Illegal Labor Markets Lent Term Ec 423: Labour Economics Lecture 9 Legal vs. Illegal Sectors So far have consider two roles of occupation selection: High vs. Low skills human capital/ signaling model Gender/Race segregation Can be other types of markets Informal: Legal jobs not reported/measured in standard activity Black Market: Trade/activity often in illegal or restricted goods Criminal Activity: Illegal actions performed for gain but not necessarily for the purpose of trade What’s Important about Illegal Markets? Important alternative way to allocate time May have different returns to human capital May have distinct career paths/specific capital/OTJ training Externalities High potential social costs to criminal activities themselves May generate costs for local areas (similar to agglomeration issues for urban growth) Link to Legal Sector Wages Decision to enter or exit may be based on expected wages Strong interaction here with: Returns to Education Education Production/Credit Constraints Discrimination Occupation Mobility May be long-term costs to entry into illegal sector Much more difficult to exit once detected This Lecture Model of Criminal Participation Focus on interaction with legal sector Wages in Legal vs. Illegal Sector Penalty for Participation Racial Composition Next time: Focus on the Illegal Sector Taxing Participation Deterrence vs. Incapcitation Extreme Test for Economics Inherently risky: attitudes toward risk are critical in decision-making. Criminal behavior is subject to strategic gaming by the police, criminals, and the public, per the Prisoner's Dilemma. Psychology of Criminality Basic Model Individual will choose to commit crimes in a given time period rather than do legal work when: (1 - p)U(Wc) - pU(S) > u(w) Wc is the gain from successful crime p the probability of being apprehended S the extent of punishment, W is earnings from legitimate work Implications for legal wages Crime must pay a higher wage than legitimate activities. If p= 0, U(Wc) > U(W) only if Wc > W As p rises the gap between Wc and W must increase to maintain the advantage of crime. Successful crime must pay off more the greater the chance of being apprehended May be non-pecuniary gains to crime (we’ll sidebar this for now but come back to it) Risk Aversion that attitudes toward risk are measured by the curvature of U Differences in responses to costs of crime changes in the chances of being apprehended changes in the extent of punishment Heterogeneity Clearly not likely to be the same as average RA in population May be lots of heterogeneity within those in the illegal sector Costs and Opportunity Costs If we accept that sentences “deter” crime, must suggest that some individuals on the margin respond to costs the major factors that affect the decisions to commit crime - criminal versus legitimate earnings, the chance of being caught, and the extent of sentencing - are intrinsically related. If tougher sentences can theoretically reduce crime then so may improvements in the legitimate opportunities of criminals Crime Supply To get the supply of crimes and criminal participation equations for the population, aggregate to obtain the supply curves of crime: CPP = f(Wc,p, S, W) CPR = g(Wo,p, S, W) CPP =f(1 - p)W c - pS - W),p) CPR = g(1 - p)Wc - pS - W,p) where the first term represents the expected value of crime versus legal work, and p measures risk. Crime “Demand” For Informal and Black Market, ‘Crime’ demand is just the demand for the products supplied Easy to imagine in the case of drugs or prostitution Generally, issue is elasticity of demand Victims' crime more complicated to think about Should be negatively related to Wc or to the expected reward to crime ((1 - p)Wc - pS - W) in a demand type relation. Intuition 1: Additional crimes are likely to induce society to increase p or S, cutting the rewards to crime. Intuition 2: As criminals commit more crimes, they will move from more lucrative crimes to less lucrative crimes. Market Equilibrium An upward sloping supply curve to crime and downward sloping "demand" relation produce a market clearing level of crime and rewards to crime comparable to the market clearing wages and employment for other occupations or industries Important implication for the efficacy of mass incarceration in reducing crimes. Simple demand-supply framework fails to explain some important phenomenon concentration of crime in geographic areas or over time Adverse effect of crime on legitimate earnings Returns to Incarceration A major benefit of incarceration is that it removes criminals from civil society so that they cannot commit additional offenses Given the wide variation in crimes committed by criminals, incarceration of chronic offenders should have a particularly large effect in reducing crime. Inelastic Supply: if you lock up someone who commits, l0 muggings a year, no one replaces that criminal in the alley, the number of muggings should drop by 10 Perfectly Elastic Supply: if you lock someone who commit, instant replacement and no decline in crime Supply and Demand with Incarceration Supply WC w2 w1 Demand L2 L1 LC Theory and Evidence Based on Model Effect of Legal Employment/wages on criminal participation Does increased unemployment increase crime? Do