Regional Integration EU An investigating analysis of EU enlargement policy Name CPR Douglas von Euler Angelica Norhagen Sofie Oestergaard Boa Nikolaj Lildal Jasper Siegfried CPR051090-3471 CPR111290-5045 CPR CPR190890-1513 CPR311089-3085 1 Table of Contents 1.0 Introduction................................................................................................................................... 3 2.1 The Eastern Enlargement ..................................................................................................................... 3 2.2 Croatia and the EU................................................................................................................................. 3 3.0 Liberal Intergovernmentalism (LI) ......................................................................................... 4 3.1 Definition .................................................................................................................................................. 4 3.2 Liberal Intergovernmentalism and CEEC ....................................................................................... 4 3.3 LI and Croatian integration ................................................................................................................. 6 3.4 LI Critique................................................................................................................................................ 7 4.0 Social Constructivism (SC) ........................................................................................................ 8 4.1 Definition .................................................................................................................................................. 8 4.2 Social Constructivism CEEC and Croatia (SC) .............................................................................. 8 5.0 Conclusion...................................................................................................................................... 9 2 1.0 Introduction Parallel with the European Community’s rapid development and enlargement during the past decades scholars’ interest to explain Europe’s integration has increased dramatically. In 1993 Andrew Moravcsik presented the rational theory Liberal Intergovernmentalism (LI). The theory received major attention by scholars around the world. The most recent enlargement to the CEEC´s in 2004/2007 and the current accession of Croatia has however fueled the debate about how to accurately explain the enlargements. The core research question of this paper is: Is European Integration explainable through only Liberal Intergovernmentalism and is integration dominated by economic interest? In order to answer the question, we will examine the two enlargements from a LI perspective and herewith investigate existing economic and business benefits. We will also examine LI’s counter theory SC in order to verify our hypothesis that LI is not sufficient enough to explain the recent integration by itself; it is necessary to study integration from a social constructive approach as well. This paper is structured in three parts. The first section will place the Eastern Enlargement (EE) and the current accession process with Croatia in a historical context. The second section examines the two cases from a Liberal Intergovernmental approach. The theory will be defined, applied to the two cases and further what business opportunities the enlargements open will be presented. The third section highlights the critique raised against the liberal intergovernmental approach and then examines the two cases from a social constructive approach. The last section will conclude our findings. 2.0 Historical Context 2.1 The Eastern Enlargement The fall of the iron curtain in 1989 increased the number of states in Europe dramatically, resulting in that The European Council decided at the Copenhagen summit in 1993 to enlarge the European Union eastwards. At the same summit the EU member states (MS) agreed that the Copenhagen criteria should lay the ground for future enlargements. In 1995 and 1996 the first Eastern European states applied for EU membership. After negotiation and national amendments the first eight states became members in 2004. This was hitherto the largest enlargement in terms of number of countries, population and landmass. Romania and Bulgaria followed in 2007. To become members the new MS had to accept the Copenhagen criteria and agree to some restrictions regarding working rights lasting up to seven years.1 2.2 Croatia and the EU After Croatia’s independence and international recognition in 1992, the interactions between Croatia and the EU gradually increased. In 2001, Croatia signed the first formal agreement with the EU; the Stabilization and Accession Agreement. In this time period the EU gradually increased trade privileges. In March 2003 Croatia applied for EU membership 1 I. Bach, S. George and S. Bumler 2011 3 and in June Croatia was granted candidate status by the European Council. 