Part F-I The Economic Theory of Crime and Punishment Applying the model of rational crime 10/21/08 Crime_D 1 Objectives - apply the predictive model of criminal behaviour - understand the specific factors that might influence the crime rate - elasticities (practical importance of individual influences) 10/21/08 Crime_D 2 Rational Crime - aggregate crime Recall the ‘first law of deterrence’ “As the expected punishment increase, the number of crimes decreases” – this describes the slope of the Aggregate Crime Curve What might cause the Aggregate Crime Curve (ACC) to shift in or out? Anything that causes the expected net benefit to the criminal to increase (decrease) will cause the ACC to shift out (in). Recall y(x) = x – c(x) focus shifts to c(x) the direct cost to the criminal of committing crime 10/21/08 Crime_D 3 Rational Crime - aggregate crime Aggregate crime curve Severity of punishment ACC2 Anything that causes the expected net benefit to the criminal to increase (decrease) will cause the ACC to shift out (in) – c(x). ACC0 ε1 ACC1 c1 10/21/08 c0 c2 Aggregate number of crimes Crime_D 4 Rational Crime - Direct Costs of Committing Crime What should be included in the costs of committing a crime c(x)? - out-of-pocket expenses - tools, information, payoffs, fencing fees, money laundering fees, etc - opportunity cost of time and effort - opportunity cost of future legitimate economic opportunities (if caught) - opportunity cost of reputation (public shame – if caught) - guilt (private shame) 10/21/08 Crime_D 5 Rational Crime - Direct Costs of Committing Crime Out-of-pocket expenses - tools, information, payoffs, fencing fees, money laundering fees, etc Some crimes are low cost crimes – e.g. shoplifting Some crimes are high cost crimes – e.g. drug smuggling, contract killing Poorer criminals - mugging, shoplifting, selling street drugs Richer criminals - drug smuggling, loan sharking, major frauds All crimes can be made more, or less, expensive to the criminal 10/21/08 Crime_D 6 Rational Crime - Direct Costs of Committing Crime opportunity cost of time and effort - some individuals are more productive criminals than are other individuals (bigger, faster, more violent, more devious, etc.). For such individuals crime is less costly – less effort. (Woody Allen robbing a bank?) - note criminals usually specialize in the types of crime in which they are most productive (shoplifters, muggers, bank robbers, counterfeiters, fraudsters, selling drugs, loan sharking, financial fraud) - some individuals are more productive in the legitimate labour market (better educated, more experience, better ‘connected’ bigger, faster, etc.). 10/21/08 Crime_D 7 Rational Crime - Direct Costs of Committing Crime opportunity cost of time and effort The following is most applicable to full-time or part-time criminals not occasional or isolated crimes - consider the expected return from ‘time and effort’ spent in legitimate employment vs. the expected return from ‘time and effort’ spent in criminal activity wE(H) >, = or < wcE(Hc) w - hourly wage in labour market (productivity in legitimate activity) wc - hourly wage in criminal activity (productivity in criminal activity) E(H) - expected hours of legitimate work E(Hc) - expected hours of criminal activity 10/21/08 Crime_D 8 Rational Crime - Direct Costs of Committing Crime opportunity cost of time and effort What affects these variables? w (productivity in legitimate activity) - age, education, literacy, accent, appearance, experience, place of residence, etc. wc (productivity in criminal activity) varies with the type of crime - experience, training, intelligence, strength, deviousness, bravery, etc. 10/21/08 Crime_D 9 Rational Crime - Direct Costs of Committing Crime opportunity cost of time and effort What affects these variables? E(H) (expected hours of legitimate work) - unemployment rate, general conditions in relevant ‘local’ labour market, etc. E(Hc) (expected hours of criminal activity) - opportunities in the relevant criminal activity, etc. 10/21/08 Crime_D 10 Rational Crime - Direct Costs of Committing Crime opportunity cost of time and effort - for a given individual wE(H) > wcE(Hc) 10/21/08 legitimate employment wE(H) = wcE(Hc) indifferent – occasional criminals wE(H) < wcE(Hc) life of crime Crime_D 11 Rational Crime - Direct Costs of Committing Crime opportunity cost of time and effort wE(H) > wcE(Hc) legitimate employment wE(H) = wcE(Hc) indifferent – occasional