Market Power Without Strategic Behavior (Monopoly or Monopolistic Competition) Monopoly • Firm with monopoly or market power has the ability to set its price and produce at any point on the market demand curve • Whether the ONLY seller in the market depends on the definition of the market – Tylenol? – Pace Salsa? – Dallas Morning News? – Raleigh/Durham Intl. Airport? Barriers to Entry • Barriers to entry are the source of all monopoly power – there are two general types of barriers to entry • Exclusive ownership of resources through – Legal barriers (e.g. patents and copyrights, gov. franchise) – Unique supply (Brad Pitt Eiffel Tower) – Sole ownership (DeBeers) • Economies of scale (Natural Monopoly) – Rent seeking behavior (lobbying lawmakers) can be used to secure barriers (e.g. tariffs or import restrictions) Price Setters • Single Price Monopolist – Assume they cannot price discriminate, or behave strategically. – Monopoly or Monopolistic Competition • Price Discrimination – first, second and third degree Revenue: Price Setter • Price Setter, the higher q, the lower the P. P Market Demand = Firm’s Demand P = P(Q) Q • Firm chooses the price along with quantity. • R depends on P and Q, but P = P(Q) • R = P(Q)·Q Revenue: Price Setter • TR and MR if demand is linear. TR, MR TR = P(Q)·Q Slope = 0 MR = 0 Q Revenue: Price Setter • R = P(Q)·Q MR dP(Q) Q dQ dP MR Q P(Q) dQ dP MR Q P dQ P(Q) Q AR P(Q) Q AR P P Market Demand = Firm’s Demand P = P(Q) P = AR MR Q Revenue: Price Setter • MR, think of dq = 1. P dP dQ D: P = P(Q); P=AR P MR Q dQ MR dP Q P dQ Q Revenue: Price Setter • MR, think of dQ = 1. elastic P dP dQ inelastic D: P = P(Q); P=AR P MR Q dQ MR dP Q P dQ • MR clearly depends on e. Q Elasticity and MR • Start with definitions of MR and e MR dP dQ P Q P, e dQ dP Q Multiply in the equivalent of 1, MR dP Q P P dQ 1 P 1 dP Q From e, e dQ P Substitute and simplify (pull the neg. sign out of the e), 1 P MR P e 1 P MR P e 1 1 Voila, MR P 1 or MR P 1 e e \ Elasticity and MR 1 MR P 1 e • • • • if |e| = 1.0, MR = 0 if |e| < 1.0, MR < 0 if |e| > 1.0, MR > 0 if |e| > ∞, MR = P Firm Supply Decision • • • • • Firm chooses the Q that will maximize profit. They do not respond to a market price. Produce a Qs where MR = MC MR comes from demand function Although shut down is still possible, 95% of treatments of market power ignore the short run and just look at the long run. Profit Max p MC SMC AC ATC P* PBE D=AR Q* • • • • MR Q On the expansion path, SMC=MC and ATC=AC. Use the SR curves to discuss the differential effects of changes in FC or VC in the short run. But there is no LR entry or exit of firms (except the potential exit of the monopolist). In the LR, the firm will choose a level of K to be on the expansion path, so long as P > AC. Zoom In D SMC ATC MC AC PBE • At Q* where MR=MC, SMC = MC and ATC=AC. dATC dAC = dQ dQ dATC ≠0 dQ • And while • However, MR Q* Price Setter in the Long Run • Simple, just MR = MC • Maximize profit w.r.t. Q • Maximize profit w.r.t. K, L Profit Maximizing Alternative 1 • Simple, set MC = MR, find q. C* C v,w,Q as from cost chapter C* w L v,w,Q v K v,w,Q dC MC v,w,Q dQ Revenue: from demand, multiply inverse demand times q P P(Q), R P(Q) Q dR MR Q dQ Set MR=MC and solve for Q * Q w,v Check to ensure that > 0, if not, then exit Profit Max , Choose q • Assuming you know C*=C(v, w, Q) max P(Q) Q C v,w,Q , where C(v,w,Q) comes from cost minimization. q FOC Q MR(Q) MC(Q) 0 Q MR(Q) MC(Q), choose q such that the MR = MC Solve for Q to get the firm supply function, Q * Q v,w