1st and 2nd Lectures, STV4346B: “Introduction to Comparative Political Economy: Approaches, theory and methodology” (some of the slides will probably be skipped in class and used in seminars 1 and 2) Carl Henrik Knutsen, Department of Political Science, UiO 10/11 and 13/11-2008 1 Politics and the economy Political institutions and processes Economic structures and processes ”Z-variables”: Geography, culture etc 2 Topics for the course Methodology and theory Different traditions of political economy Basic rational choice/microeconomics + other theoretical approaches Statistical techniques/econometrics Substance, general Allocation of resources; states and markets. Positive and normative issues. The interaction among: Politicians, bureaucrats, voters, consumers and producers. The economic factors that influence regime change and regime stability (mainly democracy) The economic effects of political institutions Substance, specific (with geographic focus) 3 Varieties of capitalism, fiscal policy, economic voting Industrial policy, land reform, the effects of inequality Neo-patrimonialism, corruption, natural resources Practical advice Read through everything once, quickly ..Then selective reading Read all abstracts at least four times Know thy lecture notes Systematize the readings into a broader framework Don’t get bogged down in details. Focus on concepts, general arguments (theoretical) and general empirical findings. 4 The exam Approximately: 5 25%: Short questions: Concepts, sketch out theory quickly, empirical findings 25%: Short essay: Related to 2-3 concrete contributions from reading list. 50%: Long essay (choice between two alternatives) Political economy Empirical interrelations between economy and politics We need theoretical and methodological frameworks that are able to deal with such interrelations: Political economy. Political economy: different meanings for different groups of academics and different traditions. My view: They are not as incompatible as they might look. Don’t pick your favorite! Choice of framework depends on research question and focus. 6 Thematical and methodological definitions of political economy Methodological definitions: Study of politics with the tools of an economist (political economics) Study of economics with the tools of a political scientist, focus on power etc, qualitative methodology. Thematical definition (favored in this course) Political economy is the study of the interrelations between political institutions and processes and economic structures and processes. 7 No restrictions on methodology or theoretical approach; in this course we will be eclectic. The definition is very general! Specifications will be made at the topic level Definitions continued COMPARATIVE political economy: comparative studies of political-economic interrelations. Differences in political institutions Differences in economic effects. Differences in economic structures Different effects on politics. Focus on the national level. Even though we are here operating with a broad definition of political economy, we need to know the various definitions and political economic theories in the literature to not be confused when reading. 8 State-centered political economy (C&L: 8) Key point of departure: Other political economy approaches have underappreciated the importance of the state. State as independent actor or (at least) state structures matter for political and economic outcomes. States are not only vehicles for social interests. Sharp separation state and private sphere/society (including economic actors). Politics conducted mainly within state-structures. States as actors: “State’s interests”. Some go even further: states assumed to follow “national interests” (whatever this means). Metaphysical description or analytical simplification? My view: States are not actors metaphysically, but we can model the state as an actor in some instances for analytical simplification. 9 State autonomy State autonomy is the key concept in much of this literature. “State autonomy… refers to the ability of the state to define and pursue an agenda not defined for it solely by private interests” (C&L:181) Ability to pursue own agenda and not be trumped by societal pressures, private interests when formulating public policy. Specifications: If we do not buy that the state is an independent actor, how do we think of state autonomy? Contrast with C&L’s Utilitarian and Marxist approaches. State officials and bureaucrats as autonomous? But why do these not act in private interest? Rules, regulations and norms matter. These are created through the years and are results of long processes. Norms and rules can be intentionally created by private actors, but not always. Often: gradual modification of rules and norms, and strong inertia in institutional structures. For analytical purposes therefore, we can often (but certainly not always!) take the rules and norms as given. Contrast with endogenous institutions and regulation. Degrees of state autonomy rather than either-or. Determinants of state autonomy: power concentration, checks and balances, structure of bureaucracy, nature of social interest groups. 