criminals wE(H) < wcE(Hc) life of crime Note that even for occasional criminals wc is relevant (again Woody Allen in ‘Take the Money and Run’ Many criminals also hold regular employment – crime is a ‘second job’ and the above would apply Both cyclical and long-term factors enter here - this is were ‘economic conditions’ might affect crime 10/21/08 Crime_D 12 Rational Crime - Direct Costs of Committing Crime opportunity cost of future legitimate economic opportunities Consider two 18 year olds: Bill - High school drop out living in poor area of town, only employed in low paying jobs very sporadically, parents have never held regular employment (expected average annual lifetime earnings - $15,000) John – currently in university, lives in suburbs, has always had a part-time job, everyone in family holds regular employment, etc. (expected average annual lifetime earnings - $65,000) 10/21/08 Crime_D 13 Rational Crime - Direct Costs of Committing Crime opportunity cost of future legitimate economic opportunities What do Bill and John risk by getting involved in criminal activity as 20 year olds? Bill - expected average annual lifetime earnings of $15,000 John - expected average annual lifetime earnings of $65,000 Socio-economic class matters – it is a determinant of your legitimate future prospects Discount rate – we will discuss later 10/21/08 Crime_D 14 Rational Crime - Direct Costs of Committing Crime opportunity cost of reputation (public shame) Again consider Bill and John - Potential personal shame would appear to be related to family status in the community - a ‘good family’, a ‘good reputation’ Again, socio-economic class would appear to matter – it is a determinant of the social status that you put at risk What are the relevant sociological phenomena ?? 10/21/08 Crime_D 15 Rational Crime - Direct Costs of Committing Crime guilt (private shame) Morality (the extent to which the individual is constrained by guilt or morality) - is the individual constrained by guilty or morality? - ‘family values’, church attendance, moral instruction in schools, etc. Let’s face it, if everyone was always ‘constrained by guilt and morality’ then there would be no rational crime. 10/21/08 Crime_D 16 Rational Crime Criminal’s optimal number of crimes - review 45o $ Expected punishment Δy/Δx Expected net benefit y(x) Optimizing criminal wants to maximize this gap Number of crimes Δp/Δx f(x) + p(x) Δf/Δx 10/21/08 Crime_D 17 Rational Crime Decision to commit crime Harm to the victim $ Expected punishment Expected net benefit y(x) $100 Rational crime $80 5 crimes $50 Number of crimes 5 10/21/08 Crime_D 18 Rational Crime Decision to commit crime Expected punishment $ Expected net benefit y(x) No rational crime Expected punishment exceeds expected net benefit for any number of crimes Number of crimes 10/21/08 Crime_D 19 Rational Crime - policies that decrease incentives to commit rational crime $ Anything that shifts the expected net benefit of crime curve downwards or the expected punishment curve upwards Expected punishment p(x)f(x) Expected net benefit y(x) = x – c(x) Optimizing criminal wants to maximize this gap Number of crimes 10/21/08 Crime_D 20 Rational Crime - policies that decrease incentives to commit rational crime 1. Decrease y(x) = x – c(x), the ‘net returns’ to a given criminal act (shifts net benefit curve downward) - make crime more costly for the criminal to undertake (higher fences, better lighting, more complicated alarm systems, more secure safes, more complicate financial reporting systems) - in general make the criminal work harder for his/her reward The usual ‘crime prevention’ techniques ‘out-of-pocket expenses’ 10/21/08 Crime_D 21 Rational Crime - policies that decrease incentives to commit rational crime and many other factors considered as direct costs of crime - opportunity cost of time and effort wE(H) > = < wcE(Hc) (education, training and other labour market policies) - opportunity cost of future legitimate economic opportunities (education, training and other labour market policies) 10/21/08 Crime_D 22 Rational Crime - policies that decrease incentives to commit rational crime and many other factors considered as direct costs of crime - opportunity cost of reputation, public shame (community reputation enhancing strategies – cultural movements such Black Pride movements, etc.) (negative strategies – drunk driving, smoking) - guilt, morality, private shame – family values, moral