10 6.7980 7.0730 7.30578 0.50778 6.7980 7.2590 7.46517 0.66717 6.7980 7.8830 8.06847 1.27047 2006M11 5.3660 5.9120 5.95310 0.58710 5.3660 6.0940 6.13010 0.76410 5.3660 6.6410 6.66235 1.29635 2006M12 5.2300 5.7070 5.71422 0.48422 5.2300 5.8900 5.84877 0.61877 5.2300 6.4980 6.42438 1.19438 2007M01 4.5720 5.6710 5.73436 1.16236 4.5720 6.1230 6.19025 1.61825 4.5720 6.9910 6.96024 2.38824 2007M02 4.3820 5.3550 5.31771 0.93571 4.3820 5.7430 5.69115 1.30915 4.3820 7.1970 7.16728 2.78528 2007M03 4.7630 5.5410 5.49228 0.72928 4.7630 6.0360 6.01600 1.25300 4.7630 7.3960 7.38122 2.61822 2007M04 5.0290 5.7840 5.75814 0.72914 5.0290 6.1490 6.14847 1.11947 5.0290 7.4950 7.52442 2.49542 2007M05 5.1310 5.9130 5.78428 0.65328 5.1310 6.1520 6.01609 0.88509 5.1310 7.2980 7.31338 2.18238 2007M06 5.2960 6.5550 6.48443 1.18843 5.2960 6.9200 6.87487 1.57887 5.2960 7.1950 7.15602 1.86002 2007M07 5.7160 6.9070 6.88214 1.16614 5.7160 7.1750 7.15199 1.43599 5.7160 7.4560 7.35640 1.64040 2007M08 5.7420 7.0310 7.15210 1.41010 5.7420 7.3050 7.41897 1.67697 5.7420 8.1230 8.23515 2.49315 2007M09 5.7170 6.4270 6.43442 0.71742 5.7170 6.6610 6.68029 0.96329 5.7170 7.3720 7.38559 1.66859 2007M10 5.7200 6.3900 6.40524 0.68524 5.7200 6.5520 6.56474 0.84474 5.7200 7.2810 7.28682 1.56682 2007M11 5.6520 6.3140 6.43751 0.78551 5.6520 6.4800 6.59786 0.94586 5.6520 7.2420 7.31950 1.66750 2007M12 5.5950 5.6980 5.74030 0.14530 5.5950 5.8140 5.85134 0.25634 5.5950 6.7230 6.81066 1.21566 2008M01 5.2100 5.4870 5.30976 0.09976 5.2100 5.6030 5.43471 0.22471 5.2100 6.1360 5.96905 0.75905 2008M02 5.9060 6.3710 6.37581 0.46981 5.9060 6.5540 6.55294 0.64694 5.9060 7.2540 7.21040 1.30440 158 2008M03 5.5210 6.3470 6.08315 0.56215 5.5210 6.5600 6.27809 0.75709 5.5210 7.5460 7.38547 1.86447 2008M04 6.5950 7.6630 7.54130 0.94630 6.5950 8.1530 8.06841 1.47341 6.5950 8.6210 8.51931 1.92431 2008M05 6.8240 8.2700 8.27902 1.45502 6.8240 8.6310 8.57366 1.74966 6.8240 9.3020 9.24406 2.42006 2008M06 6.7090 8.2250 8.30400 1.59500 6.7090 8.9550 9.03092 2.32192 6.7090 9.6900 9.60847 2.89947 2008M07 7.2690 7.8310 7.98999 0.72099 7.2690 8.5260 8.73340 1.46440 7.2690 10.2360 10.49001 3.22101 2008M08 6.6570 7.0380 7.04381 0.38681 6.6570 7.3540 7.29755 0.64055 6.6570 8.5350 8.53993 1.88293 2008M09 6.5030 7.0090 6.85502 0.35202 6.5030 7.6730 7.63920 1.13620 6.5030 8.5020 8.24814 1.74514 2008M10 7.2270 7.7770 7.73630 0.50930 7.2270 7.8640 7.74437 0.51737 7.2270 10.2020 10.36089 3.13389 2008M11 6.8390 7.9800 8.32646 1.48746 6.8390 8.5400 8.86491 2.02591 6.8390 9.1380 9.36558 2.52658 2008M12 6.0830 6.2520 6.31716 0.23416 6.0830 6.7040 6.77638 0.69338 6.0830 7.6140 7.56278 1.47978 2009M01 4.6370 5.9270 5.95808 1.32108 4.6370 6.2950 6.25147 1.61447 4.6370 7.9570 7.85322 3.21622 2009M02 4.9430 5.7720 5.75015 0.80715 4.9430 6.5410 6.54029 1.59729 4.9430 8.6520 8.67335 3.73035 2009M03 4.7870 5.8810 5.97844 1.19144 4.7870 6.5450 6.56606 1.77906 4.7870 8.5090 8.44270 3.65570 2009M04 4.7570 5.3950 5.44392 0.68692 4.7570 6.4260 6.45520 1.69820 4.7570 8.9530 9.05469 4.29769 2009M05 4.6650 5.1510 5.08022 0.41522 4.6650 6.2610 6.21410 1.54910 4.6650 8.2720 8.19704 3.53204 2009M06 4.7920 5.5040 5.56054 0.76854 4.7920 6.5260 6.53237 1.74037 4.7920 8.7740 8.80924 4.01724 2009M07 4.2520 5.2220 5.18210 0.93010 4.2520 6.4900 6.48009 2.22809 4.2520 8.5380 8.54158 4.28958 2009M08 4.4340 5.4210 5.45308 1.01908 4.4340 6.5460 6.56617 2.13217 4.4340 8.5140 8.47697 4.04297 2009M09 4.3990 5.2610 5.22591 0.82691 4.3990 6.4320 6.40811 2.00911 4.3990 8.7620 8.78216 4.38316 2009M10 4.4540 5.4360 5.44723 0.99323 4.4540 6.5670 6.57142 2.11742 4.4540 8.6270 8.63596 4.18196 2009M11 4.5300 5.3800 5.32125 0.79125 4.5300 6.5420 6.54005 2.01005 4.5300 8.5670 8.55401 4.02401 2009M12 4.7910 5.6730 5.72393 0.93293 4.7910 6.5530 6.54044 1.74944 4.7910 8.6540 8.67476 3.88376 2010M01 4.7730 5.4190 5.41820 0.64520 4.7730 6.6240 6.64895 1.87595 4.7730 8.5150 8.52515 3.75215 2010M02 4.3930 5.4230 5.47152 1.07852 4.3930 6.4830 6.47840 2.08540 4.3930 8.4470 8.40399 4.01099 2010M03 4.4140 5.1810 5.12707 0.71307 4.4140 6.5090 6.48051 2.06651 4.4140 8.7350 8.75098 4.33698 2010M04 4.5140 5.4500 5.46764 0.95364 4.5140 6.6700 6.68062 2.16662 4.5140 8.6280 8.63696 4.12296 2010M05 4.6250 5.3620 5.36320 0.73820 4.6250 6.6100 6.62557 2.00057 4.6250 8.5680 8.60981 3.98481 2010M06 4.6070 5.3560 5.35259 0.74559 4.6070 6.5220 6.55633 1.94933 4.6070 8.2880 8.30592 3.69892 2010M07 4.6090 5.3730 5.42312 0.81412 4.6090 6.3280 6.45949 1.85049 4.6090 8.1680 8.33615 3.72715 2010M08 4.5400 5.1230 5.12801 0.58801 4.5400 5.5850 5.61827 1.07827 4.5400 7.0420 7.14593 2.60593 159 2010M09 4.5680 5.0980 5.21108 0.64308 4.5680 5.3970 5.50583 0.93783 4.5680 6.3460 6.41066 1.84266 2010M10 4.1290 4.5340 4.57350 0.44450 4.1290 4.7820 4.77244 0.64344 4.1290 5.9130 5.87462 1.74562 2010M11 2.5550 4.3370 4.35705 1.80205 2.5550 4.8360 4.82007 2.26507 2.5550 6.1700 6.14670 3.59170 2010M12 2.5480 4.2370 4.09385 1.54585 2.5480 4.9260 4.82690 2.27890 2.5480 6.3260 6.29061 3.74261 2011M01 3.8070 4.9510 4.85436 1.04736 3.8070 5.4860 5.30903 1.50203 3.8070 6.5630 6.41546 2.60846 2011M02 3.3400 5.4330 5.48032 2.14032 3.3400 6.4860 6.59200 3.25200 3.3400 7.5510 7.58953 4.24953 2011M03 2.3050 5.1970 5.30808 3.00308 2.3050 5.8870 6.03866 3.73366 2.3050 7.2930 7.40873 5.10373 2011M04 2.1800 4.6430 4.55498 2.37498 2.1800 5.0300 4.95815 2.77815 2.1800 6.5180 6.50217 4.32217 2011M05 2.8090 5.0820 5.20150 2.39250 2.8090 5.4360 5.49033 2.68133 2.8090 6.6240 6.60220 3.79320 2011M06 3.1310 4.4860 4.59086 1.45986 3.1310 5.1290 5.16121 2.03021 3.1310 6.7700 6.80211 3.67111 2011M07 3.1000 3.9630 4.11117 1.01117 3.1000 4.9470 5.00876 1.90876 3.1000 6.5550 6.60114 3.50114 2011M08 1.5760 3.2240 3.20716 1.63116 1.5760 4.5980 4.48262 2.90662 1.5760 6.2460 6.23107 4.65507 2011M09 1.5310 3.3080 3.21798 1.68698 1.5310 5.2500 5.33601 3.80501 1.5310 6.3460 6.40170 4.87070 2011M10 1.6070 3.7570 3.80512 2.19812 1.6070 4.7640 4.72560 3.11860 1.6070 5.9730 5.96240 4.35540 2011M11 1.6130 3.5170 3.53404 1.92104 1.6130 4.9810 5.08966 3.47666 1.6130 6.0440 6.14689 4.53389 2011M12 1.6780 3.4320 3.36664 1.68864 1.6780 4.3670 4.36063 2.68263 1.6780 5.3550 5.34933 3.67133 2012M01 2.2320 3.7580 3.80792 1.57592 2.2320 4.4030 4.40247 2.17047 2.2320 5.3930 5.42496 3.19296 2012M02 2.5630 3.5090 3.48815 0.92515 2.5630 4.4060 4.37061 1.80761 2.5630 5.1790 5.11628 2.55328 2012M03 2.9990 3.6130 3.58573 0.58673 2.9990 4.6060 4.55610 1.55710 2.9990 5.5990 5.61035 2.61135 2012M04 2.5560 3.7490 3.78128 1.22528 2.5560 4.8880 4.87260 2.31660 2.5560 5.5230 5.47596 2.91996 2012M05 2.5790 3.5880 3.57477 0.99577 2.5790 4.9750 4.99128 2.41228 2.5790 5.8380 5.88414 3.30514 2012M06 2.4570 3.6540 3.66302 1.20602 2.4570 4.8830 4.93007 2.47307 2.4570 5.5290 5.59008 3.13308 2012M07 2.2970 3.6090 3.56509 1.26809 2.2970 4.6170 4.62744 2.33044 2.2970 5.1200 5.13225 2.83525 2012M08 2.1140 3.8280 3.93767 1.82367 2.1140 4.5580 4.56402 2.45002 2.1140 5.0380 5.06742 2.95342 2012M09 1.4750 3.2810 3.20040 1.72540 1.4750 4.5240 4.55957 3.08457 1.4750 4.8410 4.83562 3.36062 2012M10 0.8300 3.6830 3.73713 2.90713 0.8300 4.3230 4.40777 3.57777 0.8300 4.8770 4.91777 4.08777 2012M11 0.7540 3.4130 3.43866 2.68466 0.7540 3.8440 3.85214 3.09814 0.7540 4.6040 4.64955 3.89555 2012M12 0.9290 3.2850 3.30084 2.37184 0.9290 3.7980 3.85799 2.92899 0.9290 4.2990 4.33290 3.40390 2013M01 1.2450 3.2060 3.28921 2.04421 1.2450 3.4590 3.48395 2.23895 1.2450 4.0720 4.14144 2.89644 2013M02 1.0340 2.7910 2.84193 1.80793 1.0340 3.3180 3.37888 2.34488 1.0340 3.6070 3.69406 2.66006 160 2013M03 0.8220 2.5370 2.64908 1.82708 0.8220 2.9740 3.06708 2.24508 0.8220 3.0240 3.04177 2.21977 2013M04 0.4540 1.9780 1.91565 1.46165 0.4540 2.4480 2.49844 2.04444 0.4540 2.9050 2.83571 2.38171 2013M05 2.0160 2.2890 2.16991 0.15391 2.0160 2.1630 2.03700 0.02100 2.0160 3.3690 3.29628 1.28028 2013M06 2.0370 2.8830 3.03297 0.99597 2.0370 2.8750 2.94065 0.90365 2.0370 3.8560 3.92783 1.89083 2013M07 1.4220 2.1350 2.07425 0.65225 1.4220 2.5040 2.44436 1.02236 1.4220 3.3750 3.35663 1.93463 2013M08 1.5730 2.4380 2.45444 0.88144 1.5730 2.8410 2.79251 1.21951 1.5730 3.4980 3.48157 1.90857 2013M09 1.0770 2.3560 2.42317 1.34617 1.0770 3.1150 3.15340 2.07640 1.0770 3.6080 3.62428 2.54728 2013M10 0.4090 2.0210 2.00296 1.59396 0.4090 2.8980 2.91782 2.50882 0.4090 3.4990 3.49228 3.08328 2013M11 0.7540 2.1110 2.08032 1.32632 0.7540 2.7860 2.74813 1.99413 0.7540 3.5440 3.51622 2.76222 2013M12 0.9220 2.2640 2.12947 1.20747 0.9220 3.0000 2.92674 2.00474 0.9220 3.7300 3.64548 2.72348 2014M01 2.0440 2.9350 2.98954 0.94554 2.0440 3.4140 3.38232 1.33832 2.0440 4.2960 4.31302 2.26902 2014M02 1.9230 2.6630 2.60907 0.68607 1.9230 3.5930 3.61601 1.69301 1.9230 4.1820 4.14138 2.21838 2014M03 1.3990 2.9320 2.92759 1.52859 1.3990 3.4630 3.38549 1.98649 1.3990 4.4540 4.46804 3.06904 2014M04 2.2550 2.9540 3.01074 0.75574 2.2550 3.9010 4.00081 1.74581 2.2550 4.3600 4.39614 2.14114 2014M05 2.0000 2.6710 2.66819 0.66819 2.0000 3.3370 3.28940 1.28940 2.0000 4.1180 4.12920 2.12920 2014M06 1.7530 2.6850 2.67177 0.91877 1.7530 3.6060 3.60777 1.85477 1.7530 4.0430 4.02030 2.26730 2014M07 1.9200 2.7510 2.76925 