PPT

advertisement
Chapter 13
Monopoly
MODERN PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS
Third Edition
Outline





Market Power
How a Firm Uses Market Power to Maximize Profit
The Costs of Monopoly: Deadweight Loss
The Costs of Monopoly: Corruption and Inefficiency
The Benefits of Monopoly: Incentives for Research
and Development
 Economies of Scale and the Regulation of Monopoly
 Other Sources of Market Power
2
Introduction
 Since 1981 AIDS has
killed over 36 million
people.
 In the U.S., deaths from
AIDS dropped 50% due
to drugs like Combivir.
 A Combivir pill costs $0.50 to produce, but sells
for 25 times higher - $12.50. Why?
INGRAM PUBLISHING/VETTA/GETTY IMAGES
3
Definition
Market power:
The power to raise price above marginal cost
without fear that other firms will enter the market.
Monopoly:
A firm with market power. Normally thought of as a
single seller in a market
4
Market Power
 GlaxoSmithKline owns the patent on Combivir.
 A patent gives exclusive rights to make, use, or
sell the product.
 GSK’s patent prevents competition.
 This gives GSK market power.
 India does not recognize the Combivir patent.
 In India, an equivalent drug sells for $0.50, or
the marginal cost.
 Market Power = “lack of substitutes”
5
Definition
Marginal revenue (MR):
the change in total revenue from selling
an additional unit.
Marginal cost (MC):
the change in total cost from selling an
additional unit.
6
Self-Check
Market power allows a firm to raise price:
a. Above average cost.
b. Above marginal cost.
c. Above marginal revenue.
Answer: b – market power allows a firm to raise
price above marginal cost, without fear that other
firms will enter the market.
7
Market Power
 To maximize profit, firms produce at the level of
output where:
MC = MR
 A firm with market power faces a downward
sloping demand curve.
 It must lower price to sell an additional unit.
 The additional revenue per unit < current price,
or:
MR < P
8
Marginal Revenue
 When price ↓ from
$16 to $14,
quantity ↑ from 2
to 3 units
 Total revenue ↑
from $32 to $42.
 MR, or the change
in total revenue, is
$10.
9
Marginal Revenue
Price
$20
Revenue loss
$2 x 2 = $4
18
16
Price ↓ $16 to $14
14
12
10
Revenue gain
14 x $1 = $14
8
6
Demand
MR =
$10
4
2
1
2
3
4
5
6
MR
7
Quantity
10
Short-Cut for Finding MR
 MR begins at same point on the vertical axis as demand.
 MR has twice the slope (assuming linear demand curve).
Price
a
Demand: P = a – b x Q
2b
1
b
1
a/2b
MR = a – 2b x Q
Quantity
a/b
11
Self-Check
For a firm with market power, marginal revenue
is:
a. Higher than price.
b. Equal to price.
c. Lower than price.
Answer: c – A firm with market power must drop
its price to sell more units, so the marginal
(additional) revenue is lower than price.
12
Profit Maximization for Monopoly
Just like for firms in a competitive industry:
Profit maximization consists of two steps:
1.Choosing a Quantity
Rule: choose Q where MR = MC
2.Choosing a Price
Choose the highest price you can get away with…
which is the highest price consumers will pay
for that Quantity
Rule: once you’ve picked your Quantity, then
follow the graph to the Demand curve,
which shows you how much consumers
will pay (price).
13
Using Market Power to Maximize Profit
Price
($/pill)
Demand
Profit maximizing output:
MR = MC at 80 million pills
Profit maximizing price = $12.50
Profit per pill = $10.00
Total profit = $10 x 80 = $800 m
$12.50
Profit
2.50
//
AC
MC
0.50
80
MR
Quantity
(millions of pills)
14
Elasticity of Demand and Markup
 Two effects make demand for pharmaceuticals
inelastic:
• The “you can’t take it with you” effect:
 People with serious illnesses are relatively
insensitive to the price of life saving drugs.
• The “other people’s money” effect:
 If third parties are paying for the medicine,
people are less sensitive to price.
