Cola Wars Key Take-aways Explaining differences in firm-level profitability Historically, the CP industry has been very profitable, while the bottling industry has been less so Exhibit 5: pretax margin 35% vs. 9% Exhibit 4: average ROE 20-25% vs 5-10% Five forces analysis is a good starting point in explaining these differences Key factors that differ between these two industries: supplier & buyer power rivalry How intense was the Cola War? How do Coke and Pepsi compete with each other? The competitive front: shelf-space advertising direct store delivery selective discounting downstream Concentrate prices rising (Ex. 6)—CPs do not compete on price Factors that mitigate the intensity of rivalry By the 1980s any move made by one player can be matched by the other ad campaigns: Vertical integration Coke buys and recapitalizes bottlers Pepsi does same New products: Pepsi--Michael Jackson then Britney Spears Coke--Bill Cosby then Harry Potter Coke: C2 Pepsi: Pepsi Edge … Most games played to a stalemate How did Pepsi catch up? Pepsi’s Strategy Why didn’t Coke respond more aggressively? Take-away market; lower price; youth emphasis different segment Pepsi Challenge Fat/happy/lazy(?), arrogant(?), focused on international expansion Lessons: Indirect attack Exploit inflexibility Different segment Exploit (technological) change (i.e., growth of supermarkets) Vertical integration in the beverage industry Historically, CPs wrote (semi-)exclusive contracts with bottlers, but did not own them contracts gave bottlers ‘correct’ incentives non-integration kept the capital requirements of the CP industry small In the 1980 and 1990s, CPs moved toward “anchor bottler” model ownership over bottlers allowed CPs to reap economic efficiencies as well as to ensure that bottlers would adapt to changing product strategies (intro of many new products, new packages, competition in a growing number of channels, etc.) equity market’s appetite for new offerings allowed CPs to do this relatively cheaply Summary Coke and Pepsi are examples of how firms can create and exercise market power they didn’t inherit this business, they created it future success will depend on their ability to structure the industry as well as their own businesses Coke and Pepsi are smart when they go to war, they kill the bystanders, not themselves! Will these factors change as the basis of competition expands to include non-carbs? Buy, Sell, or Hold? Company Beta P/E (Forward) Mean Analyst Recommendation Coca Cola .23 19.0 2.6 Pepsi .35 18.3 1.8 Cadbury Schwepes .28 14.5 2.8 Source: Yahoo Finance, 3/17/2005 How much does industry matter? 10-20% of the variation in firms’ profits accounted for by the industry in which the firm competes Analysis based on accounting profits in publicly held companies How much does industry matter really? Average Economic Profits of U.S. Industry Groups, 1978-1996 Value Line Industry Groups ROE-Ke Spread Toiletries/Cosmetics Pharmaceuticals Soft Drink 20% 15% Tobacco Food Processing Household Products Electrical Equipment Financial Services Specialty Chemicals Newspaper Integrated Petroleum Electric Utility - East Bank Retail Store Telecom 10% 5% 0% (5%) (10%) (15%) 0 100 200 300 Tire & Rubber Electric Utility - Central Medical Services Machinery Auto & Truck Computer & Peripheral Paper & Forest Air Transport Average Invested Equity ($B) Steel 400 500 600 700 800 900 1,000 1,100 1,200 1,300 Source: Ghemawat, Strategy and the Business Landscape, p20. Objectives of industry analysis Explain the differences in profitability across industries Identify the drivers of industry-level profitability Establish a foundation for making a strategic choice Who in the value chain captures the value generated by the industry? e.g., decisions about entry, exit, or expansion Highlight important relationships that need to be managed Rivals, buyers, suppliers, complementors, potential entrants Industry analysis has traditionally been a major input into portfolio analysis for diversified firms GE / McKinsey Nine-Block Matrix Industry Attractiveness Business Strength High High Investment and Growth Medium Low Medium Low Selective Growth Selectivity Selective Growth Selectivity Harvest/ Divest Selectivity Harvest/ Harvest/ Divest Divest Harvest/ Harvest/ Divest Divest Porter’s Five Forces Threat of New Entry Bargaining Power of Suppliers • Differentiation of inputs • Switching costs • Presence of substitute inputs • Supplier concentration • Importance of volume to supplier • Cost relative to total purchases • Impact of inputs on cost or differentiation • Threat of forward integration • Economies of scale • Proprietary product differences • Brand identity • Switching costs • • • • • Capital requirements Access to distribution Absolute cost advantages Government policy Expected retaliation Rivalry Among Existing Competitors • Industry growth • Fixed costs / value added • Overcapacity • Product differences • Brand identity • • • • • • Switching costs Concentration and balance Informational complexity Diversity