2 Almost one year later, the Commission recommended opening negotiations with Croatia and the date for accession negotiation was set to March 2005, on the condition of evidence of full cooperation with the International Criminal Tribunal for former Yugoslavia (ICTY).3 The negotiation was eventually postponed due to lack of evidence showing Croatia’s full cooperation in finding former general Ante Gotovina; responsible for war crimes committed in relation to Croatia retaking control of the ‘Krajina’ region in 1995. In October 2005, ICTY declared the cooperation between Croatia and ICTY acceptable and the negotiation process began 4. The negotiations of membership and the required amendments are still in progress.5 3.0 Liberal Intergovernmentalism (LI) 3.1 Definition Liberal intergovernmentalism started as a critique of the preceding theory of EU integration, neo-functionalism. Scholar Andrew Moravcsik, founder of LI, divided the theory into a three-step process. The first step is the domestic preference formation, which states that the interest of national governments is formed by domestic political and social pressure but mainly motivated by economic benefits. The second step is interstate bargaining, which argues that the outcome of negotiations within the EU will always reflect the relative MS bargaining power. Finally, Moravcsik stresses the state’s role in an enlargement and claims that it has full control over the integration process. Integration is a sum of rational choices made by intergovernmental decisions rather than supranational negotiations. Hence supranational institutions are not sovereign and major decisions within the EU will always reflect the interests of all national governments. 6 3.2 Liberal Intergovernmentalism and CEEC According to the Domestic Preference Formation, the EE can be interpreted as the outcome of the domestic pressure in the concerned states and their rational cost-benefit calculations of economic consequences. After the fall of communist rule, the domestic interest to democratize and adapt the western European and American values created domestic pressure for integration. There was a natural interest among the CEECs to become independent from Russia.7 Furthermore, the economic aspects of the enlargement gave the CEECs integration in the EU market – access to the internal market, providing new many new business opportunities for both export and import and also creating incentives for FDI. The relevance of new business opportunities in the enlargement can also be seen among the existing MS. During the negotiation process of the EE the MS were divided up into two groups; the drivers that promoted an EE, and the brakemen who were reluctant to the expansion. The geographical position of the MS reflected the drivers, consisting of the countries bordering the CEEC, plus Britain. An EE would benefit the bordering countries 2 I. Bach, S. George and S. Bumler 2011 European Commision 2005 4 European Commosion 2005 5 Nives Miosˇic´-Lisjak 2006 6 Schimmelfennig and Moravcsik 2004 7 Sadurski 2004 3 4 through increased cross-border trade and capital movements. It was now easier for businesses to expand to the east and increase the global trade. Britain had neither short-term economic nor geographical benefits from an EE but feared the return of communism. The bordering countries were Austria, Germany and Finland, all three with high shares in exports to the applying countries. Even though some MS benefited from the EE with regards to trade, the enlargement had many implications for other MS. First, the EE was particularly costly for the less developed MS in the short run as the eastern countries were specialized in the same resource intensive industries as textile and agriculture.8 The EE meant increased competition for these countries. Furthermore, the EE was costly for the EU in the short run, as their transfers to the CEEC countries by far outweighed their contribution to the Community budget. The expected consequences on distribution of CAP, constituting 80 % of the Community budget, lead to a reform in structural policies. This reform resulted in a reduction of EU transfers and financial support to farmers mainly affecting Spain, Greece, Portugal and Ireland, all core brakemen to the enlargement and main receivers of agricultural support.9 Presumably, the future benefits from the enlargement were taken into account. Even though the eastern countries contributed relatively little to the overall EU budget when entering, the EU saw future economic potential and business opportunities in the developing postcommunist economies.10 Further, one of the main interests of the MS was also to quickly help the former USSR countries to get both politically and economically independent from Russia, to make sure further conflicts in the region wouldn’t occur. This would in turn create a more stable Europe11. The second step of LI is Interstate Bargaining, where Moravcsik suggests that the outcome of negotiation is the result of states bargaining power. When the existing MS