10 The State, a special organization Monopoly of force within defined boundaries (Weber) Ability to make binding decisions on issues which private actors cannot (laws and regulation) Ability to tax Implementor of policy 11 Some approaches in C&L (read quickly through 184-196) Statism and national interest (Krasner) States define (and act upon) national interest Transformational view of state (Skocpol among others) 12 Differences in state’s organizational structure impacts policy outcomes even when initiative from private sphere State affects private agendas and make-up of social groups State as historical specific organizational structure Rational choice A theory of human action Optimal choice under constraints Preferences are exogenously given Predictable irrationality from behavioral economics: 13 Beliefs/understanding of probabilities, some systematic biases Loss aversion, reference points Time preferences and hyperbolic discounting Reciprocity rather than self-interest? Bounded rationality (Simon) Rational choice A “deceptively simple sentence” that summarizes the theory of rational choice: “When faced with several courses of action, people usually do what they believe is likely to have the best overall outcome” (Elster, 1989:22) 1) Thin and 2) instrumental rationality: 14 Ad 1) No initial requirements on what type of goals that should be pursued. Ad 2) Actions are chosen because of intended consequences. Actions are not valued because of themselves (contrast with Kant) Przeworski (ch 1) Decentralized and centralized allocation mechanisms – final allocation results from decisions by many agents vs allocation depends on one decision. Examples: Decentralized: Grab all you can, market exchange Centralized: Dictator’s allocation, voting, lottery Does the allocation mechanism result in an equilibrium outcome (no one has incentive to deviate). Descriptive question. Does the allocation result in a Pareto Optimal outcome? Normative criterion. Is the allocation equitable? Normative criterion. 15 Przeworski cont’d State vs market as a too crude dichotomy. More fruitful questions: What are the properties of an allocation mechanism? How are states and markets organized? Always some role for government. Enforcement institutions must underpin markets. Political economic game: 1) Political actors reveal preferences for policies through menu of actions (votes, bribes, threats etc) 2) State maximizes its objectives (whatever this is), given beliefs of economic actors actions, by setting policy 3)Economic actors max utility (and profit) in markets, given the specific policy chosen Political economic equilibrium: Set of policies by state and political and economic actions by voters/producers/consumers so that no one would act different given beliefs and actions of others. 16 A political economic game of voting and taxation Voter Party A Party B State ”A” State ”B” Tax heavily Tax lightly Tax medium (4, 0) (2,2) 17 (1,3) Political economics (Ch6 in C&L) The Robbins-definition of economics: “The study of human behavior as a relationship between ends and scarce means..” Opens up for studying other aspects of human life than production and consumption of goods Preferences, beliefs and constraints Individually rational behavior Efficiency (or “collective rationality”)? Not necessarily: Depends on interaction structure 18 Holds in perfect markets (invisible hand) Does not hold for example in prisoners’ dilemma games or voting in some instances Normative political economics Normative: Analysis of desirable properties of the political system Condorcet’s paradox Voter 1 A> B> C Voter 2 C> A> B Voter 3 B> C> A Vote on alternatives pairwise: A >B>C>A…… Transitive individual preferences but no transitivity in collective preferences (desired property) 19 Arrow’s impossibility theorem These are incompatible: Non-dictatorship Unrestricted domain Independence of irrelevant alternatives Pareto Efficiency “All voting methods are flawed”. Individual preferences do not add up to consistent social preference ordering. What is the “will of the people”? Ways out of the impossibility theorem: 20 Single-peaked preferences or other restrictions on preferences Agenda control (institutional structure imposed on decision procedure) logrolling Positive political economics Two examples in C&L: Mancur Olson’s “Logic of Collective Action” and Anthony Downs’ “An Economic Theory of Democracy”. Down’s (1957) Foreword: “Downs assume that political parties and voters act rationally in the pursuit of certain clearly specified goals – it is this assumption in fact, that gives his theory its explanatory power” “Starting point” for numerous models on party and voter behavior 21 Assumptions: A Downsian game Democracy Two parties/candidates Goal for parties: Maximize political support (votes) control government. Policy only as a mean for politicians. Goal for voters: Policy (as close as possible to ideal point) Policy is unidimensional on a scale from 0 (left-wing) to 1 (right wing) Voters vote on party that are closest to their ideological preference. They are distributed uniformly on the interval [0,1] Party who wins majority forms government Rational and self-interested voters and parties. No uncertainty in the baseline model. Party cannot deviate from proposed policy once elected. 22 Downsian game continued Strategy sets for two candidates/parties, S1=S2 = [0,1] Choose policy (strategy) within this strategy set; denoted s1 and s2 If s2>s1 all voters to right of (s1+s2)/2 votes for 2 Example 2 chooses policy 0.7, 1 chooses 0.6. All voters to the right of 0.65 votes for 21 wins. Can this be a proper solution to the game? No! This is not a Nash Equilibrium: Player 2 is not playing best response to 0.6. Will win majority if plays for example 0.59 But then 1 will not play a best response.. Can for example choose 0.58 (s1,s2)= (0.5 , 0.5) is the only Nash equilibrium: both strategies are best responses to other. (50% probability of winning when tie). Nobody wants to unilaterally deviate. In equilibrium: Both parties propose the same policy. Policy convergence! 23 What does Downs tell us? Remember that a model is a model. The model can be extended to incorporate uncertainty about positions of the voters, and we can assume that parties are motivated by pushing a specific policy. If so, the convergence result does not necessarily hold. If interested: See my homepage for a presentation of “Games in the Normal Form” for extended models where there is uncertainty and where politicians care about policy (and not number of votes) Simplest possible political economic model of voting and does not describe real-world politics precisely. BUT: Captures central political mechanism: Why did Obama talk more about tax cuts and killing Bin Laden in general election than in primaries? But: What was McCain thinking when going to the right in the general election? 24 Preference requirements and utility functions, rational choice Preference requirements: Actors must be able to rank different outcomes. >, < or =. (Complete preferences) If a>b and b>c a>c (Transitivity) Utility functions: U(x), ordinal level of measurement Note that preferences are exogenous and given. Cost functions: C(x). First-and second order derivatives. U’(x)>0, C’(x)>0, U’’(x)<0 and C’’(x)> = or < 0 (depends on productiontechnology) Optimization (minimize or maximize): Differentiate and set equal to zero. 25 Example: A single market, partial equilibrium One good: x. Price for good x is p. Demand side of the market: Consumers will buy until U’(x)=p because: Supply side of the market: Assume C’(x), the marginal cost, is increasing in x (C’’(x)>0). Producers will supply until C’(x)=p. Because profits π is given by: Max U(x)-px U’(x)-p=0U’(x)=p Π(x) = px – c(x) Π’(x) =0 ↔p=c’(x) Market equilibrium: The price clears the market. Assume one consumer and one producer, both take prices as given. They will both adjust their demand and supply so that U’(x)=p and C’(x)=p U’(x)=C’(x) In equilibrium: Marginal utility of consumption equals marginal cost of production 26 The choice between two goods (Knutsen, 2008a) Max U( x1, x2) Subject to the constraint: p1 x1 + p2 x2 = m, where m is income U( x1, x2) = U( x1, m/p2 - p1/p2*x1) Optimum condition: U’(x1) + U’(x2)*- p1/p2 = 0 U’(x1) /U’(x2) = p1/p2 Marginal rate of substitution is equal to relative prices in optimum It can be shown that also marginal rate of transformation (relative cost of producing two goods on the margin) is equal to relative price ratio: Prices carry information about opportunity costs In equilibrium: Marginal rate of substitution is equal to marginal rate of transformation. Prices enable consumers and producers to adjust so that relative production costs equal relative subjective evaluation of goods. 27 Graphical sketch of general equilibrium Equilibrium relative prices and equilibrium production and consumption of X1 and X2 Indifference curves: combinations of X1 and X2 that yields a particular level of utility X2 Production possibilities set: viable combinations of X1 and X2 -P1/P2 X1 28 Normative criteria for efficiency: Pareto optimality A movement from one allocation to another that can make at least one individual better off without making any other individual worse off is called a Pareto improvement. An allocation is Pareto optimal when no further Pareto improvements can be made; that is, when no one can be made better off without anyone else being made worse off. First welfare theorem: Market equilibrium is Pareto optimal (given a set of conditions) Second welfare theorem: Any Pareto optimal allocation can be supported by a market equilibrium (given set of conditions including cost-free redistributions) 29 When does the first welfare theorem break down? Increasing returns to scale Market power Externalities Public goods Imperfect information Transaction costs Missing markets Property rights are non-existent or poorly enforced 30 Monopoly Market power Ability to influence prices When prices