of competitors Corporate stakes Exit barriers Threat of Substitutes • Relative price performance of substitutes • Switching costs • Buyer propensity to substitute Bargaining Power of Customers • • • • • • • • • • • Buyer concentration Buyer volume Buyer switching costs Buyer information Ability to integrate backward Substitute products Price / total purchases Product differences Brand identity Impact of quality / performance Buyer profits Source: Michael E. Porter, Competitive Advantage (New York: Free Press, 1985) Biotech Supply Industry: Investment thesis for Invitrogen Threat of New Entry Bargaining Power of Suppliers • Many new research tools come out of university labs – must be licensed but universities have limited bargaining power since they can’t commercialize these products themselves • Internal R&D ?? • Patents and physical control over biological materials (such as cell lines) limits entry • Exclusive licenses to sell some products • Economies of scope makes it difficult to enter with a half-full product line • Niche entry feasible Rivalry Among Existing Competitors • Growing industry • • Some products highly differentiated (although some are commodities) • Switching costs high in some lines of business (bio-informatics SW) Informational complexity Threat of Substitutes • None – these products are absolutely critical to biotechnology research Bargaining Power of Customers • Varies by segment • University research labs – fragmented, buy based on grant money – have little information and little incentive to bargain down price • Biotech research industry is also fragmented, but has more bargaining power – especially when sharing procurement effort across a variety of products Invitrogen performance Rivalry How hard firms compete on price (or increase quality levels at a given) price depends on: Concentration and balance Industry growth Fixed (or storage costs)/Value added Product differences Brand identity Switching costs Intermittent over-capacity Diverse stakes Exit barriers Threat of Entry Factors that create barriers to entry include: Economies of scale Proprietary product differences Brand image Switching costs Capital requirements Access to distribution Absolute cost advantages Learning curve Access to necessary inputs Low cost product design Government policy Expected retaliation Threat of Substitutes The ability of the industry as a whole to profitably raise price (the elasticity of the industry’s demand curve) Tobacco & pharmaceuticals – inelastic demand Steel – elastic demand Likely to change over time with technological changes or changes in consumer tastes Determined in part by relative performance / price of substitutes Buyer power Intrinsic Strength Buyer concentration Buyer volume Switching costs Buyer information Ability to backward integrate Substitute products Pull through Price Sensitivity Price/Total purchase Product differences Brand identity Impact on quality/performance Buyer profits Decision maker’s incentives Supplier Power Mirror image of buyer power Amount of value chain captured by suppliers influenced by: size and concentration of suppliers degree to which suppliers provide commodity vs. custom inputs (differentiation) availability of substitute inputs ability to backward integrate importance of volume to suppliers Dynamics Industry analysis provides a “snapshot” of current conditions in an industry As we saw in Coors, the industry “landscape” is subject to “tectonic shifts” over time. Some of these shifts are under the control of the players in the industry Coke and Pepsi shaped the terrain with respect to their bottlers Franchising Exclusivity Consolidation and spin-off An example of industry dynamics Industry structure is frequently changing Many, but not all, industries follow predictable patterns corresponding to product life-cycles Number of Firms, Entry and Exit In the US Tire Industry (1905-1980) S-curve adoption Introduction Growth Maturity Decline (?) Source: Klepper and Simons (2000). “The Making of an Oligopoly: Firm Survival and Technological Change in the Evolution of the U.S. Tire Industry” Journal of Political Economy. 108:4, p. 731 Some common long-run dynamics A major challenge for industry analysis is where to draw the boundaries Typically, industry analysis will be motivated by some choice or set of possible strategic choices Horizontal scope Vertical scope Which product markets? How many vertically-linked stages in the value chain should be considered? Geographic scope Which geographic markets? “Everything should be made as simple as possible, but no simpler” — Albert Einstein Final words on industry analysis A starting point for many types of strategic decisions Strategy should fit the external business environment In the long run, the business environment is not fixed It can be shaped by the strategic choices taken by a firm and its rivals It also changes based on factors over which the firm has little control The role of the strategist is to identify these changes and adapt the firm’s strategy to them