Appendix A: Suggested Economic Experiments to Accompany Behavioral Economics While learning about behavioral economic concepts and models can be useful, often students struggle to first admit that they fall prey to many of the same anomalies that they are learning about. It is really only after we admit we are susceptible that we can learn ways to avoid such anomalies. Economic experiments have long served as a means for researchers to demonstrate anomalous behavior. However, participation in economic experiments can also serve to cement in the behavioral economics students understanding an intuitive notion of the fundamentals of behavioral economics. For this reason, I am providing a set of experimental protocols that should be relatively easy to implement in most college classroom settings. These experiments are designed to accompany the materials from the chapters of Behavioral Economics. From experience, these exercises tend to work best when students first participate in an experiment, and then the data from the experiment is used to teach about the anomalous behavior of interest. In order to avoid the situation in which students use what they have learned from their readings to perform in a superior way in these exercises, it may be worthwhile to complete the experiments a week or two prior to covering the material and assigning the readings in the text. This makes it difficult for a student to convince themself that they are not subject to the same anomalous behavior that their peers are. Moreover, the experiments can provide a point of engagement and excitement that is difficult to obtain in most courses in economics or business. These experiments work best when students are motivated by monetary rewards. In many schools it will not be possible to provide these from the general instructional budget. Alternatively, it may be worthwhile to charge students a small fee to participate in the class (e.g., $40) and using this pool of money to reward students as they participate in experiments throughout the semester. Generally the students may participate in experiments with rewards or penalties accruing to their account. The money in this account is then distributed at some later date. In the descriptions below I refer to experimental dollars. Instructors may use actual dollars in place of these experimental dollars. Alternatively, it may be useful to create experimental dollars from small chits of paper that can be exchanged either for actual dollars or course credit at some later point. Most of these experiments are best to run with a group of 25 to 35 students. This may necessitate dividing the class into sections for days when experiments will take place. While these suggested experiments provide a solid basis for learning, many other experiments are freely available on the web and can add to the experience. All-You-Can-Eat Candies (Supports Chapter 2) Purpose: The purpose of this experiment is to demonstrate the sunk cost fallacy using a simple and inexpensive experiment. Materials: The instructor will need: i) A large bowl full of candies – more than the entire class would eat in a setting. These should be candies that can be eaten in approximately continuously varying amounts (e.g., M&Ms, Nerds) and that are generally desirable. ii) Paper cups that can be used to dole out small amounts of the candy. iii) Experimental dollars ($4 worth for each participant). iv) Small slips of paper. v) An even number of poker chips and an opaque bag or bowl to draw them from. vi) A pen. Preparation: Place the large bowl of candies on a table that is visible to all participants. Upon each poker chip, write a price. Half of the poker chips should list a higher price, like “Price = $2”, while the other half should list a lower price, like “Price = $1”. These prices should be chosen to be appropriate to the particular participants and their value for access to the candy chosen. The higher price should be low enough that most will be willing to pay this price for access to the candy. Write a participant number on each cup to allow you to keep track of how much was eaten by each and which price they paid. For the Instructor: As class members arrive, hand each one a slip of paper. At the same time, hand each class member $4 worth of experimental dollars. Once all have arrived, begin by reading aloud the For the Participant instructions. Ask if there are any questions regarding the procedure. Instruct them to write down their maximum willingness to pay for the candy. Then, call each student to the front of the class one at a time. Allow each student to draw a poker chip to determine the price. If the price is below their willingness to pay, take the necessary number of experimental dollars as a fee, and give the student a cup with a pre-determined number of pieces of candy (e.g., 10). Remind them that these may be eaten at the pleasure of the participant—but cannot be shared with any other classmates, nor removed from the classroom. Once these have been eaten, the student is allowed at any point during the class to return to the front and receive another serving. Inform them that they will need to return any uneaten candy to you in this cup at the end of the class. The number of candies in a cup should be chosen to be small enough that most students will want to return at least once, and many will want to return 3 or more times. Note on a piece of paper the subject number from the cup, and keep track of how many times the student returns for more candies. Also note the price each student pays, as well as their willingness to pay next to their participant number. Students may participate in other instruction, or an exercise (such as Reference Dependent Demand below) in the remaining class time. At the end of the class, collect all uneaten candy and use this and the number of refills each participant received to determine how many candies each student ate. For the Participant: You will now have the opportunity to purchase access to allyou-can-eat candy with the experimental dollars you have been given. Those who purchase access to all-you-can-eat candy will be given a paper cup with ___ pieces of candy in it. You may not share this or any candy with anyone else in the class. You may not remove any piece of candy from the classroom at the end of the class today. You may eat the pieces of candy at your pleasure throughout the class. If at any time after purchasing access to the candy you run out, you may return to the front of the class for a refill of your cup. In order to purchase access to the candy, you must first place a bid. Each of you will write down the highest amount you would be willing to pay to obtain access to allyou-can-eat candy on your slip of paper. The highest bid you are allowed to write down is $4. Once you have written down the most you would be willing to pay, the price for access will be determined. Your price will be determined in the following way. The instructor will call you to the front of the class and ask you to blindly draw a poker chip from a bag (or bowl). This poker chip will have a price written upon it. If this price is above your maximum willingness to pay, then you will not purchase access to the candy. If this price is below your maximum willingness to pay, you will pay the price on the poker chip, and be given access to the candy. All remaining experimental dollars will be yours to keep. It is in your best interest to write down the greatest amount your would be indifferent between retaining, or giving up in exchange for access to the candy. If you bid too little, you may end up forgoing the candy when you really want it. If you bid too much, you may end up losing more money than the candy is really worth to you. Suggestions for Use in Lecture: The key to this experiment is to use the willingness to pay data to eliminate selection bias. If we simply compare the number of candies eaten by those who pay the high price to the number of candies eaten by those who pay the low price, any difference may be due to the fact that those with higher willingness to pay also like candy a lot more. Instead, select only those who were willing to pay more than the higher price for your analysis. The analysis is most easily presented by comparing the mean number of candies eaten for the higher price to the mean number eaten for the lower price. A simple difference in means test could be presented if the background of the students includes statistics. In general we find that those who pay more (given that all were willing to pay either price) tend to eat more, demonstrating that they were eating to get their money’s worth rather than based on independently declining marginal utility of consumption. This can be a powerful example when presenting sunk cost fallacy in classroom lectures. Reference Dependent Demand (Supports Chapter 2) Purpose: These hypothetical questions are designed to demonstrate that students tend to base their evaluations of worth and utility on context. Materials: The instructor will need: i) Two sets of answer sheets printed from the section below, For the Participant Preparation: Shuffle answer sheets so that they can be distributed randomly to students in the class. For the Instructor: Distribute the materials to students, and ask them to read and answer all questions. Remind students not to discuss the questions with one another. For the Participant:1 Form A: I. Imagine that you are going to a sold-out hockey playoff game, and you have an extra ticket to sell or give away. The price marked on the ticket is $5 which is what you paid for each ticket. You get to the game early to make sure you get rid of the ticket. An informal survey of people selling tickets indicates that the going price is $5. You find someone who wants the ticket and takes out his wallet to pay you. He asks how much you want for the ticket. Assume that there is no law against charging a price higher than that marked on the ticket. What price do you ask for if 1. He is a friend_______________ 2. He is a stranger_________________ What would you have said if instead you found the going market price was $10? 3. Friend _______________ 4. Stranger________________. II. You are lying on the beach on a hot day. All you have to drink is ice water. For the last hour you have been thinking about how much you would enjoy a nice cold bottle of your favorite brand of soda. A companion gets up to go make a phone call and offers to bring back a soda from the only nearby place where beer is sold a fancy resort hotel. He says that the beer might be expensive and so asks how much you are willing to pay for the beer. He says that he will buy the beer if it costs as much or less than the price you state. But if it costs more than the price you state he will not buy it. You trust your friend, and there is no possibility of bargaining with the bar- tender. What price do you tell him? All materials for this exercise reprinted with permission from Thaler, R. “Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice” Marketing Science 27(1980): 15-25. 1 Form B: I. Imagine that you are going to a sold-out hockey playoff game, and you have an extra ticket to sell or give away. The price marked on the ticket is $5 but you paid $10 each for your tickets when you bought them from another student. You get to the game early to make sure you get rid of the ticket. An informal survey of people selling tickets indicates that the going price is $5. You find someone who wants the ticket and takes out his wallet to pay you. He asks how much you want for the ticket. Assume that there is no law against charging a price higher than that marked on the ticket. What price do you ask for if 1. He is a friend_______________ 2. He is a stranger_________________ What would you have said if instead you found the going market price was $10? 3. Friend _______________ 4. Stranger________________. II. You are lying on the beach on a hot day. All you have to drink is ice water. For the last hour you have been thinking about how much you would enjoy a nice cold bottle of your favorite brand of soda. A companion gets up to go make a phone call and offers to bring back a soda from the only nearby place where beer is sold a small, run-down grocery store. He says that the beer might be expensive and so asks how much you are willing to pay for the beer. He says that he will buy the beer if it costs as much or less than the price you state. But if it costs more than the price you state he will not buy it. You trust your friend, and there is no possibility of bargaining with store owner. What price do you tell him? Suggestions for Use in Lecture: For questions I and II, compare the mean responses of students for each of the answers. The questions posed on form A and form B are identical aside from the context given in questions I and II. Students in question I will have a tendency to value the tickets according to how much they paid for them. Thus, we should see higher average responses for form B, that paid $10, than A, that paid $10. Alternatively, individuals tend to expect higher prices at a resort than at a grocery store. Thus, we should find students with for A giving a higher mean willingness to pay than those with Form B in question II. These could be presented with simple means, or including t-tests for differences in the means if appropriate for the class and number of students. Question III on forms A and B are identical. Further, the outcomes from the questions in III are all financially identical, and thus would lead one to think that there is no difference in how happy each individual is. Nonetheless, if you present the total percent circling A, B, and “No Difference” from both Forms A and B you will most often find that students believe Mr. A is better off in 1 and 2, and B is better off in 3 and 4. This can be useful in introducing the notion of reference dependent demand. Going to the Game and the Theater (Supports Chapter 3) Purpose: These questions are designed to show that students base their decisions on how to spend based upon prior spending rather than future cost and benefit. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) Two sets of answer sheets printed from the section below For the Participant Preparation: Shuffle answer sheets so they can be randomly assigned to students. For the Instructor: Distribute the materials to students, and ask them to read and answer all questions. Remind students not to discuss the questions with one another. For the Participant: 2 Form A: 1. How much do you spend in an average week on entertainment? ______________ 2. How much do you spend on clothing in the average month? ____________ 3. How much do you spend on food in the average week? _____________ 4. Suppose you are out at a favorite hang-out with friends and spend $25 for food and drink. How much would spend on entertainment the rest of the week? ________________ 5. Suppose you receive an unexpected notice from the university that you owe $200 due immediately. The university had raised their activities fees just after you had paid your tuition and fees for the semester leading to the extra charge. How much would you spend on clothing the rest of the month? _____________ 6. You have just purchased the ingredients for a gourmet meal you have intended to make for quite a while. The ingredients cost $40. How much will you spend on food the rest of the week? _____________ 7. You accidentally spill a glass of juice on the carpet of your apartment, creating a stain. The landlord charges you $50 to clean the stain. Would you purchase a $25 ticket to a concert event later in the week? (Circle your answer) These materials are based upon Heath, Chip and Jack B. Soll. “Mental Budgeting and Consumer Decisions” Journal of Consumer Research 23(1996): pages 44 and 48. 2 Yes No 8. You buy a $75 sweater you found at a nearby store. Would you purchase a $35 pair of jeans later in the month? (Circle your answer) Yes No 9. You are required to buy a $60 novel for an English class. Would you purchase $25 worth of salmon for a dinner later in the week? (Circle your answer) Yes No Form B: 1. How much do you spend in an average week on entertainment? ______________ 2. How much do you spend on clothing in the average month? ____________ 3. How much do you spend on food in the average week? _____________ 4. Suppose you leave your apartment and find an unexpected parking ticket on your car for the amount of $25. How much would spend on entertainment the rest of the week? ________________ 5. The weather turns cold unexpectedly early and you are forced to purchase a $200 winter coat. How much would you spend on clothing the rest of the month? _____________ 6. Your car has broken down, requiring you to spend $40 on repairs. How much will you spend on food the rest of the week? _____________ 7. You spend $50 to attend a sporting event. Would you purchase a $25 ticket to a concert event later in the week? (Circle your answer) Yes No 8. You lose your wallet while walking around town. The wallet is later returned to you and you find that all your items are still in the wallet, but that $75 in cash is missing. Would you purchase a $35 pair of jeans later in the month? (Circle your answer) Yes No 9. You spend $60 on food for a special dinner. Would you purchase $25 worth of salmon for a dinner later in the week? (Circle your answer) Yes No Suggestions for Use in Lecture: Compare the average amounts given in questions 4 through 6 across forms B and A. In most cases, you will observe a lower amount when the earlier spending was in the same category (food, clothing, entertainment) as the future purchase question. Similarly you can compare the percentage “yes” responses to questions 7 through 9 for forms A and B. Again, you should see more being willing to make the future purchase when the faced with an income shock rather than after having spent within category. This is suggestive that individuals decide their future expenses based upon their recent history rather than evaluating the future costs and benefits of consumption. In each case, the income effect is controlled by including a prior expense of identical amounts between the two forms. Thus, someone who has lost $75 from their wallet should have the same enjoyment and cost for a $35 pair of jeans as one who has purchased a $75 sweater. Rebates and Bonuses (Supports Chapter 3) Purpose: Demonstrate that how students spend money will be influenced by how the income was acquired. This may not be possible in classes where a monetary reward is not possible. Materials: A small amount of money for each student (~$5), printed instruction sheets and accounting sheets listed under For the Participant. Preparation: Randomly assign students into conditions by row or other technique, so that you can pre-record which students receive form A and which receive form B. For the Instructor: Distribute the instruction sheets at one lecture surreptitiously noting which students receive which forms. At a future lecture, distribute the accounting sheets so that those in condition A receive accounting form A and those in B receive accounting form B. Please ensure that students read all instructions in both dispensations. For the Participant: Form A: To support the activities of this class, students have been charged a fee. It has been discovered that the fees collected exceed the required expenditures. Thus, we are returning your portion of the excess. Consider this a rebate on the course fees. Form B: We have decided to give each student in the class a bonus payment to show our appreciation for attendance. Accounting Form A: Previously we distributed course fee rebates in class. We are interested in how this money was spent. Please indicate your name, the approximate date spent, the items spent on and the approximate cost. Name: Date Item Amount Spent Accounting Form B: Previously we distributed bonus payments to the class. We are interested in how this money was spent. Please indicate your name, the approximate date spent, the items purchased and the approximate cost. Name: Date Item Amount Spent Suggestions for Use in Lecture: Typically those given money considered as a rebate will be much more likely to either save the money, or put it to some utilitarian use (e.g., food, clothing, or other necessary expenses). Those given a bonus are usually apt to recall spending on much more frivolous items. The best way to use this in class is to: 1. Find anecdotal examples from the accounting lists that could be shared. These may be more typical examples. 2. Quickly rate (or have a teaching assistant rate) each expense as more frivolous or utilitarian. Then report the percentage of money spent on frivolous versus utilitarian purchases for each group in class. If short of time, students can be asked to classify their own expenses as frivolous or utilitarian as part of the exercise, though sometimes this results in an ex post revision of the list of expenses. Segregating and Aggregating (Supports Chapter 3) Purpose: This exercise demonstrates that individuals prefer segregated gains and aggregated losses. Materials: Print out a questionnaire for each student from For the Participant. Alternatively, this set of questions could be conducted as an in-class survey using electronic voting (via texting or clicker). Preparation: Print and distribute sheets. For the Instructor: Each question asks students to consider two individuals who have had the same monetary shock, though each shock is framed differently. For the Participant: 3 Consider the following four vignettes. 