1 Equilibrium in Goods and Services Market Supply and Demand – Equilibrium The equilibrium output depends on how the demand and supply are determined We will first focus on the demand side: What determines the demand? Sources of Demand We have considered three approaches to measure the GDP Product approach emphasizes the value-added of domestic producers Expenditure approach emphasizes spending on final goods and services produced domestically Income approach emphasizes income earned by factors operating in domestic markets These numbers should approximately be the same, though they are not exactly identical Since we are interested in the behavior of economic agents in determining their demand, we start with the expenditure approach Expenditure Approach to GDP Captures spending on all final goods and services produced domestically Divide spending into four groups C: Personal consumption of households and non-profit organization I: firms investment spending on capital goods and change in inventories G: government expenditure (consumption and investment) NX: net exports, NX=X-M X=Exports of goods and services M= imports of goods and services Y=C+I+G+NX Personal Consumption Expenditure the largest component of expenditure: a little more than 2/3 of GDP Three categories Durable goods: motor vehicles and parts Furnishings and durable household equipment Recreational goods and vehicles other durable goods Nondurable goods Food and beverages purchased for off premise consumption Clothing and footwear Gasoline and other energy good other nondurable goods Services Households: Housing and utilities, health care, transportation, recreation, food and accommodation, financial, others Non-profit institutions 2 Investment Fixed Investment Non residential: Structures: equipment: Information processing. industrial, transportation, others Intellectual properties: software, R&D, entertainment & arts Residential: new houses and new apartments Inventory investment the reason for a change in inventory does not matter Government Expenditure: consumption expenditure (employee salaries, etc) and investment expenditure (buildings) on domestic or foreign goods and services produced in current period Transfer payments (social security, medicare, unemployment insurance, welfare payments, etc) are not payment on currently produced goods and services, and hence they are not included in the government expenditure Interest payments on government debts are excluded. Federal government National Defense: Consumption and gross investment National Non-defense: Consumption and gross investment State and Local Government Consumption and gross investment This approach identifies four groups of economic agents who demand domestically produced goods HH: Households & nonprofit organization - C Firms - I Government - G Foreign countries - EX The first three groups' expenditure includes expenditures on imported goods C=Cd+Cf, I=Id+If, G=Gd+Gf Demand for domestically produced goods Cd+Id+Gd+EX=(C-Cf ) + (I-If) + (G-Gf) + EX=C+I+G+(EX-Cf-If+Gf)=C+I+G+NX Total demand for domestically produced goods and services is Y=C+I+G+NX 3 Determinants of each component Consumption expenditure – there are many factors, but the most important factor is the disposable income: C=C(Y-T) Properties of the consumption function MPC (Marginal Propensity to Consume): additional amount of consumption as disposable income rises by 1 dollar MPC is usually less than one: 0<MPC<1 If MPC is a constant, the consumption function is a linear function: C=C0+MPC*(Y-T) C0 is called the subsistence level consumption Investment expenditure: I=I(r), r=real interest rate An increase in interest rate reduces investment Government expenditure: G This includes employee salaries and investment in buildings, national defense, etc It does not include transfer payment such as social securities, unemployment compensation, etc, because this is not the expenditure on current output Therefore, we can think of it as predetermined, unless there is a discrete