Paths and Forks or Chutes and Ladders?: Negative Feedbacks and the Dynamics of Pension Regime Change Kent Weaver Georgetown University and the Brookings Institution Policy Regimes, defined: • A system of organizing, financing and delivering policy that: – Has a distinctive distribution of costs and benefits – Is relatively stable over time Examples: • • • • The German pension system The U.S. health care system Cheap energy policies “Socialism market economy” in China The Questions: 1. How frequent is a major change in policy regimes? 2. How much do past choices constrain the range of future regime options? Do policymakers have significant discretion in shifting policy regimes? Is the best metaphor for policy regime transitions… Paths and Forks? Old 103 Path Choice at Some Times and Not at Others? Cul-de-sac or “No Exit”? Boomerang or policy reversal? ..or Driving off a Cliff? Cul-de-sac: Regime Type at t1 Regime Type 1 Regime Type 2 Regime Type 3 Regime Type 4 Regime Type 5 Regime Type 6 Regime Type 7 Regime Type at t2 Unconstrained choice: Regime Type at t1 Regime Type 1 Regime Type 2 Regime Type 3 Regime Type 4 Regime Type 5 Regime Type 6 Regime Type 7 Regime Type at t2 Paths and Forks: Regime Type at t1 Regime Type 1 Regime Type 2 Regime Type 3 Regime Type 4 Regime Type 5 Regime Type 6 Regime Type 7 Regime Type at t2 Chutes and Ladders: Regime Type at t1 Regime Type 1 Regime Type 2 Regime Type 3 Regime Type 4 Regime Type 5 Regime Type 6 Regime Type 7 Regime Type at t2 Mixed Patterns Across Regimes: Regime Type at t1 Regime Type 1 Regime Type 2 Regime Type 3 Regime Type 4 Regime Type 5 Regime Type 6 Regime Type 7 Regime Type at t2 More choice at t1: Regime Type at t1 Regime Type 1 Regime Type 2 Regime Type 3 Regime Type 4 Regime Type 5 Regime Type 6 Regime Type 7 Regime Type at t2 Regime Type at t3 More choice at t2: Regime Type at t1 Regime Type 1 Regime Type 2 Regime Type 3 Regime Type 4 Regime Type 5 Regime Type 6 Regime Type 7 Regime Type at t2 Regime Type at t3 Boomerang: Regime Type at t1 Regime Type 1 Regime Type 2 Regime Type 3 Regime Type 4 Regime Type 5 Regime Type 6 Regime Type 7 Regime Type at t2 Regime Type at t3 3. What factors determine whether policy regime change occurs? The Conventional (Piersonian) Wisdom: • Once policies are in place they are generally reinforced by: – – – • Adaptive expectations and sunk costs (lock-in effects) Political support coalitions that grow up around the policies Multiple veto points in political systems So policy regime change mostly results from exogenous shocks A Framework for Explaining Policy Regime Change: Much policy regime change has endogenous roots, and depends on: • Balance between positive and negative feedbacks from existing policy • Incremental reform options available to policymakers—and whether they have been exhausted • Regime transition opportunities available to policymakers A Quick Overview of Pension Policy in Wealthy Countries OECD countries vary substantially in what they spend on pensions Pension systems vary substantially across countries in their impact on poverty Most western countries face a severe decline in the ratio of workers to retirees…. ….that gets worse the further out projections are made And many countries have experienced falls in labor force participation for older men…. Male Labor Force Participation Rates age 60 to 64 c. 1980 and 1999 (approx.) 100 90 1980 86.4 1999 80 70 68.8 65.9 57.4 60 50 46.6 55.5 52.2 60.4 54.8 45.7 44.2 39.1 40 30.3 30 31.7 29.1 16.4 20 10 0 Canada France Germany Italy New Zealand Sweden United Kingdom United States Source: Social Security Administration, An Aging World, 2001. The initial year is 1981 for Canada and New Zealand, 1982 for France. The final year is 1996 for France. …while levels for older women are lower and show more uneven trends Female Labor Force Participation Rates age 60 to 64 c. 1980 and 1999 (approx.) 