required the applicants to fulfill the Copenhagen criteria12 and comply with several unfavorable terms they had disadvantages in negotiations, since they contributed little economically. Membership in the EU meant institutional and structural changes outlined by the Copenhagen criteria for the applicants. The EU could dictate the terms of the enlargement because the candidates had more interest in joining than the Union had in enlarging. The economic benefits of the enlargement were much higher for the CEECs then for the EU, which gave them a less beneficial position in their negotiation and conclusively lead to them accepting the criteria from the EU relatively quickly. The third step of Moravcsik’s theory is Supranational Institutions were he argues that the preferences of the national governments determine further enlargement – not the ones of supranational organizations. In the case of the EE the delegation of power from the nation to a supranational organization (EU) is illustrated by the Copenhagen criteria and the power of supranational institutions e.g. the Commission; working for the benefits of EU and not the individual MS. LI explains the delegation of decision-making to the EU as a wish of the governments to guarantee that all parties involved follows the agreements made. 13 8 Schimmelfennig and Sedelmeier 2005 EUROPA - Web Page 10 Baldwin 1995 11 Baldwin 1995 12 I. Bach, S. George and S. Bumler 2011 13 I. Bach, S. George and S. Bumler 2011 9 5 3.3 LI and Croatian integration Due to Moravcsik’s LI approach economic interests dominate domestic preference formation. One of the main economic reasons of the previous EE was to aid the former USSR countries in their economic development in order to create a strong independence from Russia.14 Even though Russia might not be a large threat in terms of Croatia, the interest in aiding the economic growth and creating business opportunities in Croatia is compelling. A stable Balkan region creates a more stable Europe and a more attractive place for foreign and European companies to invest in. This opens up new business opportunities for the region, which lead to further economic growth15. The increased political and economic stability resulting in economic growth after becoming members can be seen in the countries of the EE. Like the EE, Croatia’s integration is in particular interesting for the countries with close trade relations with the Balkan region; they will benefit economically from the membership and hoping to enhance the integration of the Balkan region.16 As suggested by the LI approach, countries with greater economic benefits will have a larger interest in initiating an enlargement than countries without. After Croatia’s recognition in 1992, the EU invested large sums in order to speed up the reconstruction and stabilization process in the region. The EU is interested in Croatia obtaining full membership and uses them as a “filter” for illegal immigrants, human trafficking, narcotics etc. from the Balkan region, which currently is a critical issue. This also leads to a more stable region and subsequently faster economic growth. The opportunity loss of not being a part of the EU and the internal market could have severe economic consequences17. The second step of LI, Interstate Bargaining, states that all countries can make their own cost-benefit analysis and they all have the right to make their own decisions in the negotiations. However, scholars have raised concerns if this actually is the case for Croatia, as they have to follow the conditions of the Copenhagen criteria in their integration. LI explains this by Croatia’s lack of leverage in the negotiation. Croatia is not able to add much to EU’s cost-benefit analysis. The macro economic benefits of Croatian membership are small to the EU as a whole, in contrast to many of the early EU enlargements where the applicants had a more influential position in their negotiations than Croatia.18 The third step of LI, Supranational Institutions, further argues that all individual states have full control over the course of European integration and that international institutions have a minor part in international bargaining. In the Croatian case, as in the EE, the nations´ delegate power to the international institutions to ensure that the states follow agreements. 