0.84925 1.9200 3.5960 3.54698 1.62698 1.9200 4.1950 4.17842 2.25842 2014M08 1.9000 2.6600 2.65759 0.75759 1.9000 3.8730 3.82345 1.92345 1.9000 4.3060 4.29779 2.39779 2014M09 1.7540 2.6720 2.71811 0.96411 1.7540 4.1530 4.25104 2.49704 1.7540 4.3610 4.39146 2.63746 2014M10 1.7420 2.4420 2.36441 0.62241 1.7420 3.5990 3.64643 1.90443 1.7420 4.1570 4.20270 2.46070 2014M11 2.0330 2.8290 2.0330 3.3310 2.0330 3.8510 where: y1 = 1-year bond yield, y3 = 3-year bond yield, y5 = 5-year bond yield, y10 = 10-year bond yield y1y3hr = holding return of 3-year bonds over 1-year bonds, y1y5hr = holding return of 5-year bonds over 1-year bonds, y1y10hr = holding return of 10-year bonds over 1-year bonds y1y3ehr = excess holding return of 3-year bonds over 1-year bonds, y1y5ehr = excess holding return of 5-year bonds over 1-year bonds, y1y10ehr = excess holding return of 10-year bonds over 1-year bonds 161 APPENDIX H: TERM SPREAD REGRESSION MODEL RESULTS OF PREDICTING EXCESS BOND RETURNS USING HETEROSKEDASTICITY-AUTOCORRELATION CONSISTENT (HAC) NEWEY-WEST TEST (TWO-PERIOD & N-PERIOD CASE) 3-month & 6-month Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 6-month & 1-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: M3M6EHR Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Dependent Variable: M6Y1EHR Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C M3M6SPREAD 0.27230 0.06972 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0033 -0.0062 0.5655 33.2534 -88.9655 0.3481 0.5565 0.3706 Std. Error 0.04507 0.07753 t-Statistic Prob. 6.04244 0.89923 0.00000 0.37060 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic 0.2921 0.5637 1.7163 1.7666 1.7367 2.1798 0.8086 Variable Coefficient C M6Y1SPREAD 0.3407 0.2156 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0440 0.0349 0.4101 17.4944 -54.9249 4.7918 0.0308 0.0815 Std. Error 0.0439 0.1225 t-Statistic Prob. 7.7690 1.7594 0.0000 0.0814 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic 0.4300 0.4175 1.0741 1.1243 1.0944 1.9987 3.0955 162 1-year & 2-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 1-year & 3-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y1Y2EHR Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Dependent Variable: Y1Y3EHR Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C Y1Y2SPREAD 0.4279 0.4235 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.1583 0.1502 0.4873 24.7001 -73.2061 19.5577 0.0000 0.0106 Std. Error 0.1269 0.1627 t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient 3.3725 2.6031 0.0010 0.0106 C Y1Y3SPREAD 0.4207 0.6313 0.7419 0.5287 1.4190 1.4692 1.4394 2.4379 6.7760 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.3506 0.3443 0.5342 29.6834 -82.9464 56.1439 0.0000 0.0000 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Std. Error 0.1227 0.1143 t-Statistic Prob. 3.4291 5.5232 0.0009 0.0000 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic 1.1322 0.6598 1.6028 1.6530 1.6231 2.3501 30.5056 163 1-year & 5-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 1-year & 10-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y1Y5EHR Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Dependent Variable: Y1Y10EHR Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C Y1Y5SPREAD 0.6378 0.6492 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.3764 0.3704 0.6688 46.5184 -106.7572 62.7810 0.0000 0.0000 Std. Error 0.2183 0.1275 t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient 2.9223 5.0911 0.0043 0.0000 C Y1Y5SPREAD 0.6378 0.6492 1.7949 0.8429 2.0520 2.1023 2.0724 2.3456 25.9194 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.6657 0.6625 0.5859 35.7012 -92.7300 207.0650 0.0000 0.0000 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Std. Error 0.2183 0.1275 t-Statistic Prob. 2.9223 5.0911 0.0043 0.0000 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic 2.8451 1.0085 1.7874 1.8376 1.8077 2.0758 229.3279 164 APPENDIX I: TWO-PERIOD CASE FORWARD SPREAD REGRESSION MODEL RESULTS USING HETEROSKEDASTICITY-AUTOCORRELATION CONSISTENT (HAC) NEWEY-WEST TEST 3-month & 6-month Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 6-month & 1-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: CSRM3 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Dependent Variable: CSRM6 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C FM3M6SPREAD -0.0017 0.2020 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0560 0.0470 0.0078 0.0064 368.4186 6.2271 0.0141 0.0198 Std. Error 0.0006 0.0854 t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient -2.8537 2.3668 0.0052 0.0198 C FM6Y1SPREAD -0.0044 0.4608 -0.0006 0.0080 -6.8489 -6.7990 -6.8287 2.2826 5.6018 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.2529 0.2458 0.0064 0.0044 388.9175 35.5472 0.0000 0.0000 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Std. Error 0.0010 0.1082 t-Statistic Prob. -4.4672 4.2606 0.0000 0.0000 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.0006 0.0074 -7.2321 -7.1821 -7.2118 1.9571 18.1527 165 1-year & 2-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: CSRY1 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C FY1Y2SPREAD -0.0026 0.1385 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0672 0.0583 0.0052 0.0028 412.1673 7.5678 0.0070 0.0056 Std. Error 0.0008 0.0490 t-Statistic Prob. -3.1961 2.8269 0.0018 0.0056 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.0006 0.0053 -7.6667 -7.6167 -7.6464 1.8423 7.9915 166 APPENDIX J: N-PERIOD CASE FORWARD SPREAD REGRESSION MODEL USING HETEROSKEDASTICITY-AUTOCORRELATION CONSISTENT (HAC) NEWEY-WEST TEST 1-year & 3-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 1-year & 5-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: CSRY3 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Dependent Variable: CSRY5 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C FY1Y3SPREAD -0.0002 -0.0040 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0003 -0.0092 0.0053 0.0030 409.5320 0.0335 0.8552 0.7885 Std. Error 0.0011 0.0147 t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient -0.2071 -0.2689 0.8364 0.7885 C FY1Y5SPREAD 0.0011 -0.0075 -0.0005 0.0053 -7.6174 -7.5675 -7.5972 1.9741 0.0723 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0092 -0.0002 0.0054 0.0030 408.7525 0.9787 0.3248 0.0999 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Std. Error 0.0011 0.0045 t-Statistic Prob. 1.0883 -1.6602 0.2789 0.0998 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.0006 0.0054 -7.6029 -7.5529 -7.5826 1.9683 2.7564 167 1-year & 10-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: CSRY10 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C FY1Y10SPREAD 0.0007 -0.0015 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0068 -0.0026 0.0054 0.0030 408.8107 0.7221 0.3974 0.1729 Std. Error 0.0010 0.0011 t-Statistic Prob. 0.6563 -1.3721 0.5131 0.1729 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.0006 0.0053 -7.6039 -7.5540 -7.5837 1.9608 1.8828 168 APPENDIX K: FORWARD SPREAD REGRESSION MODEL RESULTS OF PREDICTING EXCESS BOND RETURNS USING HETEROSKEDASTICITY-AUTOCORRELATION CONSISTENT (HAC) NEWEY-WEST TEST (TWO-PERIOD & N-PERIOD CASE) 3-month & 6-month Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: M3M6EHR Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C FM3M6SPREAD 0.2723 3.4684 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0033 -0.0062 0.5655 33.2531 -88.9650 0.3491 0.5559 0.3672 Std. Error 0.0445 3.8297 t-Statistic Prob. 6.1184 0.9056 0.0000 0.3672 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic 0.2921 0.5637 1.7163 1.7666 1.7367 2.1801 0.8202 6-month & 1-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: M6Y1EHR Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C FM6Y1SPREAD 0.3402 10.7984 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0443 0.0351 0.4101 17.4902 -54.9122 4.8180 0.0304 0.0728 Std. Error 0.0409 5.9580 t-Statistic Prob. 8.3196 1.8124 0.0000 0.0728 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic 0.4300 0.4175 1.0738 1.1241 1.0942 1.9996 3.2848 169 1-year & 2-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 1-year & 3-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y1Y2EHR Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Dependent Variable: Y1Y3EHR Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C FY1Y2SPREAD 0.4305 20.8889 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.1576 0.1495 0.4875 24.7209 -73.2506 19.4539 0.0000 0.0110 Std. Error 0.1275 8.0717 t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient 3.3760 2.5879 0.0010 0.0110 C FY1Y3SPREAD 0.7426 5.0811 0.7419 0.5287 1.4198 1.4701 1.4402 2.4364 6.6974 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0335 0.0242 0.6518 44.1783 -104.0216 3.6008 0.0605 0.0449 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Std. Error 0.1702 2.5031 t-Statistic Prob. 4.3641 2.0299 0.0000 0.0449 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic 1.1322 0.6598 2.0004 2.0507 2.0208 1.1120 4.1204 170 1-year & 5-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 1-year & 10-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y1Y5EHR Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Dependent