100 90 1980 1999 80 70 60 46.5 41.4 50 40 30 38.8 34 32.5 28.3 26 20 27.8 24.7 22.3 15.2 13 12.7 8 8.1 10 11.7 0 Canada France Germany Italy New Zealand Sweden United Kingdom United States Source: Social Security Administration, An Aging World, 2001. The initial year is 1981 for Canada and New Zealand, 1982 for France. The final year is 1996 for France. A variety of incremental policy responses have been tried to address pension funding issues: • Refinancing – Increase payroll tax base and rates – Add dedicated revenue sources or increase general revenue subsidies • Retrenchment – Change indexation formulas – Punish early retirement – Increase retirement ages But what about more fundamental reforms―shifts in pension regimes? The Questions on Pension Regime Change: • How frequent is a major change in pension policy regimes? • How much do past choices constrain the range of future pension regime options? Do policymakers have significant discretion in shifting pension policy paths? • What are the forces that determine whether pension regime changes occur? The Convention Wisdom on Pension Regime Change Categorizing Pension Regimes: • Welfare states can be divided into three categories – Universal/citizenship regimes (Scandinavia) – Social insurance “Bismarckian” regimes (continental Europe) – Residual regimes (U.K., Canada, United States, Australia) Esping-Andersen, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism The Frequency of Pension Regime Restructuring: • Welfare states have survived recent economic and demographic pressures relatively intact • Pension reform has been largely incremental rather than fundamental “regime change” Myles and Pierson, The New Politics of the Welfare State Explaining Patterns of Pension Restructuring: • “Positive policy feedbacks” limit the pension reform options of policymakers: – Constrain choice sets – Create constituencies who resist any change that would make them worse off • Age and maturity of pension regime matter (e.g., “double payment problem”) A Revised Approach Categorizing Pension Regimes: • Esping-Andersen’s tripartite categories are overly broad and misleading, e.g.: – Residual category is overly broad mixture of • means-tested • “Bismarckian Lite” • mixed regimes with distinctive challenges and regime transition opportunities – New “Notional Defined Contribution” (NDC) pension has different challenges and transition opportunities from continental/Bismarckian regimes Recategorizing Pension Regimes: – Universal/citizenship regimes (New Zealand) – Social insurance “Bismarckian” regimes (continental Europe) – “Bismarckian Lite” regimes (U.S.,Canada) – NDC regimes (Sweden, Italy) – Residual regimes (formerly Australia) – Mixed regimes (U.K., Netherlands, Switzerland, Denmark) – Privatized regimes (none among rich countries) Pension Regime Transitions 1950 1974 1985 1995 NDC Bismarckian Bismarckian Lite Universal Mixed Residual Asterisk indicates that a country has added a small mandatory or quasi-mandatory defined contribution individual account tier. 2009 Sweden * Italy * Germany * Austria France U.S. Canada N.Z.* Ireland Denmark Switz. U.K. Neth. Australia Available regime transition options depend on your starting point… Residual (Means-Tested) Pension Regime Transitions 1950 1974 1985 1995 2009 NDC Bismarckian Bismarckian Lite Canada Universal Denmark Mixed Australia Residual Universal Pension Regime Transitions: Early exits and multiple destinations 1950 1974 1985 1995 2009 Sweden * NDC Bismarckian Bismarckian Lite Universal Mixed Residual Asterisk indicates that a country has added a small mandatory or quasi-mandatory defined contribution individual account tier. Canada N.Z.* Ireland Denmark Switz. U.K. Bismarckian Pension Regime Transitions: Very late exits and only 1 destination (plus*) 1950 1974 1985 1995 NDC Bismarckian Bismarckian Lite Universal Mixed Residual Asterisk indicates that a country has added a small mandatory or quasi-mandatory defined contribution individual account tier. 2009 Sweden * Italy * Germany * Austria France “Bismarckian Lite” Pension Regime Transitions: High durability 1950 1974 1985 1995 2009 NDC Bismarckian Bismarckian Lite Universal Mixed Residual U.S. Canada Mixed Pension Regime Transitions: Multiple Precursors, No Exits, and ** 1950 1974 1985 1995 NDC 2009 Sweden * Italy * Germany * Bismarckian Bismarckian Lite Universal Mixed Residual Asterisk indicates that a country has added a small mandatory or quasi-mandatory defined contribution individual account tier. N.Z.