increases in wages in certain sectors reduce crime? Does inequality affect crime? Exclusivity of Illegal and Legal Sectors Typically for ease, we think of crime/legitimate work decision a dichotomous one, The border between illegal and legal work is porous, persons commit crimes while employed doubling up their legal and illegal work. Some persons use their legal jobs to succeed in crime Some criminals shift between crime and work over time, depending on opportunities. Maximization Problem chooses time at market work (tm) and time committing crime (tv) Individual then subject to a budget constraint and a time constraint For simplicity set nonlabor income A=0 and define the marginal rate of substitution Participation conditions The individual’s reservation wage = u0. participation in the two sectors requires that w > u0 p'(0) > u0 the returns to the first hour of work in either sector is greater than the reservation utility of an individual Participation in the Insurgency An individual working in both the legal and illegal sectors will choose their optimal time allocation to satisfy: p'(tV) = w to participate in both sectors: p'(0) > w Three groups Only Legal: p'(0) ≤ 0 : tv=0, tm>0 Both: p'(0) > 0: tv >0, tm > 0 Only Illegal: p'(0) >> 0: tv >0, tm = 0 Extensive vs. Intensive Margin In theory, can change crime labor supply both by changing number participating and/or number of hours available Can put this together to estimate Unobservability of participation Difficult to observe true participation Use production function of crime in an area j at time t as Ajt = f (Ljt, Kjt) Can Observe total number of crimes (i.e. output) Can now return this to our standard labor economics framework For many types of crime, extremely labor intensive, don’t need to worry about K Labor: Evidence: Unemployment and Crime Large sociology/criminology literature doesn’t find much Depends heavily on macroeconomic and time series variation Unclear what underlying forces drive market activity and crime—typically left out of analysis Not much “natural experiment” evidence on this Control for a bunch of stuff Structural model Mechanisms linking Crime and Economic Conditions Lots of things happen when the economy is worse Worse legitimate employment opportunities, More criminal opportunities Increased consumption of criminogenic commodities (alcohol, drugs, guns) Changes in the response of the criminal justice system. Rafael and Winters use this breakdown and then use military contracts as an instrument for employment opportunities First Stage Bottom line: Not much Evidence Controlling for other factors, almost all of these studies report a statistically significant but substantively small relationship between unemployment rates and property crime (consistent across lots of evidence) Can explain an estimated 2 percent decline in property crime (out of an observed drop of almost 30 percent) Violent crime does not change May operate in indirect channels of state and local government budgets. increased spending on police prisons Issues with Estimation Most criminals have limited education and labor market skills, poor employment records, and low legitimate earnings. For instance, the 1991 Survey of State Prison Inmates reports that two-thirds had not graduated high school, though many had obtained a general equivalency degree Among 25-34 year olds, approximately 12% of all male high school dropouts were incarcerated in 1993. The average AFQT score of criminals is below that of noncriminals. A disproportionate number of criminals report that they were jobless in the period prior to their arrest. Issues with Existing Evidence Those business cycles may not significantly affect the outcomes of the worst off Changes in unemployment not operating on correct margin Not observing same set of people affected by jobs/wages/etc. Crimes that may be most affected may be least observable Incarceration in the US Long-term Labor Market Consequences Crime rates not just negative externality, but huge costs for individuals in terms of lost earnings Why? Signal of quality Depreciation of human capital Loss of experience Identification issue Prison is not independent of other things Worse offenders in prison longer Least able in prison (?) Can try to separate out 3 effects Type of person who would be in prison (if prison itself is unobservable) Ever in prison Duration in Prison Evidence on Incarceration - 1 Freeman's studies of the effects of criminal activity on the labor market outcomes for youth finds incarceration was significantly linked to lower future employment and weeks worked, Cannot say whether the link is due to the sentencing or to the fact that only youths deeply involved in crime are incarcerated. In the NLSY young men who were incarcerated worked around 12 weeks less per year as other young men over an ensuing seven year period, giving a 25% lower rate of work activity. One reason for the huge incarceration effect in the NLSY is that persons incarcerated have a high probability of engaging in crime again and being re-incarcerated and thus not able to work even if they wanted to do so. even among non-institutionalized young men, those who have been to jail/prison have lower employment rates than others and a lower rate