are not taken for given 1st welfare theorem breaks down Why monopoly/oligpoly? Increasing returns to scale: the role of fixed costs (innovation, investment, advertising etc), Regulation differentiated products The monopoly’s profit-maximizing equation Π(x) = p(x)x – c(x) Π’(x)= p’(x)*x + p(x) –c’(x)=0 p’(x)*x + p(x) =c’(x) The monopoly sets x lower than the ”social optimum” (given by c’(x)=p). Intuition: Monopoly reduces supply to keep prices high 31 Externalities (actions with unintended consequences on other actors) Externalities from consumption and production. Both positive and negative externalities Actor does not take ext. into account when making decisions Does not provide the socially optimal amount of consumption/production in free market Examples 32 Effect\Type Consumption Production Positive Education (with knowledge spillover) Innovation (with knowledge spillover) Negative Smoking (health effects) Polluting activities Public goods 1) Non-rivalry: One actor’s consumption does not reduce the utility of another from consuming. 2)Non-excludability: Not possible to stop other actors from consuming. 1) inefficiency in market because of positive externality (does not take into account other actors’ benefits from providing good) 2)Free rider problem. Even if would like to have the public good, hope that others will provide and free-ride. In free market, no one has incentive to supply. Przeworski defines public goods only according to 1). I prefer to call nonrival but excludable goods for club goods. Public goods are defined as nonrival and non-excludable Note that excludability and rivalry are continuous dimensions Degrees of public goods. 33 Neo-classical political economy Role for government and politics when markets fail/market equilibrium is not Pareto-optimal How can government correct the workings of the market? Example 1: Negative externalities Taxation so that the actor bears the full cost (own cost + externality) will act so that optimum is realized Example 2: Assymetric information: Provide regulation, issue standards etc so that f.ex consumers can identify quality of a product in the market Example 3: Public goods: Tax and provide correct amount of public good. Example 4: Increasing returns to scale and natural monopoly: Regulate price The state’s role of securing property rights to ensure voluntary exchange. 34 Some criticisms of NCPE Keynes (1936) and inherent rigidities of the market. Slow adjustment towards equilibrium and the benefits of activist macroeconomic policy. Schumpeter (1942): Dynamic efficiency is not ensured by a statically efficient market (profit goes towards zero). Monopoly/oligopoly surpluses and incentives for innovation. Innovation Long run economic growth. The utilitarian underpinnings. Other important normative concepts than efficiency/PO: distribution and justice. 35 Uncertainty Uncertainty: General lack of knowledge about outcomes. Unproblematic for markets if uncertainty is symmetric (and actors are risk neutral). Instead of maximizing utility: Maximize expected utility! Von Neumann-Morgenstern utility functions: EU(p) = p1u1 + p2u2+…+pnun We can take into account that actors are not risk neutral. Risk aversion, two outcomes: u(px1+(1-p)x2)>pu(x1)+(1-p)u(x2) [u(50)>0.5*u(0)+0.5*u(100)] Means that a risk averse actor would rather take the expected value for certain, rather than gamble between two extremes. 36 Asymmetric information Markets in trouble when there is asymmetric information. Note that governments also would have trouble with asymmetric information. How to make actors reveal their private knowledge is a general phenomenon. However, governments might have other means to deal with such problems 1) Private information about actions, effort 2) Private information about quality, type 1) can lead to so-called “moral hazard” problems 2) can lead to so-called “adverse selection” problems 37 Some concepts Moral hazard: Incentives to act otherwise than agreed upon in contract, due to private information about own actions. Adverse selection: The tendency of an agent (or a good) of a particular type to self-select into a contract in a way not desired by the other contracting party, due to private information about own type (quality). A contractual relation can be modeled as a principalagent relationship. Principal wants a job to be done and agent is assigned to do the job 38 Principal-agent theory Principal wants to maximize profits/utility, and so does agent. Principal moves first, and can post contract as “ultimatum” to agent. When full information: When private info: Principal can design contract so that agent is pushed down to “reservation utility” (indifferent between accepting and rejecting contract). Can also choose to accept only “good” types of agents, or design different contracts to good and bad types. Agent can shirk (moral hazard) to obtain a higher utility, to the despair of the principal. Agents can also pretend to be other types than they actually are to achieve a higher utility (adverse selection). Example: voter-politician as principal-agent. 