1. George was given two scratch-off game cards from a local fast food restaurant participating in a promotion. One of the game cards resulted in George winning a $45 gift certificate, while the other resulted in his winning a $10 gift certificate. Albert was given one scratch off game ticket which resulted in a $55 gift certificate. Who was happier? Albert George Neither 2. George received a notice from his landlord stating that due to an increase in the utility costs, his monthly rent was going to increase by $100. The same day he received a notice from his auto insurance company that prices were increasing resulting in a $50 per month increase in the cost of insurance. Albert received a notice from his landlord that due to an increase in the monthly cost of utilities, his rent would be increasing by $150. His auto insurance rates remained the same. Which was more upset? Albert George Neither 3. A hailstorm damaged George’s car requiring him to pay $1000 to repair the damage. The same day he received a gift from his grandmother for $300. The same hailstorm caused damage to Albert’s car requiring him to pay $700 to repair the damage. Which was more upset? Albert George Neither These materials are based upon Thaler, R.H. “Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice.” Marketing Science 27(2008): page18. 3 4. George received an unexpected check for $1000 in the mail resulting from a contest he had entered a few months before. The same day, his car broke down requiring him to spend $300 on repairs. Albert received a $700 check in the mail resulting from a contest. Which was happier? Albert George Neither Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In class report the percentage of students giving each answer to each question. In most cases, students believe that receiving multiple gains will make you happier even if the amount gained is the same. Similarly, one receiving fewer losses is happier even if the amount lost is the same. In the case of questions 3 and 4, a large gain with a small loss is most often considered a worse outcome than a more moderate gain with no loss. A large loss with a small gain is considered better than a more moderate loss with no gain. This demonstrates the impact of segregation on the evaluation of outcomes. Pre-Payment and Post-payment (Supports Chapter 3) Purpose: This exercise demonstrates that individuals tend to be more willing to borrow money to pay for items that provide ongoing consumption, and less willing to borrow for items that are consumed once. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) Two sets of answer sheets printed from the section below For the Participant Preparation: Shuffle answer sheets so they can be randomly assigned to students. For the Instructor: Distribute the materials to students, and ask them to read and answer all questions. Remind students not to discuss the questions with one another. For the Participant: 4 Form A. 1. Imagine that you are planning a trip to Cancun Mexico for Spring Break next year. The vacation will cost $3000. Would you rather: a. Make 12 monthly payments of $250 for the 12 months prior to the trip. b. Make 12 monthly payments of $250 for the 12 months following the trip. Form B. 2. Imagine that you are planning on purchasing a used car in one year. The car will cost approximately $3000. Would you rather a. Make 12 monthly payments of $250 for the next 12 months before purchasing the car. b. Make 12 monthly payments of $250 for the 12 months following the purchase of the car. Suggestions for Use in Lecture: Simply present the percentages that choose the pre-payment and post-payment options under each scenario. In general students prefer post payment when consumption continues into the future (like with a car), Reprinted with permission from Prelec, D. and G. Loewenstein. “The Red and the Black: Mental Accounting of Savings and Debt.” Marketing Science 17(1998):page 6. 4 while preferring pre-payment for a one time consumption experience (like Spring Break). Coherently Arbitrary Bidding (Supports Chapter 4) Purpose: This exercise demonstrates that people can be influenced by arbitrary ways in which questions are framed when forming their preferences. Materials: i.) A set answer sheets printed from the section below For the Participant ii) A set of objects that can be auctioned off. This can be something as small as a mug, tickets to a sporting event or an item emblazoned with a school logo. The value of the good should be approximately equal to $X where X is the number of students in the class divided by two. This could be funded by course fees, or by the auction itself. iii) A bag and either Ping-Pong balls or a sheet of paper. Preparation: Print out one answer sheet for each student in the class. Before class, fill in the student number and the blank in question 1 by entering sequentially the numbers from 1 to π, where π is the number of students in the class. Thus, the first sheet will ask if the student would be willing to buy the item for $1, while the πth sheet will ask if the student is willing to buy the item for $π. Then, shuffle the answer sheets before distributing. Display the item to be auctioned visibly at the front of the lecture hall so all students can see it. Number the Ping Pong balls (or small slips of paper) from 1 to π, and place in the bag. It is possible to either endow students with money from the student fees collected for the course in order to play this game, or to simply require that students use their own money. For the Instructor: Distribute the answer sheets to students, and ask them to read the instructions, but not to answer any questions yet. Remind students not to discuss the questions with one another. Once all have read the materials, read the following instructions with them: “I have here a ____________ that we will be auctioning off today. One student will be given the chance to purchase this good. You will note that your answer sheet asks you two questions. “The first question asks whether you are willing to purchase the item for a specified amount. The second question asks for the largest amount of money you would be willing to pay in order to obtain the good. In a moment I will ask you to fill in this amount. Before you do, I will explain how the transaction will take place. “First, each of you will fill in your answer to questions 1 and 2. Please remember to write your name on the answer sheet. “Second, I will collect these answer sheets. “Third, I have a bag here that contains Ping-Pong balls numbered from 1 to ___--the number of students in the class. I will draw a ball at random to determine which student has the possibility of purchasing the item. Suppose I draw the number 5. Then student number 5 would have the chance to purchase the item. I will then return this ball to the bag, and randomly select a ball again to determine the price. Suppose I selected the number 15. If student number 5 stated a number greater than 15 in question 2, then next class student number 5 would need to bring $15, and I will give him the item. If student number 5 stated they were willing to pay only some number less than 15, then I would keep the item, and the student would keep their money. (It may be worthwhile giving a few more examples). “Note that it is always in your best interest to state the highest amount of money you would be willing to pay for the item.” “I need two volunteers to verify that this bag contains one and only one example of each number.” (call on two volunteers and let them inspect the bag). “Are there any questions regarding the procedure?” “The first question asks whether you are willing to purchase the good at a price specified on your answer sheet. Please circle either yes or no now.” (wait for all to circle their answer). “Please fill in your maximum willingness to pay in question 2 now” Once all have filled in answers, collect the sheets and implement the bidding mechanism as described. For the Participant: Name:_________________________ Student Number: ______________ Today, one student will be given the chance to purchase this good through one of two mechanisms. Below you will be asked to answer two questions. The first question asks whether you are willing to purchase the item for a specified amount. The second question asks for the largest amount of money you would be willing to pay in order to obtain the good. After each student fills in answers to questions 1 and 2, the instructor will collect these answer sheets. The instructor will randomly select a student by drawing a number out of a bag. The bag contains one and only one instance of each student number (listed on this sheet). The instructor will then draw a number to determine the price. ο· ο· ο· If your student number is drawn, and the price is greater than your answer to question 2 below, you will not purchase the good. If your student number is drawn, and the price is less than or equal to your answer to question 2, you will purchase the good and will need to bring money equal to the price to the instructor in order to obtain the good. If your student number is not drawn, you will not purchase the good. It is always in your best interest to state the highest amount of money you would be willing to pay for the item so that you can purchase the good in the event your number is drawn and the price is low enough that you would like to purchase it. Please do not answer questions 1 or 2 until instructed to do so. Question 1. Would you be willing to buy the item if the price were $_____________ Circle one: Yes No Question 2. What is the largest amount of money you would be willing to pay in order to obtain the item? $_________________ Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In order to use this in lecture, it is often most effective to use a simple plot of student numbers and willingness-to-pay measures. This can be produced easily using office software such as Microsoft Excel. On the xaxis you would plot student number. On the y-axis you would plot bids. You may need to plot a linear regression line to draw attention to the relationship between the two. In presenting this to the class, make sure to emphasize ο· The student numbers were passed out at random and had no inherent relationship to the good ο· Students were asked whether they would be willing to pay an amount corresponding to their student number prior to bidding. This should not impact their bid if their preferences are well formed and stable. ο· In most cases the student number does influence willingness to pay, indicating that preference formation occurs when asked for a willingness to pay. Also, this indicates that individuals anchor on arbitrary numbers when formulating their preferences. Defaults and Insurance: (Supports Chapter 4) Purpose: This exercise is used to demonstrate that most people tend to accept a default option. Note this is similar to the default insurance example referenced in chapter 4. Materials: Two sets of printed answer sheets listed under For the Participant. Preparation: This exercise is best conducted on the first day of class as one goes over the course rules and procedures. Shuffle answer sheets so that they can be distributed randomly to students in the class. For the Instructor: Distribute the materials to students, and ask them to read the instructions and answer the question. Ask those who wish to opt out of the default to hand in their slip of paper. If the choice offered is inappropriate for your class, two other similar choices could be offered (for example one option could eliminate the option to appeal a mis-graded assignment). The choices should be such that students do not strongly favor one or the other option. For the Participant: Form A: Several homework sets will be required over the course of the year. Your grade for the homework will be calculated in one of the following ways: (a) The lowest homework grade will be dropped when calculating your homework average, and this average will be applied to all homework scores when calculating your final grade. No extra credit will be available. (b) All homeworks will be graded normally and these grades will count. However, if you desire, extra credit assignments will be available in order to make up for poor performance on assignments. By default I will calculate your grade according to (a). However, if you sign the statement below and return the form to me by the end of lecture today I will grade your homework assignments according to (b). I desire to have my homeworks graded according to (b), signed _________________________________ Name: __________________________________ Form B: Several homework sets will be required over the course of the year. Your grade for the homework will be calculated in one of the following ways: (a) All homeworks will be graded normally and these grades will count. However, if you desire, extra credit assignments will be available in order to make up for poor performance on assignments. (b) The lowest homework grade will be dropped when calculating your homework average, and this average will be applied to all homework scores when calculating your final grade. No extra credit will be available. By default I will calculate your grade according to (a). However, if you sign the statement below and return the form to me by the end of lecture today I will grade your homework assignments according to (b). I desire to have my homeworks graded according to (b), signed _________________________________ Name: __________________________________ Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In class you should simply report the percentage of students who handed in forms under each default. Students will have a tendency to rely on the standard option in most cases. Here they may tend to do so even though it has an impact on their final grade. Endowment Game (Supports Chapter 4) Purpose: This exercise demonstrates the endowment effect: that willingness to accept to part with an item is generally greater than willingness to pay to obtain that same item. Materials: i.) Several identical items (like a mug) for exactly half of the class. ii.) Two sets of answer sheets printed from the section below For the Participant iii.) Die Preparation: The answer sheets should be printed and shuffled so that they may be randomly assigned. This exercise is best conducted using individual money accounts created by student fees for the course. Otherwise you will need to inform students that they will need money ahead of time. For the Instructor: When students arrive, distribute answer sheets. Ask those who have received form A to raise their hand and distribute the items to these individuals. Ask students to read the instructions, but not to answer the question yet. Remind students not to discuss the questions with one another. Once all have read the instructions, read the following to them. “Several of you have been given ___________. These now belong to you. However, you will have the opportunity to sell the item if you wish to students who have not received them. We will create a market for these items in the following way. Those who currently have one of the items will be asked for the smallest amount of money that would be required for them to agree to part with the gift. We will call this their willingness to accept (WTA). Those who do not have the items will be asked for the largest amount of money they would be willing to pay to obtain the item. We will call this their willingness to pay (WTP). “Once all have recorded these amounts, we will collect all answer sheets and determine the price for our market. Once the price is determined, ο· All with WTA less than the market price will give up the good and receive the market price in exchange. ο· All with a WTA greater than the market price will keep the good and receive no money. ο· All with a WTP greater than the market price will be required to pay the market price and receive the good in exchange. ο· All with a WTP less than the market price will keep their money and receive no good. “The market price will be determined by constructing a demand and supply curve from the responses and determining their intersection. Practically, we will pair the lowest WTA in the class with the largest WTP. If this WTP is larger or equal to this WTA, then we will continue to the second smallest WTA and the second highest WTP. If this WTP is larger than this WTA we will continue to the third pair and so on until we find the first WTA that is greater than it’s corresponding WTP. If this is the πth pair we compared, then we will set the price equal to the WTA for the (π − 1)th price. “For example, if there were ten in the class and the WTA bids were 1, 2, 3, 4, 5; and the WTP bids were 4, 3, 2, 1, 1, the first pair would be πππ΄ = 1 < 4 = πππ. The second pair would be πππ΄ = 2 < 3=WTP. The third pair is πππ΄ = 3 > 2 = πππ. Thus, the price would be set at 2, and those bidding 4 and 3 would each pay 2 and receive an item. Those willing to accept 1 and 2 would both receive 2 and give up the item. In the event that there are more willing to pay than accept at this price, we will use a roll of the die to determine which transactions take place. Those rolling the largest numbers will transact.” “Are there any questions?” After all questions have been resolved, ask students to fill in their answers, collect sheets and execute the market. For the Participant: Form A Name_________________________ You have been given ___________. This item now belongs to you. However, you will have the opportunity to sell this item, if you wish, to students who have not received them. We will create a market for these items in the following way. You and others who possess the items will be asked for the smallest amount of money that would be required for them to agree to part with the gift. We will call this their willingness to accept (WTA). Those who do not have the items will be asked for the largest amount of money they would be willing to pay to obtain the item. We will call this their willingness to pay (WTP). Once all have recorded these amounts, answer sheets will be collected and the instructor will determine the price for our market. Once the price is determined, ο· All with WTA less than the market price will give up the good and receive the market price in exchange. ο· All with a WTA greater than the market price will keep the good and receive no money. ο· ο· All with a WTP greater than the market price will be required to pay the market price and receive the good in exchange. All with a WTP less than the market price will keep their money and receive no good. The market price will be determined by constructing a demand and supply curve from the responses and determining their intersection. Practically, we will pair the lowest WTA in the class with the largest WTP. If this WTP is larger or equal to this WTA, then we will continue to the second smallest WTA and the second highest WTP. If this WTP is larger than this WTA we will continue to the third pair and so on until we find the first WTA that is greater than it’s corresponding WTP. If this is the πth pair we compared, then we will set the price equal to the WTA for the (π − 1)th price. What is the smallest amount of money you would require in order to part with the item? _______________________ Form B Name_________________________ Some in the class have been given ___________. You will have the opportunity to purchase this item from one of these students, if you wish. We will create a market for these items in the following way. Those who possess the items will be asked for the smallest amount of money that would be required for them to agree to part with the gift. We will call this their willingness to accept (WTA). You and others who do not have the items will be asked for the largest amount of money they would be willing to pay to obtain the item. We will call this their willingness to pay (WTP). Once all have recorded these amounts, answer sheets will be collected and the instructor will determine the price for our market. Once the price is determined, ο· All with WTA less than the market price will give up the good and receive the market price in exchange. ο· All with a WTA greater than the market price will keep the good and receive no money. ο· All with a WTP greater than the market price will be required to pay the market price and receive the good in exchange. ο· All with a WTP less than the market price will keep their money and receive no good. The market price will be determined by constructing a demand and supply curve from the responses and determining their intersection. Practically, we will pair the lowest WTA in the class with the largest WTP. If this WTP is larger or equal to this WTA, then we will continue to the second smallest WTA and the second highest WTP. If this WTP is larger than this WTA we will continue to the third pair and so on until we find the first WTA that is greater than it’s corresponding WTP. If this is the πth pair we compared, then we will set the price equal to the WTA for the (π − 1)th price. What is the largest amount of money you would be willing to pay in order to obtain the item? _______________________ Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In