Tax Psychology (3) Decisions under uncertainty (risk) Erich Kirchler University of Vienna, Austria TARC Master Class London - 2014 Economics Ideas of humankind: Homo Oeconomicus • Utility maximization • Rationality (consistent, goal-oriented behaviour) 2 Economics Utility maximization Rationality assumptions: Axioms Completeness (a > b; b = c; c > d; ...) Transitivity (if a > b and b > c, then a > c) Reflexivity (a = a) Non-satiation (a + 1 > a) Continuity (a, b) = (a – x, b + y) Convexity (Law of Saturation) 3 Paying taxes as outcome of a decision under risk How to increase and guarantee tax compliance ? Decision under risk Sure option Risky option Allingham & Sandmo (1972); Srinivasan (1973) Becker, G. S. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 76, 169-217. Average compliance rate by fine rate and audit probability (standard deviations in parentheses; Alm et al., 1995, p. 11) Audit Fine rate probability 1 2 4 ----------------------------------------------------------------------------0.05 9.0 ( 4.0) 6.9 ( 3.2) 12.2 ( 4.2) 0.30 10.9 ( 6.0) 21.4 ( 4.4) 39.8 ( 7.4) 0.60 9.8 ( 8.0) 54.8 (10.6) 70.3 ( 7.5) What does the theory say about what motivates tax compliance ? The standard theory of human behaviour is based on several assumptions: • Individuals are rational, • Individuals have unlimited willpower, • Individuals are self-interested. From James Alm, 2014, Tulane University, USA. What does the theory say about what motivates tax compliance ? The starting point: Economics-of-crime model • A rational individual weights the expected benefits of successful cheating against the risky prospect of detection and punishment. • The individual pays taxes because he or she is afraid of getting caught and penalized. • Indeed, the individual pays taxes because – and only because – of the fear of detection and punishment. Compliance depends upon enforcement. From James Alm, 2014, Tulane University, USA. What does the theory say about what motivates tax compliance ? However, … • • • • • • Individuals face limits of their ability to compute (e.g., bounded rationality) They systematically misperceive, or do not perceive at all, the true cost of their actions (e.g., fiscal illusion, saliency, overweighting of (low) probabilities) They face limits of their self-control (e.g., hyperboic discounting; Christmas club savings) They are affected by the ways in which choices are framed (e.g., reference points, gains versus losses, loss aversion, risk-seeing behavior) They are affected by the social context in which, and the process by which, decisions are made They are motivated by notions of fairness, altruism, trust, guilt, shame, morality, alienation, emotions, patriotism, social customs, social norms, tax morale, … From James Alm, 2014, Tulane University, USA. What does the theory say about what motivates tax compliance ? Behavioral economics suggests several main conclusions about what motivates tax compliance: • • • Enforcement matters – but many other factors matter in the tax compliance decision beyond enforcement. An individual does not always behave as assumed in the standard economic appraoch. Individuals are social creatures and are influenced by group considerations. From James Alm, 2014, Tulane University, USA. 16 min Dan Arieli Cheating Metaanalyses Andreoni, J., Erard, B., & Feinstein, J. S. (1998). Tax compliance. Journal of Economic Literature, 36(2), 818-860. Kirchler, E., Muehlbacher, S., Kastlunger, B. & Wahl, I. (2010). Why pay taxes? A review of tax compliance decisions. In J. Alm, J. MartinezVazques & B. Torgler (eds.). Developing Alternative Frameworks for Explaining Tax Compliance (pp. 15-31). London: Routledge. Most people are honest ! Correlations between tax evasion and measures of psychological instigations and constraints (Elffers et al., 1987) Behavioural outcome measures Psychological variables Dissatisfaction Dissatisfaction with tax authorities Comprehensibility of rules Personality Competitiveness Alienation Tolerance of deviance Fear of punishment Social control Personal control (attitudes) 2-year self- Documented report status Documented amount of tax evaded 0 + + 0 + + + - 0 0 0 0 0 0 Enforcing tax compliance 1. Deterrence To protect honest taxpayers from free riders, controls are The effect of deterrence measures necessary. weak and oppostite Negative is sanctions aresometimes necessary at an adequate level and in thetoproper form, depending on the ability of the tax the intended effect… offender to pay. Tax authorities need to cooperate intensively with legislators, judges, and international authorities. Enforcing tax compliance What effect have fines ? What effect have repeated audits ? A fine is a price ! Gneezy, U. & Rustichini, A. (2000). A fine is