Macroeconomics Chamberlin and Yueh Chapter 8 Lecture slides Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply • The aggregate demand schedule • The aggregate supply schedule – Long run aggregate supply – Short run aggregate supply • Equilibrium in the AD-AS Model • Comparative statics in the AD-AS model – Aggregate demand shocks – Aggregate supply shocks • Hysteresis and the Medium Run Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Learning Objectives • Understand the relation between prices and aggregate demand • To determine the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) and the long run aggregate supply for an economy • To identify the factors that lead to shifts in the long run aggregate supply curve • To acknowledge that in the short run output can deviate from its long run equilibrium level by moving along a short run aggregate supply curve. • Understanding the difference between adaptive and rational expectations formation. • Construct the AD-AS model and use it in comparative statics exercises. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning AD-AS Model • The Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply (AD-AS) model simultaneously determines output and prices. • This model simply aggregates across all goods and services, in which case, we are determining the average price level and the total level of output in the economy. The model is useful to policy makers who have in recent decades become increasingly concerned with how prices are determined, as well as output. • The AD-AS model shares many common features with the IS-LM model, particularly the Neoclassical version, but is more rigorous. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The aggregate demand schedule • The AD schedule plots the relationship between the price level and aggregate demand. Its construction comes directly from the IS-LM model – all we have to do is think about what happens to planned expenditures when prices fall. • When the IS-LM model is in equilibrium, planned expenditures are equal to actual output, so all we need to do is identify the effect of falling prices on the equilibrium level of output. • The combinations of prices and output can be plotted to form the downward sloping Aggregate Demand (AD) schedule. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The aggregate demand schedule Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The AD curve • The AD curve just tells us what the level of aggregate demand or planned expenditures is at each price level. • Changes in the price level will relate to movements along the curve. • However, if aggregate demand were to change due to a factor other than prices, the AD curve would shift. Shifts in the AD curve result from anything that shifts the IS or LM curve, other than a change in the price level. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Shifts in the AD curve Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The aggregate supply schedule • The Aggregate Supply (AS) schedule plots the relationship between the output of an economy and the price level. In essence, it sums all the output decisions by productive agents in the domestic economy. • An important distinction, though, exists between aggregate supply in the short and the long run. Output in the short run can deviate from its long run level if markets are in disequilibrium for a period of time because wages and prices adjust slowly towards equilibrium values. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Long run aggregate supply • In the long run, the supply decisions of firms are independent of prices. Prices are considered to be a nominal factor, whereas production decisions will be based on real concerns. We will see that these might include productivity, labour force participation, product market conditions, or factors determining the bargaining power of labour. • Long run aggregate supply is fixed at the long run equilibrium level of output, which in turn corresponds to the level of output consistent with equilibrium in the labour market. This level of output is often referred to as the natural level of output. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Long run aggregate supply • Establishing the equilibrium level of output therefore requires us to investigate the equilibrium in the labour market. • More specifically, we will be concerned with the equilibrium rate of unemployment, which is often referred to as the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment or the NAIRU. At this rate, there is no pressure on wages to change. And, as prices are simply a mark up on wage costs, it must also be the case that there is no pressure on prices to change either. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The equilibrium rate of unemployment or NAIRU • This refers to the rate of unemployment where the labour market is in equilibrium. • This equilibrium is considered to be the outcome of bargaining between labour (sometimes organised bodies, such as trade unions) and firms. • Bargaining works by assuming that workers are concerned with setting wages and firms with setting prices. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The wage setting curve • This schedule determines the nominal wage (W) desired by labour, and can be written as: W Z u e P • There are three factors which determine the wage (W) that workers will push for: – Pe are expectations of the price level. If workers anticipate higher prices, then the purchasing power of their wages will be reduced. Therefore, they would push for higher nominal wages so as to maintain the value of their real wages (purchasing power of wages). Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The wage setting curve – u is the unemployment rate and exerts a negative force on wage demands. The reserve army of the unemployed are taken to be the surplus labour that is available to employers. The larger this pool becomes, the more moderate wage demands will be. Workers know that if they push for too higher wages they may be substituted for cheaper unemployed labour. Also, when unemployment is high, workers anticipate that finding new employment when unemployed will be much trickier. This forms a powerful incentive to avoid becoming unemployed in the first place by moderating wage demands. The converse is also true. At low levels of unemployment, workers would be more confident in pushing for higher wages. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The wage setting curve – Z is really a catch all variable which consists of a number of items that may influence wage demands. • The first are those factors which influence the bargaining power of workers. Trade unions bargaining collectively or employment laws giving rights to workers would be examples. • The second consists of items which raise the opportunity cost of working. For example, if unemployment benefits were relatively generous, then the costs of unemployment would be correspondingly lower which would lead to more ambitious wage demands. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The wage setting curve • For simplicity, it is assumed that workers form correct expectations concerning the price level, then Pe=P. The wage setting relationship can be expressed in terms of the real wage: W w Z u P • The bargained real wage falls as unemployment rises. Changes in Z would lead to shifts in the entire function, meaning that at each level of unemployment workers would target a different real wage. • The wage setting relationship is also known as the bargained real wage (BRW), as it is the real wage that unions demand in their bargaining with employers (firms). Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The wage setting curve Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Price-setting relationship • Firms are simply assumed to set prices as a mark up on wage costs. Although in the real world, firms will face other costs such as rents and interest payments on capital, these can be ignored in this simple model: W P 1 LP • where μ is the mark up and LP is labour productivity. • Costs are given by the ratio of wages (W) to labour productivity (LP). Firm costs will rise if either wages rise, or labour productivity falls. If both move in the same proportion, then costs will remain unchanged. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Price-setting relationship • The mark up μ is largely determined by product market conditions, which primarily refer to the degree of competition in the market. • Where markets are relatively competitive, the mark up would be expected to be low, and under perfectly competitive conditions it would be expected to be zero (which means that firms set prices equal to marginal costs and only make normal profits). When firms can exert significant market power, the mark up would of course rise and firms would take more of a profit margin on their sales. One factor which might be crucial in determining the size of the mark up could be the level of competition policy in existence and how strongly it is enforced. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Price-setting relationship • The price-setting relationship above can be rearranged so it is also expressed in terms of the real wage: W LP w P 1 • The price setting function has been drawn as a horizontal line indicating that price-setting is independent of the level of unemployment. This makes the model easier to use, but is in itself is a debatable proposition. Some discussion justifying this assumption is presented in Global Applications 8.1. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Price-setting relationship Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Price-setting relationship • The price setting relationship is also known as the feasible real wage (FRW), as it states the real wage that firms can afford to pay workers given the productivity of labour and product market conditions. If there is movement in either of these two fields, then the feasible real wage will change and the price-setting schedule will shift. • An increase in labour productivity would increase the feasible real wage and hence the price-setting schedule will shift upwards. • An increase in the mark up would lower the price-setting schedule. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Equilibrium • The equilibrium rate of unemployment or the NAIRUû is where the price-setting and wagesetting curves intersect. This is simply where the bargained and feasible real wages are consistent with one another. • The dynamics of this model will always move toward the equilibrium level of unemployment. Any level of unemployment away from this would induce changes in either or both wages and prices, so that the real wage and unemployment are restored to their equilibrium values. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Equilibrium Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning From the equilibrium rate of unemployment to equilibrium level of output: Deriving the long run aggregate supply curve (LRAS) • The relationship between output and employment (N) is given by a production function: Y=F(N). • This simply defines the aggregate level of output for each level of employment, but can also be written in terms of the unemployment rate. The total labour force (L) consists of employed (N) and unemployed workers (U): L=N+U. • The unemployment rate is the proportion of the labour force that is unemployed: u=U/L. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Deriving the LRAS • Therefore, the proportion of the labour force that is employed and unemployed should just add up to one: 1=N/L+U/L, 1=N/L+u. • This can be rearranged to give employment as a function of the unemployment rate: N/L=1-u, N=L(1-u). • The level of employment is equal to the proportion of the labour force (L) that is not unemployed. If the unemployment rate is u, then this proportion will be equal to 1-u. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Deriving the LRAS • Finally, to find the equilibrium level of output, all we need to do is substitute this relationship between employment and unemployment back into the production function: Yˆ F L1 uˆ • Shifts in the long run aggregate supply schedule will result from anything that acts to alter the equilibrium level of output. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Deriving the LRAS Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning LRAS and NAIRU • This should make it clear why the equilibrium level of unemployment is referred to as the NAIRU. • It is the rate of unemployment where there is no pressure on prices to change. • The equilibrium level of output, which then defines the position of the long run aggregate supply curve, is just the level of output at the NAIRU. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning LRAS Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Shifts in LRAS Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Shifts in LRAS • These shifts in long run AS can come from four sources: • Labour productivity, LP: As labour productivity improves, the equilibrium rate of unemployment falls and equilibrium employment and output both rise. As a result, the long run AS schedule will shift to the right. As a consequence of higher productivity, the price setting schedule shifts upwards. The equilibrium rate of unemployment falls, the equilibrium level of output rises, and the long run aggregate supply curve shifts to the right. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Increase in labour productivity Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Shifts in LRAS • μ: An increase in the mark up increases the natural rate of unemployment and leads to a leftward shift in the aggregate supply schedule. An increase in the mark up would produce a downward shift in the price-setting curve and ultimately a shift in the long run aggregate supply curve. When firms increase their margins, they are increasing the average price level in the economy. At higher prices, aggregate demand will be lower, and therefore lower output and employment is sustainable. (See above figure). • Z: If the wage setting schedule shifts upwards because unemployment benefits have risen, trade unions have greater power, etc., the natural rate of unemployment rises and the long run AS schedule will shift to the left. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Increase in trade union power Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Shifts in LRAS • L: As the labour force increases, there are more available labour resources with which to produce output so the long run AS schedule shifts to the right. When the labour force increases, it implies that at every rate of unemployment below 100%, the level of employment will be higher. This is why the function which relates the level of employment to the rate of unemployment will shift upwards with an increase in the labour supply. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Increase in labour force Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Supply side policies • Shifting the long run aggregate supply function to the right is an important goal in policy making, as the equilibrium level of output increases. From this analysis, it is clear that there are a range of policies that the government may undertake to achieve this. – – – – Policies to improve productivity (higher LP). Policies to improve labour market flexibility/competition (lower Z). Policies to induce higher labour market participation (higher L). Policies to improve product market competition (lower mark up). • Taken collectively, attempts to shift the long run aggregate supply curve are known as supply side policies. • Global Applications 2.2 Mrs. Thatcher’s supply side revolution Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Short run aggregate supply • In the long run, the willingness of firms to produce does not depend on the price level, and therefore the aggregate supply function is vertical. • Aggregate supply in the short run, though, is different. In this case, it is argued that the schedule is upward-sloping, so supply rises with prices. This is how we would expect a conventional supply curve to look. • To accept an aggregate supply function which slopes upwards with prices means that we must justify why output can or might deviate from its equilibrium level. Also, as output is always expected to eventually return to its equilibrium level, we have to reason why these deviations are only temporary. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Short run aggregate supply • There are two reasons for the slope of the SRAS: • If wages and prices move slowly, then output will be away from the equilibrium level for some time. Accounting for wage and price rigidities is important. • Also important is the role that is played by expectations. When deriving the long run equilibrium level of output, we assumed that price expectations were made correctly. In the short run, though, actual prices can deviate from expected prices. This too accounts for why aggregate supply may differ in the short and long run. We will also observe that the way expectations are formed will play a critical role in the dynamics that link the short and long run. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Short run aggregate supply • One of the key features of the short run aggregate supply function is that output and prices are positively related. As output increases, then prices will also rise. • To understand what factors might be responsible for this relationship, we need to consider how prices are actually determined – a process which we have already argued is summarised by the price-setting behaviour of firms. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Short run aggregate supply • From the price-setting relationship, prices are a mark up on wage costs: • The level of wages is derived from the wage setting relationship: • If we substitute the wage setting equation into the price setting equation, we have an equation of prices determination in the economy: W P 1 LP W Pe Z u P e Z u P 1 LP Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Short run aggregate supply • The price-setting equation consists of a number of variables. These factors can in turn be split into long run and short run determinants of the price level. • We have already seen that changes in labour productivity, labour supply factors, and the mark up will lead to shifts in the long run aggregate supply curve. For this reason, we can ignore these as determining prices in the short run because any change in these variables will lead to a change in the equilibrium level of output. • The two remaining variables are the level of unemployment (which is strongly linked to output) and the level of price expectations. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Unemployment/Output • From the above price-setting equation, we can see that prices are negatively related to unemployment. • For unemployment to rise back to the equilibrium level, two things must happen. Firstly, there needs to be an increase in the nominal wage – by making labour more expensive, labour will start to price itself out of jobs. • The second movement requires an increase in prices. If wages are rising, then firms should see their costs rising and wish to raise prices. At higher prices, aggregate demand will be lower and therefore higher unemployment is sustainable. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Unemployment/Output • It should not require much convincing to accept that unemployment and output are inversely related, so a rise in output must be associated with a fall in unemployment. • This inverse relationship is known as Okun’s Law. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Relationship: Y u W P Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Unemployment/Output • This mechanism explains why prices will rise with output, but it doesn’t explain why output may deviate from its equilibrium level. • Up to now, we have assumed that markets clear quite quickly, so movements in wages and prices will quickly restore equilibrium values of output and unemployment. • This would account for a vertical aggregate supply curve. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Market clearing: A vs. B Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Will markets clear? • The conventional wisdom is that in the long run markets will clear (so the long run aggregate supply is vertical), but in the short run, wages and prices will only adjust gradually (so in the short run we can justify a position off the long run aggregate supply curve). • In the short run, an increase in output above the equilibrium level would only be partially corrected by movements in wages and prices. Therefore, prices will be expected to increase to say an intermediate level. Because prices partially adjust, output will remain above the equilibrium level, but would be lower than where there was no movement in prices. Therefore, output too will stay at an intermediate level. This output-price combination would then be expected to lie on a short run aggregate supply curve (SRAS). Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning SRAS Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning SRAS • There are two remaining unanswered questions. • The first is why markets do not immediately clear to correct any disequilibrium position in output or unemployment? The short run aggregate supply curve therefore requires us to rationalise rigidities in wages and prices. • The second remaining question relates to expectations. A position on the short run aggregate supply curve away from the equilibrium level of output implies that actual prices must differ from expected prices. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Changes in Price Expectations • The price setting relationship above shows that prices will respond positively with respect to the level of price expectations. This is easily understood from the nature of the wage bargaining process. • Workers are typically concerned with the real value of their wages. However, they can only set its nominal value and only form an expectation as to what actual prices will be. If they expect prices in the future to be higher, then in order to preserve the real value of wages, they will push for higher nominal wages. These in turn represent a cost to firms, who will respond by increasing prices. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Changes in Price Expectations • Therefore, there is a clear relationship between expected and actual prices: P W P e • An increase in price expectations will lead to an upward shift in the short run aggregate supply curve. • This is because higher expectations lead to higher prices regardless of the level of output. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Increase in price expectations Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning How are price expectations formed? • Adaptive vs. Rational Expectations • Adaptive Expectations • In forming expectations adaptively, it is stated that current expectations are derived from past observations or experiences. • In this way, price expectations are formed by a backward looking rule such as: e e t t 1 t 1 P P 1 P • where 0<λ<1. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Adaptive Expectations • In each period, the expected price is a weighted average of the actual and expected prices from the previous period. • If actual prices exceeded expectations, then the next period’s expectation will be revised upwards. Each time expectations are adjusted, the short run aggregate supply curve will shift. It is only when actual and expected prices are equal that no further changes to expectations will be required. • Therefore, over time, expectations will eventually converge to the correct price level. The speed at which expectations are updated is given by the parameter λ. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Adaptive Expectations Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Rational Expectations • These are expectations that are formed using all available information: Pt e EPt I t where It is the set of information available at time t. • As new information comes to light, expectations will adjust immediately to incorporate it. • Therefore, instead of seeing the gradual adjustment under adaptive expectations, there would be a single immediate adjustment following new information about higher prices. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Rational Expectations Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Rational vs. Adaptive Expectations • There is some debate over which form of expectations formation is the most realistic/conclusive. • Rational expectations are considered by many to be the most plausible. • The main criticism with the adaptive framework is that expectations are simply backward looking and therefore would ignore important and relevant information which should be incorporated. Therefore, past mistakes would continue to be made even though individuals have the information to correct them. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Rational vs. Adaptive Expectations • The case for adaptive expectations becomes stronger when people have less than full and perfect information. • However, would the nature of expectations formation change if changes in equilibrium prices were much harder to ascertain? It is for this reason that increased attention is now being played to adaptive rules. This is because economic theory is now turning more and more towards learning behaviour. Accepting that individuals can only hold imperfect or incomplete information about the world, then it is easy to hypothesize that they will attempt to learn over time in order to improve their decision making. Therefore, the adaptive rule can be thought of as some kind of learning mechanism. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Equilibrium in the AD-AS Model • The long run equilibrium in the AD-AS model is simply where the aggregate demand and both the long run and short run aggregate supply curves all intersect. This means that output is at its equilibrium level, and also that actual and expected prices are equal at the market clearing level. • However, in the short run the economy can deviate from the equilibrium level of output by moving to a position along a short run aggregate supply curve. This would imply a disequilibrium in either the goods or the labour market and a gap between actual and expected prices. Such a position can be sustained as long as these two conditions continue to hold. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Equilibrium in the AD-AS Model • In the long run, though, a disequilibrium in the labour or goods market would be expected to lead to adjustments in wages and prices, and price expectations would be updated. Both of these movements act to reassert the long run equilibrium position. • However, because markets tend not to clear instantaneously and expectations may be updated adaptively, it may take some time for the economy to move back to the long run aggregate supply curve. This implies that the short run may actually be a significant period of time. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Equilibrium in the AD-AS Model Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Comparative statics in the AD-AS model • Having fully established the AD-AS model, it can be now be used to perform a number of comparative statics exercises. • Shifts in the aggregate demand curve results from anything that would shift the IS or the LM curve other than a change in prices. An outward shift in the AD curve could result from any or more of the following: – – – – An increase in government spending A cut in taxes A fall in interest rates or an increase in the money supply More optimistic expectations of the future leading to higher consumption and/or investment – Added wealth effects on consumption Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Comparative statics in the AD-AS model • Shifts in the long run aggregate supply curve result from changes in the equilibrium level of output, of which there appear to be two main causes. – Productivity shocks – Supply side policies • When analysing the effects of demand and supply shocks using the AD-AS model, it is common practise to assume some price rigidities and adaptive expectations. It is reasonable to argue that markets do not clear instantaneously. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Positive aggregate demand shock Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Positive aggregate demand shock • The transition from the short to the long run sees prices rise for as long as the economy operates above the equilibrium level of output. • The length of time it takes the economy to move from point b to point c will depend on how quickly expectations are updated, and on how flexible wages and prices are. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Contraction in aggregate demand Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Contraction in aggregate demand • The path the economy takes is the opposite of that described above. • Output will fall below the equilibrium level, but will eventually be restored over time by falling prices. • The economy follows a path marked abcd, and the only long run effect is a lower price level. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Negative aggregate supply shock Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Negative aggregate supply shock • The new equilibrium results in lower output and higher prices. • However, during the T periods it takes for the economy to reach the new equilibrium, it experiences both falling output and rising prices. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Positive productivity shock Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Positive productivity shock • A higher established level of equilibrium income produces a rightward shift in the long run aggregate supply curve. • The economy will then experience a process of falling prices and rising output. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning AD and AS Shocks • Under demand shocks, it is expected that output and prices will move in the same direction. Under a supply shock, they move in the opposite direction to each other. Supply side shocks may arise from productivity shocks. • A negative productivity shock, by shifting the long run aggregate supply curve inwards, would see a period of falling output and rising prices. • A positive productivity shock would have the opposite effect, where output increases and prices fall. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Hysteresis and the Medium Run • So far it has been established that aggregate demand shocks have temporary effects on output, whereas aggregate supply shocks have permanent effects. • Hysteresis describes a situation where demand shocks may leave permanent effects on output. • This works because the initial change in output induced by a change in aggregate demand may then lead to a change in the equilibrium level of output. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Hysteresis and the Medium Run • Example 1: Suppose output rises following an increase in aggregate demand. This means that previously unemployed workers may now be employed. This could result in them picking up on-the-job skills and experiences which raise labour productivity, in which case, the long run AS curve should shift to the right and the increase in output will become permanent. • Example 2: The economy falls into recession, and aggregate demand falls and unemployment rises. Faced with a lack of jobs, workers (especially the long-term unemployed) may become increasingly despondent and leave the labour force. Workers’ skills become obsolete and they lose human capital. Therefore, L will fall and the long run aggregate supply schedule will shift left making the fall in output permanent. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Summary • The aggregate demand and aggregate supply model can be used to explain how the levels of output and prices are determined in an economy. • The aggregate demand curve identifies the total amount of planned expenditure at each price level. It is a downward sloping function, as at higher prices the real money stock is lower, interest rates are higher, and therefore planned expenditures will be lower. • Aggregate supply in the long run is fixed at the equilibrium level of output. This represents the level of output where there is no pressure on prices to change. At output levels above the equilibrium level, prices will rise, and at output levels below the equilibrium level, prices will fall. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Summary • The equilibrium level of output is derived from the equilibrium rate of unemployment, also called the nonaccelerating rate of inflation unemployment (NAIRU). This is established from a labour-firm bargaining model, where firms set prices and workers set wages. The equilibrium level of real wages and the NAIRU is determined where the wage and price-setting curves intersect. • Anything which causes either the wage or price setting curves to shift will establish a new NAIRU level of equilibrium unemployment and therefore long run aggregate supply curve. Relevant factors might include the level of productivity, the labour supply, and the degree of competition in the goods market. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Summary • In the short run, aggregate supply can deviate from the equilibrium level of output if markets do not clear and a gap emerges between actual and expected prices. Therefore, in the short run it is possible to justify an upward sloping aggregate supply curve. However, any deviation of output from the equilibrium level can only be temporary. In the long run, prices will adjust to clear markets, and expectations will be updated. • The long run equilibrium of the economy is established at the equilibrium level of output, and at a price level where actual and expected prices coincide. • The AD-AS model can be used to analyse the effects of aggregate demand and aggregate supply shocks on the level of output and prices in an economy. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Summary • Conventionally, aggregate demand shocks only have temporary effects on output. This is because markets clear slowly and expectations are adjusted adaptively. The more rigidity in wages and prices, and the more adaptively expectations are formed, the longer it takes for output to return to the equilibrium level. • Aggregate supply shocks have permanent effects on both output and prices. Because an improvement in aggregate supply generates both permanently higher output and lower prices, governments are very serious in the use of supply side policies. • Hysteresis is a powerful concept which explains why aggregate demand shocks can have very long lasting effects on the economy. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning