Brief answers to problems and questions for review

advertisement

Brief answers to problems and questions for review

1.

The quote at the start of the chapter is graphically illustrated in Figure 3.1. One could use other countries and goods to show the same point.

2.

The answer can be shown in Figure 3.1. Both the US and India can choose a point anywhere along their respective production possibilities frontiers. However, any points that do not lie along these curves are not feasible in autarky.

3.

Given an economy’s production possibilities frontier illustrated below, an economy can specialize and trade achieving a consumption point outside its frontier.

4.

Reciprocal demand is defined as the interaction of the demand by two countries for the other country’s export good in determining the international exchange ratio. The reciprocal demand theory indicates that the final international exchange ratio or the terms of trade depends on the relative strength of each country’s demand for the other country’s product. The country with the greater demand for the other country’s product will have to sacrifice more of its goods in exchange for that product resulting in a terms of trade that will distribute more of the gains to the country whose goods have a greater relative demand.

Cloth

300

U.S.

Cloth

300 D’ India

200

150

E

A

100 A’

E’

0 50

D

100 0 40 50 60

Machines Machines

5.

The terms of trade is the price that a country receives for its exports (Px) relative to the price it pays for its imports (Pm). It is usually expressed as the ratio Px/Pm.

6.

Changes in the terms of trade can indicate the distribution of the gains from trade. For example, if the price of a country’s exports increased and the price of imports did not

© 2015 W. Charles Sawyer and Richard L. Sprinkle

change then this indicates a more favorable rate of exchange for the county. In general, if Px/Pm rises the country’s welfare has improved and the reverse would also be true.

7.

Any terms of trade that is better than the rate at which a country can transform one good into another will improve welfare. Remember that trade is almost a free lunch.

You get more goods with trade for the same level of effort. Even the most unfavorable terms of trade will be better than what a country could obtain in autarky.

8.

Complete specialization occurs because as production expands in the industry with a comparative advantage, the domestic cost of producing the product does not rise. In this case, the firm’s cost curves and the product’s supply curves are horizontal. When constant costs prevail, a country does not lose its comparative advantage as it produces more of the good.

9.

Everything else equal, Mexico should be able to obtain a more favorable terms of trade.

The GDP of the US is approximately $14 trillion and the GDP of Mexico is $768 billion. The US demand for Mexican goods should be higher than the Mexican demand for US goods. This relatively higher US demand should improve the terms of trade for

Mexico.

10.

Specialization and trade under increasing cost conditions does not significantly change the conclusions reached concerning the benefits of trade under conditions of constant costs. Specializing and exporting the good in which the country has a comparative advantage and trading for other goods enables both countries to become better off by consuming beyond their respective production possibilities curves. However, production under increasing-cost conditions constitutes a mechanism that forces prices to converge and results in neither country specializing completely in the production of the good in which it has a comparative advantage. In the case of increasing costs, both countries continue to produce both goods after trade.

11.

International trade under constant and increasing costs are similar in one important respect. In both cases, both countries improve their welfare through trade as opposed to autarky. The difference between the two is in what happens to the comparative disadvantage industries. Under constant costs, the comparative disadvantage industry is

“wiped out” by imports leading the country to completely specialize in the comparative advantage industry. With increasing costs, the rising costs in the foreign country’s comparative advantage industry leads to an equilibrium where neither country completely specializes in the production of one good.

12. a.

Corn 32

10

8 A

B

12 16 22 Wheat

© 2015 W. Charles Sawyer and Richard L. Sprinkle

b.

Suppose Country A has the opportunity to trade with Country B at an international exchange ratio of 1 ton of wheat for 1 ton of corn. Assume after trade that Country A consumes 10 tons of corn. i.

32 tons of corn ii.

10 tons of corn and 22 tons of wheat, shown at point B. iii.

2 corn and 10 wheat

13.

a.

Beer

30,000

US

A (18,000B, 2,000C)

Beer

12,000

Mexico

A’ (8,000B, 1,000C)

5,000 Chips 3,000 Chips b.

MRT US is 6B=1C. MRT Mexico 4B=1C. The US should produce beer and

Mexico should produce chips. An additional 4,000 beers are produced c.

Yes, both the US and Mexico gain 2,000 beers.

14.

America has a comparative advantage in food and Europe has a comparative advantage in clothing. As a result of international specialization and trade, the US and Europe can each have levels of consumption that are superior to those attainable on their production possibilities frontiers. America can move from point A on its production possibilities frontiers to point K on its trading possibilities line. Europe, too, can move from point A′ to point K′.

© 2015 W. Charles Sawyer and Richard L. Sprinkle

Clothing F′

C′ EUROPE

H′

Exports

A′

J′ Imports

K′

D′ G′

Clothing C

A

F

Imports

K

D

J Exports H

Food

AMERICA

G

Food

© 2015 W. Charles Sawyer and Richard L. Sprinkle

Download