Variable: Y1Y10EHR Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C FY1Y5SPREAD 1.9479 -0.6568 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0029 -0.0067 0.8457 74.3843 -131.6352 0.3014 0.5842 0.6308 Std. Error 0.4034 1.3627 t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient 4.8292 -0.4820 0.0000 0.6308 C FY1Y10SPREAD 2.3129 0.6351 1.7949 0.8429 2.5214 2.5717 2.5418 0.9231 0.2323 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0353 0.0260 0.9953 103.0146 -148.8934 3.8041 0.0538 0.2159 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Std. Error 0.4030 0.5101 t-Statistic Prob. 5.7388 1.2452 0.0000 0.2159 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic 2.8451 1.0085 2.8470 2.8973 2.8674 0.4551 1.5505 171 APPENDIX L: TERM SPREAD REGRESSION MODEL WITH MOVING AVERAGE BOND RISK PREMIUM RESULTS USING HETEROSKEDASTICITY-AUTOCORRELATION CONSISTENT (HAC) NEWEY-WEST TEST (TWO-PERIOD & N-PERIOD CASE) 3-month & 6-month Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 6-month & 1-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: M3M3 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Dependent Variable: M6M6 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C M3M6SPREAD MAVM3M6 -0.0417 0.2031 -0.2750 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0667 0.0487 0.3900 15.8197 -49.5574 3.7160 0.0276 0.0542 Std. Error 0.0504 0.0843 0.3303 t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient -0.8290 2.4076 -0.8324 0.4090 0.0178 0.4071 C M6Y1SPREAD MAVM6Y1 -0.1274 0.4600 -0.5539 -0.0293 0.3999 0.9824 1.0573 1.0128 2.2870 2.9993 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.2905 0.2768 0.3156 10.3597 -26.9087 21.2897 0.0000 0.000001 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Std. Error 0.0645 0.0809 0.4128 t-Statistic Prob. -1.9759 5.6834 -1.3419 0.0508 0.0000 0.1825 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.0306 0.3711 0.5590 0.6340 0.5894 2.0093 16.2304 172 1-year & 2-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y1Y1 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C Y1Y2SPREAD MAVY1Y2 -0.0712 0.1538 -0.4604 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.1152 0.0982 0.2538 6.7000 -3.5931 6.7718 0.0017 0.0001 Std. Error 0.0449 0.0408 0.2170 t-Statistic Prob. -1.5862 3.7678 -2.1213 0.1157 0.0003 0.0363 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.0290 0.2673 0.1232 0.1982 0.1536 1.8920 10.0183 1-year & 3-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y3Y3 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C Y1Y3SPREAD MAVY1Y3 0.9662 -0.7738 -11.4883 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0847 0.0671 1.7785 328.9549 -211.9118 4.8111 0.0100 0.0000 Std. Error 0.3902 0.3915 3.8109 t-Statistic Prob. 2.4760 -1.9767 -3.0146 0.0149 0.0507 0.0032 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.1884 1.8413 4.0170 4.0920 4.0474 2.1035 11.6369 173 1-year & 10-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 1-year & 5-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y5Y5 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C Y1Y5SPREAD MAVY1Y5 4.1984 -1.6902 -56.1917 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.2544 0.2400 3.1070 1003.9670 -271.6068 17.7404 0.0000 0.0000 Std. Error 0.7776 0.3278 12.6329 t-Statistic Prob. 5.3992 -5.1560 -4.4480 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.2979 3.5641 5.1328 5.2078 5.1632 2.0479 15.4870 Dependent Variable: Y10Y10 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C Y1Y10SPREAD MAVY1Y10 4.2151 -1.3233 -36.3583 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0489 0.0306 6.0358 3788.8220 -342.6599 2.6734 0.0738 0.0101 Std. Error 1.6119 0.4497 15.3429 t-Statistic Prob. 2.6149 -2.9426 -2.3697 0.0103 0.0040 0.0196 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.5804 6.1304 6.4609 6.5359 6.4913 1.7492 4.8079 174 APPENDIX M: TERM SPREAD REGRESSION MODEL WITH SQUARED EXCESS RETURNS BOND RISK PREMIUM RESULTS USING HETEROSKEDASTICITY-AUTOCORRELATION CONSISTENT (HAC) NEWEY-WEST TEST (TWO-PERIOD & N-PERIOD CASE) 3-month & 6-month Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: M3M3 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C M3M6SPREAD M3M6EHR2 -0.0867 0.2062 -0.0017 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0573 0.0391 0.3920 15.9798 -50.0959 3.1580 0.0466 0.000074 Std. Error 0.0236 0.0508 0.0056 t-Statistic Prob. -3.6693 4.0589 -0.3122 0.0004 0.0001 0.7555 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.0293 0.3999 0.9924 1.0674 1.0228 2.2824 10.4290 6-month & 1-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: M6M6 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C M6Y1SPREAD M6Y1EHR2 -0.2025 0.5232 -0.1245 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.2804 0.2666 0.3178 10.5069 -27.6638 20.2626 0.0000 0.0000 Std. Error 0.0276 0.0422 0.0784 t-Statistic Prob. -7.3413 12.3898 -1.5875 0.0000 0.0000 0.1154 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.0306 0.3711 0.5732 0.6481 0.6035 2.0704 99.7829 175 1-year & 2-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 1-year & 3-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y1Y1 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Dependent Variable: Y3Y3 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C Y1Y2SPREAD Y1Y2EHR2 -0.1317 0.1422 -0.0031 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0676 0.0497 0.2606 7.0608 -6.3989 3.7690 0.0263 0.0038 Std. Error 0.0400 0.0535 0.0410 t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient -3.2910 2.6592 -0.0749 0.0014 0.0091 0.9404 C Y1Y3SPREAD Y1Y3EHR2 0.7877 -1.5599 0.4571 -0.0290 0.2673 0.1757 0.2506 0.2061 1.8480 5.8857 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.285 0.272 1.571 256.786 -198.661 20.778 0.0000 0.000014 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Std. Error 0.3143 0.4646 0.1064 t-Statistic Prob. 2.5063 -3.3576 4.2973 0.0137 0.0011 0.0000 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.1884 1.8413 3.7694 3.8443 3.7997 1.5929 12.4360 176 1-year & 10-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 1-year & 5-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y5Y5 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C Y1Y5SPREAD Y1Y5EHR2 2.3924 -2.9771 0.6732 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.4153 0.4040 2.7514 787.3151 -258.6017 36.9314 0.0000 0.000032 Std. Error 1.2289 0.8797 0.1438 t-Statistic Prob. 1.9468 -3.3843 4.6820 0.0543 0.0010 0.0000 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.2979 3.5641 4.8898 4.9647 4.9201 1.5118 11.4689 Dependent Variable: Y10Y10 Sample: 2006M01 2014M11 Included observations: 107 HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C Y1Y10SPREAD Y1Y10EHR2 5.9274 -5.1022 0.8780 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.2770 0.2631 5.2626 2880.3010 -327.9924 19.9188 0.0000 0.0013 Std. Error 2.0052 1.3972 0.2809 t-Statistic Prob. 2.9561 -3.6517 3.1256 0.0039 0.0004 0.0023 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.5804 6.1304 6.1868 6.2617 6.2172 1.5734 7.1234 177 APPENDIX N: TERM SPREAD REGRESSION MODEL WITH GARCH-GENERATED STANDARD DEVIATION BOND RISK PREMIUM RESULTS USING HETEROSKEDASTICITY-AUTOCORRELATION CONSISTENT (HAC) NEWEY-WEST TEST (TWO-PERIOD & N-PERIOD CASE) 3-month & 6-month Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: M3M3 Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C M3M6SPREAD GARCHM3M6STDEV -0.0008 0.2379 -0.1995 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0754 0.0575 0.3900 15.6659 -49.0740 4.2013 0.0176 0.0002 Std. Error 0.0347 0.0612 0.0644 t-Statistic -0.0222 3.8873 -3.0975 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic 6-month & 1-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: M6M6 Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Prob. Variable Coefficient 0.9823 0.0002 0.0025 C M6Y1SPREAD GARCHM6Y1STDEV 0.0043 0.5168 -0.4384 -0.0300 0.4017 0.9825 1.0579 1.0131 2.3343 9.0255 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.2981 0.2845 0.3151 10.2283 -26.4785 21.8745 0.0000 0.0000 Std. Error 0.0499 0.0333 0.0817 t-Statistic 0.0856 15.5088 -5.3685 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Prob. 0.9320 0.0000 0.0000 -0.0322 0.3725 0.5562 0.6316 0.5868 1.9219 138.7064 178 1-year & 2-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y1Y1 Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments 1-year & 3-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y3Y3 Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C Y1Y2SPREAD GARCHY1Y2STDEV 0.0591 0.2841 -0.3423 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.1226 0.1055 0.2535 6.6176 -3.4007 7.1930 0.0012 0.0003 Std. Error 0.0734 0.0671 0.1075 t-Statistic 0.8056 4.2320 -3.1827 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Prob. HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable 0.4224 0.0001 0.0019 C Y1Y3SPREAD GARCHY1Y3STDEV -0.0306 0.2680 0.1208 0.1961 0.1513 1.8127 8.9658 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) Coefficient 5.4473 3.9151 -7.9452 0.3327 0.3198 1.5219 238.5816 -193.4049 25.6809 0.0000 0.0000 Std. Error 1.2059 0.6303 1.3958 t-Statistic 4.5172 6.2110 -5.6921 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Prob. 