 The more inelastic the demand curve, the more
a monopolist will raise price above MC.
15
Elasticity of Demand and Markup
Price
Price
Relatively elastic demand
→ small markup
Relatively inelastic demand
→ big markup
P
Demand
P
MC
MC
Demand
QE
MR
Quantity
Q
MR
Quantity
16
Costs of Monopoly: Deadweight Loss
 Monopolies charge a higher price and produce
less than competitive firms.
 Monopolies reduce total surplus (consumer
surplus + producer surplus).
 This implies a deadweight loss - sales that do
not occur because the monopoly price is above
the competitive price.
 The real cost of monopoly is the lost gains from
trade or DWL.
17
Costs of Monopoly: Deadweight Loss
P
P
Consumers get this
Consumers
get this
Monopolist gets this
PM
PC
No one gets this
(deadweight loss)
Supply
MC = AC
Demand
Demand
MR
QC
Competition: P = MC
Q
QM
Q
QC
Monopoly: P > MR
18
Self-Check
A monopolist’s price is:
a. Lower than a competitive firm’s.
b. Higher than a competitive firm’s.
c. The same as a competitive firm’s.
Answer: b – a monopolist’s price is higher than a
competitive firm’s.
19
Costs of Monopoly: Corruption and
Inefficiency
 Many monopolies are the result of government
corruption.
 Tommy Suharto, the Indonesian president’s son,
was given the clove monopoly.
 He bought the
Lamborghini company
with the monopoly
profits.
In these cases, self-interest is channeled toward social
destruction through poor institutions, instead of
towards social prosperity through good institutions. 20
Costs of Monopoly: Corruption and
Inefficiency
 Monopolies are especially harmful if they control a
good that is used to produce other goods.
 In Algeria a dozen or so army generals each
control a key good
• People refer to these men as General wheat,
General tire….
• Each general tries to get a larger share of the
economic pie.
 The result is greater deadweight loss, and the
“pie” shrinks.
21
Benefits of Monopoly: Incentives for R&D
 Drug prices are lower in India and Canada.
• India does not offer strong patent protection.
• Canada’s government controls drug prices.
 It costs $1 billion to develop a new drug.
 Patents are one way of rewarding research and
development (R&D).
 Without patents firms would not spend on R&D,
fewer new drugs would be developed.
22
Benefits of Monopoly: Incentives for R&D
 Prizes can reward research and development
without creating monopolies.
 Patent Buyouts
• If the government were to compensate patent holders
the value of their patents (and then allow competition),
prices could be driven down - eliminating the
deadweight loss without eliminating the incentive to
innovate.
 Reduce price without reducing R&D.
 Must raise taxes to pay for the patent.
 May be difficult to determine a price.
23
Definition
Economies of Scale:
the advantages of large-scale
production that reduce average cost as
quantity increases.
Natural Monopoly:
when a single firm can supply the entire
market at a lower cost than two or more
firms.
24
Natural Monopoly
 Monopolies can arise naturally when economies of
scale allow a single firm to produce at lower cost than
many small firm.
 Utilities such as water, natural gas, and cable
television are often natural monopolies.
• The largest firm will be able to produce its goods at
a lower per unit cost than smaller firms, so only
one firm tends to exist.
 If economies of scale are large enough, price can be
lower under natural monopoly than under competition.
25
Natural Monopoly
P
Average costs
for small firms
Competitive
price PC
It is possible for PM < PC
If economies of scale are
large enough
Monopoly
price PM
AC
MC
Demand
Competitive
Quantity QC
Monopoly
Quantity QM MR
Q
26
Self-Check
Which of the following is most likely to be a
natural monopoly:
a. A home builder.
b. A restaurant.
c. A railroad company.
Answer: c – a railroad company is most likely to
be a natural monopoly, due to economies of scale
and the high cost of duplicating tracks.
27
Price Control and Natural Monopoly
 A price control can increase output.
 Price = MC is the optimal level of output.
 At P = MC, P < AC.
 The firm is operating at a loss and will exit
the industry.
