Scoping survey Draft Note Synergies between international forest related financing initiatives Preliminary findings for informal discussion and feedback 8 September 2012 André Brasser – Beagle Sustainable Solutions andre@beaglesolutions.nl This draft note summarizes preliminary findings of a scoping survey that is currently implemented with the aim to identify possibilities for synergies to enhance the financing for sustainable forest management (“SFM financing” in this document) from the international level. The survey aims to feed the discussions on forest financing in the Facilitative Process and the Ad Hoc Expert Group on Forest Financing that prepare the ground to come to a meaningful UNFF decision on forest financing in 2013. This draft note is specifically prepared to seize the opportunity at some upcoming events including the Organization Led Initiative of September 2012, to share the initial results of the survey and invite colleagues to provide their expert feedback to the author for consideration in the final report. Please send your observations before 6th of October to André Brasser: andre@beaglesolutions.nl Context, purpose and approach of the study In the various international fora (like CBD, UNCCD, UNFCCC, UNFF), dealing with forests, the need to mobilize new and additional financing from all sources has been identified as a key priority to be addressed at the international level. These international dialogues revealed, a range of gaps, limitations and opportunities in the current internationally forest finance architecture. Not only budgetary, geographically and thematically, but also in terms of coherence and coordination. This survey carried out by Tropenbos International has been commissioned by the Dutch Ministry of Economic Affairs, Agriculture and Innovation. It maps the most relevant international forest related financing initiatives, and compares and analyzes how forest related financing is discussed and operationalized under the different intergovernmental fora. It specifically aims to gain a better understanding of the processes that drive improved coherence, coordination and collaboration and to provide recommendations for policy makers. The survey focused on multilateral initiatives deciding on public funding. It generally inventorized the activities, approaches and underlying assumptions and principles in the major intergovernmental fora, and consequently mapped the differences and similarities in strategies and actions and identify opportunities for improved alignment. For the most relevant initiatives the degree of alignment between the funding streams have been assessed as well as the underlying drivers for alignment. For the survey an internet search has been carried out on the structure of selected international fora; in addition 11 experts in international forest related finance have been interviewed. Following are some preliminary findings to date that the author has distilled from the survey. 1 Preliminary Findings 1. A fragmented (forest)landscape Forest finance is a discussion topic in 6 UN Conventions (with 3 UN agencies involved in implementation), 9 Multilateral Banks and 10 multinational regional initiatives, generating 41 multilateral forest finance related funding streams. The discussion on the Green Climate Fund under UNFCCC is generally regarded as the most relevant in volume and possible impact on forest finance or on promoting SFM, followed by the Global Environmental Facility. Apart from UNFF that generates no funding stream itself, in the other bodies and conventions forest finance usually is one out of many issues and an element of a broader discussion on e.g. biodiversity, climate, land degradation or other. Each of these fora have their own mandate, objectives and procedures. This has resulted in a fragmented landscape with initiatives operating from different implementation realities. In addition to these, bilateral aid, private sector- and NGO programmes add other dozens of initiatives, diverging from the Norwegian Climate and Forest Initiative, the Business and Biodiversity Program of Forest Trends to the Californian, Australian or European Emission Trading Schemes. As identified in the 2012 study on forest financing by the Advisory Group on Finance of the Collaborative Partnership on Forests, the funding available from all these sources “fall far short of even the most conservative estimated needs”. Improved synergy between existing sources therefore seems to be an interesting option to create higher effectiveness and impact with the same budget. 2. Similarities on content, differences in process A general conclusion from this survey is that from a process point of view funding initiatives have many differences. They work with different political mandates. Donor interests often decide on thematic or geographical focus tending to prioritize high forested countries above low forest countries and biodiversity or climate themes above sustainable forest management. Forest funding initiatives work from different governmental sectors with specific counterparts in receiving countries. This creates separate implementation chains generating competition between implementing organization and obstructing a coordinated approach between international donors. In implementing countries, this is further frustrated by different implementation formats and procedures of funding streams. From a content point of view there are many similarities in vision and approach. Though specific funding streams highlight specific elements, reverse of forest loss, unlocking the full potential of forest products and services, capacity building and good governance are shared ambitions. There is a generally shared vision on the role of public versus private funding. As for implementation the initiatives have comparable concerns on risk mitigation, safeguards and impact. Discussions on effectiveness and transparency also show similarities e.g. on how to apply monitoring and evaluation protocols. 