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 -0.2011 1.8453 3.7058 3.7811 3.7363 2.3023 19.4891 179 1-year & 5-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y5Y5 Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments 1-year & 10-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y10Y10 Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable C Y1Y5SPREAD GARCHY1Y5STDEV R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) Coefficient 3.7559 -0.3679 -1.7671 0.1025 0.0851 3.4238 1207.4230 -279.3461 5.8845 0.0038 0.0623 Std. Error 1.9422 1.0385 0.8872 t-Statistic 1.9338 -0.3543 -1.9918 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Prob. HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable 0.0559 0.7238 0.0490 C Y1Y10SPREAD GARCHY1Y10STDEV -0.2880 3.5796 5.3273 5.4027 5.3578 2.1815 2.8524 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) Coefficient 44.4836 31.3826 -45.9519 0.4048 0.3932 4.7943 2367.4740 -315.0329 35.0211 0.0000 0.0000 Std. Error 6.3699 4.6441 6.6448 t-Statistic 6.9834 6.7575 -6.9155 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Prob. 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 -0.5570 6.1547 6.0006 6.0760 6.0312 1.3536 24.4197 180 APPENDIX O: TERM SPREAD REGRESSION MODEL WITH GARCH-GENERATED VARIANCE BOND RISK PREMIUM RESULTS USING HETEROSKEDASTICITY-AUTOCORRELATION CONSISTENT (HAC) NEWEY-WEST TEST (TWO-PERIOD & N-PERIOD CASE) 3-month & 6-month Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 6-month & 1-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: M3M3 Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Dependent Variable: M6M6 Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C M3M6SPREAD GARCHM3M6VAR -0.0557 0.2369 -0.1336 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0823 0.0645 0.3885 15.5490 -48.6768 4.6203 0.0120 0.0001 Std. Error 0.0266 0.0531 0.0359 t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient -2.0901 4.4623 -3.7243 0.0391 0.0000 0.0003 C M6Y1SPREAD GARCHM6Y1VAR -0.1331 0.4957 -0.2906 -0.0300 0.4017 0.9750 1.0504 1.0056 2.3646 10.8332 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.2937 0.2800 0.3161 10.2932 -26.8139 21.4116 0.0000 0.0000 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Std. Error 0.0338 0.0329 0.0524 t-Statistic Prob. -3.9365 15.0828 -5.5472 0.0002 0.0000 0.0000 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.0322 0.3725 0.5625 0.6379 0.5931 1.9243 154.4022 181 1-year & 2-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 1-year & 3-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y1Y1 Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Dependent Variable: M3M3 Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C Y1Y2SPREAD GARCHY1Y2VAR -0.1081 0.2691 -0.1444 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.1095 0.0922 0.2554 6.7162 -4.1851 6.3306 0.0026 0.0010 Std. Error 0.0391 0.0706 0.0533 t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient -2.7616 3.8109 -2.7079 0.0068 0.0002 0.0079 C Y1Y3SPREAD GARCHY1Y3VAR -0.0018 2.6882 -1.8489 -0.0306 0.2680 0.1356 0.2109 0.1661 1.7860 7.4174 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.3132 0.2999 1.5440 245.5611 -194.9331 23.4872 0.0000 0.000043 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Std. Error 0.3212 0.5962 0.4006 t-Statistic Prob. -0.0057 4.5085 -4.6155 0.9954 0.0000 0.0000 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.2011 1.8453 3.7346 3.8100 3.7651 2.1166 11.1118 182 1-year & 5-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test 1-year & 10-year Regression using HAC Newey-West Test Dependent Variable: Y5Y5 Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Dependent Variable: Y10Y10 Sample (adjusted): 2006M01 2014M10 Included observations: 106 after adjustments HAC standard errors & covariance (Prewhitening with lags = 3 from AIC maxlags = 4, Bartlett kernel, Integer Newey-West automatic bandwidth = 9.0000, NW automatic lag length = 4) Variable Coefficient C Y1Y5SPREAD GARCHY1Y5VAR 2.0226 0.0376 -0.6062 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.1203 0.1032 3.3898 1183.5760 -278.2889 7.0407 0.0014 0.0935 Std. Error 1.5472 0.6829 0.2775 t-Statistic Prob. Variable Coefficient 1.3073 0.0551 -2.1849 0.1940 0.9562 0.0312 C Y1Y10SPREAD GARCHY1Y10VAR -4.6250 8.6186 -2.2642 -0.2880 3.5796 5.3073 5.3827 5.3379 2.1753 2.4252 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.1178 0.1007 5.8365 3508.6710 -335.8838 6.8801 0.0016 0.0003 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic Std. Error 3.3847 2.9963 0.6543 t-Statistic Prob. -1.3664 2.8764 -3.4605 0.1748 0.0049 0.0008 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion Hannan-Quinn criter. Durbin-Watson stat Wald F-statistic -0.5570 6.1547 6.3940 6.4694 6.4246 1.5944 8.7980 183 APPENDIX P: MACROECONOMIC VARIABLES FOR THE PANEL REGRESSION Economic Activity Prices PesoDollar Rate Excess Liqudity OFW Remittances Monetary Stance US Prices Federal Funds Rate Government Budget Deficit (% of GDP) Government debt (% of GDP) Stock Market Activity Gross International Reserves Lagged BRP Bond Spread Period gmersales ginf gforex gm2 gofwrem grrp guscpi gfedrate gdeficit gdebt gpsei ggir brplag spread 2006M01 1.0395 0.0700 0.0000 7.6805 0.0000 0.000 0.0399 0.0000 -2.2709 0.0276 29.5713 2.7132 0.5260 2006M02 4.5775 0.1300 -0.0152 9.0204 -0.0554 0.000 0.0360 0.0466 0.6159 -0.2732 -0.0105 23.9039 2.8443 0.5970 2006M03 6.8537 0.0700 -0.0115 8.7325 0.1920 0.000 0.0336 0.0223 0.0901 -0.1398 0.0344 24.9294 3.0302 0.6030 2006M04 1.1194 0.0300 0.0027 9.5214 -0.1293 0.000 0.0355 0.0436 -1.6484 -3.8478 0.0340 24.7251 0.7813 3.3030 2006M05 -0.2235 0.0500 0.0149 12.5003 0.2705 0.000 0.0417 0.0313 -0.6706 -0.0258 0.0113 21.2306 0.8321 0.4410 2006M06 -2.0497 0.0300 0.0197 14.0286 -0.0326 0.000 0.0432 0.0101 1.1774 -0.8488 -0.0511 19.1859 0.8913 0.4370 2006M07 1.8194 0.0600 -0.0143 13.9473 -0.0511 0.000 0.0415 0.0501 -2.3443 -4.9986 0.0973 20.4050 0.5778 -1.7450 2006M08 -3.6870 0.0300 -0.0198 12.8876 0.0415 0.000 0.0382 0.0019 -1.8427 -1.4262 -0.0329 20.0463 0.5581 0.5510 2006M09 0.9131 0.0100 -0.0187 14.9499 -0.0709 0.000 0.0206 0.0000 -2.1322 -3.0667 0.1057 16.4545 0.5698 0.4660 2006M10 -3.3099 0.0200 -0.0079 15.5334 0.1694 0.000 0.0131 0.0000 -0.6400 -2.0703 0.0594 23.2717 0.5712 0.5580 2006M11 3.7728 0.0200 -0.0032 18.7113 -0.0352 0.000 0.0197 0.0000 -0.6458 -1.9072 0.0295 25.4208 0.5280 0.5130 2006M12 3.6440 -0.0200 -0.0076 22.9065 0.1534 0.000 0.0254 -0.0019 2.1276 -2.1388 0.0696 24.1823 0.5699 0.0070 2007M01 5.0277 -0.0100 -0.0112 22.2418 -0.1668 0.000 0.0208 0.0019 3.1779 -0.1638 0.0861 16.1387 0.6117 0.0000 2007M02 1.0593 0.0000 -0.0109 22.1364 -0.0126 0.000 0.0242 0.0019 -1.3739 -1.5881 -0.0530 19.8242 0.5877 0.6280 2007M03 5.1134 0.0200 0.0028 27.1078 0.2020 0.000 0.0278 0.0000 -4.0032 -0.1100 0.0444 19.5641 0.6243 0.3880 2007M04 2.4956 0.0500 -0.0143 28.4363 -0.0868 0.000 0.0257 -0.0019 -1.3583 -4.7798 0.0210 20.3195 0.6496 0.2840 2007M05 5.8240 0.0400 -0.0211 20.8602 0.0383 0.000 0.0269 0.0000 -1.1462 -0.9133 0.0624 22.1928 0.6208 0.8390 2007M06 5.4208 0.0300 -0.0140 20.4141 -0.0981 0.000 0.0269 0.0000 -1.4476 -4.0214 0.0536 24.8987 0.6094 -0.4670 2007M07 6.7056 0.0700 -0.0116 19.4278 -0.0172 -0.120 0.0236 0.0019 1.0396 6.5068 -0.0436 31.7047 0.6571 0.1240 2007M08 9.2975 0.0200 0.0098 14.1462 0.1007 -0.091 0.0197 -0.0456 7.7129 -0.6619 -0.0388 41.5235 0.6697 0.6940 2007M09 1.9490 0.0400 0.0013 12.0153 -0.0556 0.000 0.0276 -0.0159 -2.0449 -0.8902 0.0617 43.1096 0.5320 0.9780 2007M10 10.9215 0.0500 -0.0380 12.3970 0.2181 -0.033 0.0354 -0.0364 -0.8982 -5.1043 0.0521 45.6687 0.4937 0.7510 2007M11 0.9642 0.0800 -0.0262 9.9879 -0.1451 -0.034 0.0431 -0.0567 -37.5986 -3.2153 -0.0480 44.4605 0.4677 0.7330 2007M12 0.1423 0.1000 -0.0341 10.6946 0.1769 -0.036 0.0408 -0.0557 -1.4630 0.7551 0.0120 46.9563 0.4144 0.8220 184 2008M01 4.3288 0.1200 -0.0193 7.4956 -0.0952 -0.030 0.0428 -0.0708 -0.4436 -2.7549 -0.0982 46.9115 0.3982 0.6150 2008M02 6.0272 0.0700 -0.0065 7.0889 -0.0043 -0.046 0.0403 -0.2437 0.3633 -1.5061 -0.0416 47.8590 0.3769 0.8190 2008M03 -3.6509 0.1300 0.0143 1.8732 0.1344 0.000 0.0398 -0.1242 -0.0196 -0.4675 -0.0464 48.3690 0.2978 0.8240 2008M04 6.3780 0.2800 0.0137 0.4736 -0.0123 0.000 0.0394 -0.1264 -2.3831 -0.5689 -0.0787 44.9029 0.2990 0.7540 2008M05 -0.0821 0.1600 0.0259 3.2830 0.0139 0.000 0.0418 -0.1316 -0.7273 1.7777 0.0282 41.5396 0.1375 1.0850 2008M06 -1.0096 0.2400 0.0321 4.5635 0.0147 0.042 0.0502 0.0101 -0.8905 3.0353 -0.1300 39.1516 0.1543 -0.2190 2008M07 -1.2731 0.1400 0.0153 3.9005 -0.0579 0.054 0.0560 0.0050 -21.0636 -1.0176 0.0476 31.6998 0.1623 0.4420 2008M08 0.4772 0.0400 -0.0018 9.7952 -0.0254 0.053 0.0537 -0.0050 -1.1091 -0.0270 0.0431 20.5267 0.1749 -0.0330 2008M09 5.2344 -0.0100 0.0405 13.4449 0.0007 0.038 0.0494 -0.0950 -13.8509 -15.9064 -0.0441 18.7537 0.1179 0.5960 2008M10 3.2163 -0.0100 0.0285 13.3032 0.0764 0.000 0.0366 -0.4641 -0.5858 1.0839 -0.2407 10.6268 0.1025 -0.2780 2008M11 7.0480 -0.0500 0.0242 15.4718 -0.0860 0.000 0.0107 -0.5979 -0.5156 -0.7070 0.0105 12.5581 0.1000 0.2210 2008M12 1.4758 -0.0900 -0.0222 15.4318 0.0735 -0.023 0.0009 -0.5897 -0.6677 -1.8405 -0.0501 11.2582 0.1129 0.0510 2009M01 -9.8985 0.0300 -0.0184 15.8887 -0.1010 -0.067 0.0003 -0.0625 25.3899 4.4362 -0.0255 12.7507 0.0413 0.3760 2009M02 -2.6767 0.0800 0.0080 14.3199 0.0431 -0.086 0.0024 0.4667 -0.2381 -2.0707 0.0258 7.2663 0.0515 0.2290 2009M03 7.7598 0.0400 0.0184 14.9854 0.1147 -0.044 -0.0038 -0.1818 0.8156 -0.6959 0.0609 6.6002 0.0522 0.2210 2009M04 -1.4223 0.0300 -0.0050 13.0841 -0.0202 -0.033 -0.0074 -0.1667 -1.1502 -0.8053 0.0590 8.1437 0.0638 0.1690 2009M05 -0.7566 -0.0300 -0.0144 14.7796 0.0280 -0.030 -0.0128 0.2000 -2.4403 -9.0062 0.1359 9.2630 0.0705 0.2330 2009M06 3.0553 0.0000 0.0080 12.0225 0.0112 -0.051 -0.0143 0.1667 1.6570 0.1639 0.0204 7.5649 0.0806 0.1970 2009M07 3.6348 -0.0200 0.0050 12.5069 -0.0031 -0.029 -0.0210 -0.2381 0.1449 0.2962 0.1478 8.8574 0.0671 0.2480 2009M08 5.0092 0.0200 0.0003 12.7350 -0.0836 -0.030 -0.0148 0.0000 -0.3653 -3.7973 0.0307 12.9271 0.0810 0.1400 2009M09 5.5046 0.0700 -0.0004 10.8915 0.0569 0.000 -0.0129 -0.0625 0.2516 -0.7103 -0.0289 15.8906 0.0915 0.2460 2009M10 5.0000 0.1200 -0.0268 11.7984 0.0583 0.000 -0.0018 -0.2000 0.0375 -0.7804 0.0384 20.0878 0.1063 0.1180 2009M11 5.5000 0.1000 0.0038 11.5776 -0.0471 0.000 0.0184 0.0000 -0.7743 1.2157 0.0469 19.9287 0.1182 0.1860 2009M12 6.0000 0.0900 -0.0130 7.6200 0.0745 0.000 0.0272 0.0000 3.0374 -6.6198 0.0025 17.8207 0.1092 0.4950 2010M01 32.4400 0.0200 -0.0084 8.1000 -0.1244 0.000 0.0263 -0.0833 0.4274 -0.8650 -0.0326 16.1625 0.1169 0.2470 2010M02 14.6600 0.0600 0.0061 9.9000 0.0294 0.000 0.0214 0.1818 -0.1060 -9.3612 0.0307 17.5719 0.1050 0.4380 2010M03 7.0100 0.0400 -0.0123 9.8300 0.0993 0.063 0.0231 0.2308 0.9244 -0.7111 0.0388 16.7983 0.1189 0.1240 2010M04 10.8000 0.0400 -0.0243 12.0200 -0.0214 0.000 0.0224 0.2500 -1.0407 0.3906 0.0406 19.4007 0.1360 0.1280 2010M05 14.9000 -0.0300 0.0217 10.2600 0.0386 0.000 0.0202 0.0000 -12.7457 -0.4427 -0.0053 20.4607 0.1548 0.1040 2010M06 15.4000 -0.0200 0.0154 9.6300 0.0283 0.000 0.0105 -0.1000 0.1341 0.6538 0.0305 23.3350 0.1690 0.1820 185 2010M07 5.5000 0.0000 0.0004 9.5500 -0.0042 0.000 0.0124 0.0000 -0.0557 2.0232 0.0161 22.1057 0.1804 0.2750 2010M08 5.5000 0.0400 -0.0030 7.9900 -0.0704 0.000 0.0115 0.0556 -1.0403 -1.1376 0.0406 20.2771 0.1986 0.1830 2010M09 6.9000 0.0200 -0.0405 7.5000 0.0650 0.000 0.0114 0.0000 -25.0211 -0.2864 0.1497 26.3947 0.2160 0.2060 2010M10 10.5000 0.0200 -0.0194 10.1900 0.0457 0.000 0.0117 0.0000 -0.6682 -2.3830 0.0411 32.3812 0.2291 0.2100 2010M11 7.5000 0.1100 0.0032 7.0000 -0.0364 0.000 0.0114 0.0000 -1.0458 -0.3989 -0.0738 37.1269 0.1296 0.3060 2010M12 8.0000 0.0700 -0.0007 10.6000 0.0505 0.000 0.0150 -0.0526 -93.6084 -11.0271 0.0626 40.9796 0.1240 0.3200 2011M01 7.0000 0.0400 0.0119 9.6000 -0.1282 0.000 0.0163 -0.0556 -1.2125 -0.6509 -0.0761 39.3686 0.1347 0.2700 2011M02 8.0000 0.1100 -0.0086 9.7000 0.0162 -0.059 0.0211 -0.0588 -2.6009 -2.0187 -0.0296 39.6068 0.1369 0.0180 2011M03 -3.7000 0.0100 -0.0041 10.6000 0.0770 0.000 0.0268 -0.1250 -0.1563 -0.2301 0.0766 44.7019 0.0970 0.4120 2011M04 -1.6000 0.0600 -0.0064 7.5000 -0.0004 0.063 0.0316 -0.2857 -2.4482 0.1520 0.0652 45.8953 0.1039 0.1730 2011M05 -2.5000 0.0300 -0.0025 8.6000 0.0448 0.059 0.0357 -0.1000 -1.3656 -0.3911 -0.0173 44.3783 0.1177 0.2750 2011M06 -2.2000 0.0400 0.0181 11.9000 0.0291 0.000 0.0356 0.0000 -0.1989 -0.6601 0.0110 41.6630 0.1358 0.1870 2011M07 1.3000 0.0300 -0.0251 8.8000 -0.0127 0.000 0.0363 -0.2222 2.4432 -3.9940 0.0495 46.5543 0.1476 0.1300 2011M08 3.4000 0.0100 -0.0091 10.0000 -0.0264 0.000 0.0377 0.4286 -1.3482 -0.5778 -0.0344 52.1679 0.1044 0.2050 2011M09 0.8000 0.0700 0.0144 7.6000 0.0393 0.000 0.0387 -0.2000 -3.0066 -10.0809 -0.0802 39.8476 0.1122 0.0410 2011M10 5.5000 0.0400 0.0086 6.9000 0.0239 0.000 0.0353 -0.1250 0.1490 -0.9551 0.0835 32.6804 0.0909 -0.7060 2011M11 4.8000 0.0300 0.0021 7.2000 0.0034 0.000 0.0339 0.1429 0.0351 4.3352 -0.0283 25.8243 0.0941 0.3300 2011M12 5.5000 0.0100 0.0069 6.3000 0.0092 0.000 0.0296 -0.1250 3.6130 -3.9177 0.0382 20.7290 0.0506 -0.6550 2012M01 8.6000 0.0200 -0.0039 7.2000 -0.1348 -0.056 0.0293 0.1429 -0.8549 -1.0967 0.0710 21.7451 0.0635 0.1610 2012M02 8.0000 0.0000 -0.0220 7.2100 0.0195 0.000 0.0287 0.2500 -1.6683 22.9730 0.0460 20.5369 0.0782 0.1610 2012M03 13.3000 0.0300 0.0047 5.8000 0.0695 -0.059 0.0265 0.3000 -3.6862 -0.9881 0.0429 15.3756 0.0697 0.4210 2012M04 8.3000 0.0600 -0.0037 9.0000 0.0020 0.000 0.0230 0.0769 -2.0839 1.0842 0.0186 11.7522 0.0844 0.0130 2012M05 11.8000 0.0200 0.0035 7.8000 0.0426 0.000 0.0170 0.1429 -1.6401 2.1236 -0.0214 10.4984 0.1003 0.0120 2012M06 8.3000 0.0600 -0.0016 7.0900 0.0210 0.000 0.0166 0.0000 -0.4140 2.1031 0.0305 10.3389 0.1148 0.1210 2012M07 11.0000 0.0500 -0.0203 8.6000 -0.0013 0.000 0.0140 0.0000 2.3725 -0.6756 0.0117 10.9553 0.1302 0.0820 2012M08 -0.1000 0.0800 0.0033 7.1000 -0.0067 -0.063 0.0170 -0.1875 -1.0643 3.2316 -0.0210 6.3038 0.1300 0.2510 2012M09 2.3000 0.0200 -0.0071 8.4000 0.0231 0.000 0.0199 0.0769 -14.0139 2.4680 0.0288 9.1184 0.1162 0.2870 2012M10 7.8000 0.0000 -0.0072 9.4000 0.0487 -0.067 0.0216 0.1429 -0.6448 -0.8810 0.0147 7.8011 0.1015 0.3480 2012M11 4.4000 0.0100 -0.0080 10.6100 -0.0048 0.000 0.0176 0.0000 -0.0162 1.4569 0.0398 10.1398 0.1158 0.1880 2012M12 8.0000 0.0300 -0.0027 7.8000 0.0293 0.000 0.0160 0.0000 9.0867 -1.2845 0.0305 11.3262 0.1334 0.0350 186 2013M01 3.9000 0.0300 -0.0068 10.8000 -0.1397 0.000 0.0165 -0.1250 -0.8313 -3.5036 0.0740 10.2331 0.1376 0.2750 2013M02 1.3000 0.0300 -0.0015 10.6000 0.0008 0.000 0.0150 0.0714 -0.3984 -0.3012 0.0767 8.5858 0.1486 0.2360 2013M03 -1.5000 0.0200 0.0010 10.6000 0.0402 0.000 0.0150 -0.0667 1.9958 0.6694 0.0187 10.2747 0.1686 0.0000 2013M04 9.2000 0.0000 0.0106 10.4000 0.0287 0.000 0.0110 0.0714 -2.0456 -0.6024 0.0326 8.7217 0.1890 0.0710 2013M05 5.4000 0.0500 0.0039 10.4000 0.0329 0.000 0.0110 -0.2667 -1.3577 1.4796 -0.0069 7.7351 0.1896 0.1000 2013M06 6.4000 0.0400 0.0390 21.1000 0.0297 0.000 0.0120 -0.1818 -0.3580 -0.5063 -0.0793 6.7331 0.2111 0.0250 2013M07 4.6000 0.0300 0.0126 28.0000 0.0058 0.000 0.0150 0.0000 5.2977 5.9426 0.0269 4.2796 0.2201 0.0520 2013M08 7.6000 0.0300 0.0094 29.1900 -0.0041 0.000 0.0150 -0.1111 -1.4115 -0.8556 -0.0849 2.6796 0.2280 -0.2020 2013M09 5.9000 0.0800 -0.0007 31.6000 0.0077 0.000 0.0120 0.0000 -1.8500 1.2315 0.0192 1.8026 0.2456 0.1000 2013M10 0.7000 0.0200 -0.0148 33.0000 0.0668 0.000 0.0090 0.1250 -0.3964 -0.4587 0.0636 2.2755 0.2179 0.4200 2013M11 2.7000 0.0700 0.0087 36.6000 0.0006 0.000 0.0100 -0.1111 -1.0890 -1.4703 -0.0572 -0.4304 0.2418 0.0890 2013M12 0.9000 0.0800 0.0125 33.8000 0.0456 0.000 0.0120 0.1250 -53.5983 1.1590 -0.0514 -0.7686 0.2665 0.1240 2014M01 1.8000 0.0700 0.0188 39.5000 -0.1723 0.000 0.0160 -0.2222 -0.4300 -1.7478 0.0257 -6.9378 0.2779 0.1000 2014M02 1.0000 0.0100 -0.0007 38.1000 -0.0024 0.000 0.0110 0.0000 -0.7160 -0.1610 0.0635 -3.6876 0.1994 0.7470 2014M03 1.4000 0.0200 -0.0023 36.0000 0.0490 0.000 0.0150 0.1429 3.1352 -0.9350 0.0006 -5.1286 0.1844 0.4810 2014M04 1.3000 0.0200 -0.0034 33.6000 0.0158 0.000 0.0200 0.1250 -3.0119 6.6384 0.0434 -4.0487 0.1885 -0.1790 2014M05 1.7000 0.0900 -0.0161 27.5000 0.0347 0.000 0.0210 0.0000 -0.8543 1.8144 -0.0090 -2.1043 0.1420 0.6600 2014M06 6.8000 0.0200 -0.0023 24.2000 0.0349 0.000 0.0210 0.1111 -6.3035 0.0383 0.0296 -0.6426 0.0595 0.7190 2014M07 11.9000 0.0700 -0.0080 18.7000 0.0068 0.000 0.0200 -0.1000 -0.9718 -0.4853 0.0030 -3.0394 0.0739 0.1400 2014M08 13.7000 0.0300 0.0069 18.8000 -0.0051 0.071 0.0170 0.0000 -17.9496 -0.8357 0.0271 -2.4351 0.0767 0.2880 2014M09 4.7000 0.0200 0.0070 16.0000 0.0258 0.067 0.0170 0.0000 -1.1740 4.1820 0.0329 -4.7306 0.0777 0.3630 2014M10 5.3000 0.0300 0.0164 15.2000 0.0557 0.000 0.0170 0.0000 -0.5133 -2.2709 -0.0093 -5.0214 2.7132 0.2370 187 APPENDIX Q: RESULTS OF THE FIXED EFFECTS PANEL REGRESSION FOR THE WHOLE SAMPLE CASE (ALL VARIABLES & SELECTED VARIABLES) Whole Sample Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression (All Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample (adjusted): 2006M02 2014M10 Periods included: 105 Cross-sections included: 6 Total panel (balanced) observations: 630 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Error C 0.3513 0.0559 6.2801 BRPLAG 0.7662 0.0247 31.0612 MERSALES -0.0055 0.0024 -2.3344 INF -0.0675 0.2716 -0.2484 GFOREX 0.9399 0.8709 1.0791 M2 -0.0028 0.0016 -1.7688 GOFWREM -0.0363 0.1573 -0.2307 FRRP 0.0847 0.0826 1.0256 USCPI -0.2129 0.9665 -0.2203 GFEDRATE -0.0478 0.0801 -0.5972 GDEFICIT -0.0020 0.0010 -1.9384 DEBT 0.0042 0.0065 0.6398 GPSEI 0.3305 0.2555 1.2935 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.1095 Mean dependent var Adjusted R-squared 0.0922 S.D. dependent var S.E. of regression 0.2554 Akaike info criterion Sum squared resid 6.7162 Schwarz criterion Log likelihood -4.1851 Hannan-Quinn criter. F-statistic 6.3306 Durbin-Watson stat Prob(F-statistic) 0.0026 Wald F-statistic Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.0010 