39 Some solutions for the principal When moral hazard Design contracts that make agents “stake holder” in the outcome. For example: let agent have some of the surplus (part of profit instead of pure wage contract), or threaten to punish if moral hazard is detected/strongly suspected When adverse selection: Design different contracts that make agents self-select into different contracts 40 Impose costs on bad agent or reward good agent for revealing information about type Some comments from Evans (Ch2) “Getting the prices right” as an insufficient approach to development Neoclassical economics and focus static efficiency: What about transformation and dynamic efficiency? Gerschenkron and late developers: Hirschman and late developers: State’s role in amassing capital. State’s role in inducing entrepeneurship The role state institutions for economic development. Structure of state and state-society relations matter. But: rejection of “naïve statism”. 41 Some comments on markets.. Market/economic sphere is embedded in society (Polanyi). Norms and exchange. Granovetter and the non-existence of informalized market exchanges. Trust as crucial to non-contractual exchange. Repeated exchanges between actors that know each other, rather than anonymous one-shot exchanges Transaction costs (Williamson/Coase): In some instances, hierarchies reduce transaction costs related to exchange when compared to markets. 42 Internalization of exchanges within firms and other organizations. Evans cont’d The neo-utilitarian depiction of “state failure” Politicians and bureaucrats as self-interested agents and not as altruistic and omniscient welfare maximizers. Can the people (principal) ensure that the agents (buer and pol) act in their best interest? Capture of state by interest groups Rent seeking: Wasteful use of resources to redistribute gains/affect policy to own benefit Collective action problems Implications: The nightwatchman state? Does the conclusion follow from the premise of state failures? (I don’t think so..) Weber: Bureaucracy and capitalism together: How does the state operate and how does it regulate and interact with the economy. Not how much state! 43 Evans cont’d: why need other approaches than “neo-utilitarianism” Differences in state structures and state society relations matter for the selection and the effectiveness of policies. Context contingencies and comparative approach necessary. Need to draw on concrete historical, case-based knowledge Methodological individualism at the root of failure to understand states. Weber and the structure and norms of the idealized bureaucracy Bureaucrats do not follow private agendas (more on this next lecture) 44 Differences bureaucratic structures Diff development Evans cont’d Institutionalist revisions of neo-utilitarian model: Institutions as “rules of the game”. Creates incentives for economic actors and are thus crucial for economic outcomes. Douglass North (property rights, institutions and transaction costs, endogenous institutions and functionalism) Comparative institutional variation Migdal and strong vs weak state (state vs society in zero-sum game). Social power of local elites? Local, traditional elites related to rural interests: often opposing industrial transformation. The transformative role of the stat: Strong states transform economy and are not objects for rent seeking 45 Pierson “The notion of path dependence is generally used to support a few key claims: 46 Specific patterns of timing and sequence matter; starting from similar conditions, a wide range of social outcomes may be possible; large consequences may result from relatively "small" or contingent events; particular courses of action, once introduced, can be virtually impossible to reverse; and consequently, political development is often punctuated by critical moments or junctures that shape the basic contours of social life” Pierson Path dependence related to increasing returns: Self-reinforcing or positive feedback processes Other broader def: “History matters”. Event at t=0 affects events at t=1. “Switching costs” or “reversal costs” increase as time passes Particular importance: Formal institutional arrangements that are costly to alter once initiated and historically entrenched. Inflexibility. Potential path inefficiency A funny example: QWERTY keyboards (David). Not so funny: Dysfunctional institutional arrangements like neopatrimonial political arrangements that are hard to break up, but clearly economically inefficient. 