a price. Journal of Legal Studies 29(1) 1-18. Experimental group: Managements of 6 day care centers introduced a fine for late pick up of children; Control group: 4 day care centers did not introduce a fine. % of smokers classified as heavy smokers (25+) Reducing undesirable behavior by special taxes Australia’s National Tobacco Campaign 30 25 20 Shift from a weight to a stick based system 15 10 Harmonization of fees in different states (to end cross-border Evasion of cigarette taxes) 5 Extra tax on tobacco products 0 May 97 Nov 97 Nov 98 Scollo, Younie, Wakefield, Freeman, & Icasiano, 2003 Nov 99 Nov 00 Potential side effects of special taxes 1 % of smokers using Roll Your Own Tobacco Australia’s National Tobacco Campaign 25 20 15 Shift towards unhealthy form of tobacco consumption 10 5 0 May 97 Nov 97 Nov 98 Scollo, Younie, Wakefield, Freeman, & Icasiano, 2003 Nov 99 Nov 00 Potential side effects of special taxes 2 Cigarette sales & consumption in Washington State (USA) Tax rise from 25c to 75c per pack Stehr, 2005 Consumption remains stable Presumably due to smuggling Tax compliance (Kirchler, Maciejovsky & Schwarzenberger, 2005) .6 Compliance .5 Audit probability 30 % .4 .3 .2 .1 0 0 Base-line 1 2 3 4 Periods following audit 20 Robust phenomena: the “bomb crater effect“ and the „echo effect“ (Guala & Mittone, 2005; Mittone 2006; Kastlunger et al. 2009; Maciejovsky et al. 2007) “Echo” effect in experiments with audits in the first and second half of 60 business periods, respectively Guala and Mittone (2002, p. 12 and 13) Tax payments (averages, first group) Value (Italian Liras) 500 400 300 200 100 Tax due Average tax paid Audit 0 1 7 4 13 10 19 16 25 22 31 28 37 34 43 40 49 46 Round 55 52 58 “Echo” effect in experiments with audits in the first and second half of 60 business periods, respectively Guala and Mittone (2002, p. 12 and 13) Tax payments (averages, first group) Value (Italian Liras) 500 400 300 200 100 Tax due Average tax paid Audit 0 1 7 4 13 10 19 16 25 22 31 28 37 34 43 40 49 46 55 52 Round 58 Impact of immediate versus delayed audits on tax compliance and perceived fairness of authorities Kogler, C., Mittone, L. & Kirchler, E. (2014) Timing of feedback of tax audits matters – Uncertainty resolution in tax experiments: waiting for an audit increases tax compliance (Muehlbacher et al., 2012) – Problem: audits directly after filing taxes in most tax experiments, but in reality often years after filing a tax report (e.g., Austria 5-10 years) Feedback related to trust, trust related to compliance – In other contexts (e.g., organizational psychology; Sapienza & Korsgaard, 1996) timeliness of feedback was identified to increase trust and acceptance of decisions – In tax literature trust in state/authorities was identified as an important determinant of tax compliance and tax morale (e.g., Torgler & Schneider, 2004; Braithwaite & Wenzel, 2007; Kirchler et al., 2008) Experimental Design • 22 rounds of taxpaying in a laboratory experiment • Regular income – 3000 ECU, tax rate: 900 ECU – Pay-off determined at the end (one round randomly chosen) • Audit probability: 15% – Rounds 3, 12, 21 for all participants to keep effects of audits constant • Fine in case of detection – 2 x evaded amount (paying back + fine equal to evaded amount) • Feedback – After each round vs. only at the end (summary after the last round) • Rounds of reduced earnings – Rounds of reduced earnings: R8-10, R17-18 – Reduced income of 2500 ECU vs. additional tax of 500 ECU (compulsory) • Questionnaire: – Items: perceived fairness of tax authorities, voluntary compliance, subjective audit probability, perceived severity of fine, perceived fairness of timing of feedback, general tax morale, socio-demographic data, etc. Results I – Feedback x Compulsory Tax Covariate Gender: Mean females = 69.49% Mean males = 50.60% F(1, 121) = 7.44, p < .01 Audit Reduced Earnings Mean immediate feedback = 50.75%, Mean delated feedback = 69.29% F (1, 122) = 11.30, p < .01 Immediate vs delayed audits In experiments, uncertainty if tax report is audited is resolved immediately, whereas in real life it can take up to 7 years to know if your audited or not (Zeigarnik-Effect; unfinished businesses) Compliance decision Control group (pay 0-6 € tax) Compliance Rates: Experimental group 5 minutes 3 weeks 28% 59% Muehlbacher, Mittone, Kastlunger, & Kirchler, 2012 There is more than audits and fines, … situational and personal characteristics; social norms, fairness, … and perhaps the perception of taxpayers as cheaters is short-sighted. Diffusion of income tax evasion 10-15% of underreported income Porcano (1988), the U.S. IRS estimated 10-15% of underreported income in 1983. Five years later the tax gap was about 17% of true liability. 