Prob. 0.0000 0.0000 0.0199 0.8039 0.2809 0.0774 0.8176 0.3055 0.8257 0.5506 0.0530 0.5226 0.1963 -0.0306 0.2680 0.1356 0.2109 0.1661 1.7860 7.4174 Whole Sample Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression (Selected Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample (adjusted): 2006M02 2014M10 Periods included: 105 Cross-sections included: 6 Total panel (balanced) observations: 630 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Error C 0.3669 0.0435 8.4423 BRPLAG 0.7655 0.0238 32.1238 MERSALES -0.0067 0.0024 -2.8274 GFOREX(-1) 1.7091 0.7947 2.1505 M2 -0.0028 0.0014 -1.9458 GFEDRATE(-1) 0.2083 0.0792 2.6305 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.9208 Mean dependent var Adjusted R-squared 0.9195 S.D. dependent var S.E. of regression 0.2970 Akaike info criterion Sum squared resid 54.6098 Schwarz criterion Log likelihood -123.5966 Hannan-Quinn criter. F-statistic 719.8925 Durbin-Watson stat Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 Wald F-statistic Prob(Wald F-statistic) 0.9208 Prob. 0.0000 0.0000 0.0048 0.0319 0.0521 0.0087 0.9208 0.9195 0.2970 54.6098 -123.596 719.8925 0.0000 188 APPENDIX R: RESULTS OF THE FIXED EFFECTS PANEL REGRESSION FOR THE PERIODICAL CASE (2006-2010 & 2011-2014) (ALL VARIABLES & SELECTED VARIABLES) 2006 to 2010: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression (All Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample (adjusted): 2006M02 2010M12 Periods included: 59 Cross-sections included: 6 Total panel (balanced) observations: 354 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Error C 0.2967 0.0882 3.3621 BRPLAG 0.7330 0.0358 20.4646 MERSALES -0.0014 0.0031 -0.4350 INF 0.2617 0.4014 0.6520 GFOREX 1.4017 1.1372 1.2326 M2 0.0027 0.0042 0.6459 GOFWREM -0.0123 0.1916 -0.0641 FRRP 0.0475 0.1129 0.4207 USCPI -1.1662 1.2535 -0.9303 GFEDRATE 0.1242 0.1219 1.0190 GDEFICIT -0.0033 0.0013 -2.4652 DEBT 0.0008 0.0100 0.0825 GPSEI -0.1273 0.3609 -0.3527 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.8917 Mean dependent var Adjusted R-squared 0.8862 S.D. dependent var S.E. of regression 0.3332 Akaike info criterion Sum squared resid 37.3021 Schwarz criterion Log likelihood -104.0106 Hannan-Quinn criter. F-statistic 162.6834 Durbin-Watson stat Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 Prob. 0.0009 0.0000 0.6638 0.5148 0.2186 0.5188 0.9489 0.6742 0.3529 0.3089 0.0142 0.9343 0.7246 2006 to 2010: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression (Selected Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample (adjusted): 2006M02 2010M12 Periods included: 59 Cross-sections included: 6 Total panel (balanced) observations: 354 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Error C 0.3492 0.0455 7.6795 BRPLAG 0.7153 0.0343 20.8608 GFOREX(-1) 3.4374 1.0937 3.1429 GFEDRATE 0.2527 0.1164 2.1716 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.8918 Mean dependent var Adjusted R-squared 0.8893 S.D. dependent var S.E. of regression 0.3286 Akaike info criterion Sum squared resid 37.2415 Schwarz criterion Log likelihood -103.7227 Hannan-Quinn criter. F-statistic 355.6102 Durbin-Watson stat Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 Prob. 0.0000 0.0000 0.0018 0.0306 1.1842 0.9877 0.6369 0.7352 0.6760 2.1962 1.1842 0.9877 0.6893 0.8861 0.7676 2.2106 189 2011 to 2014: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression (All Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample: 2011M01 2014M10 Periods included: 46 Cross-sections included: 6 Total panel (balanced) observations: 276 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Error C 0.5369 0.1023 5.2495 BRPLAG 0.7122 0.0393 18.1324 MERSALES -0.0142 0.0045 -3.1685 INF -0.6943 0.7940 -0.8744 GFOREX -0.7116 1.4703 -0.4840 M2 -0.0050 0.0020 -2.5015 GOFWREM -0.0866 0.3771 -0.2297 FRRP 0.2149 0.1531 1.4034 USCPI 0.2312 2.2587 0.1024 GFEDRATE -0.2745 0.1496 -1.8347 GDEFICIT -0.0014 0.0019 -0.7666 DEBT 0.0094 0.0103 0.9111 GPSEI 0.6400 0.3970 1.6122 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.9591 Mean dependent var Adjusted R-squared 0.9564 S.D. dependent var S.E. of regression 0.2324 Akaike info criterion Sum squared resid 13.9369 Schwarz criterion Log likelihood 20.4217 Hannan-Quinn criter. F-statistic 355.5020 Durbin-Watson stat Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 Prob. 0.0000 0.0000 0.0017 0.3827 0.6288 0.0130 0.8185 0.1617 0.9185 0.0677 0.4440 0.3631 0.1081 1.3633 1.1126 -0.0175 0.2186 0.0772 1.6714 2011 to 2014: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression (Selected Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample (adjusted): 2011M02 2014M10 Periods included: 45 Cross-sections included: 6 Total panel (balanced) observations: 270 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Error C 0.4946 0.0747 6.6236 BRPLAG 0.7342 0.0380 19.3465 MERSALES -0.0179 0.0036 -4.9700 M2 -0.0048 0.0015 -3.2185 FRRP 0.3223 0.1320 2.4408 GFEDRATE(-1) 0.3163 0.0997 3.1742 DEBT(-1) 0.0133 0.0074 1.7992 GPSEI 0.9865 0.3319 2.9722 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.9597 Mean dependent var Adjusted R-squared 0.9579 S.D. dependent var S.E. of regression 0.2282 Akaike info criterion Sum squared resid 13.3842 Schwarz criterion Log likelihood 22.4733 Hannan-Quinn criter. F-statistic 510.4842 Durbin-Watson stat Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 Prob. 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0015 0.0153 0.0017 0.0732 0.0032 1.3630 1.1116 -0.0702 0.1031 -0.0006 1.6277 190 APPENDIX S: RESULTS OF THE FIXED EFFECTS PANEL REGRESSION FOR THE SHORT RATE BRP AND LONG RATE BRP (2006-2014) (ALL VARIABLES & SELECTED VARIABLES) 2006 to 2014: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Short Rate (All Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample (adjusted): 2006M02 2014M10 Periods included: 105 Cross-sections included: 3 Total panel (balanced) observations: 315 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Prob. Error C 0.1003 0.0523 1.9194 0.0559 BRPLAG 0.7639 0.0329 23.2436 0.0000 MERSALES -0.0039 0.0028 -1.3956 0.1639 INF -0.0876 0.3144 -0.2787 0.7807 GFOREX -0.1344 1.0145 -0.1325 0.8947 M2 -0.0002 0.0018 -0.0843 0.9329 GOFWREM 0.0108 0.1829 0.0589 0.9531 FRRP 0.0279 0.0960 0.2904 0.7717 USCPI 1.3544 1.1725 1.1552 0.2489 GFEDRATE -0.0461 0.0931 -0.4953 0.6207 GDEFICIT -0.0005 0.0012 -0.3894 0.6973 DEBT -0.0042 0.0076 -0.5497 0.5829 GPSEI 0.0067 0.2977 0.0226 0.9820 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.7684 Mean dependent var 0.4930 Adjusted R-squared 0.7576 S.D. dependent var 0.4991 S.E. of regression 0.2457 Akaike info criterion 0.0774 Sum squared resid 18.1175 Schwarz criterion 0.2561 Log likelihood 2.8066 Hannan-Quinn criter. 0.1488 F-statistic 71.0837 Durbin-Watson stat 2.0791 Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 2006 to 2014: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Short Rate (Selected Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample (adjusted): 2006M02 2014M10 Periods included: 105 Cross-sections included: 3 Total panel (balanced) observations: 315 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Prob. Error C 0.0931 0.0205 4.5411 0.0000 BRPLAG 0.7873 0.0300 26.2604 0.0000 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.7645 Mean dependent var 0.4930 Adjusted R-squared 0.7622 S.D. dependent var 0.4991 S.E. of regression 0.2434 Akaike info criterion 0.0243 Sum squared resid 18.4234 Schwarz criterion 0.0720 Log likelihood 0.1690 Hannan-Quinn criter. 0.0434 F-statistic 336.4543 Durbin-Watson stat 2.1000 Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 191 2006 to 2014: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Long Rate (All Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample (adjusted): 2006M02 2014M10 Periods included: 105 Cross-sections included: 3 Total panel (balanced) observations: 315 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Prob. Error C 0.6831 0.1208 5.6537 0.0000 BRPLAG 0.7339 0.0393 18.6874 0.0000 MERSALES -0.0072 0.0038 -1.8921 0.0594 INF -0.1185 0.4445 -0.2666 0.7899 GFOREX 2.0057 1.4105 1.4220 0.1561 M2 -0.0060 0.0026 -2.2821 0.0232 GOFWREM -0.1064 0.2560 -0.4155 0.6781 FRRP 0.1593 0.1352 1.1783 0.2396 USCPI -1.8374 1.5602 -1.1776 0.2399 GFEDRATE -0.0365 0.1305 -0.2800 0.7797 GDEFICIT -0.0033 0.0017 -2.0199 0.0443 DEBT 0.0131 0.0106 1.2316 0.2191 GPSEI 0.6879 0.4141 1.6612 0.0977 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.8529 Mean dependent var 2.0323 Adjusted R-squared 0.8460 S.D. dependent var 0.8712 S.E. of regression 0.3418 Akaike info criterion 0.7375 Sum squared resid 35.0570 Schwarz criterion 0.9162 Log likelihood -101.1589 Hannan-Quinn criter. 