fiscal policy changes such as Obama's stimulus package Net export: NX=NX() =real exchange rate The nominal exchange rate is the amount of foreign currency (e.g., German Mark) that that you can buy with one U.S. dollar (we will learn later the difference between the nominal and real exchange rates) An increase in exchange rate makes foreign good cheaper to U.S. buyers, and makes the U.S. good more expensive to foreign buyers. Therefore, an increase in the exchange rate increases import and reduces export. This means that the net export NX decreases as the exchange rate increases Demand for Goods and Services Sum of the demands of the four groups discussed above: Yd=C(Y-T)+I(r)+G+NX() Supply of Goods and Services assume a perfectly elastic supply That is, firms produce the amount of demand Ys=Yd=Y Equilibrium Output Output/income Y that satisfies Y=C(Y-T)+I(r)+G+NX() Note: This assumes that firms distribute all proceeds of produced output to households. There is no business taxes: only households pay income tax which is a lump sum tax (does not depend on income level) Endogenous and Exogenous variables Endogenous variable: variable that depends on other variables in the system Exogenous variable: variable that does not depend on other variables in the system 4 We start with a simplest system Endogenous variables: Y, C, Exogenous variables: r, , I, G, T, NX For given exogenous variables I, G and NX, the equilibrium income Y is the value of Y that satisfies the following equality Y=C(Y-T)+I+G+NX Graphical Analysis A graph measuring Y on the horizontal axis Draw a line that represents the supply (left hand side of the equation): It is a 45 degree line Draw a line that represents the demand (right hand side of the equation): C+I+G+NX The equilibrium income is where the two lines intersect each other Note: Suppose the current output is below the equilibrium output Y*. Then, demand is higher than supply and output rises. C+I+G+NX Ys Yd Y Comparative Statics Increase in T by T: This reduces the disposable income and shifts Yd curve downward and the equilibrium income decreases Increase in G by G: This shifts Yd curve upward and the equilibrium income increases Increase in interest rate: This reduces I and shifts Yd curve downward and the equilibrium income decreases Increase in exchange rate : This reduces NX and shifts Yd curve downward and the equilibrium income decreases 5 Algebraic solution Assume a linear consumption function Y=C0+MPC*(Y-T)+I+G+NX 𝑌= 𝐶0 −𝑀𝑃𝐶∗𝑇+𝐼+𝐺+𝑁𝑋 1−𝑀𝑃𝐶 Comparative Static Analysis Increase in T by T: Y=-[MPC/(1-MPC)]T Increase in G by G: Y=[1/(1-MPC)]G Increase in I by I: Y=[1/(1-MPC)]I Increase in NX by NX: Y=[1/(1-MPC)]NX Government expenditure multiplier 1/(1-MPC) Tax multiplier: -MPC/(1-MPC) Balanced budget multiplier: [1-MPC]/(1-MPC)=1 Explanation of Government Expenditure Multiplier Effects 1st round: an increase in G increases the demand ⇒ output increases to meet the demand: ∆𝑌1 = ∆𝐺 Proceeds from additional output are distributed to HH as wages and dividends (no retained earnings, no business taxes). That is, households' income rises by ∆𝑌1 2nd round: an increase in income of HH by ∆𝑌1 ⇒ HH consumes MPC*∆𝑌1 (and saves (1-MPC) ∆𝑌1 ) ⇒ demand increases by MPC* ∆𝑌1 ⇒ output increases to meet this additional demand: ∆𝑌2 = 𝑀𝑃𝐶 ∗ ∆𝑌1 = 𝑀𝑃𝐶 ∗ ∆𝐺 This increases HH's income by ∆𝑌2 . 3rd round: an increase in income of HH by ∆𝑌2 ⇒ HH consumes MPC*∆𝑌2 (and saves (1-MPC) ∆𝑌2 ) ⇒ demand increases by MPC* ∆𝑌2 ⇒ output increases to meet this additional demand: ∆𝑌3 = 𝑀𝑃𝐶 ∗ ∆𝑌2 = 𝑀𝑃𝐶 ∗ (𝑀𝑃𝐶 ∗ ∆𝐺) = 𝑀𝑃𝐶 2 ∗ ∆𝐺 This increases HH's income by ∆𝑌3 . This process continues and total increase in output/income is ∆𝑌 = ∆𝑌1 + ∆𝑌2 + ∆𝑌3 + ∆𝑌4 + ⋯ = ∆𝐺 + 𝑀𝑃𝐶 ∗ ∆𝐺 + 𝑀𝑃𝐶 2 ∗ ∆𝐺 + +𝑀𝑃𝐶 3 ∗ ∆𝐺 + ⋯ Therefore, ∆𝑌 = (1 + 𝑀𝑃𝐶 + 𝑀𝑃𝐶 2 + 𝑀𝑃𝐶 3 + ⋯ ) ∗ ∆𝐺 = 1 ∆𝐺 1−𝑀𝑃𝐶 And one dollar increase in government expenditure increases income by 1/(1-MPC) Remark: If the proceeds from the first round increase in output is retained and not distributed to households, the multiplier process stops there and total increase in income is just the initial increase in demand ∆𝐺. 6 Explanation of Tax Multiplier Effects 1st round: an increase in T by ∆𝐺 decreases the deposable income by the same amount. Therefore, HH consumption decreases by MPC*∆𝑇 ⇒ output decreases to meet the reduced demand: ∆𝑌1 = 𝑀𝑃𝐶 ∗ ∆𝑇 2nd round: a decrease in income of HH by ∆𝑌1 ⇒ HH reduces consumption by MPC*∆𝑌1 ⇒ demand decreases by MPC* ∆𝑌1 ⇒ output decreases to meet this additional reduced demand: ∆𝑌2 = 𝑀𝑃𝐶 ∗ ∆𝑌1 = 𝑀𝑃𝐶 2 ∗ ∆𝑇 This decreases HH's income by ∆𝑌2 . 