* Denmark Switz. U.K. Neth. Australia The Frequency of Pension Regime Restructuring: • Pension regime change is fairly frequent – 9 of 14 countries in sample have at least one – Only four (Sweden, Canada, Denmark and New Zealand) have more than one – Regime reversals (“Boomerangs”) are very rare • Bismarckian systems are beginning to “thaw” with shifts to NDC regimes and addition of small DC tiers • The U.S. is an outlier in having virtually no incremental or regime changes since 1983 Pension Regimes differ substantially in their durability: • “Bismarckian Lite” and mixed regimes are highly durable (cul-desac) in post WW II period • Universal and residual regimes virtually disappeared after World War II, with multiple destinations (paths and forks) • Bismarckian regimes were very durable until mid-1990s when shift to NDC began (precursor to “Chutes and Ladders?”) Pension Regime Restructuring— Timing: • Different types of regime transitions are concentrated in different periods: – Shifts to Bismarckian regimes stop pre1973 – Shifts to mixed regimes concentrated post-1973 – Shifts from Bismarckian to NDC regimes post-1994 (after incremental reform options exhausted) – Individual account account “add-ons” to dominant DB regimes grow beginning in 1990s Argument: Prospects for pension regime change depend on: • The balance of positive and negative feedbacks • The availability and efficacy of incremental reforms to address those challenges • The availability and political acceptability of regime transition options which vary across specific pension regimes Challenge and Change in Bismarckian Pension Regimes Challenges for Bismarckian social insurance systems are severe: • Severe sustainability issues with aging • Need to address problems of low labor market participation in 55-64 age group Male Labor Force Participation Rates age 60 to 64 c. 1980 and 1999 (approx.) 100 1980 90 1999 80 70 65.9 60.4 60 54.8 50 40 44.2 39.1 30.3 30 20 55.5 29.1 32.3 31.7 18.6 16.4 10 0 France Germany Italy US Sweden Belgium Incremental reform options for Bismarckian social insurance systems are limited: • Payroll taxes perceived to hurt competitiveness • Less visible incremental benefit cuts mostly exhausted, leaving only painful options (e.g. retirement ageSocial increase) Security Contributions as % of GDP in 2000 18 16.4 16.1 14.8 16 15 14.1 11.9 14 12.4 12 % 10 8 6.9 6.1 5.1 6 4 2 S U K U en ai n Sw ed et h N Sp s er la nd ly Ita y m an G er ce Fr an da an a C Be lg i um 0 Transition Opportunities for Bismarckian regimes are highly constrained: • Shift to mixed regime regimes unlikely due to double payment problem (only small DC “add-on” possible) • Can’t shift to universal, residual, or Bismarckian Lite regimes because of adequacy concerns • NDC regime is only remaining regime transition option (“single chute”)– and it is a recent innovation Sweden in the 1990s—Policy Feedbacks in a Bismarckian System • Universal pension • Earnings-related pension on top • Generous income-tested pension removes almost all seniors from poverty Sweden-Strong Negative Feedback Effects • Very serious fiscal challenge in both short run and long run as population ages • Very high payroll taxes and overall tax burden spark competition concerns Exhausted Incremental reform options • Strong resistance to payroll tax increases • Strong union resistance to visible benefit cuts Limited Regime Transition Opportunities: • Shift to a Mixed System very difficult given high current commitments and payroll tax • Shift to NDC system compatible with existing earnings-related system Sweden Today—An NDC System with an Individual Account Add-On: • NDC tier financed by 16% contribution rate-- risk of poor economic performance and increased longevity shifted from state to workers • Individual account tier financed by 2.5% contribution rate Challenge and Change in “Bismarckian Lite” Pension Regimes Challenges for “Bismarckian Lite” social insurance systems include: • Developing adequate mechanisms to deal with senior poverty • Adapting to changes in supplementary occupational and personal pension sectors • Addressing long-term pension funding problems in the absence of an immediate funding crisis “Bismarckian Lite” pension regimes contain room for refinancing without restructuring Social Security Contributions as % of