0.8089 F-statistic 124.2553 Durbin-Watson stat 2.0345 Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 2006 to 2014: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Long Rate (Selected Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample (adjusted): 2006M02 2014M10 Periods included: 105 Cross-sections included: 3 Total panel (balanced) observations: 315 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Prob. Error C 0.6157 0.0939 6.5551 0.0000 BRPLAG 0.7457 0.0374 19.9372 0.0000 MERSALES -0.0086 0.0038 -2.2561 0.0248 GFOREX 2.5622 1.3518 1.8954 0.0590 M2 -0.0051 0.0024 -2.1350 0.0336 GFEDRATE(-1) 0.2446 0.1275 1.9183 0.0560 GDEFICIT -0.0032 0.0016 -1.9789 0.0487 GPSEI 0.7952 0.3723 2.1362 0.0335 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.8524 Mean dependent var 2.0323 Adjusted R-squared 0.8481 S.D. dependent var 0.8712 S.E. of regression 0.3396 Akaike info criterion 0.7090 Sum squared resid 35.1691 Schwarz criterion 0.8281 Log likelihood -101.6619 Hannan-Quinn criter. 0.7566 F-statistic 195.7728 Durbin-Watson stat 2.0113 Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 192 APPENDIX T: RESULTS OF THE FIXED EFFECTS PANEL REGRESSION FOR THE SHORT RATE BRP WITH PERIODICAL TESTS (ALL VARIABLES & SELECTED VARIABLES) 2006 to 2010: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Short Rate (All Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample (adjusted): 2006M02 2010M12 Periods included: 59 Cross-sections included: 3 Total panel (balanced) observations: 177 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Prob. Error C 0.0699 0.0963 0.7257 0.4691 BRPLAG 0.7168 0.0481 14.8983 0.0000 MERSALES -0.0027 0.0040 -0.6778 0.4989 INF -0.0917 0.5053 -0.1816 0.8562 GFOREX -0.1171 1.4355 -0.0816 0.9351 M2 0.0030 0.0053 0.5703 0.5693 GOFWREM 0.0648 0.2417 0.2680 0.7890 FRRP 0.0108 0.1426 0.0760 0.9395 USCPI 1.9101 1.6929 1.1283 0.2609 GFEDRATE 0.0806 0.1531 0.5266 0.5992 GDEFICIT -0.0008 0.0017 -0.4615 0.6451 DEBT -0.0095 0.0126 -0.7534 0.4523 GPSEI -0.2966 0.4574 -0.6485 0.5176 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.6860 Mean dependent var 0.5001 Adjusted R-squared 0.6588 S.D. dependent var 0.5089 S.E. of regression 0.2973 Akaike info criterion 0.4926 Sum squared resid 14.3154 Schwarz criterion 0.7617 Log likelihood -28.5908 Hannan-Quinn criter. 0.6017 F-statistic 25.2783 Durbin-Watson stat 2.1802 Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 2006 to 2010: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Short Rate (Selected Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample (adjusted): 2006M02 2010M12 Periods included: 59 Cross-sections included: 3 Total panel (balanced) observations: 177 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Prob. Error C 0.0733 0.0370 1.9791 0.0494 BRPLAG 0.7268 0.0441 16.4937 0.0000 USCPI 2.0847 1.2460 1.6732 0.0961 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.6814 Mean dependent var 0.5001 Adjusted R-squared 0.6740 S.D. dependent var 0.5089 S.E. of regression 0.2906 Akaike info criterion 0.3941 Sum squared resid 14.5257 Schwarz criterion 0.4839 Log likelihood -29.8816 Hannan-Quinn criter. 0.4305 F-statistic 91.9528 Durbin-Watson stat 2.1914 Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 193 2011 to 2014: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Short Rate (All Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample: 2011M01 2014M10 Periods included: 46 Cross-sections included: 3 Total panel (balanced) observations: 138 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Prob. Error C 0.2543 0.0810 3.1380 0.0021 BRPLAG 0.8228 0.0478 17.2209 0.0000 MERSALES -0.0117 0.0042 -2.7900 0.0061 INF 0.7913 0.7390 1.0707 0.2864 GFOREX -0.4658 1.3743 -0.3389 0.7352 M2 -0.0045 0.0018 -2.5325 0.0126 GOFWREM -0.5204 0.3440 -1.5128 0.1329 FRRP 0.2094 0.1430 1.4643 0.1457 USCPI -4.3508 2.0878 -2.0839 0.0392 GFEDRATE 0.0146 0.1392 0.1052 0.9164 GDEFICIT -0.0008 0.0017 -0.4493 0.6540 DEBT 0.0147 0.0096 1.5343 0.1275 GPSEI 0.4597 0.3696 1.2438 0.2159 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.9118 Mean dependent var 0.4840 Adjusted R-squared 0.9018 S.D. dependent var 0.4879 S.E. of regression 0.1529 Akaike info criterion -0.8159 Sum squared resid 2.8750 Schwarz criterion -0.4978 Log likelihood 71.2998 Hannan-Quinn criter. -0.6866 F-statistic 90.8658 Durbin-Watson stat 1.6996 Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 2011 to 2014: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Short Rate (Selected Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample: 2011M01 2014M10 Periods included: 46 Cross-sections included: 3 Total panel (balanced) observations: 138 Std. Prob. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Error C 0.1149 0.0346 3.3165 0.0012 BRPLAG 0.8305 0.0471 17.6367 0.0000 MERSALES -0.0077 0.0033 -2.3200 0.0219 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.9010 Mean dependent var 0.4840 Adjusted R-squared 0.8980 S.D. dependent var 0.4879 S.E. of regression 0.1558 Akaike info criterion -0.8446 Sum squared resid 3.2293 Schwarz criterion -0.7386 Log likelihood 63.2802 Hannan-Quinn criter. -0.8015 F-statistic 302.5043 Durbin-Watson stat 1.5664 Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 194 APPENDIX U: RESULTS OF THE FIXED EFFECTS PANEL REGRESSION FOR THE LONG RATE BRP WITH PERIODICAL TESTS (ALL VARIABLES & SELECTED VARIABLES) 2006 to 2010: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Long Rate (All Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample (adjusted): 2006M02 2010M12 Periods included: 59 Cross-sections included: 3 Total panel (balanced) observations: 177 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Prob. Error C 0.7011 0.1799 3.8977 0.0001 BRPLAG 0.6563 0.0612 10.7184 0.0000 MERSALES 0.0007 0.0048 0.1414 0.8877 INF 0.4722 0.6180 0.7640 0.4460 GFOREX 2.7058 1.7405 1.5546 0.1220 M2 0.0011 0.0065 0.1735 0.8625 GOFWREM -0.0957 0.2931 -0.3265 0.7445 FRRP 0.1211 0.1754 0.6903 0.4910 USCPI -4.4339 1.9324 -2.2945 0.0230 GFEDRATE 0.2130 0.1887 1.1289 0.2606 GDEFICIT -0.0053 0.0020 -2.6198 0.0096 DEBT 0.0133 0.0154 0.8673 0.3870 GPSEI 0.1168 0.5510 0.2119 0.8325 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.8419 Mean dependent var 1.8682 Adjusted R-squared 0.8282 S.D. dependent var 0.8696 S.E. of regression 0.3604 Akaike info criterion 0.8777 Sum squared resid 21.0412 Schwarz criterion 1.1469 Log likelihood -62.6766 Hannan-Quinn criter. 0.9869 F-statistic 61.6213 Durbin-Watson stat 2.1827 Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 2006 to 2010: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Long Rate (Selected Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample (adjusted): 2006M02 2010M12 Periods included: 59 Cross-sections included: 3 Total panel (unbalanced) observations: 176 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Prob. Error C 0.5983 0.1037 5.7705 0.0000 BRPLAG 0.6963 0.0536 12.9854 0.0000 GFOREX(-1) 4.1547 1.5461 2.6871 0.0079 GDEFICIT(-1) 0.0079 0.0035 2.2464 0.0260 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.8357 Mean dependent var 1.8681 Adjusted R-squared 0.8309 S.D. dependent var 0.8721 S.E. of regression 0.3586 Akaike info criterion 0.8205 Sum squared resid 21.8655 Schwarz criterion 0.9286 Log likelihood -66.2027 Hannan-Quinn criter. 0.8643 F-statistic 172.9518 Durbin-Watson stat 2.0614 Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 195 2011 to 2014: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Long Rate (All Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample: 2011M01 2014M10 Periods included: 46 Cross-sections included: 3 Total panel (balanced) observations: 138 Std. Variable Coefficient t-Statistic Prob. Error C 1.1013 0.2209 4.9867 0.0000 BRPLAG 0.5751 0.0675 8.5210 0.0000 MERSALES -0.0191 0.0078 -2.4635 0.0151 INF -2.0512 1.3521 -1.5170 0.1318 GFOREX -1.1838 2.5000 -0.4735 0.6367 M2 -0.0088 0.0037 -2.3804 0.0188 GOFWREM -0.0739 0.6706 -0.1103 0.9124 FRRP 0.2042 0.2604 0.7840 0.4345 USCPI 6.2300 3.9012 1.5969 0.1128 GFEDRATE -0.5062 0.2557 -1.9799 0.0500 GDEFICIT -0.0027 0.0032 -0.8439 0.4004 DEBT 0.0084 0.0177 0.4726 0.6373 GPSEI 0.9249 0.6767 1.3667 0.1742 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.8980 Mean dependent var 2.2427 Adjusted R-squared 0.8864 S.D. dependent var 0.8300 S.E. of regression 0.2798 Akaike info criterion 0.3928 Sum squared resid 9.6291 Schwarz criterion 0.7110 Log likelihood -12.1034 Hannan-Quinn criter. 0.5221 F-statistic 77.3216 Durbin-Watson stat 1.5393 Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 2011 to 2014: Macro-BRP Fixed Effects Panel Regression for the Long Rate (Selected Variables) Dependent Variable: BRP Sample (adjusted): 2011M02 2014M10 Periods included: 45 Cross-sections included: 3 Total panel (balanced) observations: 135 Std. t-Statistic Error C 1.0463 0.1811 5.7780 BRPLAG 0.6446 0.0599 10.7552 MERSALES -0.0295 0.0060 -4.8733 M2 -0.0101 0.0029 -3.5202 FRRP 0.5874 0.2176 2.7003 GFEDRATE(-1) 0.5783 0.1651 3.5022 DEBT 0.0273 0.0138 1.9781 GPSEI 1.4846 0.5524 2.6872 Effects Specification Cross-section fixed (dummy variables) R-squared 0.9028 Mean dependent var Adjusted R-squared 0.8958 S.D. dependent var S.E. of regression 0.2676 Akaike info criterion Sum squared resid 8.9504 Schwarz criterion Log likelihood -8.3899 Hannan-Quinn criter. F-statistic 128.9905 Durbin-Watson stat Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 Variable Coefficient Prob. 