education, churches, etc. 10/21/08 Crime_D 23 Rational Crime - policies that decrease incentives to commit rational crime 2. Increase p(x), the probability of being caught, convicted and punished (shifts expected punishment curve upward) - increase the number and efficiency (equipment, training, etc.) of police, prosecutors, courts, prisons. - give police, courts, prosecutors more ‘political/legal’ power to investigate and prosecute suspected criminals - generally, devote more resources and give up some of the personal freedoms of all citizens 10/21/08 Crime_D 24 Rational Crime - policies that decrease incentives to commit rational crime 3. Increase f(x), the punishment if caught (shifts expected punishment curve upward) - larger fines, longer sentences, etc. - In general this requires more resources (prisons, etc.) since fines are not enough in most cases (poor criminals, really big crimes). 10/21/08 Crime_D 25 Rational Crime - what is really important? Aggregate crime is a function of y(x) = x – c(x) - crime prevention measures - opportunity cost of time and effort (education, labour market conditions) - opportunity cost of future legitimate economic opportunities (education, labour market conditions) - opportunity cost of reputation, public shame (community enhancing strategies, etc. - guilt, morality, private shame – family status, church attendance, etc. 10/21/08 Crime_D 26 Rational Crime - what is really important? and aggregate crime is a function of p(x) - number and efficiency (equipment, training, etc.) of police, prosecutors, courts, prisons. - ‘political/legal’ power to investigate and prosecute suspected criminals f(x) - larger fines, longer sentences, etc. 10/21/08 Crime_D 27 Rational Crime - what is really important? With respect to alternative theories of criminal behaviour, the model of rational crime is all inclusive. On a purely theoretical level, this makes it less useful. How do we settle debates such as ‘harsher punishment vs. better education’ What do we tell policy makers? Just do everything - anything that decreases y(x), increase p(x) or increase f(x) Not very useful advice A purely theoretical economic analysis of criminal activity takes us only so far. 10/21/08 Crime_D 28 Rational Crime - what is really important? What is required at this point is empirical analysis. The various elasticities must be quantified. Will longer sentences deter the illegal use of guns? Yes, but be how much? - will a 10% increase in the prison sentence decrease gun related crime by 25% or by 1%? Will more police on the streets deter the illegal use of guns? Yes, but be how much? - will a 10% increase in police funding decrease gun related crime by 10% or by 1%? Will better job opportunities decrease the illegal use of guns? Yes, but be how much? - will a 10% increase in job opportunities decrease gun related crime by 30% or by 1%? 10/21/08 Crime_D 29 Rational Crime - what is really important? There will always be debates over such issues and they can only be settled by appeal to empirical evidence. We will look at one of these empirical studies. The model of rational crime is important because it is the necessary first step in addressing empirical questions concerning criminal activity. It provides a framework within which to address specific questions. It tells the empiricist what factors must be controlled for when addressing specific questions. It brings structure to the various debates. 10/21/08 Crime_D 30 Rational Crime - some applications Should a thief be allowed to give good title? In Canada if you buy a stolen good, without knowing it is stolen, and it is found to be stolen you must give it back. In Europe, if you buy a stolen good, without knowing that it is stolen, and it is found to be stolen, you need not give it back. What effect do these alternative rules have on the expected number of thefts? More or fewer handguns – again has two effects on expected crime In response to recent terrorists attacks, governments have tried to decrease the returns from terrorism y(x) and increase the probability of terrorists being caught and convicted p(x) . In what ways have you personally paid some of the costs of these attempt to decease terrorism? 