SOC, check that profit is decreasing where FOC are satisfied: d2 d MR(Q) d MC(Q) d(MR) d(MC) QQ 0, or 2 dQ dQ dQ dQ dQ Finally, check to ensure that > 0, if not, then exit Profit Max 3, MRPK=v, MRPL=w • Optimize by choosing K and L. max P f K,L f K,L vK wL L ,K FOC f P f L f K,L P f K,L w 0 f L L P L fL Q P f K,L w That is: MPL MR w f e.g., let Demand: P a bQ Production: Q K L a b K L K L vK wL f P f K f K,L P f K,L r 0 Maximizing π means hiring each input K f K until MRP = its price. P K fK Q P f K,L v That is: MPK MR v f Solve for L* and K* to get the profit maximizing factor demand functions L* L v,w , K* K v,w Plug into Q f K,L to get profit maximizing supply function Q * Q v,w and check that 0, exit otherwise. Profit Max, choose K and L • SOC The function is strictly concave at L* , K* H LL LK KL KK 0, negative definite H LL KK LK 0 2 Negative definite if: LL 0, KK 0, and LL KK LK , which holds so long as LK2 is small. 2 Profit Max, choose K and L • Profit function, maximal profits for a given w, v. Plug K* =K(v,w) and L* L(v,w) into P f K,L f K,L vK wL to get the profit optimizing profit function: P f K(v,w),L(v,w) f K(v,w),L(v,w) vK(v,w) wL(v,w) Note, there is no P in this equation as determining profit maximizing K and L determines Q*, which sets P* according to demand. Monopoly Result • Compared to perfect competition, higher price, lower quantity, economic profit, higher producer surplus, lower consumer surplus. In the long run, producer surplus = profit. P MC CS P* AC DWL π D Q Q* MR Competitive Comparison • In long run, no profit or producer surplus (constant cost case anyway). • Because of the deadweight loss from monopoly, it is considered a market failure. P Competitive Market supply = Market MC PM CS AC PC D QC QM MR Q The Inverse Elasticity Rule 1 MRis defined as MR P 1 e When maximizing profit, MC MR, so the folowing must hold: 1 1 MC P 1 or MC =P 1 e e Since monopolists only produce where e -1 MC will always the price. For example 1 e = -2, MC = P 2 3 e = -4, MC = P 4 e = - , MC = P The Inverse Elasticity Rule 1 MC P 1 e MC 1 Solve for P to get: P MC 1 1 1 1 e e And we get the price as a multiple of MC (again, with e -1) e -1, P MC, b / c MC MR 0 e -2, P 2 MC e -5, P 1.25 MC e - , P MC Markup Pricing MC P 1 1 e e Rearrange again to get P MC e 1 P e 1 MC e P MC P e P MC e P e MC e P e P MC P P e P MC 1 p e P MC 1 1 e The Inverse Elasticity Rule • The gap between a firm’s price and its marginal cost is inversely related to the price elasticity of demand facing the firm P P MC 1 P e MC For -1 < e < 0, the markup exceeds the price. Huh? p-MC P D, P = P(Q) MR Q The Inverse Elasticity Rule P MC 1 P e • If e = -1, P-MC = P, the markup is p (since MC must = 0) • If e = -1.25, the markup is 80% of price • If e = -2, the markup with be 50% of price • If e = -5, the markup will be 20% of price • If e = -20, the markup will be 5% of price Change in Price for a Change in MC MC 1 1 e P 1 , when e -1 MC 1 1 e For example P P MC 1 1 e P 2, so price rises by twice the change in MC. MC P e=-5, 1.25, so price rises by 1.25 x the change in MC. MC P e 10, 1.11, so price rises by 1.11 x the change in MC. MC e=-2, Natural Monopoly • In a competitive market, so many firms can produce at the Minimum Efficient Scale (MES) – low point of AC curve – that no firm can change the market price by altering its behavior. • But if the MES is large enough that it only takes a few firms to supply the market, they will start to have market power. • If MES is so large that one firm can produce at a