Indifference Curves • An indifference curve shows a set of consumption bundles among which the individual is indifferent Quantity of Y Combinations (X1, Y1) and (X2, Y2) provide the same level of utility Y1 Y2 U1 Quantity of X X1 X2 Marginal Rate of Substitution • The negative of the slope of the indifference curve at any point is called the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) Quantity of Y dY MRS dX Y1 Y2 U1 Quantity of X X1 X2 U U1 Marginal Rate of Substitution • MRS changes as X and Y change – reflects the individual’s willingness to trade Y for X Quantity of Y At (X1, Y1), the indifference curve is steeper. The person would be willing to give up more Y to gain additional units of X At (X2, Y2), the indifference curve is flatter. The person would be willing to give up less Y to gain additional units of X Y1 Y2 U1 Quantity of X X1 X2 Indifference Curve Map • Each point must have an indifference curve through it Quantity of Y Increasing utility U3 U2 U1 U1 < U2 < U3 Quantity of X Transitivity • Can two of an individual’s indifference curves intersect? Quantity of Y The individual is indifferent between A and C. The individual is indifferent between B and C. Transitivity suggests that the individual should be indifferent between A and B C B A U2 But B is preferred to A because B contains more X and Y than A U1 Quantity of X Convexity • A set of points is convex if any two points can be joined by a straight line that is contained completely within the set Quantity of Y The assumption of a diminishing MRS is equivalent to the assumption that all combinations of X and Y which are preferred to X* and Y* form a convex set Y* U1 X* Quantity of X Convexity • If the indifference curve is convex, then the combination (X1 + X2)/2, (Y1 + Y2)/2 will be preferred to either (X1,Y1) or (X2,Y2) Quantity of Y This implies that “well-balanced” bundles are preferred to bundles that are heavily weighted toward one commodity Y1 (Y1 + Y2)/2 Y2 U1 X1 (X1 + X2)/2 X2 Quantity of X Utility and the MRS • Suppose an individual’s preferences for hamburgers (Y) and soft drinks (X) can be represented by utility 10 X Y • Solving for Y, we get Y = 100/X • Solving for MRS = -dY/dX: MRS = -dY/dX = 100/X2 Utility and the MRS MRS = -dY/dX = 100/X2 • Note that as X rises, MRS falls – When X = 5, MRS = 4 – When X = 20, MRS = 0.25 Marginal Utility • Suppose that an individual has a utility function of the form utility = U(X1, X2,…, Xn) • We can define the marginal utility of good X1 by marginal utility of X1 = MUX1 = U/X1 • The marginal utility is the extra utility obtained from slightly more X1 (all else constant) Marginal Utility • The total differential of U is U U U dU dX 1 dX 2 ... dX n X1 X 2 X n dU MUX dX1 MUX dX 2 ... MUX dXn 1 2 n • The extra utility obtainable from slightly more X1, X2,…, Xn is the sum of the additional utility provided by each of these increments Deriving the MRS • Suppose we change X and Y but keep utility constant (dU = 0) dU = 0 = MUXdX + MUYdY • Rearranging, we get: dY dX MU X U / X MU Y U / Y U constant • MRS is the ratio of the marginal utility of X to the marginal utility of Y Diminishing Marginal Utility and the MRS • Intuitively, it seems that the assumption of decreasing marginal utility is related to the concept of a diminishing MRS – Diminishing MRS requires that the utility function be quasi-concave • This is independent of how utility is measured – Diminishing marginal utility depends on how utility is measured • Thus, these two concepts are different Marginal Utility and the MRS • Again, we will use the utility function utility X Y X Y 0.5 0.5 • The marginal utility of a soft drink is marginal utility = MUX = U/X = 0.5X0.5Y0.5 • The marginal utility of a hamburger is 0.5Ymarginal utility = MUY = U/Y =0.50.5X 0.5 0.5 dY MU X .5 X Y Y MRS 0.5 0.5 dX Uconstant MUY .5 X Y X Examples of Utility Functions • Cobb-Douglas Utility utility = U(X,Y) = XY where and are positive constants – The relative sizes of and indicate the relative importance of the goods Examples of Utility Functions • Perfect Substitutes utility = U(X,Y) = X + Y Quantity of Y The indifference curves will be linear. The MRS will be constant along the indifference curve. U3 U1 U2 Quantity of X Examples of Utility Functions • Perfect Complements utility = U(X,Y) = min (X, Y) Quantity of Y The indifference curves will be L-shaped. Only by choosing more of the two goods together can utility be increased. U3 U2 U1 Quantity of X Examples of Utility Functions • CES Utility (Constant elasticity of substitution) utility = U(X,Y) = X/ + Y/ when 0 and utility = U(X,Y) = ln X + ln Y when = 0 – Perfect substitutes = 1 – Cobb-Douglas = 0 – Perfect complements = - Examples of Utility Functions • CES Utility (Constant elasticity of substitution) – The elasticity of substitution () is equal to 1/(1 - ) • Perfect substitutes = • Fixed proportions = 0 Homothetic Preferences • If the MRS depends only on the ratio of the amounts of the two goods, not on the quantities of the goods, the utility function is homothetic – Perfect substitutes MRS is the same at every point – Perfect complements MRS = if Y/X > /, undefined if Y/X = /, and MRS = 0 if Y/X < / Nonhomothetic Preferences • Some utility functions do not exhibit homothetic preferences utility = U(X,Y) = X + ln Y MUY = U/Y = 1/Y MUX = U/X = 1 MRS = MUX / MUY = Y • Because the MRS depends on the amount of Y consumed, the utility function is not homothetic Important Points to Note: • If individuals obey certain behavioral postulates, they will be able to rank all commodity bundles – The ranking can be represented by a utility function – In making choices, individuals will act as if they were maximizing this function • Utility functions for two goods can be illustrated by an indifference curve map Important Points to Note: • The negative of the slope of the indifference curve measures the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) – This shows the rate at which an individual would trade an amount of one good (Y) for one more unit of another good (X) • MRS decreases as X is substituted for Y – This is consistent with the notion that individuals prefer some balance in their consumption choices Important Points to Note: • A few simple functional forms can capture important differences in individuals’ preferences for two (or more) goods – Cobb-Douglas function – linear function (perfect substitutes) – fixed proportions function (perfect complements) – CES function • includes the other three as special cases