GDP in 2000 18 16.1 16.4 16 14.8 15 14.1 11.9 14 12.4 12 % 10 8 6.9 6.1 5.1 6 4 2 S U K U en ai n Sw ed et h N Sp s er la nd ly Ita y m an G er ce Fr an da an a C Be lg i um 0 “Bismarckian Lite” pension regimes have multiple transition opportunities: • Can shift to Bismarckian regime only before demographic crisis hits • Can shift to mixed regime as “addon” with higher contributions • Can shift to NDC regime But also have less need to shift because of availability of incremental reform options United States: Negative Feedbacks • Moderate fiscal challenge in short run and relatively modest in longer run • Adequacy: High senior poverty rates especially very old single women Incremental reform options • Benefit cuts (e.g., retirement age increases and increased income-testing at upper end) • payroll tax increases off the table because of Republican opposition United States: Regime Transition Opportunities • Shift to mixed system inhibited by financing constraints unless new revenues added • NDC system possible but inhibited by internal cross-subsidies unless new revenues added United States Today— “Bismarckian Lite” Stability : Social Security in the U.S.: • Incremental reform in 1977 and 1983 including benefit cuts and increases in standard retirement age • Virtually no policy change since then • Efforts by Bush II to get opt-out individual account reform on the agenda failed Concluding Thoughts 1. How much pension regime change?: • How much regime change you see depends on how you categorize regimes • Tri-partite conceptualization of pension regimes is inadequate • Amount of pension regime change over last fifty years has been substantial in OECD countries 2. Amount and direction of pension policy regime change depends in large part on: • Balance between positive and negative policy feedbacks – Negative policy feedbacks can be strongly transition-encouraging (e.g., affordability of Bismarckian regimes) • Incremental reform options available to policymakers—and whether they have been exhausted • Regime transition opportunities available to policymakers – Only available after invented (e.g., NDC) – Adoption depends in part on political resources 3. Prospects for specific pension regime transitions vary over time (Most common timing of pension regime transitions is shown next time to the corresponding arrow. Pension regimes with a low probability of regime exit in the current “late” period of public pension development are shown with a shaded background) Residual regime early No public pensions early middle or late middle Universal regime middle Mixed regime middle or late middle middle early “Bismarckian Lite”regime middle Bismarckian regime late NDC regime 4. Negative feedback effects are a necessary but not sufficient explanation of pension regime transitions, e.g., why: • Some Bismarckian systems (e.g., Sweden, Italy) shift to NDC while others (e.g., France) do not • New Zealand and Ireland remain outliers as residual systems • Timing differs in regime transitions 5. A broader set of explanations of pension policy regime change includes: Economicdemographic variables (e.g., aging, competitiveness, fiscal crisis Agenda-setting Policy feedbacks (e.g., policy regimes, program maturity, “micro” rules) Political Environments and strategies (e.g.,macroinstitutions, coalitions, corporatism The Problem stream The Policy stream The Politics stream Policy Adoption Policy Implementation Policy survival But examining negative feedbacks is a good place to start! 6. A framework focused on negative feedbacks and reform options has wide applicability— e.g., where Marx and Engels went wrong: Balance of positive and negative feedback effects • Anticipated near-universal immiseration did not occur Incremental Reform Options • Many incremental patches available (e.g., welfare state programs, better regulation of business cycles) • Patches became more politically feasible as voting franchise was expanded Regime Transition Options • High costs of transition • Major opposition from entrenched interests • Socialist and communist alternatives proved to have substantial negative impacts in practice • Redistributive welfare state (with great variations) proved “easier regime transition option The End– Finally!