lower average cost than two firms can splitting the market in half, then we get a natural monopoly. Large MES • Two firms each producing Q = X and charging P = AC. If one firm gets a little larger, it can gain market share and profit. • Long run equilibrium must be one firm. P MC AC D x 2x MR Q Large MES • One firm, maximized profit like other monopolies. • Barrier to entry is economies of scale P MC P* AC DWL π D Q* Q MR Regulating This Monopoly • Considered regular monopoly. • Regulate price where MC = demand • Profit > 0. P MC AC PR π D QR MR Q Natural Monopoly: Technically • Definition is a firm for which AC is declining where AC = demand • Still can earn economic profit in the long run. • But why AC declining? P MC P* AC DWL π D Q* Q MR Natural Monopoly: Technically • If AC declining at intersection with demand, it requires MC < AC where MC=MB. • Sadly, regulation cannot require MC=MB without firm exit. P MC AC PR Loss D QR MR Q Natural Monopoly: Subsidized • Could subsidize the firm (equal to loss). • Not very popular. But it is one way to think about the economics of mass transit, which is heavily subsidized. P MC AC PR Subsidy D QR MR Q Natural Monopoly Average Cost Pricing • Average cost pricing regulation ensures continued production. • DWL results, but it is the more usual strategy. P MC AC DWL PR,ACP D QR,ACP MR Q Multi-plant Profit Max Choose q1 and q2 • Assuming you know C1*=C(v, w, Q1), C2*=C(v, w, Q2) max p q1 q2 q1 q2 C1 v,w,q1 C2 v,w,q2 q1 ,q2 max R q1 q2 C1 q1 C2 q2 q1 ,q2 FOC q1 MR(q1 q2 ) MC(q1 ) 0 q2 MR(q1 q2 ) MC(q2 ) 0 MR the same in each FOC as the market does not care which plant each unit was produced. Choose q1 and q2 such that: MR(q1 q2 ) MC(q1 ) MC(q2 ) The MC in each plant much equal MR of output as a whole. Multi-plant Profit Max, SOC SOC, profit decreasing (MR falling faster than MC -- easy if MR falling and MC rising) 2R 2R 2R slope of total MR curve = , q1q1 q1q1 q1q2 2 C1 2 C1 slope of each plant's MC curves: plant 1: , plant 2: q1q1 q1q1 2 C1 2R 0, MC in plant 1 must be rising relative to MR q1q1 q1q1 2C2 2R 0, MC in plant 2 must be rising relative to MR q2 q2 q2 q2 Now the Hessian: 2 C1 2R q1q1 q1q1 2R q1q2 2R q2 q1 2C2 2R q2 q2 q2 q2 2 2 2 2 2 2R C1 C2 R R 0 q q q q q q q q q q 1 2 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 Let's break this down on the next slide... Multi-plant Profit Max, SOC 2 2 2 2 2 2R C1 C2 R R 0 qq q1q1 qq q2q2 qq 2 2 2R 2C1 2C2 2R 2R 2C2 2R 2C1 0 q q q q q q q q q q q q q q q q 1 1 2 2 1 1 1 1 2 2 But the first and last terms cancel out, leaving us with: 2 C1 2 C 2 2R 2C2 2R 2C1 0 qq q2q2 qq q1q1 q1q1 q2q2 If MR is negative (necessary for price setters) and MC is > 0, this must hold. Even if MC at both plants = 0, this will hold. Even if MC is < 0 at each plant, this MIGHT still hold. Of course, we still need MC rising relative to MR in each plant. Graphically p $ MC1 MC2 MCT MCT D MR q1 q2 Q q1+q2=Q Q Example Solution based on FOC Demand: P 200 .05Q, Q=q1 q2 C1 .05q12 C2 .025q22 200 q1 q2 .05q12 .025q22 200 .1 q1 q2 .1q1 0 q1 200 .1 q1 q2 .05q2 0 q2 Solve each for q1 and set equal: 1000-.5q2 2,000 1.5q2 q2 1,000 Into either of the FOC to get: q1 =500 Check that MR = MC1 MC2 50 Q 1,500, P 125 SOC MC1 MC2 MR .1, .05, .1 q1q1 q2q2 QQ MR MC1 0; .1 .1 .2 QQ q1q1 MR MC2 0; .1 .05 .15 QQ q2q2 2C1 2C2 2R 2C1 2R 2C2 0 qq q1q1 qq q2q2 q1q1 q2q2 .1.1 .1 .05 .05 .1 0 .01 .005 .005 0 .02 0 Monopoly and Quality • Firms purposely make goods less durable than they could so that we have to buy replacements more often! Monopoly and Quality • Demand P P(Q,X), Q is quantity and X is quality P 0, Q P 0 X • Profit MR P(Q,X) Q C(Q,X) MC FOC P C P C P(Q,X) Q 0 Q P Q Q Q Q Q P C P C Q 0 Q X X X X X MRx MCx So long as Q* such that MR = MC, also set the MR from an increase in X = the MC of that extra X. Graphically More quality means more demand and more profit P P Low X MC Medium X MC AC AC D(X) D(X) MR Q Q* MR Q* Q Graphically But only to a point P Medium X MC P MC High X AC AC D(X) D(X) MR MR Q* Q Q* Q Monopoly and Tax Policy • • • • • Flat Tax (tax = t) Unit Tax (tax = tQ) Revenue Tax (tax = t·R(Q)) Profit (Earnings) Tax (tax = t·π) For each, start with revenue function and total cost function (C*). • R=R(Q) =P(Q)*Q • C*=C(Q) No Tax P MC R(Q) C(Q) FOC R C : 0 Q Q Q R C Q Q P* AC D: P=P(Q) Q Q* MR Flat Tax ( t > 1) P MC R(Q) C(Q) t FOC R C : 0 Q Q Q R C Q Q Same result as no tax. P*t ACt t AC D: P=P(Q) Q Q*t MR Unit Tax ( t > 0) R(Q) C(Q) tQ FOC R C : t0 Q Q Q R C t Q Q Different output from no tax. R C Q where Q Q * t MCt=MC+t P MC P*t ACt=AC+t t AC D: P=P(Q) Q Q*t MR Revenue Tax (0 < t < 1) R(Q) 1 t C(Q) FOC R C : 1 t 0 Q Q Q R C 1 t Q Q Different result from no tax. R C Q where Q Q * t P MC P*t t AC D Q Q*t P(1-t) MR MRt=MR(1-t) Profit Tax (0 < t < 1) R(Q) C(Q) 1 t P FOC R C : 1 t 0 Q Q Q R C 1 t 1 t Q Q R C Q Q Same result as no tax. MC t (1 t) P* t t D: P=P(Q) Q Q* MR Monopolistic Competition in Long Run • In the short run if π > 0, then there is no difference between a monopoly and a monopolistically competitive firm. • But despite the fact that firms have market power, there are firms providing close enough substitutes that demand for all firms falls to a level where π = 0. Profit Max , Choose Q • Assuming you know C*=C(v, w, q) max P(Q) Q C v,w,Q q FOC q MR(Q) MC(Q) 0 q MR(Q) MC(Q), choose Q such that the MR = MC R C At the same time, if =0, then R=C and = , so AR = AC Q Q Monopolistic Competition in the Long Run • MR=MC, AR=AC P MC AC P* D: P=P(Q) MR Q* Q Price Discrimination • 1st degree • 2nd degree • 3rd degree • Note, “1”, “2”, “3” mean nothing. First Degree, Perfect Price Discrimination • All buyers are charged a price equal to their willingness to pay. TC in green, TR = blue+green. P MC • No DWL • No CS either – Car dealerships – Colleges – Reverse Auction AC D: P=P(Q) P=MR • Priceline q* q Third Degree Price Discrimination • Firm can separate demanders with different demand elasticities and charge different prices to each group. • A single price must be charged to all consumers in each demand group. • Arbitrage must be prevented. Third Degree Price Discrimination • It is easy, right… just set MR=MC P P P MC D1 D2 Q • But what is MR? MR1 Q1 MR2 Q2 3rd Degree Price Discrimination • If we set MR1 = MC for the first market, then P P MC MC’ D1 MC=MR2 D2 MC=MR1 MR1 Q1 MR2 Q2 • MC for the second market has to start where MC left off. Now MR and MC are not the same in both markets. Oops! 3rd Degree Price Discrimination • We need to know MR for each unit sold, whichever market it is sold in. We need MR1=MR2=MC. P P P MC D1 D2 MR1 Q1 MR2 MRT Q2 • A horizontal sum of MR gets us the total MR curve. • Set MC = MRT to get the P that allows MR1=MR2=MC Q 3rd Degree Price Discrimination • Set that MC =MR1=MR2 to get the q in each market. P P P MC D1 D2 MR1 Q1 MR2 MRT Q2 • At those q, use demand to get the P in each market to maximize profit. MR1=MR2, but P1≠P2 Q The Math • Max π = P1(Q1)•Q1+P2(Q2)•Q2-C(Q1+Q2) • FOC Q1 RQ1 (Q1 ) CQ1 (Q 1 Q 2 ) 0 Q2 RQ2 (Q 2 ) CQ2 (Q 1 Q 2 ) 0 • Solve for Q1 and Q2, then use demand