order to use this in lecture, it is often most effective to plot WTP and WTA curves on the same graph in the form of a demand curve. This can be produced easily using office software such as Microsoft Excel. On the x-axis would be the number of students ranging from 1 to half the number of students in the class. On the y-axis you would dollar amounts. For the WTA curve, the curve will plot the points such that at each point π₯, we plot the maximum WTA such that there are exactly π₯ students who have given WTA equal to or larger than the plotted point π¦. This should trace a downward sloping line. For example, the example from “For the Instructor” would result in a plot of points (1,5), (2, 4), (3, 3), (4, 2), (5, 1). On the same graph, but in another color or style, plot the maximum WTP that would result in at least π₯ students purchasing the good. For the example in “For the Instructor” this would result in the points (1, 4), (2, 3), (3, 2), (4, 1), (5, 1). In general the WTP curve will be lower than the WTA curve. In presenting this to the class, make sure to emphasize ο· Students were randomly assigned to either receive or not receive the items. Rationally, there is little reason to believe that receiving the item should influence your valuation of the item. This indicates that possession of an item influences one preference for that item. Vickrey Auction (Supports Chapter 5) Purpose: This exercise is designed to demonstrate the natural tendency of participants to bid more than the optimal amount in a second price sealed bid auction. Materials: For each student you will need to print (found in For the Participant) i.) Instruction Sheet ii.) 10 bidding sheets iii.) One value sheet for each student. Five different versions of the value sheet are given. One fifth of the participants should receive each version. Additionally, the instructor will need at least one copy of each value sheet. Additionally, you will need to print 20 reward sheets (found in For the Instructor) These materials are designed to conduct 10 rounds of the Vickrey auction. Materials can be adjusted to accommodate fewer rounds if desired. This experiment is best conducted with experimental dollars. You will also need one die. Preparation: Print all materials. Shuffle the value sheets so that they may be randomly assigned to students. To conserve lecture time, you may wish to distribute materials prior to students entering the lecture room. Each student will need one instruction sheet, one value sheet, 10 bidding sheets. For the Instructor: Request that all students read the instruction sheet given them. Emphasize that students should not communicate with each other over the course of the experiment. Once all have read the instructions, you may reread the instructions aloud if desired. Ask students if they have any questions regarding how the experiment will proceed. You may need to make some statement about how experimental dollars will translate into actual dollars. Ask students to fill out their first “Bid Sheets”, and then collect the sheets. Determine the winner and the price for the auction as described. Fill out two reward sheets. Declare the winner along with the winning bid and the auction price. Give one reward sheet to the winner and retain the remaining for your records. After the first round, you may choose to explain the auction mechanism again and use the bids from the first round as an example. Future rounds are conducted in the same way. If an individual wins a second time, be sure to use their prior reward sheet to calculate an accurate budget for the next round. You may need to explain this budget to the winner in each round. Reward Sheet Round Number:_______________________ Winner’s Name:_______________________ Winner’s Value:_______________________ Auction Price:_______________________ The resulting budget (Prior budget + Winner’s Value – Auction Price) = _______________ (Bids in future periods should not exceed this budget). For the Participant: Instruction Sheet You will now be participating in a series of 10 auctions. Each of the auctions will be conducted in the same manner. You have been given 10 experimental dollars to use in these auctions. In each auction, you will have the opportunity to bid by filling out your “Bid Sheet” with the amount of your bid. At no time are you allowed to bid more than the amount remaining from this 10 experimental dollars. Winning the auction means you will receive a particular amount of money. The amount of money you receive is assigned to you and may differ from the amount another student might win in the auction. You have been given a sheet of paper labeled “Value Sheet.” This sheet lists how much money you will receive should you win the auction by round. Thus, if your sheet lists “$2” under round one, then winning the auction in the first round will result in you receiving $2. The top right corner of your “Value Sheet” lists the type (either A, B, C, D or E). This type must be recorded on each “Bid Sheet” prior to submitting a bid. You may record this on each “Bid Sheet” now. In each round, you will record your bid on your “Bid Sheet”, and fold your bid sheet so that your bid cannot be seen by others. The bid sheets will then be collected by the instructor or an assistant. The instructor will then announce the owner of the highest bid. This is the winner of that round’s auction. The winner will be required to pay the second highest bid, and receive the value specified on their value sheet for that round. No others will be required to pay or receive any experimental dollars. So, if there were five students in the class, and their bids were $4, $3.50, $2, $1, then the student bidding $4 would win, and pay $3.50. If this students value for the auction were $5, then this would result in them receiving $5 − $3.50 = $1.50 as a result of the auction. Once the winner is announced, if there are additional rounds left, the next round of bidding will begin. This student would then have $11.50 with which to bid in the next round. In the event of a tie, the winner will be selected by the roll of a die. Each person placing the highest bid will roll the die, with the highest roll resulting in a win. The winner in this case will pay their bid. Value Sheet Form A Round Value 1 $1.00 2 $1.00 3 $1.50 4 $1.50 5 $2.00 6 $2.00 7 $2.50 8 $2.50 9 $3.00 10 $3.00 2 $3.00 3 $2.50 4 $2.50 5 $1.50 6 $1.50 7 $2.00 8 $2.00 9 $1.00 10 $1.00 2 $2.00 3 $3.00 4 $3.00 5 $1.00 6 $1.00 7 $1.50 8 $1.50 9 $2.50 10 $2.50 2 $1.50 3 $1.00 4 $1.00 5 $2.50 6 $2.50 7 $3.00 8 $3.00 9 $2.00 10 $2.00 2 $2.50 3 $2.00 4 $2.00 5 $3.00 6 $3.00 7 $1.00 8 $1.00 9 $1.50 10 $1.50 Value Sheet Form B Round Value 1 $3.00 Value Sheet Form C Round Value 1 $2.00 Value Sheet Form D Round Value 1 $1.50 Value Sheet Form E Round Value 1 $2.50 Bid Sheet Name:____________________________ Value Sheet Form: ______________ Round Number:_________________ My bid: __________________________ Should not exceed $10 plus your winnings (or minus your losings) from prior rounds. Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In presenting the results of the Vickrey auction in class it is often most useful to first explain the optimal bid in the Vickrey auction is to bid one’s assigned value. Then: ο· Define a variable π¦π‘ = π₯π‘ − π£π‘ , where π₯π‘ is an individual’s bid in auction π‘ and π£π‘ is the individual’s valuation in auction π‘. Thus π¦π‘ is the excess bid. Present the class average π¦π‘ by round. ο· Present the percentage of students bidding above their value by round. ο· Present the net winnings in each round of the auction. This is particularly effective if the net winnings are negative-a regular occurrence English Auction (Supports Chapter 5) Purpose: This exercise is designed to demonstrate bids within the English Auction tend to be lower (and thus closer to the optimum) than the Vickrey Auction bids. Materials: For each student you will need to print (found in For the Participant) i.) Instruction Sheet ii.) One value sheet for each student. Five different versions of the value sheet are given. One fifth of the participants should receive each version. Additionally, the instructor will need at least one copy of each value sheet. Note that ties will be common with only five versions of the value sheet. If the instructor wishes, they can create additional versions of the value sheets to reduce the number of ties. Alternatively, one may simply run the auction within groups of 5 (so each group of 5 has one of each value sheet). iii.) Bid Sheet Additionally, you will need to print 20 reward sheets (found in For the Instructor) These materials are designed to conduct 10 rounds of the English auction. Materials can be adjusted to accommodate fewer rounds if desired. This experiment is best conducted with experimental dollars. You will also need one die. Preparation: Print all materials. Shuffle the value sheets so that they may be randomly assigned to students. To conserve lecture time, you may wish to distribute materials prior to students entering the lecture room. Each student will need one instruction sheet, one value sheet, 1 bidding sheet. For the Instructor: Request that all students read the instruction sheet given them. Emphasize that students should not communicate with each other over the course of the experiment. Once all have read the instructions, you may reread the instructions aloud if desired. Ask students if they have any questions regarding how the experiment will proceed. You may need to make some statement about how experimental dollars will translate into actual dollars. Ask all students to stand up, and remain standing until you call out a price they are unwilling to pay. Begin with a small value, e.g. $0.10, and increase by increments of $0.10. After each price in which someone sits down, remember to remind them to record their final bid on their “Bid Sheet.” Determine the winner and the price for the auction as described. Ask the winner for their value sheet form letter in order to determine their valuation. Fill out two reward sheets following each auction. Declare the winner along with the winning bid. Give one reward sheet to the winner and retain the remaining for your records. After the first round, you may choose to explain the auction mechanism again and use the bids from the first round as an example. Future rounds are conducted in the same way. If an individual wins a second time, be sure to use their prior reward sheet to calculate an accurate budget for the next round. You may need to explain this budget to the winner in each round. In the event of a tie, use a die roll to determine who will actually win the auction. Reward Sheet Round Number:_______________________ Winner’s Name:_______________________ Winner’s Value:_______________________ Auction Price:_______________________ The resulting budget (Prior budget + Winner’s Value – Auction Price) = _______________ (Bids in future periods should not exceed this budget). For the Participant: Instruction Sheet You will now be participating in a series of 10 auctions. Each of the auctions will be conducted in the same manner. You have been given 10 experimental dollars to use in these auctions. In each auction, you will have the opportunity to bid. At no time are you allowed to bid more than the amount remaining from the 10 experimental dollars. At the beginning of each round, the instructor will ask you to stand. The instructor will then begin to call out potential prices. For example, the instructor may call out “$1.” If you are willing to pay a price of $1 in order to win the auction, you should remain standing. If the price is too high, and you are unwilling to pay this price, you should sit down. The instructor will continue to call out higher and higher amounts until only one bidder remains standing. Once you sit down, you will be required to record on your “Bid Sheet” the last called price for which you remained standing for that round. Winning the auction means you will receive a particular amount of money. The amount of money you receive is assigned to you and may differ from the amount another student might win in the auction. You have been given a sheet of paper labeled “Value Sheet.” This sheet lists how much money you will receive should you win the auction by round. Thus, if your sheet lists “$2” under round one, then winning the auction in the first round will result in you receiving $2. The winner will be required to pay the auction price, which is the last price for which more than one bidder was standing, and receive the value specified on their value sheet for that round. No others will be required to pay or receive any experimental dollars. So, if two students were standing when $3.50 was called out, but only one student when $3.51 was called out, the last student standing would win, and pay $3.50. If this students value for the auction were $5, then this would result in them receiving $5 − $3.50 = $1.50 as a result of the auction. Once the winner is announced, if there are additional rounds left, the next round of bidding will begin. This student would then have $11.50 with which to bid in the next round. In the event of a tie, the winner will be selected by the roll of a die. Each person placing the highest bid will roll the die, with the highest roll resulting in a win. The winner in this case will pay their bid. Value Sheet Form A Round Value 1 $1.00 2 $1.00 3 $1.50 4 $1.50 5 $2.00 6 $2.00 7 $2.50 8 $2.50 9 $3.00 10 $3.00 2 $3.00 3 $2.50 4 $2.50 5 $1.50 6 $1.50 7 $2.00 8 $2.00 9 $1.00 10 $1.00 2 $2.00 3 $3.00 4 $3.00 5 $1.00 6 $1.00 7 $1.50 8 $1.50 9 $2.50 10 $2.50 2 $1.50 3 $1.00 4 $1.00 5 $2.50 6 $2.50 7 $3.00 8 $3.00 9 $2.00 10 $2.00 2 $2.50 3 $2.00 4 $2.00 5 $3.00 6 $3.00 7 $1.00 8 $1.00 9 $1.50 10 $1.50 Value Sheet Form B Round Value 1 $3.00 Value Sheet Form C Round Value 1 $2.00 Value Sheet Form D Round Value 1 $1.50 Value Sheet Form E Round Value 1 $2.50 Bid Sheet Name:____________________________ Value Sheet Form: ______________ Round 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Bid (last called price for which I stood) Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In presenting the results of the English auction in class it is often most useful to first explain the optimal bid in the English auction is to sit down when one’s assigned value is exceeded. Then: ο· Define a variable π¦π‘ = π₯π‘ − π£π‘ , where π₯π‘ is an individual’s bid in auction π‘ and π£π‘ is the individual’s valuation in auction π‘. Thus π¦π‘ is the excess bid. Present the class average π¦π‘ by round. ο· Present the percentage of students bidding above their value by round. ο· Present the net winnings in each round of the auction. This is particularly effective if the net winnings are negative-a regular occurrence In each case, you should contrast the results with the results of the Vickrey auction. Dutch Auction (Supports Chapter 5) Purpose: This exercise is designed to demonstrate the uncertainty involved in formulating a Dutch Auction bid. As well, this will demonstrate the relationship between the winning Dutch Auction price and the Vickrey price. Materials: For each student you will need to print (found in For the Participant) i.) Instruction Sheet ii.) One value sheet for each student. Five different versions of the value sheet are given. One fifth of the participants should receive each version. Additionally, the instructor will need at least one copy of each value sheet. Note that ties will be common with only five versions of the value sheet. If the instructor wishes, they can create additional versions of the value sheets to reduce the number of ties. Alternatively, one may simply run the auction within groups of 5 (so each group of 5 has one of each value sheet). Additionally, you will need to print 20 reward sheets (found in For the Instructor) These materials are designed to conduct 10 rounds of the English auction. Materials can be adjusted to accommodate fewer rounds if desired. This experiment is best conducted with experimental dollars. You will also need one die. Preparation: Print all materials. Shuffle the value sheets so that they may be randomly assigned to students. To conserve lecture time, you may wish to distribute materials prior to students entering the lecture room. Each student will need one instruction sheet, one value sheet. For the Instructor: Request that all students read the instruction sheet given them. Emphasize that students should not communicate with each other over the course of the experiment. Once all have read the instructions, you may reread the instructions aloud if desired. Ask students if they have any questions regarding how the experiment will proceed. You may need to make some statement about how experimental dollars will translate into actual dollars. Ask all students to be seated, and remain seated until you call out a price they are willing to pay. Begin with a large value, e.g. $5.00, and decrease by increments of $0.10. Wait for a student to stand after each called price. When one stands, they are the winner and pay the price at which they stood. Ask the winner for their value sheet form letter in order to determine their valuation. Fill out two reward sheets following each auction. Declare the winner along with the winning bid. Give one reward sheet to the winner and retain the remaining for your records. After the first round, you may choose to explain the auction mechanism again and use the bids from the first round as an example. Future rounds are conducted in the same way. If an individual wins a second time, be sure to use their prior reward sheet to calculate an accurate budget for the next round. You may need to explain this budget to the winner in each round. In the event of a tie, use a die roll to determine who will actually win the auction. Reward Sheet Round Number:_______________________ Winner’s Name:_______________________ Winner’s Value:_______________________ Auction Price:_______________________ The resulting budget (Prior budget + Winner’s Value – Auction Price) = _______________ (Bids in future periods should not exceed this budget). For the Participant: Instruction Sheet You will now be participating in a series of 10 auctions. Each of the auctions will be conducted in the same manner. You have been given 10 experimental dollars to use in these auctions. In each auction, you will have the opportunity to bid. At no time are you allowed to bid more than the amount remaining from this 10 experimental dollars. At the beginning of each round, the instructor will ask you to be seated. The instructor will then begin to call out potential prices. For example, the instructor may call out “$5.” If you are willing to pay a price of $1 in order to win the auction, you should stand up. If the price is too high, and you are unwilling to pay this price, you should remain seated. The instructor will continue to call out lower and lower amounts until the first bidder stands. Whoever stands first will be considered the winner, and the auction price will be equal to the price called by the instructor when they stood. Winning the auction means you will receive a particular amount of money. The amount of money you receive is assigned to you and may differ from the amount another student might win in the auction. You have been given a sheet of paper labeled “Value Sheet.” This sheet lists how much money you will receive should you win the auction by round. Thus, if your sheet lists “$2” under round one, then winning the auction in the first round will result in you receiving $2. The winner will be required to pay the auction price, which is the price called when they decided to stand, and receive the value specified on their value sheet for that round. No others will be required to pay or receive any experimental dollars. So, if the first student stood when $3.50 was called out, this student is the winner and must pay $3.50. If this student’s value for the auction were $5, then this would result in them receiving $5 − $3.50 = $1.50 as a result of the auction. Once the winner is announced, if there are additional rounds left, the next round of bidding will begin. This student would then have $11.50 with which to bid in the next round. In the event of a tie, the winner will be selected by the roll of a die. Each person placing the highest bid will roll the die, with the highest roll resulting in a win. The winner in this case will pay their bid. Value Sheet Form A Round Value 1 $1.00 2 $1.00 3 $1.50 4 $1.50 5 $2.00 6 $2.00 7 $2.50 8 $2.50 9 $3.00 10 $3.00 2 $3.00 3 $2.50 4 $2.50 5 $1.50 6 $1.50 7 $2.00 8 $2.00 9 $1.00 10 $1.00 2 $2.00 3 $3.00 4 $3.00 5 $1.00 6 $1.00 7 $1.50 8 $1.50 9 $2.50 10 $2.50 2 $1.50 3 $1.00 4 $1.00 5 $2.50 6 $2.50 7 $3.00 8 $3.00 9 $2.00 10 $2.00 2 $2.50 3 $2.00 4 $2.00 5 $3.00 6 $3.00 7 $1.00 8 $1.00 9 $1.50 10 $1.50 Value Sheet Form B Round Value 1 $3.00 Value Sheet Form C Round Value 1 $2.00 Value Sheet Form D Round Value 1 $1.50 Value Sheet Form E Round Value 1 $2.50 Suggestions for Use in Lecture: It is not possible to determine any bids except the winning bid. In presenting the results of this experiment, you should display the winning price and the value received in each round. You should also ask students to describe how they decided when to stand. You should emphasize that they were unsure of whether they could remain sitting and still