3rd round: a decrease in income of HH by ∆𝑌2 ⇒ HH reduces consumption MPC*∆𝑌2 ⇒ demand decreases by MPC* ∆𝑌2 ⇒ output decreases to meet this additional reduced demand: ∆𝑌3 = 𝑀𝑃𝐶 ∗ ∆𝑌2 = 𝑀𝑃𝐶 ∗ (𝑀𝑃𝐶 2 ∗ ∆𝑇) = 𝑀𝑃𝐶 3 ∗ ∆𝑇 This decreases HH's income by ∆𝑌3 . This process continues and total decrease in output/income is ∆𝑌 = ∆𝑌1 + ∆𝑌2 + ∆𝑌3 + ∆𝑌4 + ⋯ = 𝑀𝑃𝐶 ∗ ∆𝑇 + 𝑀𝑃𝐶 2 ∗ ∆𝑇 + +𝑀𝑃𝐶 3 ∗ ∆𝑇 + ⋯ Therefore, 𝑀𝑃𝐶 ∆𝑌 = (𝑀𝑃𝐶 + 𝑀𝑃𝐶 2 + 𝑀𝑃𝐶 3 + ⋯ ) ∗ ∆𝑇 = 1−𝑀𝑃𝐶 ∆𝑇 And one dollar increase in lump sum tax collection decreases income by MPC/(1-MPC) 7 Alternative expression for the equilibrium condition We will consider a closed economy first, that is, NX=0 The equilibrium condition is Y=C(Y-T)+I+G National Savings S=Y-C-G Note: National saving S can be decomposed into private saving (Y-T-C) and public saving (T-G): Y-C-G = (Y-T-C) + (T-G). The equilibrium condition can now be written as S=I The national saving S is the supply of Loanable Funds and investment is the demand for loanable funds. Interest rate is the price of loanable funds If interest rate is flexible (endogenous) as we will learn later, then it adjusts until supply equals demand (saving equals investment). Graphical analysis of equilibrium condition S=I in loanable fund market in a closed economy S=Y-C-G=Y-C(Y-T)-G=Y-[C0+MPC(Y-T)]-G = -(C0+G-MPC*T) + (1-MPC)*Y In a graph with Y on the horizontal axis, the savings function is a line intercept -(C0+G-MPC*T) and slope (1-MPC) which is the marginal propensity to save (MPS). Investment is assumed I=I(r), which does not depend on Y. Therefore, for a given r, the line that represents the investment is a horizontal line (i.e., stays the same as Y changes) The equilibrium income is where the two lines intersect each other S I Y Comparative static analysis An increase in G or a decrease in T reduces the national savings for any given Y (i.e., the intercept term becomes a larger negative number). This shifts the S curve downward. Therefore, the equilibrium income rises An increase in investment (say, due to a decrease in r) shifts I curve upward, and hence the equilibrium income rises. An increase in G and T by the same amount shifts the S curve downward, which increases the equilibrium income. 8 IS Curve: Goods and service market equilibrium We showed that an increase in interest rate r reduces investment, which in turn reduces the equilibrium income, given G and T. Therefore, there is a negative relationship between Y and r that keeps the G&S market at equilibrium Consider a graph that measures Y on the horizontal axis and r on the vertical axis. The line that shows the relationship between Y and r for the equilibrium in the goods and service market is called the IS curve. The name is from I=S equilibrium condition. Algebraic derivation Suppose the consumption and investment functions are linear C=C0+MPC*(Y-T) I=I0-d*r where d is a constant slope of the investment function. It captures the effect of a change in r on I: an increase in r by 1% reduces investment by $d From the equilibrium condition Y=C(Y-T)+I(r)+G, or I(r)=S=Y-C(Y-T)-G, we write Y=C(Y-T)+I(r)+G=C0+MPC*Y-MPC*T+I0-d*r+G Solving for Y, we have Y C0 MPC * T I 0 G d r 1 MPC 1 MPC or solving for r r C0 MPC * T I 0 G 1 MPC Y d d This explicitly shows the negative relationship between Y and r. r An increase in C0, I0 and G shifts the IS curve upward An increase in MPC shifts the IS curve down and makes it steeper An increase in d shifts the IS curve down and makes it flatter IS Y