Objectives of Competition Policy Lesson 2 Welfare Welfare of the industry (consumer surplus + producer surplus) Effects of price increases (the increase in profit may not compensate the reductions of consumer surplus) Distributional issues are overlooked (it is possible to operate redistribution schemes suche that both producers and consumers are better off) Welfare from a dynamic point of view: future welfare matters as wellEx. Fixed costs are already recovered and P =MC leads to maximise welfare BUT firms would not invest and innovations not introducedfuture welfare is reduced Consumer surplus Some standards seem to prerfer consumer surplus as the objective of competition policy. In some cases (cartels) there may not be contrast with welfare maximisation but in general we cannot exclude differences Consumers are dispersed and cannot lobby as firms (no “countervailing power”) a reason to give more weight to consumer surplus BUT it may not be wise to adopt consumer surplus as an objective for many reasons: 1.It neglects firms gains and at present consumers own firms through pension and investments funds receive dividends and capital gains Literally maximising consumer surplus implies P=MC needs to subsidize fixed cost regulation replace the market Defence of smaller firms Antitrust policies were born to defend farmers and small firms hurted by large trusts The defence of Small firms is not against welfare maximisation if it is limited to protect them from the abuse of large firms to balance financial and economic power On the contrary helping small firms to survivie when they are not operating at efficient scale encourages inefficient allocation of resources and keep high prices The EU states tha SME are more dynamic but the empirical evidence is not conclusive It may be wise that competition agencies. Neglect agreements and mergers among SME but systematically helping them is not a rational choice SME are hurt by lack of infrastructure and imperfect markets but these are matter for other public policies. Promoting market integration (EU) A political objective not necessarily consistent with welfare maximisation EU forbids price discrimination across markets but such an argument has no economic rationale Price discrimination in the car market (Italy and BELGIUM) Pi > PB to avoid discrimination: PB < P < Pi- Italians are better-off, Belgian are worse-off and what about the profit? a priori the welfare effect is ambigous Economic freedoom In specific cases there may be contrast between economic freedoom and efficiency Most obvious case: vertical restraints resaleprice maintenance and territorial restraints may be effcient as they stimulate the effort of retailers or avoid setting prices above what is optimal for the manufacturerbut they are against economic freedoom Fairness and equity Small shopkeepers V. large supermarket chains Supermarkets enjoy buyer power and sell at lower prices than small shops forced to close-down Some argue this result is unfair and small shops be protected contrary to efficiency principlesif small shops do not reach the minimum efficient scale should accept lower profits or exit the market Fairness and efficiency not always are in contradiction: if a chain store has large market share and charges prices below cost (predatory pricing) to force small firms out of the market this is bot unfair and reduces welfare once competitors are eliminated the chain store start charging monopoly prices Strategic reasons: Industrial and trade Policies C.P. may be strategically used to support National Champions or to break-up foreign champions Lax competition policies in some Countries hide the aim of allowing national firms go bigger to be successfull in international competition Strategic trade policy may be hided behind competition laws and their implementation Ex. US laws give exemptions to export-cartels: 1. if the only purpose is to engage in export trade 2. do not restrain trade in the US 3.do not restrain the trade of export competitors CP can be used to achieve protectionist goals: anti-dumping laws in principle avoid foreign firms to sell below cost (often they protect domestic firms from efficient foreign competitors) Industrial & trade policy: obstacle to CPSubsidies & State aid Main features of EU Competition law Art. 81 e Art.82 Treaty of the European Community Direct applicability: they are part of the law of member Countries are enforeceable by National Courts Art.are enforced by the EC through the DG Comp. At the national level by National Comp. Authorities. Jurisdiction against actions of the EC: Community level Court of first instance & Court of Justice (appeal) At the national level Courts decide according to the national systems against decisions of National Competition Authorities Art.81 It deals both with horizontal & vertical agremments but from the economic point of view effects could be quite different Horizontal agreements (with competitors) reduce competition and welfare should be prohibited except some cases (cooperative R&D agreements) Vertical agreements (manufacturer & retailer) may enhance effciency and cause problems only when are undertaken by firms enjoying market power Agreements need not be formal or written (concerted practice is the word used…and leave space for interpretation..) Some sectors: agriculture, defence, transport..enjoy block exemptions Art.82 The list of abuses cannot be exhaustive More generally art.82 considers exploitative behaviour (excessive prices) and exclusionary practices: predatory pricing,exclusive dealing, refusal to supply Firstly it should be shown that a dominant position exists THEN that the dominant firm has carried out an abusive behaviour Dominance relates to a case where a firm enjoys a very high degree of market power but the jurisprudence made it clear that even a firm with a market share of 40% may be a dominant one European law does not punish the creation of a dominant position, but just its abuse one does not want to punish firms that have been more successfulincentives might be reduced in this case