3. Coordination OK, being coordinated no! The survey identified a general understanding on the need for improved coherence, coordination and collaboration in forest financing. Although the UNFF is being regarded as the forum where global forest affairs are being discussed, a coordinating role on forest finance is for many not obvious. Many initiatives say to promote improved coherence and are willing to take on a role in coordination, but are reserved of being coordinated. The main driver behind, is the focus on delivering on self-defined objectives through self-defined approaches. Though generally mentioned as an issue, creating improved coherence with other SFM financing streams does not seem to be a priority.1 4. Why coordination is not happening The different priorities, reporting systems, types of projects and funding cycles of the identified SFM financing streams in this study, make it very difficult to standardize projects/programmes in a way that makes coordination functional. Real coordination implies a certain collaboration which might well require financing initiatives to adapt programmes to fit in with others. The change might be such that an amendment is needed to the original funding proposal. 1 This is one of the findings of a study on how coherence has been evaluated in different fields (including SFM related financing). The study concludes that evaluation of coherence is still in an early and nascent stage, especially when compared with ‘main stream’ development evaluation in relation to other criteria such as effectiveness, efficiency and impact. The authors argue that this is not surprising considering the limited amount of investment that has been made to evaluate coherence in international cooperation Keijzer. N en Oppewal J. (2012) Learn to walk before you run, review of methodological approaches for evaluating coherence in the field of international cooperation. European Center for Development Policy management, ECDPM 2 Lack of coordination is not unique to International forest finance. It prevails also in many other themes where players with different agendas meet on an overlapping issue. Coordination is becoming increasingly difficult when diversity of issues, number of stakeholders and thus complexity increases. This creates a vicious circle: more resource are needed to improve coherence, making it more costly and less attractive to give it the priority required. 5. The benefits of improved coordination In management literature (Mooney and Reelay) coordination is being described as the “orderly arrangement of group efforts to provide unity of action in the pursuit of common goals.” It gives proper direction to organisations and enhances proper use of resources. Applied to this survey on SFM financing, the fragmented forest finance landscape does not seem to support coordination. Nevertheless various cases of coordination (at different levels and in different forms) in international forest financing have been identified in the survey. These coordination cases can be grouped in two types of coordination benefits generated: 5.1. Sharing of knowledge and capacity, agreeing on role division and joint policy making can be the outcome if employees from different organizations pragmatically start to coordinate their operations. This has happened in diverse cases as e.g. the REDD partnership within UNFCCC or the FAO/ITTO attempt to align work programmes, the CBD/UNFCCC secretariat cooperation. The development of joint working plans as e.g. between UNFF and UNCCD needed a formal approval of the Conference of the Parties. The development of the Lifeweb internet platform that matches supply and demand of projects is another form of “soft” coordination. The connectedness of participants through social media, discussion platforms and other internet communication opportunities in general increasingly facilitates these types of informal bottom up cooperation. 5.2. Streamlining of procedures and alignment of instruments as the result of a more robust type of cooperation at the governmental level. Where national governments are committed to perform, coordination at organizational level can develop. In e.g. Ghana ,Vietnam and Mexico this has resulted in different types of national platforms that coordinate the application and implementation of international donor funding. Establishment of National Trust funds as in e.g. Brazil, Guyana and Indonesia provides another example of national level coordination of forest finance. At the international level the joint FLEGT/REDD cooperation as a result of the Chatham House talks are an example of this as is the UNREDD/FIP/FCPF coordination that has been achieved due to pressure from various donors to change policies. 6. Lessons learned: preconditions for coordination Theory says that for coordination to be successful, four classical principles of coordination - as defined by Mary Parket Follet - have to be in place2: 1. Early stage: coordinate already in the planning phase 2.Continuity: not only in the planning stage but in organizing, directing, controlling, 3. Direct contact: between managers and subordinates; 4.Reciprocal relations: decision of one affects all others in the organization. These theory applied to the coordination cases in SFM financing identified in this survey, lead to a list of preconditions that have to be met to improve coherence, coordination and collaboration: 1. High priority. There need to be clear self interest for coordination: non coordination has to have serious consequences so that organizations have a genuine wish to coordinate among themselves on a voluntary basis. Outside the forest finance sector this is e.g. demonstrated in the international discussion on standard setting for Intellectual Property. 2. General agreement There must be general agreement on the overall problem assessment, strategy and approach. Bring to light policies that are at odds with each other. When such contradicting policies actually share the same overall objective, it is clear that the incoherence needs to be resolved. If the 2 Mary Parker Follett (1868-1933) is a classical management theorist that stressed the importance of coordination in labour situation of different individuals doing portions of the task. She gave four main Principles of co-ordination the so called Follett's Principles of Coordination. These four principles must be followed to make co-ordination effective. Atkinson M. (2007) Better at working together, interagency collaboration, part 1 Literature review. 3 contradicting policies have very different objectives, it is important to properly evaluate their respective impacts as a basis for trade-off decision at the political level. 3. Limited scope The scope must be manageable and the number of issues limited to ensure that clear outcomes can be reached. 