curves to get P1 and P2 MR and Elasticity • Remember that with price setters: 1 MR P 1 e • Since MR is the same for both markets • And… 1 1 MR P1 1 P2 1 e1 e2 1 1 e2 P1 P2 1 1 … so all you need is e1 and e2 e1 Example Demand 1: P1 80 5Q 1 ; R1 80Q 1 5Q 12 Demand 2: P2 180 20Q 2 ; R2 180Q 2 20Q 22 Cost: C 50 20 Q 1 Q 2 Max 80Q 1 – 5Q 12 180Q 2 20Q 22 – 50 20 Q 1 Q 2 FOC Q1 80 – 10Q 1 – 20 Q2 180 – 40Q 2 – 20 Solve to get 1 Q 1 6; P1 50; e1 1.67; 1 .4 e1 1 Q 2 4; P2 100; e2 1.25; 1 .2 e2 1 P1 1 and ; P2 2 1 e2 1 1 2 e1 1 3rd Degree Price Discrimination • Set that MC =MR1=MR2 to get the q in each market. P P P MC 100 50 D1 D2 6 MR1 Q MR2 20 Q MRT 6 4 • At those q, use demand to get the P in each market to maximize profit. MR1=MR2, but P1≠P2 Q Constant MC If MC is constant, you can simply set MR = MC in each market separately. Meh. Price P1 P2 MC MC D Q1 MR MR Q1 * 0 Q2 * D Q2 Second Degree • There are different definitions. 1. Sellers cannot differentiate buyers, so must set pricing to let the buyer self-sort themselves. 2. Generally achieved through non-linear pricing (price varies by quantity or quality). • Includes – Volume discount (as you buy more, the price falls) – Two-Part Tariff (tariff meaning price) – Bundling Volume Discount, Electricity • Graph is consumer specific • Consumer surplus now A + B + C • No so much a volume discount as a first use surcharge! P P1 A B P2 P3 PS C MC=AC Q3 Q Volume Discount: Shoes • Buy one for full price, get a second pair for ½ price! • Consumer surplus now A + B P A P1 P2 PS B MC=AC Q2 Q Two-Part Tariff • Tariff means “price” • First part is an “entry fee” and the second is the per unit fee. • Even with volume discounts, we can think of part of the initial higher price as an entry fee. • Some times the analysis is for the market and sometimes consumer specific. Two-Part Tariff (Demand is Market Demand with N consumers) • Could max profit the usual way by PM, QM (PS = C+D+F+G+J+K) • But if you can charge a fee to be able to buy, fee = (A+B+C+D+E)/N, then charge PC for the good. • PS = A+B+C+D+E+ F+G+H+J+K+L • If demanders potential consumer surplus varies a lot from (A+B+C+D+E)/N then that cannot be the entry fee. P MC PM PC B A C D G F AC E H I K L D: P=P(Q) J MR QM QC Q Laser Printers • HP charges a low price for printers (the access fee) • However, if 10 buyers each have consumer surplus of $892 (from printer plus ink) and the other 90 have CS = $12 each, entry fee is problematic. • When consumer demand varies a lot, low entry fee and higher unit price. For printers, high demanders buy more as they use them up faster. P MC PM PC B A C D G F AC E H I K L D: P=P(Q) J MR QM QC Q Two-Part Tariff • High demanders and Low demanders • In this case, the entry fee must work for the low demanders, and the price for use (ink cartridges), must be where the profit comes from. P Representative High Demander P Representative Low Demander Printer Price PINK MC=AC D MR MR Q D Q Two-Part Tariff • If mostly high demanders, then sacrifice the low. • Profit off the cartridges =$0. P Representative High Demander P Representative Low Demander Printer Price PINK MC=AC D MR MR Q 0 D Q Two-Part Tariff • If mostly low demanders, get little from the high demanders. • Profit off the cartridges =$0. P Representative High Demander P Representative Low Demander Printer Price PINK MC=AC D MR MR Q D Q Individual Analysis • Sometimes you see this as an individual level analysis. • Problem here is each consumer must be charged the same “A.” • In this case, assumption is MC=AC as a