47 Technology and increasing returns Four features that generate increasing return-structures Large fixed costs Learning effects Coordination effects Adaptive expectations Direct analogies to politics, institutions: Institutions are 48 a) costly to generate, b) require learning as you go along (learning by doing) from different actors, c) interaction between actors within rule-based framework depend on coordination d) actions depend on beliefs about what others do Pierson cont’d Read Pierson’s interpretation of North Institutional complementarity (see also Hall and Soskice): complementary organizational forms and institutions A source of increasing returns North: “interdependent web of an institutional matrix” 49 Politics and increasing returns (A) Four aspects of political life that make it conducive to increasing returns: 1) Central role of collective action 2) high density of institutions (use initial position to entrench position and increase power even more) 4) intrinsic complexity and opacity 50 (legal constraints on behavior) 3) political authority and asymmetries of power (coordination and adaptive expectations plus difficulty of changing politics individually) (where are the prices? Multiplicity of political issues and goals of actors, long lags and complex causal chains) Politics and increasing returns (B) Three aspects of politics that make it more susceptible to increasing returns than economic processes 1) weakness of competition and learning enhancing mechanisms 2) short time horizons of political actors (switching costs up front!) 3) status quo bias built into political institutions 51 (self correction possible, but difficult due to opacity of politics) (constitutions as example, credible commitment devices, political consensus and uncertainty when change) Pierson page 263: Effects of increasing returns on politics 1. Multiple equilibria. Under a set of initial conditions conducive to increasing returns, a number of outcomes-perhaps a wide range-are generally possible. 2. Contingency. Relatively small events, if they occur at the right moment, can have large and enduring consequences. 3. A critical role for timing and sequencing. In increasing returns processes, when an event occurs may be crucial. Because earlier parts of a sequence matter much more than later parts, an event that happens "too late" may have no effect, although it might have been of great consequence if the timing had been different. 4. Inertia. Once an increasing returns process is established, positive feedback may lead to a single equilibrium. This equilibrium will in turn be resistant to change. 52 Some implications “Historical” causes Implications for analysis The role of time Problems with functionalist explanations (institutions are not necessarily efficient) Problem with the approach: How to test hypotheses from path dependent arguments? 53 Statistics/econometrics OLS Pooled Cross Section - Time Series (OLS with Panel Corrected Standard Errors as example) Panel Data Fixed Effects (Random Effects) Instrumental Variable Analysis/2SLS Matching 54 Repetition of multivariate regression/OLS Remember interpretation of coefficient: Average increase in Y when X increases one unit and all other variables are held constant. OLS as best linear unbiased estimator (BLUE) when certain conditions are satisfied 55 The underlying relationship is linear No autocorrelation No heteroskedasticity No omitted variables (important: Omitted variable bias!) No endogeneity (y affects x) No measurement error in x See Knutsen 2008b for full list What to do when we have a panel data structure? Panel units assumed to be countries here, but can be regions, individuals, firms etc. If no country specific effects, and we want to use both intra-national variation (over time) and variation between countries: OLS with PCSE. Interpretation: Just as OLS! But: takes into account heteroskedasticity between panels, contemporraneous correlation (between panels), and autocorrelation (within panels). These adjustments are crucial when using panel data. 56 Panel data: Fixed Effects What if there are country specific effects? Control for these effects by using dummies for all countries Fixed Effects Only intra-national variation is used Strict technique. Reduces omitted variable bias, but also reduces the amount of information used for inference 57 2SLS Main application: endogenous independent variables Intuition: Use only exogenous part of variation in X. Must find at least one instrument: Instrument should be correlated with X, but not directly linked with Y. Instrument should be as highly correlated with X as possible. Method: First run OLS regression with X as dependent variable and instrument(s) and all control variables as independent Then take the predicted value of X from the first regression rather than the actual X and use in the second (original) regression. 2SLS is consistent, and does not run into the endogeneity bias problems of OLS The major problem with 2SLS is that it yields large standard errors (particularly when low correlation between instrument and X) difficult to find significant results. 58 Matching Non-parametric: Does not need to assume anything about the functional form of relationship. Treatment and control variables Find (one or more) most similar units to use as matches for each unit. Similarity calculated on the basis of control variables. BUT: Unit and match must differ on the treatment variable (dichotomous) Find treatment effect for each comparison (difference in Y between unit and match) Calculate average treatment effect 59