win once the price got below their own value. In each case, you should contrast the results with the results of the Vickrey auction. Common Value Auction (Supports Chapter 5) Purpose: This exercise is designed to demonstrate the natural tendency for the winner of a common value auction to bid more than the good is worth—known as the winner’s curse. Materials: For each student you will need to print (found in For the Participant) i.) Instruction Sheet ii.) 5 bidding sheets iii.) One value sheet for each student. Five different versions of the value sheet are given. One fifth of the participants should receive each version. Additionally, the instructor will need at least one copy of each value sheet. Additionally, you will need to print 10 reward sheets (found in For the Instructor) for each group of students that will participate in the auction. These materials are designed to conduct 5 rounds of the Common Value Vickrey auction. Materials can be adjusted to accommodate fewer rounds if desired. This experiment is best conducted with experimental dollars. This experiment is also best conducted in smaller groups (for example groups of 5), though this can cause an added administrative burden. Larger groups will work, but results in fewer winners (and hence fewer demonstrating the curse). You will also need one die. Preparation: Print all materials. Shuffle the value sheets so that they may be randomly assigned to students. To conserve lecture time, you may wish to distribute materials prior to students entering the lecture room. Each student will need one instruction sheet, one value sheet, 10 bidding sheets. For the Instructor: Request that all students read the instruction sheet given them. Emphasize that students should not communicate with each other over the course of the experiment. Once all have read the instructions, you may reread the instructions aloud if desired. Ask students if they have any questions regarding how the experiment will proceed. You may need to make some statement about how experimental dollars will translate into actual dollars. Emphasize to the students that no one knows the true value of winning the auction, but that the value will be the same no matter who wins. Also emphasize that they have only been given a guess of the true value. Ask students to fill out their first “Bid Sheets”, and then collect the sheets. Determine the winner and the price for the auction as described. Fill out two reward sheets. Declare the winner along with the winning bid and the auction price. Give one reward sheet to the winner and retain the remaining for your records. After the first round, you may choose to explain the auction mechanism again and use the bids from the first round as an example. Future rounds are conducted in the same way. If an individual wins a second time, be sure to use their prior reward sheet to calculate an accurate budget for the next round. You may need to explain this budget to the winner in each round. The common values for each round are: Round Value 1 $3.25 2 $3.50 3 $2.75 4 $2.15 5 $4.00 Reward Sheet Round Number:_______________________ Winner’s Name:_______________________ Winner’s Estimate:____________________ Common Value:_______________________ Auction Price:_______________________ The resulting budget (Prior budget + Winner’s Value – Auction Price) = _______________ (Bids in future periods should not exceed this budget). For the Participant: Instruction Sheet You will now be participating in a series of 5 auctions. Each of the auctions will be conducted in the same manner, and you will only be bidding against those from your group of 5. You have been given 20 experimental dollars to use in these auctions. In each auction, you will have the opportunity to bid by filling out your “Bid Sheet” with the amount of your bid. At no time are you allowed to bid more than the amount remaining from this 20 experimental dollars. Whichever member of your group of 5 wins the auction will receive a particular amount of money, with the amount changing in each round of the auction. However, none of you knows for certain what this amount of money is. However, each of you has been given a guess as to the value of the auction listed on the paper labeled “Value Sheet.” For each round, one of your group has been given a guess that is equal to the true value of the auction plus $1.00, one has been given a guess equal to the value of the auction plus $0.50, one has been given a guess equal to the true value of the auction, one has been given a guess equal to the true value minus $0.50, and one has been given a guess equal to the true value minus $1.00. You are not allowed to communicate with each other regarding your guesses or your bids. The top right corner of your “Value Sheet” lists the type (either A, B, C, D or E). This type must be recorded on each “Bid Sheet” prior to submitting a bid. You may record this on each “Bid Sheet” now. In each round, you will record your bid on your “Bid Sheet”, and fold your bid sheet so that your bid cannot be seen by others. The bid sheets will then be collected by the instructor or an assistant. The instructor will then announce the owner of the highest bid. This is the winner of that round’s auction. The winner will be required to pay the second highest bid, and receive the true value of the auction. No others will be required to pay or receive any experimental dollars. So, if there were five students in the group, and their bids were $4, $3.50, $2, $1, then the student bidding $4 would win, and pay $3.50. If the true value of the auction was $3.75, then this would result in them receiving $3.75 − $3.50 = $0.25 as a result of the auction. Once the winner is announced, if there are additional rounds left, the next round of bidding will begin. This student would then have $20.25 with which to bid in the next round. In the event of a tie, the winner will be selected by the roll of a die. Each person placing the highest bid will roll the die, with the highest roll resulting in a win. The winner in this case will pay their bid. Value Sheet Form A Round Value 1 $3.25 2 $3.00 3 $3.25 4 $1.15 5 $5.00 2 $4.00 3 $1.75 4 $3.15 5 $4.00 2 $2.50 3 $3.75 4 $2.15 5 $3.50 2 $4.50 3 $2.75 4 $1.65 5 $4.50 Value Sheet Form B Round Value 1 $2.75 Value Sheet Form C Round Value 1 $3.75 Value Sheet Form D Round Value 1 $2.25 Value Sheet Form E Round Value 1 $4.25 2 $3.50 3 $2.25 4 $2.65 5 $3.00 Bid Sheet Name:____________________________ Value Sheet Form: ______________ Round Number:_________________ My bid: __________________________ Should not to exceed $20 plus your winnings (or minus your losings) from prior rounds. Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In presenting the results of the Common Value Auction in class it is often most useful to first explain the optimal bid in this auction is to bid one’s estimate of the value minus the maximum error (in this case minus $1). Then: ο· Define a variable π¦π‘ = π₯π‘ − π£π‘ , where π₯π‘ is an individual’s bid in auction π‘ and π£π‘ is the optimal bid for that individual. Thus π¦π‘ is the excess bid. Present the class average π¦π‘ by round. ο· Present the percentage of students bidding above the common value by round. ο· Present the average net winnings in each round of the auction across groups. In general the net winnings are usually negative demonstrating the winner’s curse. Investments and Evaluation (Supports Chapter 6) Purpose: This exercise demonstrates that decision-makers who evaluate investment portfolios less frequently will face fewer of the effects of loss aversion because of statistical aggregation. Losses over several periods of realizations are less likely than losses in a single period, leading to more stable and profitable portfolios. This exercise is best accomplished when a class can be divided into two sections. If the class cannot be divided, you will need to divide the room into halves and ensure that there is no communication—including expressions of exasperation when returns are revealed. Materials: For each participant you will need to print i.) An instruction sheet and portfolio calculation sheets (from For the Participant). Half of these should be form A and the rest should be of form B ii.) 5 investment sheets for those in treatment A iii.) 25 investment sheets for those in treatment B iv.) 5 return forms for those in treatment A v.) 25 return forms for those in treatment B You will also need to print one instructor’s return sheet (in For the Instructor) and a pair of dice. Preparation: Print all materials. To conserve time you may wish to distribute materials before students arrive. This will include an instruction sheet and 5 investment sheets for each student in treatment A, and an instruction sheet and 25 investment sheets for those in treatment B. You may need assistance in distributing materials throughout the exercise. In this case it may be helpful to ask two students to volunteer to forgo participating and serve as assistants in return for a guarantee of the average experimental dollar return. For the Instructor: Request that all students read the instruction sheet given them. Emphasize that students should not communicate with each other over the course of the experiment and that they should refrain from making expressions that could be interpreted as expressing exasperation or elation. Once all have read the instructions, you may reread the instructions aloud if desired. Ask students if they have any questions regarding how the experiment will proceed. You may need to make some statement about how experimental dollars will translate into actual dollars. Emphasize that the roll of one pair of dice will determine the returns from investments. Ask for two volunteers to inspect the dice and try them to see if they appear to be fair. For treatment A: ο· Ask students to fill out the investment sheet for period 1. Make sure all have written their name on the investment sheet. ο· ο· ο· ο· ο· ο· Collect all investment sheets. Roll the dice first to determine the returns for investment A, and record the return on the instructor’s return sheet and the student return sheets Roll the dice second to determine the returns for investment B, and record the return on the instructor’s return sheet and the student return sheets Distribute the return sheets to all students in treatment A (alternatively you could announce the return if those in treatment B are not present) Ask students to update their portfolio value sheet (you may need to provide instruction) Ask students to fill out the investment sheet for the next period and repeat the process for all 25 periods For treatment B: ο· ο· ο· ο· ο· ο· ο· ο· ο· Ask students to fill out the investment sheet for the first 5 investment periods. Make sure all have written their name on the investment sheet. Collect all investment sheets. Roll the dice first to determine the returns for investment A, and record the return on the instructor’s return sheet and the student return sheets Roll the dice second to determine the returns for investment B, and record the return on the instructor’s return sheet and the student return sheets Repeat the dice rolls for each investment 5 times writing each result in the instructor’s and student return sheet. Calculate the five period return and record this on both instructor and student return sheets, recording the answer on the appropriate Subtotal line Distribute the return sheets to all students in treatment B (alternatively you could announce the five period return if those in treatment B are not present) Ask students to update their portfolio value sheet (you may need to provide instruction) Ask students to fill out the investment sheet for the next 5 investment periods and repeat the process for all 25 periods In the first investment period, the 5-period cumulative return and the cumulative return are equal to the current period’s return. In each succeeding line of the instructor’s return sheet, the cumulative return is equal to the prior period’s cumulative return multiplied by the current period’s return. The 5-period cumulative return will be equal to the previous period’s cumulative return multiplied by the current period’s return except following one of the subtotal lines. On these lines, the 5-period cumulative return will be equal to that period’s return. The total investment value for each individual student may be calculated after completion of the exercise using the student investment sheets and the returns sheet. If both treatments run simultaneously in the same room, it may be easiest to use the same dice rolls to determine the outcomes each period. This will also provide clear contrasts when a series of losses are rolled. However, the instructor needs to ensure that groups do not communicate with one another. Instructor’s Return Sheet Investment A: Investment B: 2= 8= 2= 8= 3= 9= 3= 9= 4= 10= 4= 10 = 5= 11 = 5= 11 = 6= 12 = 6= 12 = 7= 7= Period Investment A Investment B Single 5 -Period Cumulative Single 5-Period Cumulative Period Cumulative Return Period Cumulative Return Return Return Return Return 1 2 3 4 5 Subtotal 6 7 8 9 10 Subtotal 11 12 13 14 15 Subtotal 16 17 18 19 20 Subtotal 21 22 23 24 25 Subtotal For the Participant: Form A Instruction Sheet You will now be participating in an exercise that mimics investment in a stock market. You are initially endowed with $10 to invest. You may invest your money in one of two investments: Investment A and Investment B. You will be participating in this exercise for 25 investment periods. After each period, you will be informed of the return on investment from the previous period for each of the two investment options, and be asked to determine the allocation of your investment between the two options for the current investment period. All money in each period must be invested in one of the two options. Each period you will fill out an investment sheet and record the percentage of your portfolio that you wish to place in Investment A. The remainder will be allocated to Investment B. Make sure that your name and the investment period are recorded on each investment sheet you hand in. The one period returns for each investment will be determined by the rolling of two dice. The dice will be rolled once to determine the one period return for Investment A, and the dice will be rolled a second time to determine the one period return for investment B. The precise relationship between the outcome of the dice roll and value of an investment are derived by multiplying the amount invested by the corresponding numbers below. Thus, if $10 was invested in investment A and a 2 was rolled, the return would be 1 × $10 = 10. Any number above 1 represents a gain, while any number below 1 represents a loss. Investment A: 2 = 1.00 8 = 1.30 3 = 1.05 9 = 1.35 4 = 1.10 10 = 1.40 5 = 1.15 11 = 1.45 6 = 1.20 12 = 1.50 7 = 1.25 Investment B: 2 = 0.1 0 8 = 3.00 3 = 0.25 9 = 3.25 4 = 0.50 10 = 3.50 5 = 0.75 11 = 3.75 6 = 1.00 12 = 4.00 7 = 2.00 Thus, on average, investment A will yield a 25% increase in the value of an investment each period, with a standard deviation of 12%, while investment B will yield a 100% average increase in value each period with a standard deviation of 125%. Investment B has a higher return, but also a higher risk. Return Sheet Investment Period__________________ This period’s return: Investment A ____________________ Investment B:___________________ Portfolio Value Calculation Sheet Period Percent in A Return on A Value of A (=Portfolio Value × Percent in A × Return on A) Percent Return in B on B Value of A (=Portfolio Value × Percent in B × Return on B) Total Portfolio Value (=Value of A + Value of B) 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 Form B Instruction Sheet You will now be participating in an exercise that mimics investment in a stock market. You are initially endowed with $10 to invest. You may invest your money in one of two investments: Investment A and Investment B. You will be participating in this exercise for 25 investment periods. After each set of five investment periods, you will be informed of the return on investment from the previous five periods for each of the two investment options, and be asked to determine the allocation of your investment between the two options for the next five investment periods. All money in each period must be invested in one of the two options. For each set of 5 periods you will fill out an investment sheet and record the percentage of your portfolio that you wish to place in Investment A. The remainder will be allocated to Investment B. Make sure that your name and the number of the set of investment periods (e.g., 1-5, or 6-10, etc.) are recorded on each investment sheet you hand in. The one period returns for each investment will be determined by the rolling of two dice. The dice will be rolled once to determine the one period return for Investment A, and the dice will be rolled a second time to determine the one period return for investment B. The precise relationship between the outcome of the dice roll and value of an investment are derived by multiplying the amount invested by the corresponding numbers below. Thus, if $10 was invested in investment A and a 2 was rolled, the return would be 1 × $10 = 10. Investment A: 2 = 1.00 8 = 1.30 3 = 1.05 9 = 1.35 4 = 1.10 10 = 1.40 5 = 1.15 11 = 1.45 6 = 1.20 12 = 1.50 7 = 1.25 Investment B: 2 = 0.1 0 8 = 3.00 3 = 0.25 9 = 3.25 4 = 0.50 10 = 3.50 5 = 0.75 11 = 3.75 6 = 1.00 12 = 4.00 7 = 2.00 Thus, on average, investment A will yield a 25% increase in the value of an investment each period, with a standard deviation of 12%, while investment B will yield a 100% average increase in value each period with a standard deviation of 125%. Investment B has a higher return, but also a higher risk. Portfolio Value Calculation Sheet Cumulative Percent Periods Return on in A A Value of A (=Portfolio Value × Percent in A× Return on A) Cumulative Percent Return on in B B Value of A (=Portfolio Value × Percent in B × Return on B) Total Portfolio Value (=Value of A + Value of B) 10 1-5 6-10 11-15 16-20 21-25 Return Sheet Investment Periods __________________ Per period returns: Investment A: 1st ________ 2nd _______ 3rd _______ 4th _______ 5th _______ Investment B: 1st ________ 2nd _______ 3rd _______ 4th _______ 5th _______ Cumulative return: Investment A ____________________ Investment B:___________________ Investment Sheet Name ____________________ Investment Period___________________ Percent to Invest in A (1 to 100) __________________________ Total Value of Portfolio__________________________ Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In presenting the results of the exercise, it is best to first present the overall average returns for those in treatment A and those in treatment B. Usually those in treatment A will receive a higher average return. Next, display a graph that shows investment period on the x-axis, and a line graph for returns (one for each investment) and a third line representing the average holding of investment B for those in treatment A. A similar graph should be displayed for those in treatment B, displaying the period-by-period returns rather than the 5 period returns. This will allow the instructor to demonstrate the emotional response to a one period negative return in treatment A. Alternatively the 5 period averaging leads to less emotional response in the portfolio. Risky Choices (Supports Chapter 6) Purpose: These simple questions are based upon Matthew Rabin’s calibration work to demonstrate that individuals appear to display too much risk aversion over small gambles. Materials: One printed survey sheet for each student. Preparation: Print the sheets and distribute. For the Instructor: Ask students to fill out survey sheets. Remind them to answer honestly. Because of the amounts of money involved, this exercise is best administered as a survey with hypothetical questions rather than as a rewarded experiment. For the Participant: Survey Sheet This survey will ask you about a series of risky choices. While all of the questions are hypothetical, please answer as if you would immediately face the consequences of the gamble. In each question you will be asked whether you would be willing to accept a particular gamble or not. Accepting the gamble would mean that you would win or lose the amounts specified with the probabilities specified. Rejecting the gamble would result in no change in your income. Treat each question as if none of the gambles in prior or subsequent questions would be implemented. 