4. Role division Organizations must understand and recognize each other’s mandate and position. Work programmes should be put next to each other to decide on the who does what, when. This was e.g the case UNREDD/FIP/FCPF example where the issue was limited to REDD readiness and organizations brought in different specific expertise on crediting (World bank) and field assistance (FAO). 5. Resources Political agreement on coordination improvement needs to be translated in a priority issue in work programme, clear objectives and sufficient resources made available to enable implementation. Some kind of a coordinating body needs to be in place. 6. Attitude People involved need to be skilled in negotiating and networking, taking full advantage of the communication facilities provided by the internet to feed in knowledge and expertise from a broader constituency and build up wider support. 7 Avenues for improved coherence, coordination and collaboration Not all preconditions necessarily need to be in place to improve coherence and coordination of international forest financing fora. There are different avenues. In general four models can be distinguished with respectively a focus on International coordination, coordination on the country level, brokering and spontaneous coordination through an “invisible hand”. 1. International coordination International funding streams work with very similar procedures and create a logical role division in types of funding and in regions. This provides an easy to understand and logical palette of international funding streams for receiving countries. Focus on interna onal alignment Interna onal Agree on interna onal role division Streamline procedures One format for all Na onal 2. National alignment In this model there is no attempt to improve coordination of international forest financing initiatives. The focus is on the creation of a national platform in receiving countries. Depending on their needs and specifics, countries develop their own arrangement to “pick and choose” the international funding streams that are most appropriate. In countries as e.g. Brazil such national leadership is already the case 4 Focus on na onal alignment Interna onal No interna onal coordinaton Agree on role division at countries level Countries pick and choose what fits Na onal February 16th 202 3. Brokering Both on the national and on the international level no coordination between different organizations is required. Intermediate organizations provide matching services to national governments to link up with the most appropriate international funding mechanism. On the other hand these intermediates support international funding streams to match with the country that fits best to their priorities and requirements. Brokering Interna onal Match make Na onal 4.The invisible hand In this “let hundred flowers blossom” model there is no coordination at all. The international forest finance arena is regarded a market place. A continuous stream of international funding streams is introduced on the market. The most successful operating funding streams will remain and the less successful disappear. The invisible hand Interna onal Let 100 flowers blossom Survival of the fi est mechanism No coordina on at all Na onal 5 Discussion, (draft) conclusions and recommendations The invisible hand model probably resembles the current situation the most. The benefit of this scenario is the freedom of organizations to launch funding streams they think work the best for their purpose. It creates an almost open source type of learning space where ideally the quality of funding streams gradually improves due through an iterative process of learning by doing. From this perspective the forest finance landscape is not “fragmented” but “diverse”, with initiatives complementing each other. The downside of this scenario however are the inefficiencies, doubling of activities and gaps as observed in the scoping survey. In combination with the far too limited budget available for forest finance this doesn’t seem to be the preferred scenario. Taking the above listed preconditions required for coordination into consideration it seems that in the current situation, a focus on national level coordination provides most benefits. Priority, agreement, scope and role division, seem to be easier to establish at the national than at the international level. There is also a legal rational: countries are responsible for their own government. The role of international SFM financing should be to strengthen national forest financing processes. These national processes show great differences. Countries with limited resources and poorer developed forest sectors face the danger to be too exclusively focused on attracting funding streams as such. National forest policies then change with changing “vogues” in international SFM financing, provoking a donor driven approach, frustrating structural improvements of the national forest sector. Countries with a better organized forest sector can take a more independent position in attracting international SFM funding and decide on which funds are appropriate and which aren’t. Intermediates with a brokering function can help to develop towards such a model as identified in the broker model. The avenues identified do not exclude each other. In the process towards country self reliance, the current “Invisible hand” model might well be complementary to a national alignment model. The strength of the “invisible hand” to deliver a variety of different international funding streams, could be of help at the national level to have enough variety to pick and choose from and link up with the many different realities and public and private investment needs in countries. But the observed inefficiencies in international SFM financing should be reduced to create a better functioning model. International forest financing policy makers should be aware of these different avenues and try to find the right balance between national and international alignment strategies. At the international level there is not much added value in attempts to create “an orderly arrangement of group efforts to provide unity of action in the pursuit of common goals“ as coordination can be defined. The focus should and can be on streamlining procedures, complementary work planning and other forms of coordination on the technical level, where needed secured by governmental approvals. The increased connectedness through internet and associated opportunities for coalition building makes this “soft coordination” almost a natural process that has taken off already. 6