14 Baldwin 1995 Ashbrook 2010 Nives Miosˇic´-Lisjak 2006 17 Nives Miosˇic´-Lisjak 2006 18 Nives Miosˇic´-Lisjak 2006 15 16 6 3.4 LI Critique The LI approach explains various parts of the integration, in particular for the countries directly affected by a more developed region, but the theory has received a lot of critique from several scholars who believe that there are several flaws to the theory. They instead argue that a SC approach is more accurate. There are economic benefits to the enlargement but many are hard to predict and become relatively speculative in the long run, as they are determined by how the region stabilizes and how investors respond to the development. The cost-benefit analysis is therefore highly uncertain for the MS. The critique suggests that integration is not purely based on an economic cost benefit analysis. Nives Miosˇic´-Lisjak argues that the idea of countries having full control over the course European integration was something that could have been applied for the first MS in the beginning of the European community, but not to the same degree in the case of the EE or Croatia in the current EU.19 Thomas Risse explained it through his metaphor: “The EU looks more like an exclusive club dictating the terms of accession to new members”.20 This critique has been demonstrated through the avis Croatia received when applying for membership. Germany and France were in favor of an immediate start to negotiations with Croatia while Britain and the Netherlands were concerned about Croatia’s participation in aiding ICTY, and therefore argued for a delay in negotiations. The same was seen in the EE, when the existing MS, leaving little control of the negotiation left for the eastern countries, set the terms of membership. Also the requirements and demands of the Copenhagen Criteria set by the MS and negotiated by the EU as one united actor leaves little or no room for Croatia to influence their integration. This means that neither the individual MSs nor Croatia and the eastern countries are in full control of the integration, arguably undermining the LI approach suggesting that all countries have control over the course of the integration. LI further argues that state’s actions are based on domestic social and political pressure. Croatia’s lack of influence in the integration process has lead to an increasing euroscepticism within its population. This demonstrates why Croatia acts, to some extent, in other interests than its own. As mentioned earlier Croatia’s accession negotiation depended on their cooperation with ICTY in capturing Ante Gotovina. John E. Ashbroke provides evidence that indicates that Croatia’s participation in finding Gotovina was not at all appreciated or condoned by the domestic public opinion. Gotovina is to a large extent seen as a national hero in Croatia, both among the population and by many prominent politicians.21 This clash of interests, with the Croatian government wanting to meet the conditions of the EU on one hand and the national hero status of Gotovina on the other has lead to an increasing euroscepticism among the population. Despite this, Croatia still participated to the best of their abilities in their work with ICTY. It was seen as necessary in order to begin negotiations. Nives Miosˇic´-Lisjak 2006 Thomas Risse 2009 21 Nives Miosˇic´-Lisjak 2006 19 20 7 4.0 Social Constructivism (SC) 4.1 Definition Social Constructivism emerged in the late 1990´s as a critique to the overall rationalist approach; instead of a materialistic focus it emphasizes the role of cultures, norms and values, and how these shape their respective social environments. SC suggests that shared rules and values connect the members of a group; hence the common identity of EU is the main reason for the EU’s further enlargement. Political actors of the European integration internalize social norms that further shape the European identity and thus the Union’s interests. In consequence, the “European identity” is not seen as static; it changes over time, as norms and values (stemming from new actors) also change. 4.2 Social Constructivism CEEC and Croatia (SC) Scholar Frank Schimmelfennig argues that the LI cannot by itself explain the EU’s decision to enlarge to the east22. Instead he argues that it was the EU’s collective identity, together with the sense of social responsibility towards the east that resulted in the EE. There were certain norms and values deeply embedded in the EU identity that played a significant role in the EU’s policy towards the EE. Most common was the importance of the liberal democratic structure in both the economic and political markets. J. Richardson further argues that the EU enlarges to include states that share their values of liberal democratic norms inside the geographical area of Europe.23 The EU felt a responsibility to maintain the commitment made in the Maastricht Treaty stating that any European state with the same values and norms and built upon a democratic structure are welcome to apply for membership.24 The fall of communism in 1989 resulted in a massive political change in the former communist countries. As a result of independency, the eastern governments expressed a desire to “return to Europe”25 – rejecting the ideas of communism, and instead identifying themselves with the norms and values dominating the EU. The Copenhagen criteria (1993) were laid down as guidelines for the eastern European applicants to reform the eastern block and “fit in” to the common identity of the EU. Once fulfilling the criteria, the countries were welcome to become members. SC is reflected by the Copenhagen criteria, stating that the EU integration is deeply dependent on the collective European identity and how well applicant states share the common values within the EU. As discussed earlier, not all MS encouraged the EE at the initial negotiations. SC explains the different approaches that existed by saying that all members of the EU share certain values, whilst others are not commonly held; some values have become more of a characteristic of the group collectively. The EE can be seen as a result of the EU’s self-image as a stabilizer26. In the previous enlargements of Greece, Portugal and Spain, the EU took on a role as a supporter and consolidator in democratic and liberal economic reforms. In the long run it was the responsibility towards the CEECs that made the group of brakemen (France, Greece, Spain etc.) support the enlargement. 