25% underpaid 7.3% non-compliance, wide variation across types of income and deductions Slemrod et al. (2001) explain that the detected rate of non-compliance is 7.3%, but varies widely across types of gross income and deductions. In 1988, voluntary Andreoni and colleagues (1998) estimate that over 25% of all U.S. taxpayers underpaid their taxes in 1988. In developed countries, tax evasion is estimated to reach 20% of the level of tax revenues, while in developing countries the percentages are even higher (Orviska & Hudson, 2002). reporting was 99.5% for wages and salaries, but only 41.4% for self-employed income. In 2002, King & Sheffrin report that according to the U.S. IRS, 99% of wage income is correctly reported, but less than 70% of income from unincorporated businesses is correctly reported. Elffers (2000) writes, “[…] the gloomy picture of massive tax 4.2% corrected their tax files to their disadvantage, 23.8% corrected them to their advantage. Assuming that those negatively correcting their files made unintentional evasion is a phantom”. make reports. 13.5% overstate their taxes, presumably duedid to mistakes,¼and an accurate equal percentage of those who positively corrected their files voluntary reporting 99.5% for wages and salaries, but only 41.4% for self-employed There is little doubt that non-compliance should be contained and evasion, in particular, needs to be combated. It is, however, wrong to assume that the majority of people try to evade or avoid paying taxes. Long and Swingen (1991) write that some taxpayers are not predisposed to evade and do not search for ways to cheat. Survey studies and experiments on income tax behaviour show that honesty characterises a majority of participants (e.g., V. Braithwaite, 2003d; James & Alley, 2002; Kirchler, Muehlbacher, Hoelzl, & Webley, 2005). Antonides and Robben found that 4.2% of participants in their study corrected their tax files to their disadvantage, whereas 23.8% corrected them to their advantage (Antonides & Robben, 1995). Assuming that those negatively correcting their files made unintentional mistakes, and an equal percentage of those who positively corrected their files did so also undeliberately, then less than 20% were intending to cheat. On the basis of 1982 U.S. IRS audit data, Alexander and Feinstein (1987) report that approximately one quarter of all taxpayers make accurate tax reports. According to their analysis, 13.5% overstate their taxes, presumably due to errors in completing tax returns. If the same percentage understates their taxes due to errors, then more than half of taxpayers tend to be honest. errors. If the same understates taxes due to errors, then so also undeliberately, then percentage less than 20% intend to their cheat. more than half of taxpayers tend to be honest. Hessing, Elffers, and Weigel (1988) estimate that more than two thirds of taxpayers declare their income honestly. 2/3 declare their income honestly The assumption that taxpayers are generally compliant is challenged by the wide use of tax preparers and studies contending that taxpayers generally demand aggressive advice (Duncan, LaRue, & Reckers, 1989; Jackson, Milliron, & Toy, 1988; Milliron, 1988). These studies were conducted from tax preparers’ view, but investigations from taxpayers’ perspectives reveal a different picture. The use of a tax practitioner does not seem primarily driven by the desire to avoid paying taxes, but by the uncertainty about the tax law and the motivation to report correctly. The use of a tax practitioner does not seem primarily driven by the desire to avoid paying taxes, but by the uncertainty about the tax law and the motivation to report correctly. Economic Psychology Agenda 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. Self-Conception Objectivity & Intentions (Psycho-) Logics Rituals of Adults The Invisible Hand Mental Accounting Trick & Treat Courage & Risk 20 US Cents Invulnerability Whatever you want! In the Shadow Nudges 75.000 US$ Ideas of Mankind Methods Economic Decisions Lay Economic Theories Markets Consumption, Saving, Loans Marketing Policy Businessmen/women Work & Satisfaction Financial Markets Currency & Inflation Counter-Productivity State: Power and Trust Prosperity and Happiness 31 Decision Anomalies: Perception of information Cognitive scrooges: Reality is subjectively construed and interpreted • Estimation of the diameter of coins • Optical illusions 32 Paying back loans You have lended 3.000 € and need to pay it back with 12% annual interest rate. Each month you pay 30 €. How long does it take to pay the credit back? (a) less than 5 years (b) 5 to 10 years (c) 11 to 15 years (d) 16 to 20 years (e) for ever 15% 31% 18% 10% 26% 33 Risk and emotions Emotions Probabilities are ignored or low probabilities are overestimated Money 18 16 Prices paid to avoid electric shock and $20 penalty 14 12 Shock 10 8 6 4 2 0 1% 99 % Probability The willingness to pay to avoid electric shocks barely depends on the probability of being exposed to electric shocks (Rottenstreich & Hsee: Money, Kisses, and Electric Shock: On the Affective Psychology Risk. Psychological 34 Science, 2001) Risk-aversion Daniel Bernoulli (18th century): Human beings are risk averse! A sure gain of € 8.000 is preferred to a possible gain (p = .85) of € 10.000. 