of employment than they had before going to jail or prison ( Nagin and Waldfogel (1995) find a positive effect of conviction on employment in a sample of British youths. Evidence on Incarceration - 2 Bushway's (1996) analysis of the National Youth Survey 32 found adverse effects from being arrested on both weeks worked and weekly earnings. Grogger (1995) merged longitudinal arrest records from the California correctional system with unemployment insurance earnings records to examine the effects of arrests and sanctions on male employment and earnings. Within three yem's of an arrest, respondents who were arrested worked seven weeks less, and earned $92 per week less, than would otherwise be expected without an arrest Men who were arrested, convicted, or sent to jail or prison had lower earnings and employment than others, but more in the short-term than in the long run. Workers who went to prison had about a 20% lower earnings than others, while those who went to jail experienced about a 15% lower earnings Attributed about one-third of black-white differences in non-employment to the effect of arrests on future employment. Waldfogel (1992) finds a large effect of incarceration on earnings and employment The negative earnings effect is more pronounced among white collar criminals, 10-30% less 5-8 years after release than those convicted but not incarcerated. Conviction for embezzlement and larceny reduces the future legitimate incomes by about 40%, Lott (1993a) shows even greater drops in legitimate income, presumably due to reduced time in legitimate work, for persons convicted of drug dealing. Effect of Duration on Earnings What is the effect of longer incarceration rates on earnings? (Kling AER paper): Variation in judges generates variation in sentencing Judges are randomly assigned Look at earnings and recidivism rates (we’ll focus on the first one) Earnings by Duration in Prison Source: Kling, AER (1999) Identification Begin with simple OLS specification of earnings (Y) on sentence length (S) controlling for individual characteristics, X, Data used in the paper has very small sample size of observations on both pre- and post-spell outcomes for the same individuals to estimate the extent of any pre-existing differences, he imposes a modeling assumption that the association between incarceration length and pre-spell outcomes is stable over time. How he estimates—OLS Fixed effects model: Assume things are the same for individuals and any deviation due to incarcerations so look at same individuals, pre and post incarceration Control for actual pre-existing differences and then compare changes over time Source: Kling, AER (1999) How he estimates—IV Model exogenous variation in sentence length itself as function of judge (Z) Identifying assumption Judge Assignment is random Some judges have ‘preference’ for longer sentences Preference independent of underlying case characteristics (or at least conditionally independent) Source: Kling, AER (1999) Bottom line on Duration no substantial evidence of a negative effect of incarceration length on employment or earnings. In the medium term, seven to nine years after incarceration spells began, the effect of incarceration length on labor market outcomes is negligible. In the short term, one to two years after release, longer incarceration spells are associated with higher employment and earnings -- a finding which is largely explained by differences in offender characteristics and by incarceration conditions, such as participation inwork release programs. Bottom-line on Incarceration Involvement with the criminal justice system affects future labor market outcomes. Incarceration is negatively correlated with future outcomes while the correlation between arrest and conviction and ensuing work activity is generally more moderate. The question remains open, however, about the causal mechanisms, if any, that underlie the links. Moreover, the effects probably vary among groups and over time and across prison experiences. As more and more men are sent to jail or prison Any stigma attached to incarceration in the job market may fall (it is less of signal) The adverse relation between incarceration and labor outcomes may also have a strong age component, being larger among younger men and smaller among older men in the declining part of the age-crime curve. Some evidence that prisoners who receive job training or who work in prison have better employment experiences after release than others. Is there a ‘stigma’ to incarceration? The labor market prospects of ex-offenders are likely to be impacted by whether employers have access to their criminal history records. Employers may be reluctant to hire job applicants with criminal histories for fear that such applicants may harm a customer or be more likely to steal. If employers can and do review criminal history records, individuals with past convictions are likely to be excluded from consideration. Given the high proportion of blacks who have served time, one might argue that such exclusion should have particularly adverse consequences for African-Americans. Holzer, Rafael, Stoller (2006) The effect of Criminal Background Checks Use variation in legality of employment checks to measure likelihood of