horizontal line. P A PC MC=AC B QC Q Consumer Analysis: Golf Club • Demand for a round of golf: “A” is the cost of joining the club, Pg is the price of a round. • “B” is revenue from each round. P A Pg MC=AC B Qg Q Two-Part Tariff with Entry Fee Only • Here we assume there are two types of consumers. High demanders and Low demanders • Two different quantity or quality packages can be offered. • Two-part tariff, but while the entry fee > 0, the unit fee is zero. • Demanders self select whether they are willing to pay more or less. Phone Plans • Assume MC = 0 • Plan L: Charge a price = size of area A for Q1 • Plan H: Charge a price = size of A+B+C for Q2 P DH B DL A C Q1 Q2 Q Phone Plans • But the high demanders would choose Plan L, get Q1 minutes and gain CS = B. • So it would seem that max charge for Play H is A + C. • High demanders pay A + C, and get CS = B. P DH B DL A C Q1 Q2 Q Phone Plans • • • • Even better, don’t offer Q1 as an option. Plan L: Q’1 minutes for a price of A. Plan H: Q2 minutes for a price of A + A’ + C + C’. High demanders still choose Plan H, get CS = B (which is now smaller) P • Profit gains C’ and loses A’ DH B DL C’ A C A’ Q’1 Q1 Q2 Q Phone Plans • • • • Profit Max: Q*1 stops moving leftward when ΔA’ = ΔC’ Plan L: Q*1 minutes for a price of A. Plan H: Q2 minutes for a price of A + A’ + C + C’. Low demanders get no surplus, high demanders get CS = B P • Low demanders pay A and get A (no consumer surplus) • High demanders pay A+A’+C+C’ and get A+A’+B+C+C’ • Consumer surplus = B DH B Q*1 such that: PH (Q’1) = 2 PL (Q’1) ΔC’ DL C’ A ΔA’ C A’ Q*1 Q1 Q2 Q Quantity and Quality • Phone carriers offer plans with more or fewer numbers of unlimited minutes. • But firms can vary quality instead of quantity. – Airlines offer business and coach class. • Don’t alter quantity, but quality • Lower the coach quality to encourage high demanding business travelers to pony up for business class. Bundling • There are several items that different consumers are willing to pay different amounts for, but we don’t know which items each consumers values most. • This is a version of buy one pair, get a second for ½ price, but you cannot buy one pair. Bundling • Econ students are willing to pay $80 for Excel and $40 for Word. • History students are willing to pay $40 for Excel and $80 for word. P • Selling them for $80 each means selling one of each so revenue is $160. • Selling them for $40 each means selling four, for a total revenue of $160. • Microsoft only sells a package of both for $120, so revenue is $240 A 80 B 40 MC=AC Q=2 Q Microsoft doesn’t need to know which program any buyer is willing to pay more for. Monopoly and Patents • New ideas (inventions, creative works, etc.) are costly to produce. • Once created, intellectual property has a low cost of distribution. • Perfect competition in production is assured. • No incentive to do the hard work of creation. • Writers of the US Constitution saw this – Framers specified patent and copyright protection • Yet guaranteed monopoly rights creates DWL. – Framers saw this too and also specified limits. Are the limits correct? • 17 years for a patent • How does the PDV of DWL compare to the PDV of all future consumer surplus? • Studies suggest the 17 year patent provides about 90% of the CS that would be possible if the 17 years were adjusted either direction depending on the case. Copyright Duration Assumes the author lives for 35 years beyond the creation of the work. So the current 105 year copyright is the 35 years while alive + 70.