Chapter 19 Stabilization, Adjustment, Reform & Privatization CHAPTER 4 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 1 Stabilization, Adjustment, Reform & Privatization Economic adjustment (sometimes used broadly) can refer to structural or sectoral adjustment, macroeconomic stabilization, & economic liberalization & reform. Adjustment often requires LDCs & transitional countries to borrow from & meet conditions set by the World Bank & IMF as a last resort. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 2 Scope of chapter Adjustment & stabilization (especially by World Bank & IMF) in LDCs. Public enterprises & role of public goods. Importance of government sector. Concept of state-owned enterprises (SOEs). Size of SOE sector. Arguments for public enterprise. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 3 Scope of chapter (continued) Performance of private & public enterprises. Determinants of public enterprise performance. Privatization. Pitfalls of privatization. Public enterprises & multinational corporations. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 4 Scope of chapter (concluded) Adjustment, stabilization, & liberalization in economies of transition, especially Russia, China, & Poland. Lessons LDCs can learn from Russian, Polish, & Chinese transitions to the market. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 5 World Bank Interest subsidy account for poorest countries [International Development Association (IDA)]. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 6 Balance of payments equilibrium International balance on the goods and services balance over the business cycle, with no undue inflation, unemployment, tariffs, and exchange controls. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 7 Chronic external deficits require borrowing Often from International Monetary Fund (IMF) as lender of last resort. A member borrowing from the IMF (in excess of member’s reserve contribution) agrees to certain performance criteria, with emphasis on long-run international balance and price stability. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 8 IMF conditionality (i.e., conditions) The borrower adopts adjustment policies to attain a viable payments position. Conditionality involves a quid pro quo for borrowing. IMF requires adjustment policies as necessary for preserving the revolving nature of IMF resources. Policies may require that government reduce budget deficits through increasing tax revenues and cutting back social spending, limiting credit creation, achieving market-clearing prices liberalizing trade, devaluing currency, eliminating price controls, or restraining public-sector employment and wage rates. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 9 Internal & external balance Internal balance – Balance or equilibrium in the domestic macroeconomy, including full employment and price stability. External balance – An international balance on goods and services balance. In Figure 19-1, you switch (change exchange rate) or reduce expenditures so that S-I intersects with X-M at full employment. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 10 CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 11 Critique of World Bank & IMF Adjustment Programs Excessive emphasis on austerity programs: contractionary monetary & fiscal policies. Emphasis on short term rather than long-term structural change. Too little emphasis on maintaining growth. Too little emphasis on protecting underprivileged or vulnerable (although sometimes this may be the fault of the domestic government’s priorities). Programs frequently do not improve external accounts. National adjustment plans superior to World Bank and IMF initiated plans. Sequence of liberalization may worsen adjustment and growth. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 12 Adjustment and Liberalization in Eastern Europe, the Former Soviet Union, and China IMF, World Bank & European Bank for Reconstruction & Development (EBRD), which loans to Eastern Europe & former Soviet Union, indicates that virtually all developing & transitional countries need to adjust & reform. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 13 IMF Managing Director Jacques de Larosiere (1987) “Adjustment is now virtually universal [among LDCs]. . . . Never before has there been such an extensive yet convergent adjustment effort” (IMF Survey, February 23, 1987, p. 50). Since communism’s collapse, the IMF would add transitional countries to other LDCs. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 14 Socialism collapsed in Eastern Europe about 1989 & the Soviet Union in 1991 All faced painful transitions to a market economy, with falling real GDP, high unemployment, high inflation, & increased poverty & inequality in initial years of transition, before positive growth & improvement in other key variables. Transition is like a valley between the 2 hills of communism & capitalism (Fig. 192). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 15 CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 16 Sequence of turning points Poland (1991), Slovenia (1992), Hungary (1992-94), Czech Republic (1992-94), forming a W with later growth reversal), Slovakia (1993): only countries to recover to pre-1989 GDP levels by 2001. Russia attained its turning point in 1998, about the time of ruble devaluation. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 17 Russia Adjustment for black market may mean 1994 GDP was 67 (not 48), with 1990=100. But consumption/income increased, consumers had greater choice of goods, & less waste of central planning. Schleifer (2004) sees Russia as a “normal” middle income country, almost recovering 1990 GDP levels by 2001. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 18 CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 19 Table 3-1. Annual Rates of Growth of Real GNP per Capita (percent), 1870-1998 6 4 5 3 4 5 1870 to 1913 1913 to 1950 1950 to 1973 1973 to 1998 1870 to 1998 Multiplication of 1870 GNP per capita in 1998 Japan 1.48 0.89 8.05 2.34 2.63a 27.6a United States 1.82 1.61 2.45 1.99 1.90 11.2 Germany 1.63 0.17 5.02 1.60 1.81 9.8 Argentina 2.50 0.74 2.06 0.58 1.53 7.0 United Kingdom 1.01 0.92 2.44 1.79 1.39 5.9 Australia 1.05 0.73 2.34 1.89 1.35 5.6 Russia-USSR 1.06 1.76 3.36 1.75 1.11 4.1 China 0.10 2.86 5.39 1.70 8.70 India 0.54 1.40 2.91 0.89 3.10 0.62 0.22 Maddison 2001:186, 196, 216, 265. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 20 Former Soviet Union (FSU) people misinterpreted pauperization Dudrick et al’s (2003) characterization of the people of Georgia: “The fact that the . . . economy collapsed after the actual political breakup of the Soviet Union led [many people] to attribute their pauperization to the demise of the Soviet state . . . rather than its inherent economic weaknesses. They continued to associate the Soviet Union with economic stability.” CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 21 Evolution vs. “shock therapy” Should transition to the market be gradual or abrupt? Sachs (1999), advisor to Poland’s Lech Walesa & Russia’s Boris Yeltsin argues for an abrupt transition to the market. Popov (2001) contends that shock therapists emphasized “introducing the whole reform package at once to ensure that it became too late and too costly to reverse the reforms.” CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 22 Wachtel, an evolutionist (1992) Shock therapy downplays the creation of a small-scale private sector, small independent banks, market reforms in agriculture, “safety net” for social programs, & full employment. Poznanski (1996): institutions form at relatively slow pace. By mid-1990s, electorates in Poland, Russia, & Hungary, disillusioned with market reforms, voted the former Communist Party, refashioned as social democrats or democratic socialists, to parliamentary plurality in place of economic reform. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 23 Sachs’ rejoinder (1994) The Soviet Union’s production was in decline, inflation rates were surging, & the black market value of the ruble was falling in the immediate years before Yeltsin’s transitional government came into power in late 1991. U.S. & IMF disbursed aid too slowly. “Shock therapy” never failed because it was never tried. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 24 Popov (1996): Russian reform was inconsistent shock therapy Failed in macroeconomic stabilization, eliminating subsidies, & shutting down loss-making enterprises. Pressure of interest groups & lack of consensus: Russia had little choice but to tolerate a high rate of inflation in the early 1990s (Table 19-2). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 25 CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 26 Inflation costly for those on fixed incomes A Ukraine woman: “When I retired, I had 20,000 rubles in my savings account. . . . But what the government did with it – the government we trusted with our money! They’ve indexed savings so that inflation ate it! That money is now not enough for bread and water” (World Bank 2001). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 27 Reddaway & Glinski, Market Bolshevism Yeltsin & his advisers promoted shock therapy in late 1991 as part of a “Russian historical pattern of ‘revolutions from above.’” They resisted opposition to the encrusted Soviet party and state leadership, the nomenklatura. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 28 Soviet Union net material product (NMP) Fell 3% 1981-1990. Collapsed in early to mid-1990s. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 29 What brought the Soviet Union down (Gorbachev, 1985-1991 Soviet leader) “What happened to the Soviet Union happened mainly for domestic reasons. It was a failure of the model based on a command economy and dictatorship. The rejection of freedom and democracy, the decision making monopoly of one party, and the monopoly of one ideology all had a chilling effect on the country. That model turned out to be incapable of making structural changes. It did not open up ways for initiative and was overly centralized.” (Gorbachev 2003). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 30 What were the reasons for the collapse of the Soviet state and the slow growth of Russia in the 1990s? Distorted incentives & price signals: Soviet material balance planning, the detailed allocation by central administration of the supply and demand for basic industrial commodities, was slow, cumbersome, lacked clarity, and distorted incentives. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 31 Distorted incentives & price signals Targets unclear. Toward end of period, firms sometimes “stormed” to reach target. At other times, units deliberately slowed down operations so as not to increase targets too much for the subsequent period. Management’s motivation: to hide the true capabilities of the plant from planners. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 32 1. Distorted incentives & price signals Problems of overordering & hoarding labor & raw materials. Incentives rewards managers for maximizing output not profit. Or if profit used, poor guide when prices are set without reference to supply & demand. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 33 2. The party & state monopoly Communist Party (CP), with its interlocking & overlapping authority over the Soviet government, had monopoly over political & economic power. “Redness” (political correctness) more important criterion than expertness in making decisions. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 34 CP controlled the state CP bore full burden of economic management. CP’s interest: gained from concentration & limiting competition, as managers & workers reap rewards from increased enterprise profits & revenues. Those dissatisfied with economic performance were a challenge to the political order. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 35 CP controlled the state Reforms encouraging entrepreneurial activity meant Old Guard received advantages in obtaining permits & access to funds. Under reform, managers, bureaucrats, & party apparatchiks gained control of the more viable socialist enterprises through privatization. In many instances, government officials looted the enterprises, either controlling the newly privatized firms or leaving no assets for others. Much privatization involved large-scale giveaway to insiders. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 36 Soviet leadership fused state with economy Built-in bias against change. State socialism in post-Stalin period became softer, leakier, & less oppressive. Soviet leadership did not recognize greater autonomy of decentralized unit. Sequestering of surpluses reduced by central government, eroding revenue collection. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 37 Is state socialism reformable? Kaminski (1992): no. Direct controls essential for party & state to defend privileged position. Party officials & apparatchiks opposed reform because it reduced power & ability to solicit kickbacks & other benefits. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 38 Nomenklatura system Party & state used nomenklatura system, power to recommend & approve managers. Millar (1994): the “party” is over, but nomenklatura lives on. Nomenklaturs repositioning itself to control new private economy. Reddaway & Glinski (2002): Yeltsin favored commercialized nomenklatura & supporters in West, at expense of middle class & democrats: road toward market bolshevism or authoritarianism. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 39 Decision making in Soviet Union highly centralized CP, President, Politburo (CP’s policy setting body), Gosplan (State Planning Committee reporting to Politburo). Gorbachev (1985-1991) removed Gosplan & central management, decentralizing units were free to do what they thought best, destabilizing the economy. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 40 Gorbachev sequenced Perestroika (restructuring) wrongly Decision making decentralized without introducing market. Enterprises made deliveries at state agencies at set prices, not adjusted to reflect supply & demand. Number of centrally distributed commodities fell from 13,000 (1987) to 618 (1989). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 41 State made production decisions No longer disaggregating these decisions at enterprise level. Enterprises stopped producing low-profit items, reducing machinery, metals, chemicals, & wood produced. Russian leaders did not replace abolished socialist institutions with capitalist institutions (Kotz 1992). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 42 Ruling stratum in Soviet-type economies maximized economic rents CP used nomenklatura to achieve goals. Appointments based on loyalty not management. Russia’s economy “nomenklatura privatization” (Goldman 2003). Economic oligarchs from nomenklatura, former factory managers, & marginal persons operating outside the law during communism (Goldman). After 1991, planning & distribution changed names but still goal of market competition (Afanasyev 1994). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 43 Nomenklatura privatization Much of country’s wealth transferred into hands of CP’s senior officials (began in late 1980s). Masqueraded as liberalism. Ironically capitalist nomenklatura & nouveau rech allies oppose CP, committed to nationalization. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 44 3. Contradictions under decontrol 1970s & early 1980: central authority fell. Shadow economy (black market) grew from 6% (1960) to 23% (1988). Gorbachev thought problem in 1970-85 was “relaxation of discipline.” Gorbachev’s solution: excess increase in machine building, anti-alcohol campaign, undermined black market (essential to circumvent rigidity of material balance planning), reduced economic rewards & punishment, attacking bureaucrats (demoralizing them). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 45 Perestroika (economic restructuring) and glasnost (openness) delegitimized authority Late 1980s & early 1990s: murders, bribery, corruption, & other registered crime increased considerably. Organized crime controlled 20% of new enterprises in the 1990s (Eaves). Mayor Sobchak (St. Petersburg): country out of control, because old structures destroyed & new ones not emerged (Eaves 1992). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 46 Decontrol of economic activity New opportunities shielded illegal activity, such as asset-stripping & favorable buyouts under rubric of privatization. Thousands of mafia gangs had connections to major sections of government bureaucracy. Mafia increased cost of business & discouraged foreign investment. Will liberalization contain mafia & shadow economy or make it difficult for Russian entrepreneurs to survive? Boundary between criminal & legal business activity is hazy. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 47 4. Distorted information Late 1980s, culminating in 1991: rulers no longer collected information about economic opportunities, enforced planning preferences, or received feedback on performance. Why? Officials & subordinates withheld, distorted, or manipulated information for their own advantage. Scarcity of information during 1990s. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 48 Enterprise monopolies 1991: 77% of 7664 product groups produced by single firms. Average Russian firms employed 800 workers, much larger than West or Poland. To avoid turnover taxes, Russian firms highly vertically integrated & plagued by gigantimania. Suppliers were monopolists, bargaining with other monopolists. Critics argue that transitional authorities should have demonopolized, breaking up large industrial concentrations, but difficult to split up. Popov (1996): foreign trade deregulation & currency convertibility would have undermined monopolies. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 49 5. Lack of scarcity prices Soviets allocated resources inefficiently, disregarding scarcity prices. Planners allocated funds bureaucratically, ignoring interest rate in allocating capital. In late 1980s, Russia used 15 X steel, 9 times rubber, & 6 X energy that U.S. did per unit of GDP. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 50 Industrial output value subtractor Meaning, e.g., factories used rubber tires whose world market prices were less than value of raw material embodied in them! No boom in Russian manufacturing since 1991. Russia’s adjustment of industrial output unable to compete at world prices. Russia adjusted less than East-Central Europe, where prices were closer to world level (Popov 1996). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 51 Why wage arrears? Firm negative value added. Demand for hard budget accountability. Many firms returned to barter, paying workers with, e.g., caskets, lingerie, or bricks, the final product. Firms sometimes forced into arrears because other units (government was the worst offender) did not pay their creditors. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 52 Administered prices - Losing farms received subsidies. State farms paid wages similar to factories. Giant state monopoly, Agroprom, which received incredible subsides, hampered agricultural output growth. Wrong (non-market) wage & price signals don’t motivate increased productivity. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 53 6. Overvalued ruble 1991-98. Before 1998, much capital flight In August 1998, ruble lost > 60% of value, triggering immediate inflation and reduction in real output. August 1998 debt default not necessary if Russia had changed exchange rates with inflation. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 54 7. Negative real interest rates Inflation, often > than 100% yearly, was in excess of cost of borrowing. Positive real interest rates would have raised cost of financing stocks & inventories, making rubles worth more than goods, encouraging selling of stocks. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 55 8. Consumer sector as buffers Food & basic consumer goods, which could be reduced, were buffer under planning when higher priority sectors (steel & defense) scarce. Prices at less than market meant long lines, shortages, & low quality, dampening personal incentives & worker productivity. Has taken many years to recover from Soviet lack of investment in food production. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 56 Distortions from inflation Inflation increased 112,000-fold from 1990 to 1994. Inflation driven by excessive credit creation (at 10% interest yearly) to state enterprises. Subsidies were 24.5% of GDP in 1992. Government saved credit system, creating perverse incentives & numerous distortions (but as Popov claimed, inflation & distortion are preferable to civil war). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 57 9. Soft budget constraint - - Lack of financial penalties when enterprises or projects fail. Virtually no firm penalized for losses. Few experienced market’s creative destruction, where industry’s old, high-cost producers are replaced by new, low-cost producers. Banks continued to loan to fellow nomenklatura. Firms entered & exited in no relationship to profitability (Kornai). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 58 How does socialism’s legacy soften firm’s budget limitation 1/ Government grants soft subsidies in response to lobbying or bargaining by influential apparatchiks or officials. 2/ Rules for taxation not uniform. Tax payments can be reduced by pressure & pleading. 3/ Banks tend to loan to firms in trouble or whose managers complain. 4/ Contracts between buyers & sellers are not free, especially when ministries are involved. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 59 Meaning of soft budget constraint Hardness means serious consequences form deficit. Softness arises from external help to protect firm from loss of jobs, redistribution of resources to weak enterprises, & guarantees of security and survival to influentials. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 60 10. Inability to collect taxes - - - After 1991, Russia had difficulty raising revenue. 1/ no longer turnover tax or monopoly from foreign trade earning. 2/ growing size of shadow economy (1/3 of GDP). 3/ refusal of many firms to pay taxes essential for legitimacy & public services. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 61 Revenue decline as proportion of GDP in Russia Tax revenue/GDP declined from 47.2% in 1990 to 26.1% in 1995, lower percentage than in Hungary, Estonia, & Ukraine, and much lower than OECD countries. Although health care, education, other social spending, & defense were cut dramatically in 1990s, most government programs were kept half-alive, halffinanced, & barely working (Popov 1996). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 62 11. “Torn” safety net Soviet legacy of “company town,” in which Russian employers provides apartment space, land for house & vegetables, medical care, schools, specialized advanced education, subsidized cafeterias & buffets, recreational facilities, travel, vacation sanatoria, & food, clothing, & hardware stores. Welfare system was linked to the enterprise. After communism’s collapse, firm owners reluctant to dismiss employees. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 63 12. Increase in inequality & poverty After 1991, inequality increased greatly (Gini=45.6 in 2000). Wage earners, pensioners, & government officials without access to wealth in private sector were hurt in shift to market, especially with hyperinflation. Tuberculosis, typhoid fever, & cholera, virtually eliminated, reappeared in early 1990s. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 64 13. Lack of market institutions Collapse of state & non-state institutions without replacement. Reflection of collapse of institutions: dollarization, barterization, poor enforcement of contracts & law, increased crime (Popov). Land property rights poorly established. Farming population resisted privatization. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 65 14. Neglect of services Soviet Union overindustrialized, neglecting services. Services replaced slowly. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 66 15. Lack of technological progress Soviets’ low (negative in late 1980s) total factor productivity growth because of exhaustion of input growth. Khrushchev: bureaucrats do not want to change from old nag to race horse, as he might tear away on turn & spill them out of the sleigh. Soviet managers resisted innovation, as resources for it threatened plan fulfillment. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 67 16. Military-industrial complex Unprecedented peacetime cost of military expenditures in 1970s, 1980s, & early 1990s. Russia’s military contributed twice the share of GDP of U.S. in late 1990s. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 68 17. Environmental degradation Major contributor to fall in life expectancy: 70 in 1978-92 to 65 in 19942003. Feshbach-Friendly: Soviet Union died by ecocide through plundering rich natural resources & systematic neglect & poisoning of Soviet people. Chernobyl (1986) & seas & lakes poisoned. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 69 18. Collapse of trade among communist countries Russia’s trade with Eastern Europe fell by 1989 (when most East-Central European countries started transition) to 1990 by > 50%. Inter-republic trade in former Soviet Union (FSU) fell by 46% from 1991 to 1992. Popov (1996) argues that the collapse of interCOMECON & inter-republican trade was a result of changes in relative prices, meaning fuel importing countries could no longer finance trade deficits with Russia. Popov estimates supply shocks triggered 40% decline in GDP. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 70 Initial Conditions: Liberalization, Institutions, & Democratization: A Summary Angjellari’s econometric analysis (2003) identifies initial conditions, institutional development, democratization, & liberalization as major variables explaining differences in real GDP growth among 25 transitional countries (5 growing & 20 declining) of the former Soviet Union & East-Central Europe in the 1990s. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 71 Russia’s legacy of the Soviet period: initial conditions in 1991 Distorted incentives & price signals. Party & state monopoly. Inconsistencies under openness & decontrol. Distorted information. Enterprise monopoly. Lack of scarcity pricing. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 72 Russia’s legacy Consumer sectors as buffers. Soft budget constraints. Lack of market institutions. Neglect of services. Lack of technological progress.. Burden of military-industrial complex Degraded environment. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 73 Important factors affecting Russia’s economic performance by period Initial conditions important in early 1990s. Slow progress in liberalization & marketization important in early & middle 1990s. Slow institutional development important in later 1990s. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 74 Little progress in institutional development in late 1990s in Russia Development of markets: antitrust protection. demands for high budget constraints. creative destruction of inefficient firms. alternatives to nomenklature leadership. capacity to raise taxes. Development of alternative institutions for health & welfare: Institutions to foster technological innovation. Development of accurate data sources. Government agency to support environmental protection (Angjellari 2003). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 75 Democratization important in affecting structural reform (liberalization) & institutional reform (Angjellari 2003) Freedom House (2003) ranks Russia as “partly free,” noting the “powerful oligarchic interest and wide discrepancies in income that have an impact on the rule of law & equal political participation. “Russia has lost considerable ground in its protection of basic political rights & civil liberties over the last seven years, . . . experienc[ing] an overall decline since 1997 in . . electoral process; civil society; independent media; governance; and constitutional, legislative, and judicial frameworks.” CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 76 Russia as “illiberal democracy (Cornia & Popov 2001:17) Moscow-based journalist Masha Gessen (2003) characterizes the Russia of President Vladimir Putin (2000- ) as a “managed democracy.” CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 77 William Smirnov, Deputy Head, Institute of State & Law, Russian Academy of Sciences (2003) Russia, rather than being a “fully-fledged democracy,” is an “electrocracy,” in which the political and business elite isolated themselves from the unwanted part of society. Other stratums became isolated despite their will, mostly because of destitution. Small layers of the elite privatized not only most of the public property, but also huge chunks of state, justice and legal systems. Regional “czars” adopted their own constitutions and decrees.” CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 78 Lack of democratization & development of civil society Civil society: Institutions independent of the state – private and nongovernmental entities such as labor unions, religious organizations, educational and scientific communities, and the media. This lack hampered market & institutional reform, leaving Russia well behind such rapid reformers as Poland, Slovenia, and Hungary. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 79 Poland’s Transition to the Market Poland’s transition from socialism to the market was more successful than Russia’s and may have been more successful than any country of the former Soviet Union and East-Central Europe. Polish success underlines the importance of initial conditions and institutional development. Poland was the earliest transitional economy to stop its slide in output, in 1992, and the first to attain pre-transition GDP, in 1996 (Figure 19-2). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 80 Poland compared to Russia Poland’s history under socialism, only since World War II, was shorter than Russia’s. Russia’s socialism was more centralized and totalitarian than Poland’s was. Poland had sources of opposition to communism in the Roman Catholic Church, (and after 1980) the Solidarity labor union (led by Lech Walesa), and the intelligentsia. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 81 Changes in Poland before 1989 Since 1970, Poland had a gradual disintegration of planning and a parallel reemergence of capitalist markets, changes that made the post-1989 reforms less momentous (Poznanski 1996:ix). Poland’s businesses faced fewer government restrictions and fewer deamdns by bureaucrats for bribes (Raiser 2001:232). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 82 Changes in Poland before 1989 Reforms during the 1980s failed to increase productivity and contributed to a “cataclysmic” balance-ofpayments crisis, but created market institutions that were further strengthened after 1989. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 83 Poland’s changes in 1989 Central planning ended. Prices decontrolled. Legal system established to support decentralized actions of private property owners. Commercial code, company law, and a system of judicial enforcement of contracts from before World War II were established (Sachs 1993:35-78). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 84 Poland’s private sector Agriculture was never collectivized. Outside agriculture, private sector share of GDP was about 35% in 1989 (Raiser 2001:232). By 1991, most of the private sector was indigenous new enterprises and expanded private entities rather than state-owned enterprises that were privatized (Poznanski 1996:240). In the first 30 months after mid-1991, the beginning of stabilization, 700,000 new businesses were started. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 85 Poland’s private sector (cont.) At the end of 1993, half the employment and GDP was in the private sector (Sachs 1993:xii). By 1997, there were 10 legally registered enterprises per 100 persons, close to the Western average, but compared to less than 2 in Russia (Popov 2001:45). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 86 Macroeconomic stabilization Inflation in 1989, with generous wage indexation and credit expansion, was 638%. Deputy Prime Minister Leszek Balcerowicz undertook a plan of macroeconomic stabilization, with a tightening of credit, raising of the discount rate, cessation of cheap credit to industry, devaluation of the zloty, and liberalization of international trade to provide competition to monopolies as prices were decontrolled (Sachs 1993:44-66). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 87 Poland stabilized monetary policy and zloty currency in 1989 Stabilization encouraged trade with Eastern Europe, the Soviet Union, & the West. Prices began to stabilize in 1990-91. Poland reduced the length of transition to world prices, so that the initial depression from changing trade patterns was shorter. Poland’s opening of the market to foreign trade, together with the slashing of subsidies, improved domestic efficiency (Sachs 1993). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 88 Safety net and mass support Social safety net, which included price stabilization, unemployment benefits, job training, health car, and pension guarantees, contributed to greater mass support for reform than in Russia (Sachs 1993). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 89 Debt reduction & stabilization fund Beginning in 1990, US & Western governments, & commercial banks, wrote down debt. DCs established stabilization fund to defend zloty, allowing a fresh start, despite Poland’s external economic crises of the 1980s. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 90 Poland’s integration into EU Membership in EU in 2004 provided additional incentives and support for market and institutional reforms in Poland (and Hungary, Czech Republic, & Slovakia). Poland’s GDP PPP 38% of EU 15 in 2001, Hungary 51%, & Czech Republic 56% (Economist 2001). Recently EU acceding countries hope convergence within EU will occur as fast as that of Greece (1981), Portugal, and Spain (1986). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 91 China’s Economy Long-term growth Brief Summary of Mao’s Economics, 1949-1976 The Transition to a Market Economy, 1979Agricultural Reforms Township & Village Enterprises (TVEs) The Individual Economy Industrial Reforms Poverty, Undernourishment, & Inequality Banking Reform Globalization, International Trade, and Exchange Information Technology Comparing China’s & Russia’s Transition CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 92 China’s long-term growth In 0 CE, China comprised about 26% of the world’s gross domestic product (GDP), the world’s total output of goods & services (Maddison 2001:263). In 1000 CE, 23%; 1500 25%, 1600 29%, 1700 22%, 1820 33%, 1870 17%, 1913 9%. China only surrendered the world’s lead in GDP to the U.S. in the 1890s, when China had the world’s largest population of 380-400 million (Maddison 1997: 114, 182, 190). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 93 China’s long-term growth Currently (2004), China’s GNI or GNP (N for national), at $7,170 billion (purchasing power parity equivalent, PPP), ranks second to the U.S.’s $12,151 billion (PPP), while Japan is 3rd with $3,838 billion, & India 4th with $3,347 billion (World Bank 2006:292-293). Nafziger (2006:73) projects that (assuming 2% annual growth for the U.S. and 5% for China, including Hong Kong) China will become first again in GNP PPP in 2020. China’s 2004 GNP per capita (PPP), at $5,530, ranks 63rd among 134 countries (with data). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 94 Growth since liberation (1949) China, in 1949, was among the poorest countries in the world, with a per capita income estimated to be lower than Africa, India, and the rest of Asia (Maddison 2001:264). China was in the same position in 1973 (ibid.). But by 1998, after two decades of economic reform, China had a higher per capita income than Asia (excluding Japan), & a per capita income more than double those of India & Africa. See slide 20’s table for annual growth in GNP per capita (PPP). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 95 Summary of Mao’s Economics Mao stressed prices determined by state; state or communal ownership of means of production; international & regional trade and technological self-sufficiency; noneconomic (moral) incentives; “politics” (not economics) in command; egalitarianism; socializing the population toward selflessness; continuing revolution (opposing an encrusted bureaucracy); & development of a holistic Communist person. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 96 Maoists vs. pragmatists From 1952 to 1966, pragmatists, primarily managers of state organizations and enterprises, bureaucrats, academics, managers, administrators, and party functionaries, vied with Maoists for control of economic decisionmaking. But during the Cultural Revolution, from 1966 to 1976, the charismatic Mao and his allies won out, purging moderates from the Central Communist Party (for example, Deng Xiaoping) to workplace committees. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 97 The Transition to a Market Economy, 1979 After Mao’s death (1976), Chinese leadership, led by Deng, recognized that despite rapid industrial growth under Mao, imbalances remained from the Cultural Revolution, such as: substantial waste amid high investment too little emphasis on consumer goods lack of wage incentives insufficient technological innovation too tight control on economic management taxing of enterprise profits & full subsidy for losses (soft budget constraint) too little international economic trade & relations. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 98 What took place? Annual real (inflation adjusted) growth in GNP p.c. (1973-1998), 5.4%, fastest in the world, continuing through 2005. Wong (2003:113) indicates that China’s annual growth faster than South Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, and Malaysia. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 99 Quality of China’s income data Western economists are skeptical about Chinese data. Summers & Heston (1991:327-368) indicate: “Chinese growth rates are overstated as they are heavily based on growth in physical output figurers rather than deflated expenditure series.” What are the confidence intervals for China’s gross product PPPs? Firebaugh (2003:111) assigns an “F” to Chinese data, with the error rate 50 percent! CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 100 Rawski (2001:347-354), using energy, industry, and agricultural production figures, estimates GDP growth, 1998-2001, at 0.1-2.7% yearly rather than the official 7.7%. Managers & provincial officials understate capacity & overreport production to superiors to receive greater reward received by those who meet or exceed plan fulfillment. Premier Zhu Rongji (2000) complained that “falsification and exaggeration [of economic statistics] are rampant (ibid.). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 101 Young (2003:1220-1261) contends that with “minimal sleight of hand,” you can transform China’s growth from extraordinary to mundane: understatement of industrial enterprise inflation should require downward adjustment by 2.5% yearly, 1978-1998. Maoist China’s health care system, universal albeit at a basic, minimal level, broke down, giving way to a marketized system providing excellent care for the privileged but sometimes very little for the masses (Bhalla 2002:184). Still most economists believe China’s growth under market reforms was rapid but uneven. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 102 Early reform was “socialism with Chinese characteristics,” not capitalism No grand blueprint but 7-8 years of experimentation. Reform step by step, through trial & error, drawing on incremental changes from past. Chinese proverb: “Keep touching stones while walking across a river.” Incremental building in contrast to Russia’s more abrupt strategy (Wang 1994: 14-15, 27, 113). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 103 Chinese characteristics meant: Shrinking state industrial, corporate boards limited in firing managers. Party committees in private enterprises. Entrepreneurs as members of Communist Party. Growing entrepreneurial activity both private & public sectors. Household management of farm plots under longterm contracts with collectives. “Massive changes in economic policy dictated without consultation” (Waldron 2002). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 104 Agricultural Reforms During Maoist era, agricultural growth slower than industrial growth. State transferred surplus from agriculture to state by underpricing agricultural products & overpricing industrial products sold to peasants (Lippit 1987:224). Post-Maoist agricultural reforms had greatest impact on Chinese people, concentrated primarily in countryside. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 105 China’s agricultural reforms, 1979-84 Decontrolled (increased) farm commodity prices. Virtually eliminated farm compulsory deliveries to state. Reduced multi-tiered pricing. Relaxed interregional farm trade restrictions. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 106 China’s agricultural reforms, 1979-84 Encouraged rural markets. Allowed direct sales of farm goods to urban consumers. Decollectivized agriculture, instituting individual household management of farm plots under long-term contracts with collectives & allowing farmers to choose cropping patterns & nonfarm activities (system used previously in 1956 & 1961-64. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 107 Results of agricultural reforms, 1979-84 1977-84: growth in food output per capita, 4.6% yearly, even outstripped by growth in oilseed, livestock & cotton output. Gross ag output increased 9% 1977-84. Reversed pre-1979 dependence on imported grains, exporting corn, other coarse grains, soybeans, & raw cotton, competing with U.S. in Japan & Asia. Achieved without increased farm inputs except chemical fertilizer (World Bank 1986: 104-06; Lichtenstein 1991:60-61). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 108 Dalian harbor corn barge CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 109 Yangtze-Jialing Rivers’ farm trader CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 110 Chongking farm produce trader CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 111 Technical efficiency (total factor productivity, TFP) in China’s agriculture Output per combined factor input fell 1952-1978, but increased 1978-1984, becoming major source of growth. Why? Decollectivization, household responsibility system, linked reward to output, & modest price decontrol increased resource productivity. Work monitoring & incentives improved, agriculture was diversified, & families allocated more labor to highly remunerative noncrop or nonagricultural activities. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 112 After 1984: agricultural growth decelerated 1. 2. 3. Minister of Agriculture He Kang (1989): “situation in agricultural production is grim” (Lichtenstein 1991:61). Most rural areas already captured onetime gains from household accountability. In late 1980s, government reduced massive subsidies, reducing procurement price state paid farmers. In mid-1980s, many farmers awoke to profitable opportunities in rural (township & village) enterprises [TVEs] in industry & trade. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 113 Agricultural growth deceleration 4. Farmers (based on previous volatility & 5. 6. uncertain future) feared reversal in land tenure system. Rural banking infrastructure underdeveloped & politicized, so few loans available at market interest for flourishing households. 1970s government distributed right to communal land in fragmented plots on basis of household size rather than farm management ability, so few highly productive farmers had opportunity to expand (Hardt & Kaufman, Lichtenstein, Putterman, Fewsmith). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 114 In 1990s Agricultural productivity grew rapidly, even when adjusted for gains exaggerated. WTO accession in 2001 increased pressure for further domestic agricultural reform. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 115 Rural population density China population density 10.2 persons per hectare of arable land, twice the EU & 7 X US, but less than Japan & Korea. China’s agricultural comparative advantage in “labor-intensive crops such as fruits and vegetables and a disadvantage in . . . landextensive crops such as grains and oilseeds” (OECD 2002:62). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 116 2003: 61% of China lived in rural areas, partly legacy of Maoist era when migration to urban areas was discouraged. Globalization & structural shifts with economic growth accelerating fall in agriculture’s share of China’s export & migration of surplus farm labor to urban areas, where China has comparative advantage. Also liberalization means farmers face adjustment with competition from other regions (OECD:60-63). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 117 Long-term property rights Are Chinese farmers going to invest & innovate when unsure that their rights to the land are secure? However, in 2004, China’s national legislature amended the constitution to formally protect private rights. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 118 Township & Village Enterprises (TVEs) 1980s TVEs, organized as cooperatives, produced 60-70% of rural output. Enjoyed cheap production factors, primarily cheap labor (with no lifetime employment guarantees as in SOEs), startup capital from collective accumulation, banks, & credit cooperation, & free (sometimes almost unlimited) land. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 119 TVEs Cheap products catered to market, giving TVEs advantage over other sectors (private sector not fully accepted & SOEs not reformed). Business & government functions overlapped & TVEs had no government burden. Flexible: contracts or leasing with other entities, joint-stock cooperatives, limited liability companies, shareholding companies, conglomerates, foreign joint ventures, or conglomerates; or in a few instances privatized. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 120 TVEs Production helped correct price distortions, & pushed reform forward (Lin, Cais, & Li 2003). Outstripped SOEs in productivity (Jefferson 1999:168). 1996: TVEs & other urban collective enterprises comprised 39% of industrial output, growing share since 1985 (Jefferson & Rawski 1999:27). Shared surpluses with workers. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 121 Individual economy Reform included small entrepreneurial activity (individual economy). Cooperatively run enterprises, e.g., TVEs, requiring far less capital per worker than SOEs, precursor of individual economy. After 1976, trigger to urban reform dealing with urban unemployment from youths returning from being “sent down” to learn from peasants in the countryside during the Cultural Revolution. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 122 Youths could not be absorbed in SOEs, overstocked with underemployed workers. Youths & others opened small restaurants, repair shops, other retail outlets, or became pedicab operators (Lippit). Income higher than state sector jobs. Urban consumers could buy produce from farmers coming to cities. China’s privately self-employed in cities & towns (mostly services, commerce, handicrafts, & catering grew from 150,000 in 1978 to about 5-10 million in 1998. In 1996, individual owned firms were > 80% of 8 million enterprises but less than 16% of industrial output (Jefferson & Rawski). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 123 CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 124 Industrial reforms: greater specialization Mao’s self-reliance fostered provincial protectionism. 1979 reforms contributed to substantial gain to specialization from reducing regional protectionism. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 125 State-owned enterprises (SOEs) reform Initially SOE reform emphasized more effective state control rather than efficiency, profitability, or privatization. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 126 Management responsibility system (MRS) failed to achieve goals MRS: manager’s task carefully defined & performance determines managers’ & workers pay; reforms were to give enterprise management much autonomy in suppliers, hiring & firing labor, setting prices, raising capital, & contract with foreigners. Management responsible for success or failure of enterprise. Producers undertake initiative & decisions, not government CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 127 Few managers opt for MRS (early in 1980s) Not enough discretion to have responsibility for success or failure. Not enough food & consumer goods to reward higher productivity of managers & workers. Central planners and banks (later regional) made decisions of amount of output, inputs. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 128 Multiple levels of controls at different levels of govt, numerous overlapping authorities for project control, & fragmented administrative control: Chinese terms “too many mothers-inlaw” (SOE, Qingdao Forging Machinery Plant (1980s), responsible to national Ministry of Machine Industry, city materials board, county for material supplies, municipal machine industry office for plant production, country planning agency for output value, county agencies for supplies from the plant, two separate county agencies for personnel, & county committee for petty matters, immersed in implementing policies (Guangliang). What room did manager have left for rewards and incentives for performance? CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 129 Managers little control over performance in early reform planning system Planning not integrated or coherent. Targets not consistent. Investment decisions bureaucratized & politicized (not based on returns or profitability). State gave managers production plans & designated product recipients – little room for initiative or innovation. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 130 Redeeming feature: plan not as rigid in practice as in theory – prevented Chinese state sector from grounding to a halt. Manager spent time negotiating special deals with planning bureaucracy & other managers. Premium on “back door” deals not organizing labor & other inputs more efficiently. Manager saving money of little use for success because manager could borrow money cheaply from the People’s Bank or take funds from enterprise’s net income. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 131 Managers tried to increase profits in instances when they could keep a larger & more predictable portion of them and use them for bonuses for them & workers, rather than turning profits over to the state budget (Perkins). Profits can guide enterprise behavior efficiently only if they are determined by prices reflecting true economic scarcity. When prices set incorrectly (in early 1980s), they gave wrong signals to enterprises, spurring them to produce too little of what was short and too much of what was in surplus. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 132 For market to have meaning Enterprises must be able to buy productive inputs & sell products on market. Enterprises must be able to retain profits for capital; instead in early 1980s capital was allocated administratively rather than by interest payment or rates of return. Multiple prices by regions should correspond to cost of distances traveled. Enterprises must compete rather than have monopoly control of particular markets. Central planners should not allocate key inputs administratively. No “iron rice bowl,” with enterprise managers little control over paying or hiring labor or firing unproductive workers (lack of safety net increased reluctance to fire workers). “Hard budget constraint” – not negotiating or bargaining for profit & output targets during output year. No subsidizing losses; no politicized bank lending or bank distribution of loans or tax breaks to troubled & powerful enterprises (reality was that successful firms with surpluses infused life into failing firms). Enterprises need scope to search market for cheapest input cost combination. Firm free of fear of worker unrest & widespread wage pressures & agitation from increased food prices & craving for consumer goods. No “whipping the fast ox” – enterprise deliberately slowing down operations to avoid increased target in subsequent year. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 133 Later improvements in reforms 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. By late 1980s & 1990s, more managers adopted reforms: Wrenching industrial recession of 1980-81 & observation that smaller & private firms took advantage of opportunities offered by the market (Jefferson & Rawski 1999a:84). Buyers’ market from increases in supply of light industry & consumer goods. Key management reform expanded right of firm to increasing share of profits. By 1990s, profit not plan fulfillment became SOE’s prime motivator (as government reduced industrial products subject to compulsory planning). Slowdown in revenue growth hardened budget constraints of officials & bankers, “sending enterprises to market” (Jefferson & Rawski 1999). Increasing right to sell products outside plan. Increased competition shown by industrial concentration ratios lower in China than in Japan or US (ibid.). Contract responsibility enabled firms to retain all or increasing share of above-quota profits. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 134 Overall increased competition in 1990s & early years of 21st century SOE reforms plus competition and increased share from joint ventures, private enterprises, & collective enterprises increase efficiency. SOE share of industrial output fell from 80% in 1978 to 55% in 1990 to 43% in 1994 to 28% in 1996 (ibid). Still SOEs dominated heavy industry, industry employment (35%), and bank loans (50%). Most SOEs were still losing money in 2004-06. Can China change ownership rights without experiencing waste from privatization by insiders, creating billionaire oligarchs, as in Russia? Privatization slower in China than Russia. Nolan thinks China lacks truly competitive global firms so that, from a global perspective, China’s “industrial policy of the past two decades must be judged a failure.” CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 135 Poverty, inequality & undernourishment Mao’s rhetoric emphasized egalitarianism & building up “weakest link,” but inequality in range comparable to Bangladesh & Sri Lanka. China’s rural & urban inequalities were low, but urban bias policies widened ruralurban inequality so it was higher than India’s. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 136 Deng Xiaoping: “To get rich is glorious” Repudiation of Mao. Urban inequality rose from 1988 to 1995, primarily where economic reform increased income & widened inequality in coastal regions & in nonstate sector. Rural inequality increased because of wage & business income’s increased importance (Knight & Song (2001:117-18). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 137 China high in income inequality 1980s & 1990s: China one of the more unequal countries in Asia & among LDCs (Riskin, Renwei, & Shi 2001:3). Gini coefficient of household income per capita rose from 38% to 45% 1988 to 1995 (Knight & Song 2001:84). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 138 Poverty fell Rural poverty: 1978 (33%) to 1984 (11%). Urban poverty: 1981 (1.9%) to 1984 (0.3%). Poverty reduction from 1984 through early 1990s stopped falling in rural, & slowed in urban China, despite rapid growth. Income inequality increased 1985 to 2001 in both rural & urban areas, but largest contributor was widening rural-urban gap. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 139 How to reverse increasing income inequality & end of significant poverty reduction in late 1980s & 1990s. 1. Pay more attention to rural economic development. 2. Social security policy for unemployed, sick, & aged. 3. More investment in basic education & human capital. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 140 Affecting income inequality & poverty 4. Personal income taxes to redistribute income (small percentage of urban workers pay tax). Improve tax collecting capacity. 5. Reduce subsidies & benefits for highincome groups in urban areas. 6. Increase labor mobility, especially ruralurban (Renwei 2001:40-42). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 141 Gender inequality “Missing women” – female deficit (94 female, 100 male) because of bias in nutrition & health care favoring males; & job, education, & economic discrimination. Only small fraction due to female infanticide & fetal sonogram identification. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 142 Food in China During the Chinese Cultural Revolution (1966-76), some Western economists accepted the official claim that the country had no malnutrition. Imfeld (1976:157) maintained that “in contrast to India, China has eliminated hunger. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 143 China v. India Food production per capita in China fell more than 12% between the 1930s & late 1970s. Food production per capita in China grew slightly faster than in India, 1952-84. However pre-reform (1954-77), India’s average food output (0.4% p.a.) grew faster than China’s (0.3% p.a.), although China’s absolute level was higher, & the percentage malnourished was lower, than India. Post-reform China’s food output per capita growth outstripped India’s 4.6% to 3.0 p.a., 1977-84. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 144 Annual figures based on 5-year moving average that avoids influence from abnormal change. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 145 Nobelist A.K. Sen: India v. China Having enough to eat depends on society’s system of entitlement (rights & opportunities a person possesses). One-third 1/3 of Indian population goes to bed hungry every night & suffers regular deprivation; India takes nonacute endemic hunger in stride. India, however, provide entitlements to avoid severe famine through food imports, redistribution, & relief. India’s democracy means that crusading newspapers or effective political opposition pressure prevent severe famine. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 146 Food: India v. China Maoist China was opposite. In a normal year, China’s poor were better fed. However, during a famine that increased malnutrition & mortality in China from 1959 to 1961 (fig. 7-2) , political pressure for agriculture success made local officials unwilling to report food shortages (Sen, World Bank, Lardy). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 147 Banking reform China no capital market before 1978: SOEs & other firms financed investment from retained profits, interest-free budgetary grants, & loans from state-owned banks. China’s banks were “appendages of government” in which bank managers were rewarded on party loyalty (Lardy 1998; Economist 2004). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 148 Nonperforming loans/deposits are 30% Result of years of politically motivated lending. Lardy (2004) thinks government cannot bail out banks yet, as they will soon return to an unsustainable debt position unless “they can operate on a commercial basis.” Free convertibility of yuan will put pressure on China’s banks, requiring higher interest rates to prevent depositors from fleeing to higher-yielding foreign assets (Lardy). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 149 Increasing international trade & exchange During Maoist period, China stressed selfsufficiency. In 1960, amid an ideological dispute, the Soviets canceled contracts & pulled out materials, spare parts, and blueprints from aid projects & joint ventures in China, leaving bridges & buildings half built (although China finished the projects). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 150 1977: China opened door toward world market Recognition of cost of technological self-reliance. China stressed basic studies, application of science & technology, & learning foreign technology through sending students to foreign academic institutions, absorbing foreign production techniques suitable to China’s conditions, & raising skills of Chinese workers, technicians, & managers (Beijing Review 1998). In 2001, China joined World Trade Organization, which applies to countries where market prices are the rule. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 151 Special economic zones (SEZs), 1979-80 Export processing zones for foreigners to set up enterprises, hire labor, & import duty-free goods for processing & reexporting. Foreign investors received preferential tax rates, reduced tariffs, flexible labor & wage policies, more modern infrastructure, & less bureaucracy than elsewhere in China. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 152 2001 foreign direct investment (FDI) flows to LDCs China $46.8 billion (also $23.8 billion to Hong Kong) of $209.4 billion (UNCTAD 2003). China overtook US as top ranking country in FDI confidence (World Bank 2003). Taiwan citizens heavy investors, especially in electronics, taking advantage of language affinity & cheap labor, usually by entering circuitously through Hong Kong or Macao. Asia Times (2003) estimates that Taiwanese firms in China are responsible for 40% of China’s exports. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 153 FDI composition Overseas Chinese are even more experienced & enterprising than overseas Indians or overseas members of other Asian nations. China also benefited from the fact that Western & Japanese investors feared being excluded from what comprises about 12% of world GNI PPP, & will eventually be the largest market in the world. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 154 FDI composition 85% of FDI flows in 1998 were to relatively prosperous coastal areas, with largest amount in Guangdong Province near Hong Kong (OECD 2001). FDI flows account for about 15% of China’s total capital formation, one of the highest rations among LDCs. 1995: FDI controlled 47% of China’s manufacturing exports & 53% of investment in electronics. FDI firms are much more profitable than domestic firms, especially SOEs (Huang 2001). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 155 Is FDI linked to the indigenous economy? Not an isolated enclave. “Foreign firms, especially “joint enterprises have strongly influenced the process of industrial reform by bringing . . . access to offshore pools of funds & intimate knowledge of advanced technology, market intelligence, & management systems into partnership with Chinese enterprise. [These innovations have] begun to ripple through China’s business community through supplier networks, competitive pressures, and the rotation of Chinese personnel to and from foreign-linked enterprises.” (Jefferson & Rawski 1999:40). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 156 Global production networks (GPNs) China, even more than other LDCs, boosted exports by participation in GPNs dominated by DCs such as the US & Japan. Exports of US affiliates as a percentage of China’s exports were 36% in 1998. Figure 15-8 shows US affiliate percentages in other Asian countries, Mexico, Canada, & all countries with US affiliates in 1982 & 1998. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 157 CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 158 China as source for FDI US has both largest inward & outward flows of FDI in 2001. When Hong Kong is included, China ranked 2nd in 2001 in inward flows (or 1st in LDC inflows). The world’s potentially largest markets & low-cost labor intensive production in China has become the world’s major industrial workshop, attracting many MNCs. Most of the world’s business community believes that no one could afford to ignore the enormous investment opportunities in China. But China is a hard bargainer, demanding total access to foreign technology in exchange for access to its market (Kranhold 2004). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 159 CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 160 China in global production networks GPNs enable production to be broken into discrete stages, each performed in countries best suited for the stages. Frequently, China and other LDCs undertake production activities requiring low-skilled labor, a low-tech component of a high-tech good. However, China has doubled global production sharing from 1980 to 1998, as indicated by the doubling of imported inputs into a unit of export. China has negotiated favorable joint ventures & technology transfers, enabling learning gains to be captured in domestic enterprises independent of the foreign MNC (World Bank Group 2004). CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 161 China produces highest stages In some instances, China, having begun with the lower-added steps, has decided to produce the highest stage in China. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 162 CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 163 Comparing China’s & Russia’s Transitions to the Market 1. 2. Nolan (1995) explains why China’s economic growth and reforms were successful compared to Russia: China’s pursued economic reforms while avoiding political liberalization (similar to East Asian fast-growing economies; and China’s step-by-step approach to economic reform, rejecting “shock therapy,” especially as practiced by the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 164 Nolan on Russia Nolan shows how Russia’s efforts at glasnost (openness) and democratization destroyed the old state apparatus while failing to construct an effective successor state, thus engendering an economic collapse. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 165 Ross’s (1994) rules for liberalization 1. 2. 3. Decontrol prices, marketize, & privatize when you have competitive sectors, such as China’s agricultural sector. Maintain controlled prices where you have monopolistic and oligopolistic sectors, as in China’s industrial sector. Only decontrol industrial prices when you can provided international competition. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 166 China’s success relative to Russia In agriculture, China decollectivized much more successfully than Russia, which stifled private initiative and marketization. In industry, China encountered many of the same stubborn interests opposing liberalization. China, while suffering from corruption, resisted Russia’s asset stripping & favorable buyouts of state industrial enterprises from apparatchiks. Still China’s path toward reform by “touching stones while walking across a river” could be imperiled by instability during the early decades of the 21st century. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 167 Lessons for LDCs LDCs should not follow the path of Russia or China to reform, although LDCs can learn lessons from Russia and China. Each developing country needs to find its own path toward adjustment and development. CHAPTER 19 ©E.Wayne Nafziger Development Economics 168