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0006 0.0079 0.0006 0.0501 0.0082 2.2405 0.8289 0.2724 0.4876 0.3599 1.5609 196 BIBLIOGRAPHY Abola, Victor. “Domestic Interest Rates: After disasters, a downward trend”, Recent Economic Indicators, November 2014. “Adaptive Expectations Hypothesis,” Investopedia, http://www.investopedia.com/terms/a/adaptiveexpthyp.asp (accessed April 20, 2015). “Akaike Information Criterion,” Wikipedia, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Akaike_information_criterion (accessed April 15, 2015). Amadeo, Kimberly. “How an Inverted Yield Curve Predicts a Recession,” about news, http://useconomy.about.com/od/glossary/g/Inverted_yield.htm (accessed April 4, 2015). Balfoussia, Hiona and Wickens, Michael. “Macroeconomic Sources of Risk in the Term Structure”, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 39, no. 1 (2007), http://www.jstor.org/stable/4123075. “Bayesian Information Criterion,” Statistical & Financial Consulting by Stanford PhD, http://stanfordphd.com/BIC.html (accessed April 15, 2015). Bernanke, Ben. “Long-Term Interest Rates” (online copy of speech, Annual Monetary/ Macroeconomics Conference: The Past and Future Monetary Policy, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, San Francisco, California, March 1, 2013) http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20130301a.ht m (accessed April 4, 2015). Bico, Czen Alfie. “Estimating and Forecasting the Philippines Zero-Coupon Yield Curve: A Multimethod Approach” (Thesis, University of Asia and the Pacific, 2010) . 197 “Bills-to-Bonds Ratio,” Asian Bonds Online, http://asianbondsonline.adb.org/philippines/data/bondmarket.php?code=Bi lls_Bonds_Ratio_Total (accessed April 5, 2015). Boero, Gianna. and Torricelli, Costanza. “The Information in the Term Structure of German Interest Rates” (2000). “Bonds Turnover Ratio,” Asian Bonds Online, http://asianbondsonline.adb.org/philippines/data/bondmarket.php?code=B ond_turn_ratio (accessed April 5, 2015). Campbell, John. “Some Lessons from the Yield Curve,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 5, no. 3 (1995), http://www.jstor.org/stable/2138430. Campbell, John. “Stock Returns and the Term Structure” NBER Working Paper 1626 (1985). Campbell, John. and Shiller, Robert. “Yields Spreads and Interest Rate Movements: A Bird’s Eye View,” The Review of Economic Studies 58, no.3 (1991), http://www.jstor.org/stable/2298008. Chantapacdepong, Pornpinun. “Determinants of the time varying risk premia,” Discussion Paper No. 07/597, Department of Economics, University of Bristol, 2007. Cochrane, John. and Piazzesi, Monika. “Bond Risk Premia” (Research paper for the National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, 2002). Cochrane, John. and Piazzesi, Monika. “Decomposing the Yield Curve” (Research paper for the National Bureau of Economic Research, Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 2008). “Conundrum: a glut-wrenching experience”, The Economist, November 20, 2014. http://www.economist.com/blogs/freeexchange/2014/11/conundrums. Craine, Roger and Martin, Vance. ““Interest Rate Conundrum” Coleman Fung Risk Management Research Center Working Papers 2 (2009). 198 Daquigan, T. (2011). Linking Inflation Expectations and Yield Spread: The Philippine Case. School of Economics, University of Asia and the Pacific. Diaz, Johann. “The Philippine Term Structure of Interest Rates: An Empirical Analysis” Thesis, University of Asia and the Pacific, 2012. Elliot, Larry. Global financial crisis: five key stages (2007-2011), The Guardian, http://www.theguardian.com/business/2011/aug/07/global-financial-crisiskey-stages (accessed March 19, 2015). Engle, Robert, “GARCH 101: The Use of ARCH/GARCH Models in Econometrics”, Journal of Economic Perspectives 15 (2001). “Expectations Theory”. Investopedia. http://www.investopedia.com/terms/e/expectationstheory. asp (accessed September 26, 2014). “Forward Rate” Investopedia, http://www.investopedia.com/terms/f/forwardrate.asp (accessed April 4, 2015). Geiger, Felix. “The Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates,” in the The Yield Curve and Financial Risk Premia, Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 2011. Guidolin, Massimo. and Thornton, Daniel. “Predictions of Short-Term Rates and the Expectations Hypothesis of the Term Structure of Interest Rates” (Working Paper Series for the European Central Bank, 2008), 11-12. Guinigundo, Diwa. The impact of the global financial crisis on the Philippines financial system – an assessment, BIS no. 54, http://www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap54s.pdf (accessed March 19, 2015). Gujarati, Damodar. Basic Econometrics: International Edition (New York: McGraw-Hill, 2003). 199 Hardouvelis, Gikas. “The term structure spread and future changes in long and short rates in the G7 countries: Is there a puzzle?,” Journal of Monetary Economics (1993). Ilmanen, Antti. Expected Returns on Major Asset Classes (Research Foundation of CFA Institute: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 2012). Ireland, Peter, “Monetary Policy, Bond Risk Premia, and the Economy,” National Bureau of Economic Research (2015). “Kurtosis,” Investopedia, http://www.investopedia.com/terms/k/kurtosis.asp (accessed April 5, 2015). Lee, Sang-Sub. “Macroeconomic Sources of Time-Varying Risk Premia in the Term Structure of Interest Rates,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27, no. 2 (1995), http://www.jstor.org/stable/2077883. Mankiw, Gregory., Goldfeld, Stephen., and Shiller, Robert. “The Term Structure of Interest Rates Revisited,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1986, no.1 (1986), http://www. jstor.org/stable/2534414. McCallum, Bennett. “Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates” NBER Working Paper 4938 (1994). Mishkin, Frederic. “A Multi-Country Study of the Information in the Term Structure about Future Inflation,” National Bureau of Economic Research (1989). Mishkin, Frederic. “The Information in the Term Structure,” National Bureau of Economic Research 2575 (1988). Munasib, Abdul. “Term Structure of Interest Rates: The Theories”, Econ 3313 – Handout 03, Middle Tennessee State University, http://raptor1.bizlab.mtsu.edu/s-drive/FMICHELLO/Fin%204910% 20Options,%20Futures%20and %20other%20Derivatives/Extra%20Readings/Term% 200 20structure%20of%20interest%20rates.pdf (accessed December 26, 2014). North, Gary, “The Yield Curve: The Best Recession Forecasting Tool” Gary North’s Specific Answers, http://www.garynorth.com/public/department81.cfm (accessed April 4, 2015). “Quantitative Methods – Skew and Kurtosis,” Investopedia, http://www.investopedia.com/exam-guide/cfa-level-1/quantitativemethods/statistical-skew-kurtosis.asp (accessed April 5, 2015). “Republic of the Philippines Launches Domestic Liability Management Exercise”, Bureau of the Treasury, http://www.treasury.gov.ph/wpcontent/uploads/2014/08/press-release.pdf (accessed April 6, 2015). “Republic of the Philippines Starts Year Blazing a Trail in International Capital Markets”, Bureau of the Treasury, http://www.treasury.gov.ph/wpcontent/uploads/2015/01/Press-Release-RP-Starts-Year-Blazing-a-Trailin-Intl-Capital-Markets.pdf (accessed April 6, 2015). Shiller, Robert., Campbell, John., and Schoenholtz, Kermit. “Forward Rates and Future Policy: Interpreting the Term Structure of Interest Rates”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1983, no.1 (1983), http://www.jstor.org/stable/2534355. Simon, David. “Expectations and Risk in the Treasury Bill Market”, The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 24, no. 3 (1989), http://www.jstor.org/stable/2330816. Smith, Peter. and Wickens, Michael. “Asset Pricing and Observable Stochastic Discount Factors” Journal of Economic Surveys, 16 (2002). “Statistical Sampling and Regression: Covariance and Correlation,” PreMBA Analytical Methods, https://www0.gsb.columbia.edu/premba/analytical/s7/s7_5.cfm (accessed April 17, 2015). 201 Tease, Warren. “The Expectations Theory of the Term Structure and Short-Term Interest Rates in Australia” (Research discussion paper for the Reserve Bank of Australia, 1986). “The F-test,” The F-Test for Linear Regression, http://facweb.cs.depaul.edu/sjost/csc423/documents/f-test-reg.htm (accessed April 15, 2015). “The Republic of the Philippines Announced the Results of its Domestic Liability Management Program”, Bureau of the Treasury, http://www.treasury.gov.ph/wp-content/uploads/2014/08/ResultsAnnouncement.pdf (accessed April 6, 2015). “Trading Volume,” Asian Bonds Online, http://asianbondsonline.adb.org/philippines/data/bondmarket.php?code=Tr ading_Volume (accessed April 5, 2015). Tzavalis, Elias. and Wickens, Michael. “Explaining the Failures of the Term Spread Models of the Rational Expectations Hypothesis of the Term Structure,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 29, no. 3 (1997), http://www.jstor.org/stable/2953700. Walsh, Carl. “The Term Structure of Interest Rates,” in the Monetary Theory and Policy, (Massachusetts: The MIT Press, 2010). Yap, Josef, Reyes, Celia, and Cuenca, Janet. “Impact of the Global Financial and Economic Crisis on the Philippines,” Philippine Institute for Development Studies (2009). 202