1. Would you accept a gamble that gave you a 50% chance of winning $11, and a 50% chance of losing $10? Yes No 2. Would you accept a gamble that gave you a 50% chance of winning $15, and a 50% chance of losing $14? Yes No 3. Would you accept a gamble that gave you a 50% chance of winning $50, and a 50% chance of losing $45? Yes No 4. Would you accept a gamble that gave you a 50% chance of winning $101, and a 50% chance of losing $100? Yes No 5. Would you accept a gamble that gave you a 50% chance of winning $110, and a 50% chance of losing $100? Yes No 6. Would you accept a gamble that gave you a 50% chance of winning $1100, and a 50% chance of losing $1000? Yes No 7. Would you accept a gamble that gave you a 50% chance of winning $1,000,000, and a 50% chance of losing $100? Yes No 8. Would you accept a gamble that gave you a 50% chance of winning $1,000,000, and a 50% chance of losing $196? Yes No 9. Would you accept a gamble that gave you a 50% chance of winning $5,000,000, and a 50% chance of losing $450? Yes No 10. Would you accept a gamble that gave you a 50% chance of winning $10,000,000, and a 50% chance of losing $10,000? Yes No 11. Would you accept a gamble that gave you a 50% chance of winning $10,000,000, and a 50% chance of losing $1,000? Yes No 12. Would you accept a gamble that gave you a 50% chance of winning $110,000,000, and a 50% chance of losing $10,000? Yes No Suggestions for Use in Lecture: The questions are paired so that anyone who is universally risk averse and rejects gamble 1 should also reject gamble 7. Anyone who rejects gamble 2 should reject gamble 8. And so on. It is generally effective to present the percentage of students who reject one of the first six gambles and accept the corresponding gamble from the last six. Presenting each of these usually generates at least two or three that are relatively prominent violations. This can then be used to underscore the strict implications of the expected utility model. Investments and Evaluation (Supports Chapter 6) Purpose: These hypothetical questions are designed to demonstrate that students will make different decisions when presented sequentially than when decisions are aggregated. Materials: The instructor will need: i) Two sets of answer sheets printed from the section below, For the Participant Preparation: Shuffle answer sheets so that they can be distributed randomly to students in the class. For the Instructor: Distribute the materials to students, and ask them to read and answer all questions. Remind students not to discuss the questions with one another. For the Participant:5 Form A: Imagine that you face the following pair of concurrent decisions. First, examine both decisions, then indicate the options you prefer. Decision (i) Choose between: A. A sure gain of $240 B. 25% chance to gain $1000 and 75% chance to gain nothing Decision (ii) Choose between: C. A sure loss of $750 D. 75% chance to lose $1000 and 25% chance to lose nothing Form B: Imagine that you face the following decision. Examine the options, and then indicate the options you prefer. Choose between: A. A sure loss of $510 5 All materials derived from Tversky A. and D. Kahneman. “Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions.” Journal of Business 59(1986):S251-S278. B. 75% chance to lose $760 and a 25% chance to gain $240 C. 25% chance to gain $250 and 75% chance to lose $750 D. 56.25% chance to lose $1000, 6.25% chance to gain $1000 and 37.5% chance to gain nothing Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In lecture it is often easiest to begin by presenting the questions as they appear on form A, and then demonstrating their equivalence to the questions on form B. Afterwards, you may present the proportion of students who chose each possible combination in form A and compare to the choices for form B. Investments and Evaluation (Supports Chapter 6) Purpose: This exercise demonstrates how individuals will seek diversity when making many decisions simultaneously while they may actually seek uniformity when these same decisions are broken out to their constituent parts. Materials: The instructor will need: i) One set of answer sheets of type A (an example appears below in For the Participant). You will need to fill in the three items you decide to use on each of the forms and make sure to use these same three items on all days. The types of items may be adjusted for the course budget and availability of items. ii) You will need to print two sets of answer sheets of type B. iii) Small food items—usually candies of different sorts. Preparation: This exercise takes place over three lectures and all students participate in the same treatment. On the first day, all students need to fill out answer sheet A indicating what treats they want for each of the next two lectures. In the next two lectures, pass out form B and allow students to choose whichever of the treats they like regardless of their stated intention. You will need to bring enough of each item to ensure that all requests can be filled. For the Instructor: Day 1: Instruct students that you will be giving out treats the next two lectures. Ask them to fill out their order forms so that you can make sure there is enough of each item to fill their orders. Day 2: Instruct the students that you have their previous order sheets, but that you have enough on hand for them to choose whatever they like. Ask them to fill out their order and then distribute the items. Day 3: Instruct the students that you have enough on hand for them to choose whatever they like. Ask them to fill out their order and then distribute the items. For the Participant: Form A Name_______________ Over the next two lectures we will be having a small treat in class. Please place your order by circling exactly one item for each of the two days. Day 1: ___________________ ______________________ _______________________ Day 2: ___________________ ______________________ _______________________ Form B Name_______________ Please select the treat you would like today by circling your selection. ___________________ ______________________ _______________________ Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In lecture it is often best to present the percentage of students who choose different items on form A and the percentage of students who chose the same items on each of the forms B. This will usually demonstrate that students believed they would have a greater desire for diversity than is actually realized in later preferences. Flipping Coins (Supports Chapter 7) Purpose: This exercise demonstrates the tendency individuals have to see positive correlation where draws are indeed independent. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) One set of answer sheets in For the Participant ii.) Small stickers that can be used to verify outcomes (you will need one sticker for each student making a correct prediction in all rounds) iii.) A coin Preparation: Pass out the answer sheets prior to beginning the exercise. For the Instructor: Instruct participants to answer the initial question. After the initial question is answered, then instruct the student that you will be flipping a coin repeatedly. Each time before you flip the coin, you will ask them to predict the outcome. They will earn $0.25 experimental dollars each time they predict it correctly. They will lose $0.25 experimental dollars each time they predict incorrectly. You may need to make a statement about how experimental dollars will translate into actual dollars. Instruct students that those making a correct prediction will be verified by either you or an assistant. Prior to each coin toss, ask all students to first record their prediction on the sheet, and have all predicting a heads to raise their hand and keep them raised until you say to lower them. This will allow you so observe if any attempt to change their answers after the toss. After each coin toss, place a sticker next to the correct prediction on the answer sheet for all who made the right prediction. For the Participant: Answer Sheet 1. Using an “H” to indicate “heads” and a “T” to indicate “tails, write down a series of results that would seem typical of the flipping of a fair coin 25 times, (e.g., HHTHTTH…) 2. The instructor will now begin an exercise of flipping a coin. Prior to each coin flip, please make a prediction regarding the outcome of the flip. Do not record your prediction until the instructor requests you to do so. Round 1 2 3 Prediction Actual 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 Suggestions for Use in Lecture: Generally students will be more likely to predict a tail when a heads has just occurred and a head when a tail has just occurred. Additionally, a long string of one outcome will induce many to predict the other outcome. It is usually most effective to present the average percentage predicting a head in a round in which a tail was last flipped, and the average percentage predicting a head in a round when a head was last flipped. Additionally, it may be useful to present a graph with the x-axis representing round, and the y-axis representing the percentage predicting heads and marking on the graph the result of each round. As you present the results remind the students that one coin flip provides no information about the next coin flip. Predicting and Inferring (Supports Chapter 7) Purpose: This experiment can demonstrate the representativeness heuristic-that individuals tend to inflate the probability that what they have observed is representative of the underlying process that generated it. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) One set of answer sheets in For the Participant ii.) One record sheet in For the Instructor iii.) Two identical opaque bags iv.) Seven white Ping-Pong balls v.) Six colored Ping-Pong balls vi.) A six-sided die Preparation: Prior to the beginning of class, place three white and three colored Ping-Pong balls in the first bag, and place 4 white and 2 colored Ping-Pong balls in the second bag. Pass out all answer sheets before the beginning of class. Ensure that there is enough space for you to conduct all required procedures outside of the view of students. For the Instructor: Instruct participants to write their name on their answer sheet. Instruct the class that you have two bags full of colored and white Ping-Pong balls. One bag, Bag A, has three white and three colored balls, while the other, Bag B, has four white and two colored balls. Additionally, inform them that you have a standard six-sided die. You may wish to write this information on a whiteboard or display it on a screen. Invite two members of the class to come forward and inspect the two bags and confirm your description to the class. Read the following instructions to the class: You will now participate in 10 rounds of an inference exercise. In each round, I will draw three Ping-Pong balls from one of the bags, which I will do outside of your view. You will then be asked to record which bag (either A or B) you believe the balls came from, and your guess as to the probability that I am drawing from that bag. Before drawing the Ping-Pong balls, in each round I will select the bag to draw from by rolling the die, also outside of your view. If I roll a 1, 2, 3 or 4, I will select Bag A. If I roll a 5 or 6, I will select Bag B. For each round in which you predict correctly which bag I am drawing from, you will receive $0.25 experimental dollars. For each round in which you are wrong, you will lose $0.25 dollars. Ask students if they have any questions. Begin round one by rolling the die, making sure that students cannot see the result. Record the result of the die roll and the resulting bag on the Record Sheet. Then, being careful that students cannot observe which bag you are using, draw three Ping-Pong balls and display them for the students. Ask students to record their responses for round 1. Replace the Ping-Pong Balls, and continue in a like manner for rounds 2 through 10. Afterwards, collect the answer sheets, and then announce the results for each round. You can then use the answer sheets and record sheet to determine rewards. Note that you should not reveal the results of any roll until after you have collected the answer sheets. Record Sheet Round 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Die Roll Bag Draw For the Participant: Answer Sheet Name_________________________ Round 1 Which bag do you believe the With what probability to instructor is drawing from? you believe the instructor (Circle one) is drawing from that bag? (Answer should be between 0 and 1) A B 2 A B 3 A B 4 A B 5 A B 6 A B 7 A B 8 A B 9 A B 10 A B Suggestions for Use in Lecture: When you happen to draw two white balls and one colored ball, students will tend to over predict the probability that you are drawing from Bag B. One way to illustrate this is to present the class average predicted probabilities for each scenario of draw that occurred (three colored, one white two colored, two white one colored and three colored) and the probabilities that would correspond to Bayesian beliefs (the corresponding probabilities you are drawing from Bag B are 0, 0.23, 0.37, 0.54). As well, it can be useful to display the percent predicting Bag A and Bag B for each round, and the actual bag that was being used. Representativeness (Supports Chapter 7) Purpose: These hypothetical questions can demonstrate the representativeness heuristic. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) One set of answer sheets in For the Participant Preparation: Pass out the answer sheets prior to beginning the exercise. For the Instructor: Instruct students to answer the questions on their answer sheet and hand in their sheets. For the Participant: Answer Sheet6 Question 1: A cab was involved in a hit and run accident at night. Two cab companies, the Green and the Blue, operate in the city. You are given the following data: (a) 85 percent of the cabs in the city are Green and 15 percent are Blue (b) A witness identified the cab as Blue, This witness was tested under similar visibility conditions and made correct color identifications in 80% of the trial instances. What is the probability that the cab involved in the accident was a Blue Cab rather than a Green one? ______________ (a number between 0 and 1) Question 2: Bill is 34 years old. He is intelligent, but unimaginative, compulsive, and generally lifeless. In school, he was strong in mathematics but weak in social studies and humanities. Please rank order the following statements by their probability, using 1 for the most probable and 8 for the least probable. _____ Bill is a physician who plays poker for a hobby. _____ Bill is an architect. _____ Bill is an accountant. Question1 reprinted with permission from Tversky, A. and D. Kahneman. “On Prediction and Judgment” Oregon Research Institute Bulletin (1972). Questions 2 and 3 reprinted with permission (and slight modifications) from Tversky, A. and D. Kahneman. “Extensional Versus Intuitive Reasoning: The Conjunction Fallacy in Probability Judgment.” Psychological Review 90(1983): page 297. 6 _____ _____ _____ _____ _____ Bill plays jazz for a hobby. Bill surfs for a hobby. Bill is a reporter. Bill is an accountant who plays jazz for a hobby. Bill climbs mountains for a hobby. Question 3: Linda is 31 years old, single, outspoken, and very bright. She majored in philosophy. As a student, she was deeply concerned with issues of discrimination and social justice, and also participated in anti-war demonstrations. Please rank order the following statements by their probability, using 1 for the most probable and 8 for the least probable. _____ Linda is a teacher in elementary school. _____ Linda works in a bookstore and takes Yoga classes. _____ Linda is active in feminist organizations. _____ Linda is a psychiatric social worker. _____ Linda is a member of the League of Women Voters. _____ Linda is a bank teller. _____ Linda is an insurance salesperson. _____ Linda is a bank teller and is active in feminist organizations. Suggestions for Use in Lecture: For question 1, the instructor should present the average predicted probability that the Blue cab was involved in the accident, and compare this average to the probability according to Bayes rule 0.15 × 0.85/(0.15 × 0.85 + 0.85 × 0.15) = 0.5. Note that if they assessed the probability higher than that of Bayes rule, it was as if they were ignoring the base rate (the overall prevalence of Blue cabs) to some extent. When presenting questions 2 and 3, simply note average rank of each outcome. Generally students rank the compound options (e.g., Linda is a bank teller and is active in feminist organizations) as more probable than at least one of the components (e.g., Linda is a bank teller). Discuss how this may come about because the compound answer is more representative of the description of Linda than the single component. Flipping Cards (Supports Chapter 8) Purpose: This simple experiment demonstrates the confirmation effect. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) One set of answer sheets in For the Participant ii.) 3” x 5” index cards (enough for each student to receive 4) iii.) Markers Preparation: Before class starts, mark each card with a letter on one side and a number on the other side. At least every fourth card should be marked with a vowel, and every fourth card should be marked with a 5. For the Instructor: Once class has started, distribute answer sheets. Explain to the class that they will each receive four cards. They are not to turn the cards over. Each card has been marked on one side with a letter and on the other side with a number. After giving this instruction, place four cards on each student’s desk, ensuring that each student has at least one vowel and one “5” showing. Explain to students that you are interested in testing the hypothesis that each card marked with a vowel on one side is marked with a “5” on the other side. Without turning the cards over, please fill in part 1 of the answer sheet. After all have completed part 1, instruct them to turn over only the cards they selected and complete part 2. Once all have completed part 2, ask them to turn over the remaining cards and, in part 3, write down anything they may have learned from turning over these last cards with respect to the hypothesis. For the Participant: Answer Sheet Name_________________________ Part 1 Please draw the markings on the four boxes below so that they resemble the cards on your desk In order to test the hypothesis described by the instructor, which cards would you need to turn over (please list only those necessary to test the hypothesis) _______________________________________________________________________ Part 2 List what is written on both sides of all cards you turned over (you will likely not fill in all the blanks below) 1. 2. 3. 4. Front___________ Front___________ Front___________ Front___________ Back______________ Back______________ Back______________ Back______________ Do you believe the hypothesis is true or false? ___________________ Part 3 ________________________________________________________________________ Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In general you should find some prevalence of students that will not think it is necessary to turn over any card displaying a number other than 5. It may be useful to display a histogram of responses from part one displaying the frequency of various cards being cited as necessary to test the hypothesis (e.g., a bin for vowels, a bin for “5”, a bin for numbers other than 5, and a bin for consonants). It may also be useful to display the number from part 2 who believe the hypothesis is true. By failing to turn over numbers other than 5, students will have a higher probability of not finding disconfirming information. Finally, it may be useful to note the number of students in part 3 who realized they should have turned over the other number cards. Debate Club (Supports Chapter 8) Purpose: This exercise is designed to demonstrate confirmation bias and the tendency to dispute or disregard information that is counter to one’s own beliefs. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) One set of answer sheets in For the Participant ii.) One team sheet to record who is pro and who is anti, in For the Instructor Preparation: Before class, the instructor will need to print one answer sheet for each student. For the Instructor: Once class starts, inform the class that they are going to engage in a policy debate. Announce that one side will be arguing for the taxing of sugared sodas (or select some other topic that is likely to generate a nearly even split within your class) while the other side will be arguing against the tax. They are allowed to determine which side of the debate they will be on. Ask all who wish to argue for the tax to raise their hand, and note their names. Then note the names of those who are opposed. Students will be given 5 minutes to prepare their own arguments. After this 5 minutes, you will call upon 3 pro students and 3 anti students. Each will be given 3 minutes to make their point. The debate will alternate sides with a Pro student arguing first. All students will be asked to rate the effectiveness of each debater and rank them in order of how convincing their arguments are. Randomly select three students from each side after 5 minutes has passed. Remind students to rank all debaters at the end of the exercise. Team Sheet Pro Anti For the Participant: Answer Sheet Name____________________________________ Debater 1 (Pro): Strongly Agree The arguments were accurate: 1 2 3 4 5 Strongly Disagree 6 7 The arguments were flawed: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 He/she was effective: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 He/she persuaded me: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Strongly Agree The arguments were accurate: 1 2 3 4 5 Strongly Disagree 6 7 The arguments were flawed: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 He/she was effective: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 He/she persuaded me: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Debater 2 (Anti): Debater 3 (Pro): Strongly Agree The arguments were accurate: 1 2 3 4 5 Strongly Disagree 6 7 The arguments were flawed: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 He/she was effective: 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 He/she persuaded me: 1 2 3 4 5 6 Strongly Agree The arguments were accurate: 1 2 3 4 5 Strongly Disagree 6 7 The arguments were flawed: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 He/she was effective: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 He/she persuaded me: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Debater 4 (Anti): Debater 5 (Pro): 7 Strongly Agree The arguments were accurate: 1 2 3 4 5 Strongly Disagree 6 7 The arguments were flawed: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 He/she was effective: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 He/she persuaded me: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Strongly Agree The arguments were accurate: 1 2 3 4 5 Strongly Disagree 6 7 The arguments were flawed: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 He/she was effective: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 He/she persuaded me: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Debater 6 (Anti): Please rank the debaters in order of their persuasiveness (most persuasive first). Use their number to identify them. ___________ ___________ ___________ ___________ ___________ ___________ Suggestions for Use in Lecture: It is most effective to display the average Likert scale ratings for each team (pro or anti) by the pro or anti status of the rater. It is best to present these as team averages so that a particularly poor debater is not singled out. In general you will find that those who are pro tend to rate pro debaters as more effective and persuasive. Additionally, it may be useful to display the average rank of a pro or anti debater as determined by pro or anti students. These can be simple means. A Matter of Confidence (Supports Chapter 8) Purpose: This exercise is designed to demonstrate overconfidence in expressing ones certainty regarding some general fact. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) One set of answer sheets in For the Participant Preparation: Prior to the beginning of class, the instructor will need to print an answer sheet for each participant. The instructor is encouraged to edit the questions listed so that some are more relevant and familiar to students and some are less so. Questions relating to the size or function of the school they attend may be particularly useful. For the Instructor: Instruct the class that they will be asked to take a survey. The survey lists several statistics without giving you the number (for example, the U.S. GDP in 2012). For each statistic, the student is asked to give one high number such that they believe there is only a 5% chance that the true value is above the number you write. The student will also be asked for a low number such that there is only a 5% chance that the true value is below this low number. Ask students if they understand the task and answer any questions they may have. Statistic The population of Rhode Island in 2010 Answer 1,052,567 (U.S. Census) The percent of US voters who selected Barack Obama for 51.1 president in 2012 (New York Times) The land area of the United States in square miles 3,537,436 (Graphic Maps) Percent of Americans living below the poverty line in 2011 15 (U.S. Census) Number of new houses sold in the United States in 2012 368,000 (U.S. Census) Normal yearly snowfall in Syracuse, New York 116.9 (Nat. Weather Service) Total enrollment at the University of Maryland, College Park in 26,826 Fall 2011 (undergraduate and graduate) (umd.edu) Average annual rainfall in Berkeley, California 25.40 (Nat. Weather Service) Percent of U.S. adults who report having had an alcoholic 64% (Gallup) beverage in the last week (July 2012) Percent of U.S. households who report having access to the 44 internet (2010) The elevation (in feet) of the tallest mountain in the U.S. The elevation (in feet) of the lowest point in the U.S. Median age of United States residents in 2010 Average in-state tuition for a public 4 year institution of higher learning (2012) Percent of Americans that identify themselves as Christians (2012) Percent of Americans that identify themselves as Catholics (2012) Percent of American that identify themselves as atheists (2012) Current national debt per capita (2012) Amount collected by the US federal government in individual income taxes in 2012. Percent of total government revenues generated by individual income taxes (2012). (U.S. Census) 20,320 (Rand) -282 (Rand) 37.2 (U.S. Census) $8,655 (College Board) 77 (Gallup) 23.3 (Gallup) 5 (WIN Gallup) $48,700 (U.S. Treasury, U.S. Census) $1.4 Trillion (U.S. Treasury) 27.5 (U.S. Treasury) For the Participant: Answer Sheet Definition of a 90% confidence interval: An interval that, on average, contains the true value about 9 out of every 10 draws. You should expect that 9 out of every 10 of the intervals you give below will contain the truth, and 1 out of every 10 will not. The lower bound should be a value such that you believe there is a 5% chance that the true value falls below the lower bound. The upper bound should be a value such that you believe there is a 5% chance that the true value falls above the upper bound. Statistic The population of Rhode Island in 2010 The percent of US voters who selected Barack Obama for president in 2012 90% Confidence Interval Lower Upper Bound Bound The land area of the United States in square miles Percent of Americans living below the poverty line in 2011 Number of new houses sold in the United States in 2012 Normal yearly snowfall in Syracuse, New York Total enrollment at the University of Maryland, College Park in Fall 2011 (undergraduate and graduate) Average annual rainfall in Berkeley, California Percent of U.S. adults who report having had an alcoholic beverage in the last week (July 2012) Percent of U.S. households who report having access to the internet (2010) The elevation (in feet) of the tallest mountain in the U.S. The elevation (in feet) of the lowest point in the U.S. Median age of United States residents in 2010 Average in-state tuition for a public 4 year institution of higher learning (2012) Percent of Americans that identify themselves as Christians (2012) Percent of Americans that identify themselves as Catholics (2012) Percent of American that identify themselves as atheists (2012) Current national debt per capita (2012) Amount collected by the US federal government in individual income taxes in 2012. Percent of total government revenues generated by individual income taxes (2012). Suggestions for Use in Lecture: It is easiest and most effective to display the percentage of students whose intervals contained the true value for each question. You could also calculate an overall containing percentage. The point you should make is that well more than 10% of the true values fall outside of the interval for most questions. Moreover, if you have included some questions that are more familiar to students you might see a tendency for less than 10% of the true values to fall outside of the intervals. Decision under Risk (Supports Chapter 9) Purpose: This exercise is designed to demonstrate the Allais and common ratio paradoxes as well as preference cycling. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) One set of answer sheets in For the Participant ii.) An opaque bag and 16 ping pong balls. iii.) An 10-sided die iv.) A probability scale sheet in For the Instructor v.) A highlighter pen Preparation: Before class, number the Ping-Pong balls from 1 to 16. For the Instructor: As class begins distribute the answer sheets to students. Once all have their answer sheets, read the following instructions: Please write your name on your answer sheet. On your answer sheet you are presented with a series of choices between two gambles. Each lottery lists the probability of receiving various amounts of money. When we begin the exercise, you will be asked to circle your choice for each of the 16 choice problems. I have a bag with 16 Ping-Pong balls, numbered from 1 to 16. [Display the bag and invite one member of the class to confirm that there are 16 balls and that they are numbered as described]. After you have completed your selections on the answer sheet, you will have the opportunity to play one of the choices you made for experimental dollars. The choice you play for will be selected at random. You will be asked to draw a Ping-Pong ball from the bag. The ball you draw will determine which choice will be played for real rewards. The result of the gamble will be determined by the roll of an 10-sided die. [Display the die]. Ask students if they have any questions regarding the procedure. Once all questions have been answered, ask students to begin the exercise. When each student finishes have them draw their own Ping-Pong ball, and replace the ball and circle the corresponding problem on the student’s answer sheet. Then have the student roll the die, and show them the corresponding result of their gamble from the probability scale sheet. Highlight the outcome of the gamble that resulted from the die roll and collect the student’s sheet in order to record the monetary reward. Probability Scale Sheet For each of the gambles with probabilities measured in tenths, roll the die one time. If the result of the roll is π· then define π₯ = π·/10 and use the scale below to determine the outcome. For each of the gambles with probabilities measured in hundredths, roll the die twice. If the result of the first roll is π· and the result of the second is π , first redefine π· π any result of “10” as a “0” then define π₯ = 10 + 100. Then use the scale below to determine the outcome. Gamble 1B: π₯ = 0.1 → $0; 0.2 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.9 → $6; π₯ = 1.0 → $14 Gamble 2A: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.3 → $0; 0.4 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $11 Gamble 3A: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.4 → $3; 0.5 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $10 Gamble 4A: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.4 → $0; 0.5 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $6 Gamble 4B: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.5 → $0; 0.6 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.9 → $6; π₯ = 1.0 → $14 Gamble 5A: 0.00 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.57 → $0; 0.58 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.99 → $11 Gamble 6B: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.3 → $1; 0.4 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $7.50 Gamble 7A: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.7 → $0; 0.8 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $6 Gamble 7B: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.8 → $0; π₯ = 0.9 → $6; π₯ = 1.0 → $14 Gamble 8A: 0.00 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.93 → $0; 0.94 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.99 → $11 Gamble 8B: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.8 → $0; 0.9 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $7 Gamble 9A: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.6 → $3; 0.7 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $10 Gamble 10A: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.8 → $0; 0.9 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $6 Gamble 10B: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.9 → $0; π₯ = 1.0 → $14 Gamble 11A: 0.00 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.13 → $0; 0.14 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.99 → $11 Gamble 11B: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.2 → $2; 0.3 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $11 Gamble 12A: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.4 → $0; 0.5 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.6 → $6; 0.7 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $14 Gamble 12B: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.5 → $0; 0.6 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $14 Gamble 13A: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.7 → $0; 0.8 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.9 → $6; π₯ = 1.0 → $14 Gamble 13B: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.8 → $0; 0.9 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $14 Gamble 14A: 0.00 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.41 → $0; 0.42 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.99 → $11 Gamble 14B: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.6 → $2; 0.7 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $11 Gamble 15A: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.7 → $0; 0.8 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $11 Gamble 16A: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.2 → $0; 0.3 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.8 → $6; 0.9 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $14 Gamble 16B: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.3 → $0; 0.4 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.7 → $6; 0.8 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $14 For the Participant: Answer Sheet Name ______________________________ Problem 1. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $6 with probability 1 Gamble B $0 with probability 0.1 $6 with probability 0.8 $14 with probability 0.1 Problem 2. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.3 $11 with probability 0.7 Gamble B $7 with probability 1 Problem 3. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $3 with probability 0.4 $10 with probability 0.6 Gamble B $1 with probability 0.3 $7.50 with probability 0.7 Problem 4. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.4 $6 with probability 0.6 Gamble B $0 with probability 0.5 $6 with probability 0.4 $14 with probability 0.1 Problem 5. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A Gamble B $0 with probability 0.58 $11 with probability 0.42 $0 with probability 0.4 $7 with probability 0.6 Problem 6. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $5 with probability 1 Gamble B $1 with probability 0.3 $7.50 with probability 0.7 Problem 7. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.7 $6 with probability 0.3 Gamble B $0 with probability 0.8 $6 with probability 0.1 $14 with probability 0.1 Problem 8. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.93 $11 with probability 0.07 Gamble B $0 with probability 0.9 $7 with probability 0.1 Problem 9. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $3 with probability 0.6 $10 with probability 0.4 Gamble B $5 with probability 1 Problem 10. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.8 $6 with probability 0.2 Gamble B $0 with probability 0.9 $14 with probability 0.1 Problem 11. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.14 $11 with probability 0.86 Gamble B $2 with probability 0.2 $11 with probability 0.8 Problem 12. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.4 $6 with probability 0.2 $14 with probability 0.4 Gamble B $0 with probability 0.5 $14 with probability 0.5 Problem 13. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.7 $6 with probability 0.2 $14 with probability 0.1 Gamble B $0 with probability 0.8 $14 with probability 0.2 Problem 14. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.42 $11 with probability 0.58 Gamble B $2 with probability 0.6 $11 with probability 0.4 Problem 15. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.7 $11 with probability 0.3 Gamble B $2 with probability 1 Problem 16. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.2 $6 with probability 0.6 $14 with probability 0.2 Gamble B $0 with probability 0.3 $6 with probability 0.4 $14 with probability 0.3 Suggestions for Use in Lecture: The problems listed on the answer sheet fall into one of three categories. Problems 1, 4, 7, 10, 12, 13 and 16 are designed to demonstrate the common outcome (Allais) effect. It is usually effective to select two of these problems to work out on the board in presentation. If, without loss of generality, we let π’(0) = 0, then choosing Gamble A in any of these problems implies that 0.2 × π’(6) > 0.1 × π’(14). Thus, a rational decision-maker would only choose Gamble A in each of these problems, or always reject B in each of these Gambles. It is then useful to display the percentage of students who violated this rule, and to display the percent choosing Gamble A in each of these problems. It could also be useful to plot each of these problems on the Marschak-Machina triangle to demonstrate their location and how expected utility preferences would exclude switching between A and B between problems. This can be easily done using a simple scatter plot in Excel using the probabilities of the lowest and highest amounts as the x and y coordinates. Problems 2, 5, 8, 11, 14 and 15 are designed to demonstrate the common ratio effect. It is usually effective to select two of these problems to work out on the board in presentation. If, without loss of generality, we let π’(0) = 0, then choosing Gamble A in either problems 2, 5 or 8 implies that 0.3 × π’(11) > π’(7). Thus, if one chooses A for any of these three, one should not also choose B for any of these three. Additionally, choosing Gamble A in problems 11, 14 or 15 implies that 0.3 × π’(11) > π’(2). Thus again, anyone who chooses A for any of these three and also select B for any of these three is in violation of expected utility. It is then useful to display the percentage of students who violated this rule, and to display the percent choosing Gamble A in each of these problems. It could also be useful to plot each of these problems on the Marschak-Machina triangle to demonstrate their location and how expected utility preferences would exclude switching between A and B between problems. Problems 3, 6 and 9 are designed to demonstrate preference reversals. If one chooses Gamble B in problem 3 and Gamble A in problem 6, one should not also choose Gamble B in problem 9. Additionally, if one chooses A in problem 3 and B in problem 6 one should not also choose A in problem 9. In this case it is most effective to simply demonstrate how these are intransitive choices and then display the percentage of students who have made such inconsistent choices. Decision under Risk (Supports Chapter 9) Purpose: The purpose of this exercise is to demonstrate the Ellsberg paradox. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) One set of answer sheets in For the Participant ii.) Two opaque bags iii.) 12 white Ping-Pong balls and 12 colored Ping-Pong balls. Preparation: Prior to class, label the bags as “A” and “B”. Place 8 white Ping-Pong balls and 4 colored balls in bag A. Place the remaining balls in bag B. For the Instructor: Give each student a copy of answer sheet I and instruct him or her to fill in his or her name. Read the following instructions: I have two bags filled with white and colored Ping-Pong balls [display the bags]. Bag A has 8 white PingPong balls and 4 colored Ping-Pong balls [invite a student to confirm this statement]. Bag B has white and colored Ping-Pong balls, but I will not tell you the number of each within Bag B. You will be asked to select which bag you would like to draw from. In a moment I will draw one Ping-Pong ball out of each bag. If I draw a colored ball from the bag that you have selected, you will win $5 [or some other prize]. If I draw a white ball from the bag you have selected, you will win nothing. Write the distribution of balls in Bag A on the board so all can see. Then ask all students to make their selection on their answer sheet. Be sure to collect these answer sheets. Now hand out answer sheet II. Instruct them that after the first draw, you will replace the Ping-Pong balls and draw a second ball from each bag. This time, however, participants will receive $5 if a white ball is drawn. Ask them to record their preference on answer sheet II. Be sure to collect these sheets prior to drawing Ping-Pong balls so that students cannot change their answer. You may decide to run this experiment more than once and experiment with the distribution of balls in the known bag. For the Participant: Answer Sheet I Name ______________________________ You will be rewarded if a colored ball is drawn from the bag you choose. If a white ball is drawn from the bag you choose, you will receive nothing. Please select which bag you would like to be rewarded based upon. Please circle one Bag A 8 white 4 colored Bag B ? Answer Sheet II Name ______________________________ You will be rewarded if a white ball is drawn from the bag you choose. If a colored ball is drawn from the bag you choose, you will receive nothing. Please select which bag you would like to be rewarded based upon. Please circle one Bag A 8 white 4 colored Bag B ? Suggestions for Use in Lecture: Students will be curious to know the distribution of balls in Bag B. It may be useful to first tell them what the distribution was. Then, report the percentage of those who chose Bag A in round I and in round II. These responses are likely to be inconsistent with the notion that they have a fixed belief about the distribution of balls in Bag B. Gains and Losses (Supports Chapter 10) Purpose: The purpose of this exercise is to demonstrate the reflection effect. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) One set of answer sheets in For the Participant ii.) An opaque bag and 8 Ping-pong balls. iii.) An 10-sided die iv.) A probability scale sheet in For the Instructor v.) A highlighter pen Preparation: Before class, number the Ping-Pong balls from 1 to 8. For the Instructor: As class begins distribute the answer sheets to students. Once all have their answer sheets, read the following instructions: Please write your name on your answer sheet. On your answer sheet you are presented with a series of choices between two gambles. Each lottery lists the probability of receiving various amounts of money. When we begin the exercise, you will be asked to circle your choice for each of the 8 choice problems. I have a bag with 8 Ping-Pong balls, numbered from 1 to 8. [Display the bag and invite one member of the class to confirm that there are 8 balls and that they are numbered as described]. After you have completed your selections on the answer sheet, you will have the opportunity to play one of the choices you made for experimental dollars. The choice you play for will be selected at random. You will be asked to draw a PingPong ball from the bag. The ball you draw will determine which choice will be played for real rewards. The result of the gamble will be determined by the roll of an 10-sided die. [Display the die]. Ask students if they have any questions regarding the procedure. Once all questions have been answered, ask students to begin the exercise. When each student finishes have them draw their own Ping-Pong ball, and replace the ball and circle the corresponding problem on the student’s answer sheet. Then have the student roll the die, and show them the corresponding result of their gamble from the probability scale sheet. Highlight the outcome of the gamble that resulted from the die roll and collect the student’s sheet in order to record the monetary reward. Before administering this exercise, you should be sure that all students could sustain the potential losses listed (for example, if all have earned at least $30 experimental dollars throughout the semester). If not, you may need to either endow each with enough experimental money to allow the exercise, or instead make the experiment hypothetical. Probability Scale Sheet For each of the gambles with probabilities measured in tenths, roll the die one time. If the result of the roll is π· then define π₯ = π·/10 and use the scale below to determine the outcome. For each of the gambles with probabilities measured in hundredths, roll the die twice. If the result of the first roll is π· and the result of the second is π , first redefine π· π any result of “10” as a “0” then define π₯ = 10 + 100. Then use the scale below to determine the outcome. Gamble 1A: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.2 → $0; 0.3 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $20 Gamble 2A: 0.00 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.97 → $0; 0.98 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.99 → −$15 Gamble 2B: 0.00 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.98 → $0; π₯ = 0.99 → −$30 Gamble 3A: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.8 → $0; 0.9 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $20 Gamble 3B: 0.00 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.74 → $0; 0.75 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.99 → $15 Gamble 4A: π₯ = 0.1 → $0; 0.2 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → −$15 Gamble 4B: 0.00 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.54 → $0; 0.55 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.99 → −$30 Gamble 5A: π₯ = 0.1 → $0; 0.2 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → $15 Gamble 5B: 0.00 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.54 → $0; 0.55 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.99 → $30 Gamble 6A: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.8 → $0; 0.9 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → −$20 Gamble 6B: 0.00 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.74 → $0; 0.75 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.99 → −$15 Gamble 7A: 0.00 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.97 → $0; 0.98 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.99 → $15 Gamble 7B: 0.00 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.98 → $0; π₯ = 0.99 → $30 Gamble 8A: 0.1 ≤ π₯ ≤ 0.2 → $0; 0.3 ≤ π₯ ≤ 1.0 → −$20 For the Participant: Answer Sheet Name ______________________________ Problem 1. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.2 $20 with probability 0.8 Gamble B $15 with probability 1 Problem 2. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.98 −$15 with probability 0.02 Gamble B $0 with probability 0.99 −$30 with probability 0.01 Problem 3. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.8 $20 with probability 0.2 Gamble B $0 with probability 0.75 $15 with probability 0.25 Problem 4. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.1 −$15 with probability 0.9 Gamble B $0 with probability 0.55 −$30 with probability 0.45 Problem 5. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.1 $15 with probability 0.9 Gamble B $0 with probability 0.55 $30 with probability 0.45 Problem 6. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.8 −$20 with probability 0.2 Gamble B $0 with probability 0.75 −$15 with probability 0.25 Problem 7. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.98 $15 with probability 0.02 Gamble B $0 with probability 0.99 $30 with probability 0.01 Problem 8. Please circle the gamble you prefer Gamble A $0 with probability 0.2 −$20 with probability 0.8 Gamble B −$15 with probability 1 Suggestions for Use in Lecture: Each of the problems corresponds to another problem that is identical except that the values that can be won are multiplied by −1. Students will have a tendency to switch their preferences between the positive (gain) gambles and the negative (loss) gambles. In most cases, students will behave as if risk averse over gains and risk loving over losses. To demonstrate this, first note which problems correspond to one another (e.g., Problem 1 and Problem 8, Problem 2 and Problem 7, Problem 3 and Problem 6, Problem 4 and Problem 5). Then display the percentage choosing Gamble A in each problem pointing out the differences within the corresponding pairs. It may be useful to point out which of the pairs are more risk averse (e.g., Gamble B in Problem 1 and Gamble B in Problem 8). What and When to Eat (Supports Chapter11) Purpose: The purpose of this exercise is to demonstrate hot-cold empathy gap. Materials: This exercise must take place over two or more classes. In the first class, the instructor will need: i.) One bag of candy bars. These should be relatively filling and rich candy bars. ii.) A set of answer sheets found in For the Participant In the second class, the instructor will need: i.) Enough candy bars to fill the orders from the previous class. ii.) Enough of a lighter snack to fill the orders from the previous class. This lighter snack can be something like a fruit, or crackers. Preparation: Count out enough candy bars to give them to one half of the class prior to the first lecture. Arrive early for the lecture. Prior to the second lecture count out enough of each snack to fill the orders from the previous lecture. For the Instructor: In the first class, reward the first half of students that arrive with a candy bar. Instruct them that you will only give it to them if they will eat it before class starts. Record the name of each student who takes a candy bar. Once class starts, pass out the answer sheets and ask students to fill them in. Explain that next class you will be handing out some food and that students need to place their order. In the next class, simply fill the orders that were placed previously. For the Participant: Answer Sheet Name _______________________ Next lecture, we will be having some food in lecture. Would you rather have (circle one) A candy bar [fill in brand and description of size] A healthy snack [fill in alternate lighter snack, with size and description] Suggestions for Use in Lecture: Students who had a filling candy bar will be less likely to choose a filling candy bar for the next class because they feel less hungry when ordering. Explain that some students were given a candy bar prior to class. Then display the percentage choosing each option conditioned on whether they received a candy bar or not. The Consequences of War (Supports Chapter11) Purpose: The purpose of this exercise is to demonstrate hindsight bias. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) A set of form I answer sheets found in For the Participant (enough for half of the students) ii.) A set of form II answer sheets found in For the Participant (enough for half of the students) Preparation: Shuffle the answer sheets before distribution. For the Instructor: Instruct students to fill out the answer sheets by circling the outcome they would guess to be the most probable outcome. For the Participant: 7 Answer Sheet (Form I) Consider a British campaign in 1814 against a group of Nepalese. One text describes the conflict this way: “For some years after the arrival of Hastings as governor-general of India, the consolidation of British power involved serious war. The first of these wars took place on the northern frontier of Bengal where the British were faced by the plundering raids of the Gurkas of Nepal. Attempts had been made to stop the raids by an exchange of lands, but the Gurkas would not give up their claims to country under British control, and Hastings decided to deal with them once and for all. The campaign began in November, 1814. It was not glorious. The Gurkas were only some 12,000 strong; but they were brave fighters, fighting in territory well-suited to their raiding tactics. The older British commanders were used to war in the plains where the enemy ran away from a resolute attack. In the mountains of Nepal it was not easy even to find the enemy. The troops and transport animals suffered from the extremes of heat and cold, and the officers learned caution only after sharp reverses. Major-General Sir D. Octerlony was the one commander to escape from these minor defeats.” Given this history, would you guess the conflict to result in: (a) British victory (b) Gurka victory The quote is reprinted with permission from Woodard, E.L. Age of Reform London: Oxford University Press, 1938, 383-384. The question is reprinted with permission from Fischoff, B. “Hindsight≠ Foresight: The Effect of Outcome Knowledge on Judgment Under Uncertaintly. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 1(1975): 288-299. 7 (c) military stalemate with no peace settlement, or (d) military stalemate with a peace settlement. Answer Sheet (Form II) Consider a British campaign in 1814 against a group of Nepalese that resulted in Nepal ceding one third of their territory to the British. One text describes the conflict this way: “For some years after the arrival of Hastings as governor-general of India, the consolidation of British power involved serious war. The first of these wars took place on the northern frontier of Bengal where the British were faced by the plundering raids of the Gurkas of Nepal. Attempts had been made to stop the raids by an exchange of lands, but the Gurkas would not give up their claims to country under British control, and Hastings decided to deal with them once and for all. The campaign began in November 1814. It was not glorious. The Gurkas were only some 12,000 strong; but they were brave fighters, fighting in territory well-suited to their raiding tactics. The older British commanders were used to war in the plains where the enemy ran away from a resolute attack. In the mountains of Nepal it was not easy even to find the enemy. The troops and transport animals suffered from the extremes of heat and cold, and the officers learned caution only after sharp reverses. Major-General Sir D. Octerlony was the one commander to escape from these minor defeats.” Given this history (pretending you did not know the outcome), would you guess the conflict to result in: (a) British victory (b) Gurka victory (c) military stalemate with no peace settlement, or (d) military stalemate with a peace settlement. Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In lecture, display the two answer sheets so that students can see the subtle difference between the two. Then simply display the percentage choosing each outcome conditioned on which form they received. There will generally be a higher percentage choosing option (a) when reading form II. Apples and Oranges (Supports Chapter 12) Purpose: The purpose of this exercise is to demonstrate present biased preferences and potentially the asymmetry between gains and losses. This is usually best conducted earlier in the semester. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) A set of form I answer sheets found in For the Participant (enough for half of the students) ii.) A set of form II answer sheets found in For the Participant (enough for half of the students) iii.) Candy bars (or some other treat)—enough to provide the necessary rewards. iv.) A fair coin. Preparation: Print answer sheets and shuffle them so that they may be easily assigned randomly. For the Instructor: Distribute answer sheets to the class so that half receives form I and half receives form II. Instruct them to write their name on their answer sheet. Read the following instructions: On your answer sheet, you are presented with three questions. The first question is hypothetical and will not result in any reward. The second and third questions may result in a real reward. In each you are asked to choose between different amounts of candy bars at different points of time. [Display the candy bars so the class knows they are real.] After you have made your selection for both questions 2 and 3, I will flip a coin to determine whether we will implement your answer to question 2 or question 3. Heads will result in question 2, and tails will result in question three. Please fill out your answer sheets now. After all have filled out their answers, collect the sheets and flip the coin so all can see. Then, provide the resulting reward at the specified time. For the Participant: Answer Sheet (Form I) Question 1: Suppose you bought a tablet computer on an installment plan. You are required to make two payments: one this week and one six months from now. Which would you prefer? (circle one) A. A payment this week of $320 and a later payment of $220 B. A payment this week of $230 and a later payment of $320 Question 2: Which would you prefer? (circle one) A. One candy bar today. B. Two candy bars next lecture. Question 3: Which would you prefer? (circle one) A. One candy bar in the second to last lecture of the semester. B. Two candy bars on the last lecture of the semester. Answer Sheet (Form II) Question 1: Suppose you bought a tablet computer on an installment plan. You must make two payments of $400: one this week and one six months from now. However, a sale has just been announced that will apply to your purchase retroactively. Which would you prefer? (circle one) A. A rebate of $80 on the payment this week and a rebate of $180 on the later payment. B. A rebate of $170 on the payment this week and a rebate of $80 on the later payment. Question 2: Which would you prefer? (circle one) A. One candy bar today. B. Two candy bars next lecture. Question 3: Which would you prefer? (circle one) A. One candy bar in the second to last lecture of the semester. B. Two candy bars on the last lecture of the semester. Suggestions for Use in Lecture: For question 1, Form I frames the cost of the tablet as a loss while Form II uses the rebate to frame the cost as a gain. Typically, you will observe students preferring to delay the cost when framed as a loss rather than when framed as a gain. It may be useful to simply present the percentages in each condition choosing A and B. For questions 2 and 3, again present the percentage of students choosing each outcome (forms I and II are the same for these questions). In general, more will choose A for question I while more will choose B for question 3. These responses are inconsistent with the exponential discounting model that are commonly used in economics. It may be useful to present the percentage that make this inconsistent set of choices. Turn-it-in Now or Whenever (Supports Chapter 13) Purpose: The purpose of this exercise is to demonstrate the tendency to procrastinate and the willingness of individuals to use commitment mechanisms to enforce good behavior. This exercise is best assigned at the beginning of the semester. Materials: None Preparation: On the first day of class, assign each student to write a paper demonstrating the importance of a behavioral economic concept in a current policy or other issue in the news. Randomly assign students to one of two conditions alphabetically based upon their first name. One half will be required to turn their paper in on a date roughly half way through the semester. The other half are allowed to choose their due date. However, this date must be before the date you intend to lecture on commitment mechanisms. All will face a 1% penalty per day the assignment is late. They must tell you the day they choose for their due date before the next lecture. Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In most cases, students who had the date imposed upon them perform better than those who choose their date. Moreover, those who choose their date usually do not choose the last possible date. In lecture it can be effective to note the distribution of dates chosen, and the average scores of both groups. Dictator Games (Supports Chapter 14) Purpose: The purpose of this game is to demonstrate the prevalence of other regarding preferences. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) A set of answer sheets found in For the Participant Preparation: Print all answer sheets. Prior to the start of class, use the class list to assign half of students to group 1 and half to group 2. Also assign each participant to two distinct pairs involving one student from group 1 and one from group 2. For the Instructor: As students enter class, distribute the answer sheets (one for each student) only to those in group 1. Inform students of which group they belong to, and ask them to sit with their first assigned pair. Read the following instructions: You have been placed in pairs in order to play a game. Please fill in the names on your answer sheet. Those in group 1 have been given $10 that they may divide with their partner who is from group 2. Those in group 1 please fill in your answer sheet indicating how much of the $10, if any, you would like to share with your partner. After all have filled in their sheets, collect the answer sheets. Instruct partners to sit with their second assigned pair and distribute answer sheets to those in group 2. Now read the following instructions: Those in group 2 have now been given $10 that they may divide with their partner who is from group 1. Those in group 2 please fill in your answer sheet indicating how much of the $10, if any, you would like to share with your partner. For the Participant: Answer Sheet Name (Group 1) _________________________ Name of partner (Group 2)_____________________________ How much of the $10 do you wish to give to your partner? $______________________ Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In lecture it can be useful to simply present the histogram of amounts given to partners. In almost all cases, students will give their partner more than $0 indicating they may regard the preferences of their partner in addition to their own. Also, you may find that many decide on an even split of the money. Take it or Leave it Game (Supports Chapter 14) Purpose: The purpose of this game is to demonstrate that individuals behave as if they are unselfish. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) A set of answer sheets found in For the Participant (enough for half the class for each round desired). Preparation: Before class, determine the names of pairs which will play each other at the game and which role they will play (player 1 or player 2). If you decide to run more than one round, you should determine a new set of pairs for each round. For the Instructor: Once students enter the class, inform them of the pairing they will be playing in and the role they will play. Instruct them to sit together as a pair. Give one answer sheet to each player 1. Instruct each pair to write their names at the top of the answer sheet, and to sign their initials next to their name. Read the following instructions: You are now asked to play a game called “Take it or Leave it.” A diagram on your answer sheet describes the rewards that will be earned depending on the actions of the players. For example, at the beginning of the game, player 1 has a choice to either ‘Take’, labeled “T”, or to ‘Leave’, labeled “L”. If player 1 takes it, then he will receive $0.40 and player 2 will receive $0.10 and the game is over. If player 1 leaves it, then it is player 2’s turn. If at that point player 2 takes it, player 2 will receive $0.80 and player 1 will receive $0.20 and the game is over. If player 2 leaves it, then it will be player 1’s turn. Ultimately if all players decide to leave it each time they get a turn, then player 1 will receive $25.60 and player 2 will receive $6.40 after each player has had three turns and the game will end. The game will always end if any player decides to take it. We will play in the following way. When it is your turn, circle your decision and sign your initials on the space next to that turn. If your choice results in the other player taking the next turn, then pass the sheet to them. When your game has ended, raise your hands and we will collect your sheet. If you wish to run multiple rounds of the game, repair students for another round after all have finished a game. For the Participant: 8 Answer Sheet Name (Player 1) ____________________ Initial ____________ This version of the TIOLI game is due to McKelvey, R.D. and T.R. Palfrey. “An Experimental Study of the Centipede Game.” Econometrica 60(1992):803-836. 