22 Schimmelfennig 2005 Richardson 2006 Nives Miosˇic´-Lisjak 2006, Treaty of the European Union Artikel 6 & 49 25 Richardson 2006 26 I. Bach, S. George and S. Bumler, 2011 23 24 8 Applying the SC theory on the possible enlargement of Croatia, there are many similarities. As mentioned above economic benefits for the EU are nearly non-existent in the short run. Instead the EU is seeking to enlarge because Croatia, as also the rest of the Balkan states, is both geographically and culturally part of Europe. The EE even enhanced this already existing feeling of isolation. Mesic´, the President of Croatia, said: Croatia is a country whose history reaches far back into the past of Europe, a country that has always been and has never stopped being a part of the European countryside . . . We do not want to live isolated. We have given our contribution to Europe innumerable times in the past. We want and are capable to do the same in the future as well. . . . We expect Europe to recognize us and accept us as its inseparable part. (Mesic´, 2003) 5.0 Conclusion EU integration in the earliest enlargements was mainly motivated by economic benefits. In the early enlargements the applying states, as in the first enlargement towards Britain, Ireland and Denmark27, also contributed to the cost-benefit of EU, giving applicants bargaining power in negotiations and hence able to affect the direction of negotiations. In the case of the EE and current accession of Croatia, the enlargements has created (will potentially create) many business opportunities and economical benefits especially for the regions but as well for the EU as a whole. A more stable Eastern Europe and Balkan region means a more stable Europe, which in turn leads to faster economic growth. Their accession to the internal market opens up the possibility for imports and exports from foreign international corporations. Although economic benefits and business opportunities are numerous for both EU and the candidate states, it is still impossible to overlook the shift towards SC. The Copenhagen Criteria is a strong example as it includes many criteria about norms and values. The period following the fall of communism saw an increased focus on shared norms and values and the creation of a common European identity. Hence integration needs to be viewed from a social constructive approach as well. Therefore our main hypothesis that LI and economic factors can’t efficiently explain enlargements is verified and that existing EU enlargement policy must be explained by a combination of Moravcik’s LI and the critical perspective of social constructivism, emphasizing the role of common values and norms. 27 I. Bach, S. George and S. Bumler, 2011 9 References: Ashbrook, John E.: Croatia, Euroskepticism, and the Identity Politics of EU Enlargement, Problems of Post-Communism, vol. 57, no. 3, M.E. Sharpe, May/June 2010, pages 23–39 I. Bach, S. George and S. Bumler: Enlargement, I. Bach, S. George and S. Bumler, Politics in the European Union, 3rd Edition, Oxford University Press, New York 2011 pages 529-551 Baldwin, Richard E.: The Eastern Enlargement of the European Union, European Economic Review 39 (1995), p. 474-481 EUROPA, Agriculture and Rural Development budget expenditures, Web Page, http://ec.europa.eu/agriculture/fin/budget/index_en.htm, accessed 05.06.2011 European Commission: Croatia 2005 Progress Report, Brussels 2005 Miosˇic´-Lisjak: Croatia and the European Union, Policy Studies, Vol. 27, No 2, 2006, Policy Studies Institute, Routledge 2006 Richardson, J.: “European Union - power and policy making”, Routledge, London 2006 Risse, T.: “Social Constructivism And European Integration”, (London: Sage 2007), in A. Wiener and T. Diez, European Integration theory, 2nd Edition, Oxford University Press, Oxford 2009 Sadurski: Accession’s Democracy Dividend: The Impact of the EU enlargement upon Democracy in the New Member States of Central and Eastern Europe, European Law Journal, Vol. 4, July 2004, page 399: Blackwell, Malden 2004 Schimmelfennig, Frank and Moravcsik, Andrew: Liberal Intergovernmentalism. In: Antje Wiener und Thomas Diez: European Integration Theory, University Press, Oxford 2004 Schimmelfennig and Sedelmeier: The politics of European Union enlargement: theoretical approaches, [electronic resource] Routledge, London 2005 10