 Price = AC is the lowest price the firm will accept.
 Firm is earning zero (normal) profit.
 Output is higher than at monopoly price.
28
Price Control and Natural Monopoly
Price
• PM and QM are set where MR = MC
• Optimal quantity is where P = MC
• At optimal Q, firm suffers a loss
Monopoly
price PM
P = MC
AC
Loss (P < AC)
QM
Monopoly
quantity
Optimal
quantity
MC
Demand
Quantity
MR
29
Price Control and Natural Monopoly
Price
• At P = AC, firm has normal profit
• Results in some deadweight loss
Monopoly
price PM
Deadweight Loss
P = AC
AC
P = MC
QM
Monopoly
quantity
Optimal
quantity
MC
Demand
Quantity
MR
30
Natural Monopoly - Regulation
 Government Regulation or ownership can solve
the Natural Monopoly problem.
 California deregulated electricity prices with
disastrous results.
• High demand pushed generators to capacity
• Utilities’ demand for electricity is inelastic when supply
is critically low.
• System was designed for regulation, not competition
• Social cost of an outage – at least $10,000/Mwh if not
higher
• “Electricity is damn useful stuff”
31
Natural Monopoly - Regulation
• Firms that generated electricity found a way to
increase profit by shutting down some of their
generators “for maintenance and repair.”
 When supply decreased, the price rose rapidly.
 Enron and others “gamed” the system for their benefit
• California put wholesale price controls in place
• Deregulation, ultimately caused PG&E to file for
bankruptcy, and added $50,000,000,000 to total
power costs in the region
• Other Western States would up charging as
much as $5000/Mwh (normal - $40/Mwh)
32
More On Regulation
• Many assume that market failure can be
corrected via regulation
• Implicitly presume that regulation is done
competently if not perfectly
• “Nirvana” fallacy - the fallacy of comparing
actual things with unrealistic, idealized
alternatives. It can also refer to the
tendency to assume that there is a perfect
solution to a particular problem.
•
Example: using political, not economic criteria
33
More On Regulation
 Sometimes regulatory actions are hardly
“solutions” (i.e. Calif electric “deregulation”)
 Many believe Dodd-Frank Financial
Regulation bill has made things worse
 What matters is the effectiveness of the
regulation in terms of costs/benefits,
including potential opportunity costs
 i.e. over-regulation can stifle market forces
for cost reduction and/or innovation
 “Power does not equate to wisdom”
34
Self-Check
A monopolist will have normal profit when its
price is set equal to:
a. Marginal cost.
b. Average cost.
c. Total cost.
Answer: a – a monopolist will have normal profit
when P = AC.
35
Definition
Barriers to entry:
factors that increase the cost to new
firms of entering an industry.
36
Other Sources of Monopoly Power
37
Numerical Example - Monopoly
A monopolist's demand curve is described by the equation Q = 50 – 0.5P. The marginal revenue
curve is described by the equation MR = 50 – Q. Marginal cost per unit is constant at $5, and
there are no fixed costs to be considered here. What is the monopolist's profit-maximizing
quantity and profit level? Show all your calculations.
MC = 5, MR = 50 – Q, FC = 0
MC = MR is profit max Quantity
so 50 – Q so Q = 45, Q = 45
Solve for P using demand equation:
Q = 50 - .5P
45 = 50 - .5P (solve for P)
5/.5 yields P = 10
Profit = TR – TC
(45)*(10) – ($5)*45 = 450-225
Profit = $225
38
Takeaway
 For a monopolist, marginal revenue is less than
market price (MR < P).
 Monopolies:
• Charge a higher price than competitive firms.
• Reduce total.
• Create a deadweight loss.
• Use market power to earn above normal profits.
 The markup of price over marginal cost is larger
the more inelastic the demand.
39
Takeaway
 Patent monopolies involve a trade-off between
deadweight loss and innovation,
 Natural monopolies involve a trade-off between
deadweight loss and economies of scale.
 Outcomes can be improved by:
• Opening the industry up to competition.
• Regulating the monopolist.
40
Download