8 Name (Player 2) ____________________ Initial ____________ First turn: Player 1: Take It Player 1= $0.40 Player 2 = $0.10 Leave It Player 2’s turn _______________ Player 1 Initials Second turn: Player 2: Take It Player 1= $0.20 Player 2 = $0.80 Leave It Player 1’s turn _______________ Player 2 Initials Third turn: Player 1: Take It Player 1= $1.60 Player 2 = $0.40 Leave It Player 2’s turn _______________ Player 1 Initials Fourth turn: Player 2: Take It Player 1= $0.80 Player 2 = $3.20 Leave It Player 1’s turn _______________ Player 2 Initials Fifth turn: Player 1: Take It Player 1= $6.40 Player 2 = $1.60 Leave It Player 2’s turn _______________ Player 1 Initials Leave It Player 1= $25.60 Player 2 = $6.40 _______________ Player 2 Initials Sixth turn: Player 2: Take It Player 1= $3.20 Player 2 = $12.80 Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In lecture it is generally useful first to demonstrate the Subgame Perfect Nash equilibrium strategy that results in both players taking at every opportunity. Then report number of games that ended in each turn. This demonstrates that individuals allowed the pot to grow before taking. Giving Ultimatums (Supports Chapter 15) Purpose: The purpose of this game is to demonstrate preferences for fairness. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) A set of answer sheets found in For the Participant Preparation: Print all answer sheets. Prior to the start of class, use the class list to assign half of students to group 1 and half to group 2. Also assign each participant to two distinct pairs involving one student from group 1 and one from group 2. For the Instructor: As students enter class, distribute the answer sheets (one for each student) only to those in group 1. Inform students of which group they belong to, and ask them to sit with their first assigned pair. Read the following instructions: You have been placed in pairs in order to play a game. Please fill in the names on your answer sheet and have each player sign their initials next to their names. Those in group 1 will take the first turn and must propose a way to share $10 with their partner who is from group 2. After the player from group 1 proposes a split, the player from group 2 will have the opportunity to either accept or reject the proposed split. If the split is accepted, the player in group 2 will receive the amount the first player proposed, and the first player will retain the rest of the $10. If the player in group 2 rejects the offer, neither player will receive any money. Are there any questions regarding the way this game is played? Once all questions have been answered, instruct those in group 1 to fill in their answer sheet indicating how much of the $10, if any, they propose to share with their partner, and to initial next to their proposal. Once they have proposed and initialed, instruct them to pass their answer sheet to their partner. The instruct those in group 2 to either accept or reject the offer and to initial next to their decision. After all have completed this exercise, collect all answer sheets. Instruct partners to sit with their second assigned pair and distribute answer sheets to those in group 2. Instruct students to repeat the process, only with the roles of the groups switched. For the Participant: Answer Sheet Name (Group 1) _________________________ Initial ___________ Name of partner (Group 2)_____________________________ Initial ___________ Group 1: How much of the $10 do you propose to give to your partner? $______________________ Initial ___________ Group 2: Do you: Accept Reject Initial__________ Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In lecture it can be useful to simply present the histogram of amounts proposed to share, the number of rejected offers and the amounts of the rejected offers. In many cases, the second player will reject the offer if it appears too small, even if it means giving up money. Fairness (Supports Chapter 15) Purpose: The purpose of this exercise is to demonstrate how fairness may limit firm behavior (Based on Kahneman, Knetsch and Thaler, 1986) Materials: The instructor will need: i.) A set of answer sheets found in For the Participant (half of Form I and half of Form II) Preparation: Prepare answer sheets for distribution by shuffling answer form so that students will be randomly assigned to receive either Form I or Form II. For the Instructor: Distribute the answer sheets and ask students to fill out the survey questions. For the Participant: 9 Answer Sheet (Form I) Name____________________________ Please circle your answers to each of the survey questions below. 1. A hardware store has been selling snow shovels for $15. The morning after a large snowstorm, the store raises the price to $20. Please rate this action as: Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 2. A small photocopying shop has one employee who has worked in the shop for six months and earns $12 per hour. Business continues to be satisfactory, but a factory in the area has closed and unemployment has increased. Other small shops have now hired reliable workers at $9 an hour to perform jobs similar to those done by the photocopy shop employee. The owner of the photocopying shop reduces the employee’s wage to $9. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 3. A house painter employs two assistants and pays them $12 per hour. The painter decides to quit house painting and go into the business of providing landscape services, where the going wage is lower. He reduces the workers’ wages to $9 per hour for the landscaping work. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair This exercise is reprinted with permission from Kahneman, D., J.L. Knetsch and R. Thaler. “Fairness as a Constraint on Profit Seeking: Entitlements in the Market.” American Economic Review 76(1986):728-741. 9 4. A company is making a small profit. It is located in a community experiencing a recession with substantial unemployment but no inflation. There are many workers anxious to work at the company. The company decides to decrease wages and salaries 7% this year. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 5. A shortage has developed for a popular model of automobile, and customers must now wait two months for delivery. A dealer has been selling these cars at list price. Now the dealer prices this model $200 above list price. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 6. A small company employs several people. The workers’ incomes have been about average for the community. In recent months, business for the company has not increased as it had before. The owners reduce the workers’ wages by 10% for the next year. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 7. Suppose that, due to a transportation mixup, there is a local shortage of lettuce and the wholesale price has increased. A local grocer has bought the usual quantity of lettuce at a price that is 30 cents per head higher than normal. The grocer raises the price of lettuce to customers by 30 cents per head. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 8. A landlord owns and rents out a single small house to a tenant who is living on a fixed income. A higher rent would mean the tenant would have to move. Other small rental houses are available. The landlord’s costs have increased substantially over the past year and the landlord raises the rent to cover the cost increases when the tenant’s lease is due for renewal. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 9. A small company employs several workers and has been paying them average wages. There is severe unemployment in the area and the company could easily replace its current employees with good workers at a lower wage. The company has been making money. The owners reduce the current workers’ wages by 5%. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 10. A grocery store has several months supply of peanut butter in stock which it has on the shelves and in the storeroom. The owner hears that the wholesale price of peanut butter has increased and immediately raises the price on the current stock of peanut butter. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 11. A small factory produces tables and sells all that it can make at $200 each. Because of changes in the price of materials, the cost of making each table has recently decreased by $40. The factory reduces its price for the tables by $20. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 12. A severe shortage of Red Delicious apples has developed in a community and none of the grocery stores or produce markets have any of this type of apple on their shelves. Other varieties of apples are plentiful in all of the stores. One grocer receives a single shipment of Red Delicious apples at the regular wholesale cost and raises the retail price of these Red Delicious apples by 25% over the regular price. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 13. A grocery chain has stores in many communities. Most competition from other groceries. In one community the competition. Although its costs and volume of sales are the elsewhere, the chain sets prices that average 5% higher communities. Completely Fair Acceptable of them face chain has no same there as than in other Unfair Very Unfair 14. A landlord rents out a small house. When the lease is due for renewal, the landlord learns that the tenant has taken a job very close to the house and is therefore unlikely to move. The landlord raises the rent $40 per month more than he was planning to do. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 15. A store has been sold out of a popular toy for a month. A week before Christmas a single box of the toy is discovered in a storeroom. The managers know that many customers would like to buy the toy. They announce over the store’s public address system that the toy will be sold by auction to the customer who offers to pay the most. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 16. A business in a community with high unemployment needs to hire a new computer operator. Four candidates are judged to be completely qualified for the job. The manager asks the candidates to state the lowest salary they would be willing to accept and then hires the one who demands the lowest salary. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair Answer Sheet (Form II) Name____________________________ Please circle your answers to each of the survey questions below. 1. A hardware store has been selling snow shovels for $15. The morning after a large snowstorm, the store raises the price to $20. Please rate this action as: Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 2. A small photocopying shop has one employee who has worked in the shop for six months and earns $12 per hour. Business continues to be satisfactory, but a factory in the area has closed and unemployment has increased. Other small shops have now hired reliable workers at $9 an hour to perform jobs similar to those done by the photocopy shop employee. The current employee leaves, and the owner of the photocopying shop decides to pay a replacement employee $9 an hour. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 3. A house painter employs two assistants and pays them $12 per hour. The painter decides to quit house painting and go into the business of providing landscape services, where the going wage is lower. He reduces the workers’ wages to $9 per hour for the landscaping work. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 4. A company is making a small profit. It is located in a community experiencing a recession with substantial unemployment and inflation of 12%. The company decides to increase salaries only 5% this year. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 5. A shortage has developed for a popular model of automobile, and customers must now wait two months for delivery. A dealer has been selling these cars at a discount of $200 below list price. Now the dealer sells this model only at list price. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 6. A small company employs several people. The workers’ have been receiving a 10% annual bonus each year and their total incomes have been about average for the community. In recent months, business for the company has not increased as it had before. The owners eliminate the workers’ bonus for the year. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 7. Suppose that, due to a transportation mixup, there is a local shortage of lettuce and the wholesale price has increased. A local grocer has bought the usual quantity of lettuce at a price that is 30 cents per head higher than normal. The grocer raises the price of lettuce to customers by 30 cents per head. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 8. A landlord owns and rents out a single small house to a tenant who is living on a fixed income. A higher rent would mean the tenant would have to move. Other small rental houses are available. The landlord’s costs have increased substantially over the past year and the landlord raises the rent to cover the cost increases when the tenant’s lease is due for renewal. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 9. A small company employs several workers and has been paying them average wages. There is severe unemployment in the area and the company could easily replace its current employees with good workers at a lower wage. The company has been losing money. The owners reduce the current workers’ wages by 5%. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 10. A grocery store has several months supply of peanut butter in stock which it has on the shelves and in the storeroom. The owner hears that the wholesale price of peanut butter has increased and immediately raises the price on the current stock of peanut butter. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 11. A small factory produces tables and sells all that it can make at $200 each. Because of changes in the price of materials, the cost of making each table has recently decreased by $20. The factory does not change the price for the tables. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 12. A severe shortage of Red Delicious apples has developed in a community and none of the grocery stores or produce markets have any of this type of apple on their shelves. Other varieties of apples are plentiful in all of the stores. One grocer receives a single shipment of Red Delicious apples at the regular wholesale cost and raises the retail price of these Red Delicious apples by 25% over the regular price. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 13. A grocery chain has stores in many communities. Most competition from other groceries. In one community the competition. Although its costs and volume of sales are the elsewhere, the chain sets prices that average 5% higher communities. Completely Fair Acceptable of them face chain has no same there as than in other Unfair Very Unfair 14. A landlord rents out a small house. When the lease is due for renewal, the landlord learns that the tenant has taken a job very close to the house and is therefore unlikely to move. The landlord raises the rent $40 per month more than he was planning to do. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 15. A store has been sold out of a popular toy for a month. A week before Christmas a single box of the toy is discovered in a storeroom. The managers know that many customers would like to buy the toy. They announce over the store’s public address system that the toy will be sold by auction to the customer who offers to pay the most. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair 16. A business in a community with high unemployment needs to hire a new computer operator. Four candidates are judged to be completely qualified for the job. The manager asks the candidates to state the lowest salary they would be willing to accept and then hires the one who demands the lowest salary. Completely Fair Acceptable Unfair Very Unfair Suggestions for Use in Lecture: In lecture it can be useful to select several of the questions and display the percentage selecting each option for these questions. Display and read the questions as you discuss them. For paired questions (2, 4, 5, 6, 9 and 11) it will be useful to display both questions at once and discuss their subtle difference. In each case it can be useful to demonstrate how these questions demonstrate the rules of fairness that seem to be ingrained in how we perceive the market. A Matter of Trust (Supports Chapter 16) Purpose: The purpose of this game is to demonstrate that individuals are willing to trust others. Materials: The instructor will need: i.) A set of Trustor decision sheets found in For the Participant (enough for half of the class) ii.) A set of Trustee decision sheets found in For the Participant (enough for half of the class) iii.) Enough envelopes to have at lease on for each member of the class (extras may be useful). Preparation: Mark each envelope with the name of one student. Randomly pair students’ names and record the pairs. Do not disclose these pairs to any member of the class. Assign one from each of these pairs to play the role of trustor and the rest to play the role of trustee. For the Instructor: Begin by distributing envelopes and decision sheets to each of the trustors. Read the following instructions: Half of you have been given envelopes and decision sheets. You will be paired with another member of the class in order to play a game. You will not know which member of the class you are playing with. If you have an envelope and a decision sheet, you have been endowed with $10 on your student account. You may decide to keep this money, or to send it to your anonymous partner. Whatever amount you send will be tripled before it is given to your partner. Your partner will then have the opportunity to send any amount of the money they receive back to you. There is no promise that they will send anything back. Thus, if I wrote on my decision sheet that I wanted to send $5, I would keep $5 and my partner would receive $15 (three times the $5 I sent). If they decided to return $7, I would end with $12, and they would end with $8. Alternatively, if they decided not to return anything, I would end with $5 and they would end with $15. On the other hand, if I was given an envelope and decided to send my anonymous partner nothing, they will not receive any money. Are there any questions? After responding to all questions, ask all trustors to fill in their decision sheets leaving the bottom portion blank, and place their sheets in the envelope. Collect all envelopes. Open each envelope noting the name of the trustor. Fill in the amount received (multiplied by three) for each trustee on their Trustee decision sheet, and place in the appropriate envelope. Distribute these envelopes to the trustees. Inform trustees that they may now decide how much of the money sent to them they would like to return. Ask them to fill in their decision sheet and place back in their envelope. Collect these envelopes and use the trustee decision sheets to fill in the bottom portion of the Trustor decision sheets. Distribute the Trustor decision sheets to the Trustors to inform them of the outcome of the game. Use the Trustee decision sheets to update student accounts and to code the data from this exercise. For the Participant: Trustor Decision Sheet Name_____________________________ You have been endowed with $10. You may send any portion of this $10 (or none) to your anonymous partner. The money you send will be tripled before your partner receives it. Your partner will be free to choose whether to send any amount of this money back to you. I will send $_______________ Your anonymous partner has returned $_______________ Trustee Decision Sheet Name_____________________________ Your anonymous partner was given $10 and decided to send $____________. This money has been tripled, so that you now have $_____________. You may return any portion of this (or none) to your partner. I will return $_______________ Suggestions for Use in Lecture: It is useful to simply display the average amount sent by the trustees to demonstrate the level of trust they have. It may also be useful to display the average portion returned conditioned on how much was sent (for example using a histogram).