10/21/08 Crime_D 31 Rational Crime - some applications Does poverty ‘cause’ crime; yes and no. Poverty does not generally cause tax fraud, price fixing or major financial frauds. Poverty (a downturn in the level of economic activity), or inequality in the distribution of wealth, might lead to more theft, muggings, embezzlements, etc. Consideration of y(x), the net benefit that a given criminal gets from a given crime, indicates that the opportunity cost of criminal activity falls as legitimate economic options (current and future) deteriorate (the relative returns from crime increase) - a group of rich people living next to a group of poor people provide potentially profitable crime opportunities. Does poverty, or unemployment cause people to be ‘bad’, become less moral? NO, but as economic conditions deteriorate (current or future), relative prices (wages) began to change and crime becomes a relatively more profitable activity. It causes them to do ‘bad things’. Can wealth cause crime? Are some crimes positively related to income? 10/21/08 Crime_D 32 Rational Crime - some applications More police should lead to less crime but so do more efficient courts (quicker and more certain conviction) and longer prison sentences. What does the above model imply about the allocation of a fixed criminal/justice budget across police, courts and prison? Why is it that local police forces apparently ‘waste’ their time on public education programs encouraging ‘crime prevention’ for breaking and entering, theft from autos, muggings, etc. but when one of these crimes actually occurs they don’t ‘really do much’? 10/21/08 Crime_D 33 Rational Crime - what about the individual’s rate of discount? Crime and its consequences usually represent a series of events that occur over time Generally: - crime is committed today - consequences are suffered tomorrow - punishment, loss of future legitimate opportunities Criminals are often described as individuals with little ‘impulse control’ or with ‘no thought for the future’ Economists would refer to ‘rates of discount’ 10/21/08 Crime_D 34 Rational Crime - what about the individual’s rate of discount? Rate of discount A $1 today does not have the same value as a $1 tomorrow Suppose the interest rate (r) is 10% then $1 today is worth $1.10 is one year’s time - $1x(1.10) $1 in one year’s time is worth $1 in one year’s time Conversely, $1 today is worth $1 today $1 in one year’s time is worth $0.909 today - $1/(1.10) 10/21/08 Crime_D 35 Rational Crime - what about the individual’s rate of discount? Rate of discount The present value (today’s value) of $1 received in one year’s time is equal to $1/(1+r) - where r is the annual rate of discount In general the present value (today’s value) of $x received in ‘n’ years is equal to $x/(1+r)n Example: $1,000 received in 5 years with a 10% rate of discount $1,000/(1.10)10 = $1,000/2.5937 = $385.55 10/21/08 Crime_D 36 Rational Crime - what about the individual’s rate of discount? What determines an individual’s personal rate of discount? This is a matter of personal taste and preferences – ‘rate of time preference’ – how much of a return do we want in order to delay our gratification? (or how much are we willing to pay to move our gratification forward in time?) ‘more jam today, or more jam tomorrow’? Some people deny themselves small pleasures to save and earn a 3% return on their savings Others run up credit card debts and pay an interest rate of 20% on that debt Most of us are somewhere in between these two examples. 10/21/08 Crime_D 37 Rational Crime - what about the individual’s rate of discount? Example: Net gain crime today Punishment in 2 years $100 $200 $181 Punishment in 5 years PV of punishment: r=5% r=25% r=50% $157 $26 $100 10/21/08 $200 PV of punishment: r=5% r=25% Crime_D $128 $66 r=50% $89 38 Rational Crime - what about the individual’s rate of discount? Comments: - The above is just one aspect to the decision to commit crime – it does not imply that everyone who runs up VISA debt is likely to commit crimes - However, the higher the discount rate and the more delayed is the punishment, the more attractive will be the net gains from crime today (SWIFT PUNISHMENT) - There is always the uncertainty of punishment and individuals with high discount rates also tend to discount uncertain future events even more (CERTAIN PUNISHMENT) - An individual’s discount rate might vary with their mood (manic – depressive, alcohol, drugs, etc.) 10/21/08 Crime_D 39 Rational Crime - what about non-rational individuals? Crimes of passion, insane, drunk, drugged Such crimes fall outside our model Are criminals rational amoral people? I HOPE SO! 10/21/08 Crime_D 40 10/21/08 Crime_D 41