35 Risk-aversion and -inclination a) Sure win of € 240 or 25 % chance of winning € 1.000 and 75 % chance of winning 0 b) Sure loss of € 750 or 75 % chance of loosing € 1.000 & 25 % chance of loosing 0 36 Prospect Theory Descriptive decision theory explaining a number of decision anomalies in decision making under risk. Phase 1: Editing Simplification of the decision problem Phase 2: Evaluation Assessment of the alternatives 37 Prospect Theory Phase 1: Editing Simplification of the decision problem Coding: What is an event related to (reference point)? Combination: Independent events are often seen combined. Segregation: Safe events are often separated from risky ones. Cancellation: Identical aspects of two alternatives are ignored whereas disparities are weighted heavily in judgments. 38 Prospect Theory Phase 1: Editing Simplification of the decision problem Simplification: e.g. odd numbers are rounded. In the case of very low or very high probabilities this process is fundamental. Detection of dominance: Salient alternatives are discarded in the beginning and are not taken into account any further. 39 Prospect Theory Phase 2: Evaluation Assessment of alternatives Assessment is guided by two principles • The value is estimated in relation to a reference point. • Probabilities are taken into account. 40 Prospect-Theorie Subjective value + concave Loss Gain -A -B A convex B 41 Prospect Theory: Weighting function Decision weight 1 0.5 0 42 0 0.5 Probability p 1 42 Neuropsychology / Neuroeconomics Support for the assumptions of the prospect theory comes from neuroeconomics, examining the brain activity while decisions are made. Neuroscientific methods allow the analysis of the activities of the human brain (e.g. Prince & Pawelzik, 2008). In addition to imaging and psychophysiological methods, the measurement of individual neurons, the electrical brain stimulation or the elimination of brain regions can be counted among the methodological tools of neuroscience and, more recently, of neuroeconomics. First and foremost imaging and psychophysiological methods are used. Apart from the electroencephalogram (EEG), positron emission tomography (PET) is used, which allows the creation of cross-sectional images of the brains of humans and mapping biochemical and physiological processes. Currently, functional magnetic resonance imaging (fMRI) is most popular. This method allows the representation of metabolic activity in the brain by measuring the magnetic properties of oxygenated and deoxygenated blood. Using psychophysiological methods, different physiological responses to a stimulus, such as blood pressure, heart rate, sweating, dilated pupils or muscle tone, can be measured (Sanfey, 2007). Many studies have shown that economic decisions are correlated with neurophysiological processes (e.g., Delgado, Locke, Stenger, & Fiez, 2003; Knutson, Taylor, Kaufman, Peterson, & Glover, 2005). Sanfey, Rilling, Aronson, Nystrom, and Cohen (2003) examined fMRI responses of the players to fair and unfair offers in the ultimatum game and found out that in the case of rejected, unfair offers other brain regions are activated, as in the case of accepted, unfair offers. 43 Experiment 5 25 1. Choose 5 or 25 2. Outcome: gain or loss 3. Result: 4. Brain activity: 25 gain & correct 5 gain & incorrect 25 loss & incorrect 5 loss & correct 265 milliseconds after the information about a win or loss => higher amplitude of a potential springing from the frontal area of the Cerebrum Medium in the event of a loss. 44 Libertarian Paternalism • Asymmetric (libertarian) paternalism: – Does not affect rational decision makers; – Works to the advantage of biased decision makers. • Policy applications – – – – – Providing information; Framing; Changing status quo; Format effects; Motivational effects. Tax compliance of people who are liable to wage tax and of self-employed persons as a function of the refund amount or balance due (Cox & Plumley, 1988; as cited in Webley et al., 1991) Compliance rate in percent 100 wages/salaries 95 90 business income 85 80 75 70 65 <-1.000 <- 500 <- 100 <- 0 >- 0 >- 100 refund 46 Size of refund or balance due (US $) >- 500 >-1.000 balance due