background checks Look at employment rates of blacks Follow-up studies in sociology using ‘names’ approach on resume finds more mixed results Hard to know how much is really due to incarceration statistical discrimination vs. other stuff Costs for Non-Criminals Employer review criminal history records may also impact the labor market prospects of individuals without criminal records. If accessibility to criminal history information is limited (due to cost, state prohibitions, or the incompleteness of state and federal records), employers may infer the likelihood of past criminal activity from race Such statistical discrimination would adversely affect the employment outcomes of individuals with clean histories that belong to demographic groups with high conviction rates. How big is the effect? about 30% of employers do not want to hire exoffenders but do not check criminal records. For these employers, there is a total employment reduction of 1.0-1.3 percentage points on a base of roughly 10 percent (Table 2). These data imply that statistical discrimination of this type reduces the demand for labor among black men by 10-13 percent, which can be regarded as a lower bound to the true effect. The extent to which this reduced demand translates into wage and employment reductions then depend, of course, on the relevant labor demand and supply elasticities for this group The Illegal Sector Slightly outside the bounds of labor economics Prostitution/drugs/ etc. typically performed by organized crime Markets for illegal activity linked with markets for informal activity Negative externalities: Increased crime in neighborhoods Reduced property values worse public goods, etc. Big Issue: Observability Very hard to observe Prices Quantities Labor Supply/Demand Not clear how well defined market is Extortion/risk/costs of business Inelastic demand Growing work Economics of Organized Crime Mostly Theoretical on networks or organization Increasing Empirical focus, largely due to international terrorism issues Economics of Drugs/Drug Markets Addiction Penalties Rehabilitation Innovation in Illegal Markets: Crack Crack cocaine is a smoked version of cocaine that provides a short, but extremely intense, high. The invention of crack represented a technological innovation that dramatically widened the availability and use of cocaine in inner cities. Sold in small quantities in relatively anonymous street markets, crack provided a lucrative market for drug sellers and street gangs Observing Crack Really hard to do Previous literature has mixed up outcomes At the time, didn’t really know what was happening so not much data collection Now, hard to observe ex-post Outcomes and correlates the same thing—hard to test what the causal effect was Homicides Foster care Birthweight Hard to know what the true contribution of crack might be Outcomes vs. Proxies Inputs into the index cocaine arrests and cocaine-related ER visits frequency of crack cocaine mentions in newspapers, Cocaine-related drug deaths the number of DEA drug seizures and undercover drug buys that involve cocaine. Outcomes - 1 Outcomes - 2 Drugs and Gangs An important aspect of illegal markets is that the finance illegal activities Most frequent concern is the role of drugs in financing gangs and thus encouraging violence Akerloff and Yellen (1994) model: need 3 parties: the gang, the police and the populace Concerns over negative externalities here are very large Gang Organization Data Really not many sources Levitt and Venkatesh collect data in Chicago gangs We don’t know how externally valid these are Provide important insight into gangs Average Financing of Gangs How much money per sale? ‘‘back-of-the envelope’’ suggest these estimates are reasonable. Using these revenue figures and average dollars per sale of $10 the number of sales per hour by a drugselling team ranges from five to twelve over the sample. That frequency of sale is consistent with self-reports of the participants as well as other observational data Expenditures nonwage costs: costs of drugs sold payments to higher levels of the gang Weapons payments to mercenary fighters funeral costs/ payments to families of the deceased The greatest nonwage expenditure of the gang was the regular tribute payment to higher levels of the gang. almost 20 percent of total revenues. Returns to Gang Membership the gang leader retains between $4,200 and $10,900 a month as profit, for an annual wage of $50,000–130,000 This value is well above what leaders could hope to earn in the legitimate sector given their education and work experience. otherwise would have been, The officers each earn roughly $1000 per month. These tasks are generally full-time jobs (in the sense that the people who perform them would be unlikely to be concurrently employed in the legitimate sector) Return to gang-membership - 2 Relatively low wages in the first few years In year four: wages shoot up. Why? On the job training? Increased promotion/weeding out Tournament Evidence of Gang Tournament Next Time Economics of Crime: The Costs side What happens if we increase the cost of crime? Increased Sentence Length Increase Probability of Detection Does response depend on type of crime? Does response depend on type of criminal?