EP06: Energy and Climate Change Dr Jean-Francois Mercure, Pablo Salas, jm801@cam.ac.uk pas80@cam.ac.uk Lecture 7 – Climate change mitigation policy Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - Integrated Assessment Models - Introduction - IAMs from Energy Models – the 70s - Beyond price elasticity - Some early examples of energy models - First energy-climate modules - IAMs in the 90s - Connections with other climate science research - IAMs and scenarios of climate change - The IPCC - IPCC and the Assessment Reports - IPCC and the scientific knowledge - Optimal emission trajectories - Emission Scenarios: IS02 and SRES - Emission Scenarios: RCPs. - Fourth Assessment Report - Fifth Assessment Report Lecture 7 – Climate change mitigation policy - Example of neoclassical modelling - DICE - The Stern Review Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - Grubb’s 3 pillars of sustainable development - Smarter choices - The end-use toolbox - The innovation chain and technology policy: - The innovation chain - Bridging the technology valley of death - Technology push and pull policy - DIAM Model - Motivation - Mitigation Costs - Climate Damages - Results & Conclusions Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - Integrated Assessment Models - Introduction Most economic studies of climate change integrate geophysical stocks and flows with economic stocks and flows. From the economic point of view, valuation (prices) are required to analyse market transactions. Therefore, all the “goods” are transformed into a common unit of account, which can be money (using “purchasing power parity” or PPP), equivalent consumption, or utility. Given the complexity of the problem, scientists have tried to model the interaction of the climate and the economy using Integrated Assessment Modelling (IAM). In the third assessment report, the IPCC defined Integrated Assessment as an “interdisciplinary process of combining, interpreting, and communicating knowledge from diverse scientific disciplines in such a way that the whole set of cause-effect interactions of a problem can be evaluated”* Four approaches identified by the IPCC to IA for climate change**: • Computer-aided modelling • Scenario analysis • Simulation gaming and participatory IA • Qualitative assessment *IPCC, (2001). Third Assessment Report. Climate Change 2001 - Working Group III. Mitigation. Technical Summary. **Schneider, S. 2005. Integrated Assessment Modeling of Global Climate Change: Much Has Been Learned - Still a Long and Bumpy Road Ahead. The Integrated Assessment Journal. Vol. 5 (1), pp. 41–75. Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - Integrated Assessment Models - IAMs from Energy Models – the 70s Integrated assessment models of climate change grew organically from energy models. Before 1973 Energy demand determined mainly by GDP growth rate. Modelling approach: Minimisation of energy supply costs given exogenous demand. It made sense during 50s-70s, given the lack of abrupt discontinuities in energy prices. After 1973 Demand trend extrapolation has proven unsatisfactory. Energy models need to incorporate more accurate price interactions and feedback mechanisms. Rising energy prices affect energy consumption and GDP growth. Partial equilibrium replaces general equilibrium analysis. Demand (willingness to pay) as decreasing continuously differentiable function, and supply (incremental costs), step-function. Demand determined statistically Supply determined using linear programming. Equilibrium price maximises shaded area (net economic benefit). Manne, A., Richels, R., Weyant, J. 1979. “Feature Article - Energy Policy Modeling: A Survey”. Operations Research 27(1):1-36. Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - Integrated Assessment Models - Beyond price elasticity The classical interaction between GDP and energy demand was represented by: However, there are feedbacks between the energy sector and the rest of the economy. GDP growth and energy price are interdependent. The partial equilibrium price elasticity concept was replaced by the “two inputs economy”: Elasticity of substitution: at any given point, holding output constant, the inputmix adjusts to stay in an optimal point. It measures the substitutability between goods. Manne, A., Richels, R., Weyant, J. 1979. “Feature Article - Energy Policy Modeling: A Survey”. Operations Research 27(1):1-36. Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - Integrated Assessment Models - Some early examples of energy models Some of the energy models of that time: Models PIES Kennedy Baughman - Joskow ALPS ETA-MACRO Policies Issues addressed U.S. oil dependence Pricing policies of OPEC Electricity pricing Commercialisation of nuclear reactors US economic growth vs energy use Number of regions 9 U.S. Regions Non communist world, 6 regions 9 U.S. regions U.S. , 1 region U.S. , 1 region ETA-Macro was one of the first models to imbed an energy system in a full economic growth model Manne, A., Richels, R., Weyant, J. 1979. “Feature Article - Energy Policy Modeling: A Survey”. Operations Research 27(1):1-36. Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - Integrated Assessment Models - First energy-climate modules While scientists at that time started to identify climate change as a key long-term issue, energy models did not explicitly included CO2 emissions or climate change in their analyses. One of the precursors in this area was William Nordhaus, who published one of the first energy-economic models including a climate module*. Model “Optimizing the Energy-Environment System”* Eq. (1) and (2) describe the energy system, eq. (3) describes cumulative emissions, and eq. (4) and (5) describe the mass of carbon on different stratums. *Nordhaus, W., 1977. “Economic Growth and Climate: The Carbon Dioxide Problem”. The American Economic Review, Vol. 67 (1), pp. 341-346 Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - Integrated Assessment Models - First climate modules (cont...) Nordhaus, W., 1977. “Strategies for the Control of Carbon Dioxide”. Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper N. 443. Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - Integrated Assessment Models - IAMs in the 90s End-to-end characterisation of IAMs William Nordhaus (“Optimizing the Energy-Environment System” model) and Alan Manne (ETA-MACRO model), where precursors in the development if IAMs. Nordhaus’ model was the first model that combines energy conversion, emissions and atmospheric CO2 concentration. Key components of full scale IAMs IPCC, (1995). Second Assessment Report. Climate Change 1995 - Working Group III. Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - Integrated Assessment Models - Connections with other climate science research Integrated Assessment Modeling Consortium (IAMC). http://www.iamconsortium.org Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - Integrated Assessment Models - IAMs and scenarios of climate change Moss et al. 2010. “The next generation of scenarios for climate change research and assessment”. Nature, 463, 747-756. Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - The IPCC - IPCC and the Assessment Reports The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) was created in 1988 by the World Meteorological Organization (WMO) and the United Nations Environment Program (UNEP). Its first task was to prepare a comprehensive review and recommendations with respect to the state of knowledge of the science of climate change; the social and economic impact of climate change, and possible response strategies and elements for inclusion in a possible future international convention on climate. Today the IPCC's role is as defined in Principles Governing IPCC Work, "...to assess on a comprehensive, objective, open and transparent basis the scientific, technical and socioeconomic information relevant to understanding the scientific basis of risk of human-induced climate change, its potential impacts and options for adaptation and mitigation. IPCC reports should be neutral with respect to policy, although they may need to deal objectively with scientific, technical and socio-economic factors relevant to the application of particular policies.” Assessment Reports: 1990, 1995, 2001, 2007 and 2014 The First Assessment Report (1990) played a decisive role in leading to the creation of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC), the key international treaty to reduce global warming and cope with the consequences of climate change. The Second Assessment Report provided important material drawn on by negotiators in the run-up to adoption of the Kyoto Protocol in 1997. Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - The IPCC - IPCC and the scientific knowledge The IPCC reviews and assesses the most recent scientific, technical and socio-economic information produced worldwide relevant to the understanding of climate change. It does not conduct any research nor does it monitor climate related data or parameters. IPCC, (1995). Second Assessment Report. Climate Change 1995 - Working Group III. Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - The IPCC - 1st (top right), 2nd (bottom left) and 3rd (bottom right) AR optimal emission trajectories. IPCC, (1990). First Assessment Report. Climate Change 1990 – Working Group III. The IPCC Response Strategies. IPCC, (1995). Second Assessment Report. Climate Change 1995 - Working Group III. Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. IPCC, (2001). Third Assessment Report. Climate Change 2001 - Working Group III. Mitigation. Technical Summary. Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - The IPCC - Emission Scenarios: IS02 and SRES. IS92: In 1992. the IPCC produced six (a-f) global and regional greenhouse gases (GHGs) emissions scenarios projected from 1990 through 2100 (for the 2nd Assessment Report). “A set of updated scenarios have been developed for use in modelling studies which describe a wide range of possible future emissions in the absence of a coordinated policy response to climate change”. SRES: In 2000, the IPCC produced four family of scenarios, “to describe consistently the relationships between emission driving forces and their evolution and add context for the scenario quantification” IPCC (1992). The 1992 IPCC Supplement: Scientific Assessment. IPCC Working Group I. IPCC (2000). Special Report. Emission Scenarios. Summary for Policy Makers. IPCC Working Group III. Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - The IPCC - Emission Scenarios: SRES. A1: Globally fast economic growth and development A1F1: fossil intensive A1T: non-fossil energy sources A1B: balanced A2: Regionally oriented economic development B1: Global environmental sustainability B2: Regional environmental sustainability tech. More Economic A1 More Global B: balanced FI: fossil intensive T: non-fossil A2 B1 B2 More Regional More Environmental IPCC (2000). Special Report. Emission Scenarios. Summary for Policy Makers. IPCC Working Group III. Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - The IPCC - Emission Scenarios: RCPs. The scientific community designed the “representative concentration pathways” (RCPs) in three phases: 1) Development of a scenario set containing emission, concentration and land-use trajectories 2) A parallel development phase with climate model runs and development of new socio-economic scenarios. 3) A final integration and dissemination phase. Globally fast economic growth and tech. development Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - The IPCC - Fourth Assessment Report The approach taken by the IPCC over the different assessment reports has a clear evolution. The change relates to the increase in our knowledge and understanding of the science behind climate change, and also to a better understanding of the human response to it. Compared to previous assessments, the Fourth Assessment Report paid greater attention to the integration of climate change with sustainable development policies, the relationship between mitigation and adaptation and a consistent evaluation of uncertainty and risk. IPCC, (2007). Fourth Assessment Report. Climate Change 2007 - Working Group III. Mitigation. Ch3. Issues related to mitigation in the long-term context, p 199 IPCC, (2007). Fourth Assessment Report. Climate Change 2007 - Working Group III. Mitigation. Technical Summary, p42 Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - The IPCC - Fifth Assessment Report Compared to previous reports, the, the Fifth Assessment Report puts greater emphasis on assessing the socioeconomic aspects of climate change and implications for sustainable development, risk management and the framing of a response through both adaptation and mitigation. It provides more detailed information on regions, including on climate phenomena such as monsoons and El Niño. IPCC, (2013). Fifth Assessment Report. Climate Change 2013 – Working Group I. The Physical Science Basis. Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - Example of neoclassical modelling - DICE (Nordhaus, 1994,2007,2010) ‘The DICE (Dynamic Integrated model of Climate and the Economy) model views the economics of climate change from the perspective of neoclassical economic growth theory. In this approach, economies make investments in capital, education, and technologies, thereby reducing consumption today, in order to increase consumption in the future. The DICE model extends this approach by including the “natural capital” of the climate system as an additional kind of capital stock. In other words, it views concentrations of GHGs as negative natural capital, and emissions reductions as investments that raise the quantity of natural capital (or reduce the negative capital). By devoting output to emissions reductions, economies reduce consumption today but prevent economically harmful climate change and thereby increase consumption possibilities in the future.’ neoclassical economic growth theory • Identical and rational agents maximise their consumption. • Future consumption is compared to current consumption using a discount rate ρ. Nordhaus, W. 2011. “Integrated Economic and Climate Modeling”. Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1839 Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - Example of neoclassical modelling - DICE (cont.) concentrations of GHGs as negative natural capital • Damage function (Ω<1) decreases output (Q) emissions reductions as investments • Abatement cost (Λ), increases proportionally to emissions targets (μ). By devoting output to emissions reductions, economies reduce consumption today • Abatement actions (Λ, μ), have a negative impact on output (Q). Therefore, they decrease current consumption (C). Nordhaus, W. 1994. “Managing the Global Commons: The Economics of Climate Change”. The MIT Press Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - The Stern Review (2006) “There is still time to avoid the worst impacts of climate change, if we take strong action now.” First sentence of the Summary of Conclusions of the Stern Review ‘The [Stern] Review first examines the evidence on the economic impacts of climate change itself, and explores the economics of stabilising greenhouse gases in the atmosphere. The second half of the Review considers the complex policy challenges involved in managing the transition to a low-carbon economy and in ensuring that societies can adapt to the consequences of climate change that can no longer be avoided’. ‘Most formal modelling in the past has used as a starting point a scenario of 2-3 ºC warming [...] equivalent to a permanent loss of around 0-3% in global world output compared with what could have been achieved in a world without climate change [...] However, those earlier models were too optimistic about warming. [...] more recent evidence indicates that temperature changes resulting from BAU trends in emissions may exceed 2-3 ºC by the end of this century [...] With 5-6 ºC warming - which is a real possibility for the next century - existing models [...] estimate an average 5-10% loss in global GDP, with poor countries suffering costs in excess of 10% of GDP.’ Stern, N. (2006), Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change. Lecture 7-H1: Climate policy as viewed in classical economics - The Stern Review (cont.) ‘Achieving these deep cuts in emissions will have a cost. The Review estimates the annual costs of stabilisation at 500-550ppm CO2e to be around 1% of GDP by 2050 - a level that is significant but manageable’. Estimates of the damage costs of climate change (left panel) and the costs of emission reduction (right panel) according to the Stern Review and according to previous studies Stern, N. (2006), Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change. Tol, R. & Yohe, G. (2006). A Review of the Stern Review Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - Grubb’s 3 pillars of sustainable development - Smarter choices - The end-use toolbox - The innovation chain and technology policy: - The innovation chain - Bridging the technology valley of death - Technology push and pull policy - DIAM Model - Motivation - Mitigation Costs - Climate Damages - Results & Conclusions Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - Grubb’s 3 pillars of sustainable development 1. Introduction: Trapped? 2. The Three Domains • Standards and engagement for smarter choice Pillar 1 Pillar II Pillar III • 3: Energy and Emissions – Technologies and Systems • 4: Why so wasteful? • 5: Tried and Tested – Four Decades of Energy Efficiency Policy • Markets and pricing for cleaner products and processes • 6: Pricing Pollution – of Truth and Taxes • 7: Cap-and-trade & offsets: from idea to practice • 8: Who’s hit? Handling the distributional impacts of carbon pricing • Investment and incentives for innovation and infrastructure • 9: Pushing further, pulling deeper • 10: Transforming systems • 11: The dark matter of economic growth 12. Conclusions: Changing Course Routledge/Taylor & Frances, Published March 2014 Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - Grubb’s 3 pillars of sustainable development Pillar 1: Pillar 2: Pillar 3: Smarter choices - Technology/practice adoption Markets and pricing Innovation and institutions - Pricing the externality, - Technology evolution energy/carbon markets - Behavioural Econ, Choice modelling - Classical Econ, optimisation - Evolutionary Econ, Transitions theory - Standards, labelling, regulatory policy - Carbon and energy pricing - Technology R&D policy: ‘Bridging the valley of death’ Innovations systems Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - Grubb’s 3 pillars of sustainable development Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - Smarter choices: Standards and engagement - Negative costs in the McKinsey curve Grubb, Planetary Economics, Ch 4 p. 132 (2014) Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - Smarter choices: Standards and engagement - Drivers and Barriers Grubb, Planetary Economics, Ch 4 p. 136 (2014) Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - Smarter choices: Standards and engagement - The end-use toolbox Grubb, Planetary Economics, Ch 5. p 180 (2014) Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - The innovation chain and technology policy: - The innovation chain Grubb, Planetary Economics, Ch 9. p 325 (2014) Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - The innovation chain and technology policy: - Bridging the technology valley of death Grubb, Planetary Economics, Ch 9. pp 328-332 (2014) Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - The innovation chain and technology policy: - Technology push policy: R&D and technology support One side of the bridge: Part of the problem lies in a schism between the modern innovator – e.g. the university researcher – and commercialisation, which requires different skills and institutional capabilities/capacities, and access to finance 1. The private sector is not able to bear many of the risks of innovation without very large expected returns 2. The innovator is not able to access finance to develop working ideas 3. The government is able to pick up this risk for the sake of social benefit, thereby diversifying government expenditure to support economic performance Technology push mechanisms - Intellectual property rights Ensures ‘monopoly rights’ to the innovator in order to maintain an innovation incentive - Incubators and technology transfer services: Offers start-up companies connection between funding sources and research institutes. e.g. Cambridge Enterprise with angel/venture capital investors - Public-private partnerships The government picking up part of the costs/risks, e.g. Carbon Trust technology accelerators - Government market engagement Government funded demonstration projects or deployment programmes, e.g. in Danemark for wind power Grubb, Planetary Economics, Ch 9. p. 335 (2014) Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - The innovation chain and technology policy: - Demand pull policy The other side of the bridge: Part of the problem is to generate an actual market for new technologies to be adopted. Under the promise that diffusion would yield enough cost reductions to make technologies competitive, the creation of a market is crucial from the start. Demand pull mechanisms (in the low carbon electricity context) - Carbon pricing, emissions taxes Amount paid by operators of polluting equipment proportionally to emissions (polluter pays principle) - Renewable obligations Proportion of electricity produced by firms generated by renewables - Capital cost subsidies - Feed-in tariffs Ensures a specific price given to renewables producers, can be fixed or re-adjusted - Finance mechanisms May be useful to balance revenue generating and costly policies from the government perspective: - Carbon pricing/taxing can generate substantial income - Capital cost subsidies/feed-in tariffs can involve significant expenditures as diffusion takes off - It is likely most effective to have combinations of policies Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - The innovation chain and technology policy: - Porter’s hypothesis Porter Hypothesis: Environmental regulation can lead firms to invest in R&D which ultimately can lead to improved competitiveness due to: - Signals companies about resource deficiencies & new technologies Raises corporate awareness Reduces R&D investment uncertainty Creates pressure for innovation Levels the transitional playing field Going back to van Bursik: this could be evidence! Van Bursik et al Environ. Res. Lett. 9 (2014) 114010 Grubb, Planetary Economics, Ch 9 p. 340 (2014) Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - DIAM model - Motivation • Seemingly big discrepancies between different views of the urgency of climate action & cost of delay – Eg. IEA vs Nordhaus • Proposition that this is not only due to different specifications of climate damage, but also assumed characteristics of the emission systems (particularly energy) • The vast majority of stylised global cost-benefit models assume a cost function in relation to the degree of abatement from ‘reference projection’ at time t • This has no underlying history – no inertia or induced tech eg. DICE equations Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - DIAM model - Mitigation Costs Mitigation (abatement) costs defined to depend on both the degree and the rate of abatement relative to ref projection: – Degree of deviation from baseline is classical, DICE-like formulation – Rate-dependent costs reflect the inertia of change – investment in changing the underlying pathway Each rises non-linearly: the model assumes quadratic dependence (like DICE for the enduring cost term): Abatement cost at time t = Ca x (degree of abatement)² + Cb x (rate of abatement)² or more compactly: Abatement cost C(t) = Ca . ε(t) ² + Cb . (dε/dt) ² where ε(t) is the degree of cutback Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - DIAM model - Climate Damage Climate Damage: a simplified approach, inspired by the observation from model ensembles finding a closely linear relationship between cumulative CO2 emissions and global temperature change at a given point in time: – central estimate that 500GtC cumulative emissions increases global temperature by about 1 deg.C (some time lags of secondary importance for most practical emission trajectories). Generally accepted non-linear relationship between temperature change and damage Present model assumes that global damage increases in proportion to the square of temperature change: Annual damage from climate change at time t, d(t) proportional to (temperature change) ² = (E(t)/500) ² where E(t) is the cumulative CO2 emissions (in GtC) at time t. Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - DIAM model - Optimal emission trajectory Grubb, M., Lange, R-J., Salas, P. and Mercure, J-F. (2014). “The impact of energy system adaptability and inertia on optimal climate mitigation”. Presented at to International Association of Energy Economics, Annual Conference ,New York, 15-17 June 2014 Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - DIAM model - Damage function Time profile of climate damages differs radically between models, and across DIAM runs Grubb, M., Lange, R-J., Salas, P. and Mercure, J-F. (2014). “The impact of energy system adaptability and inertia on optimal climate mitigation”. Presented at to International Association of Energy Economics, Annual Conference ,New York, 15-17 June 2014 Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - DIAM model - Damage function Optimal cost structure for adaptive systems requires early abatement efforts compared to traditional non-adaptive approach. Grubb, M., Lange, R-J., Salas, P. and Mercure, J-F. (2014). “The impact of energy system adaptability and inertia on optimal climate mitigation”. Presented at to International Association of Energy Economics, Annual Conference ,New York, 15-17 June 2014 Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - DIAM model - Conclusions It is not just the assumed discount rate and scale and non-linearity of impacts that matters! • With any significant discount rate, the time delay between emissions and assumed impacts is a crucial determinant. • Standard frameworks imply sharply rising costs – both damages and mitigation costs over the century • The adaptability of energy systems is also a major driver of the net benefits of early action – will vary by specific options and would justify diversity in apparent mitigation costs • The combination can lead to ‘cost benefit’ effort levels similar to a risk-averse strategy dominated by non-linearly / threshold assumptions, may almost stabilise gross costs Lecture 7-H2: Technology R&D policy for climate change mitigation - DIAM model - Mathematical Formulation Grubb, M., Lange, R-J., Salas, P. and Mercure, J-F. (2014). “The impact of energy system adaptability and inertia on optimal climate mitigation”. Presented at to International Association of Energy Economics, Annual Conference ,New York, 15-17 June 2014 Lecture 7: References Grubb, M. (2014). “Pushing further, pulling deeper: bridging the technology valley of death”. Chapter 9 on Planetary Economics, by Grubb, M., Hourcade, J-C. And Neuhoff, K. ISBN: 978-0-415-51882-6. Grubb, M., Lange, R-J., Salas, P. and Mercure, J-F. (2014). “The impact of energy system adaptability and inertia on optimal climate mitigation”. Presented at to International Association of Energy Economics, Annual Conference ,New York, 15-17 June 2014 IPCC, (1990). First Assessment Report. Climate Change 1990 – Working Group III. The IPCC Response Strategies. IPCC, (1992). The 1992 IPCC Supplement: Scientific Assessment. IPCC Working Group I. IPCC, (1995). Second Assessment Report. Climate Change 1995 - Working Group III. Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. IPCC, (2000). Special Report. Emission Scenarios. Summary for Policy Makers. IPCC Working Group III. IPCC, (2001). Third Assessment Report. Climate Change 2001 - Working Group III. Mitigation. Technical Summary. IPCC, (2007). Third Assessment Report. Climate Change 2007 - Working Group III. Mitigation. Ch3. Issues related to mitigation in the long-term context. IPCC, (2007). Fourth Assessment Report. Climate Change 2007 - Working Group III. Mitigation. Technical Summary. IPCC, (2013). Fifth Assessment Report. Climate Change 2013 – Working Group I. The Physical Science Basis. Integrated Assessment Modeling Consortium (IAMC). http://www.iamconsortium.org Manne, A., Richels, R., Weyant, J. 1979. “Feature Article - Energy Policy Modeling: A Survey”. Operations Research 27(1):1-36 Moss et al. 2010. “The next generation of scenarios for climate change research and assessment”. Nature, 463, 747-756. Lecture 7: References (cont.) Nordhaus, W., 1977. “Economic Growth and Climate: The Carbon Dioxide Problem”. The American Economic Review, Vol. 67 (1), pp. 341-346. Nordhaus, W., 1977. “Strategies for the Control of Carbon Dioxide”. Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper N. 443. Nordhaus, W. 1994. “Managing the Global Commons: The Economics of Climate Change”. The MIT Press Nordhaus, W. 2011. “Integrated Economic and Climate Modeling”. Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1839 Schneider, S. 2005. “Integrated Assessment Modeling of Global Climate Change: Much Has Been Learned - Still a Long and Bumpy Road Ahead”. The Integrated Assessment Journal. Vol. 5 (1), pp. 41–75. Stern, N. (2006). Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change. Tol, R. & Yohe, G. (2006). A Review of the Stern Review. Van Bursik et al (2014). Environmental Research Letters. 9, 114010