Egypt’s Post Revolution Development Path From A Dynamic Economy Wide Model “A Three-Year Economic Recovery Plan” Motaz Khorshid Professor, Cairo University Former Minister of Higher Education and State for Scientific Research Cairo, Egypt Mobile: + (20122)2440988 Tel. Work: + (202)33358241 Mail: motaz.khorshid@gmail.com Asaad El- Sadek Ph.D. Student Faculty of Computers and Information Cairo University, Cairo, Egypt Mail: aelsadek_2006@yahoo.com The international Conference on Economic Modeling (EcoMod14) 16 -18 July, 2014 Bali, Indonesia 1 Abstract The Egyptian revolution broke out in January 25, 2011, a revolution that sparked the national movements in the Arab world and impressed the world as a model of an unprecedented popular peaceful uprising included all the spectrums of Egypt’s society. The revolution addressed corruption and tyranny and lift the banner of freedom, justice and democracy. In June 30, 2012 Mohamed Morsi was elected as a president of Egypt for a mandate of 4 years. Despite people’s aspiration for a better future, the continuation of the political instability, social injustice and economic problems during the year following the election have generated an increased feeling of insecurity and discontent. In June 2013, the Egyptian people decided to rebel against the unsatisfactory performance of the new political regime and succeeded to isolate the president with a support from the national military force. Since January revolution of 2011 and during the following transition period, Egypt continued to witness a considerable slowdown of its economic activity, a drop in domestic and foreign direct investments, a sizable decline in industrial production, a notable deterioration in foreign reserves and foreign exchange revenues and a growing government budget deficit. In 2014, Egypt’s socioeconomic indicators are still showing a declining trend reflected in; i) less than 2 percent increase in GDP coupled with a stagnated per capita real income, ii) an investment rate fluctuating around 16% of GDP compared to 22% in 2008, iii) a continuing low rate of national savings, iv) a sizable decline in the foreign direct investment flows - which amounted to about 2 billion US Dollars per year, compared to an average of 13 billion dollars during the 1990 decade and the begin of the current century, v) a critical unemployment situation, especially among youth and educated women with an average unemployment rate of more than 13% compared to 9% or less five years ago, vi) a high poverty rate accounting to more than 25% of the total population compared to less than 17% at the beginning of the third millennium, vii) a continuing budget deficit and unprecedented levels of domestic public debts exceeding 80 percent of GDP in June 2013, viii) A trade deficit in the current account of the balance of payments showing a continuous declining trend and ix) an upward rising trend of inflation derived by the prevailing increase in the state budget deficit. 2 Against this background, the Egyptian Cabinet approved in 28/08/2013 an urgent plan to stimulate the economy during the period from July 2014 until June 2017 (3 years). The overall objectives of this short/medium term plan is to achieve a GDP growth rate between 5% and 7% and reduce the unemployment rate to less than 9%, which represents the rate prevailed before January 25, 2011. The plan primarily depends on improving investments environment by relying on private, public and foreign direct investments (FDI). The plan suggests also an increased role of government in revitalizing the economy, with respect to investment spending, public consumption and employment strategy. To support the development and follow up of the three year stimulating plan of the Egyptian economy and to formulate alternative socioeconomic development policies and scenarios related to investment allocation and government spending policies, a three-sector five-institution economy wide model is constructed and implemented. The developed model reflects the structural features of the Egyptian economy and its modes of functioning and it is implemented using the general algebraic modeling system (GAMS) software. The Planning model is viewed as a consistent economy wide analytical tool following the general equilibrium tradition. To ensure the generation of the future path of the economy, it is equipped with a set of dynamic adjustment mechanisms. The development planning accounting framework of the model represents a Social accounting matrix (SAM) with three productive activities (primary, industrial and services activities), six institutions (urban and rural households, private and public corporations, and general government) and the outside world. Domestic institutions have both current and capital accounts. Factors of production include labor and capital services. Labor factors (or compensation of employees) are broken down by economic activity (private, public and government labor) and household area (urban and rural areas). Capital services include both public and private accounts. Commodities are composed of domestic, imported, exported and composite goods and services (merging domestically produced with imported goods) with each of them divided into primary, industry and services activities. Gross fixed capital formation is composed of private (households and 3 private companies) and public (government and public enterprises) investments as well as foreign direct investments (FDI). Government accounts disaggregate tax income into direct, indirect taxes and subsidies. Finally, the rest of the world account includes exports, imports, net transfers from abroad (in the form of worker’s remittances, investment income, foreign direct investments and other current transfers). The purposes of the paper are: (1) to assess the economic impact of the revolution and highlight the principal economy wide challenges facing the Egyptian economy, (2) to develop the accounting framework, economic rationale and mathematical structure of the economy wide model used to test the development policies of the stimulating plan, (3) to use the developed model to simulate the behavior of the economy under the selected development choices of the three year plan with the purpose of identifying appropriate policy measures needed to achieve the purposes of the three-year economic recovery program. Despite the short/medium term nature of the planning period, the results show that a sizable increase in annual growth rate of investment spending from 7.4 to 13 percent coupled with similar growth in government spending ranging from 5 to 7 percent per annum as well as an appropriate policies for attracting foreign direct investments (FDI), would significantly improve the growth prospects of real GDP. Based on the results of model, GDP is expected to increase from 3.4 percent in the reference path to around 4.7 percent when the stimulating scenario is applied. It should be noted however that, the failure to achieve a growth rate that exceeds 5 percent annually – based on the objectives of the recovery plan - is due to the negative impact of the selected stimulating policies on Egypt’s trade balance or net exports. Export promotion measures would be strongly requested in this respect to overcome this difficulty. Finally, the adopted three-year recovery plan succeeds to improve the per capita indicators and the welfare measures of Egyptians as well as to reduce the average unemployment rate from 13 percent in 2013/14 to around 9.9 percent in 2016/17. 4 Based on the above rationale, the paper is organized around seven sections. After this introductory part, the next two sections describe the post revolution economic performance and outline the accounting framework of the model. Sections four briefly describes the economic rationale, overall structure and disaggregation level of the model as well as the policy measures amenable to analysis based on its structure. Section five summarizes the components of the plan scenarios to be tested by the model. The sixth section describes the results and summarizes the main findings of applying the three year stimulating plan with special emphasis on the capacity to reach the planned targets and the feasibility of the selected policy measures to the Egyptian context. The final section includes the references. Post revolution economic performance Since January 2011 revolution, the Egyptian economy is witnessing a significant decline in its overall performance [14, 15, 16]. The evolution of the rate of economic growth over the three years - following the outbreak of the January 25th revolutiondisplays a deteriorating performance. The rate of GDP growth in real term collapsed from a peak value of 7.2% in 2007/2008 to just 2.1% in 2012/2013 because of the political stress and security unrest resulting generally in adverse consequences on economic and development performance. The growth rates of most of economic sectors followed the same declining pattern of the economy. However, on the positive side, the fiscal year 2012/2013 witnessed a significant increase in the rate of real growth (6.6%) in the tourism sector, compared to the year immediately following the revolution (-5.9%). This is mainly attributed to the decision of a lot of countries, led by Germany to ease degrees of travel warning to Egypt. The construction sector also saw a notable growth during the same year (5.9%) as the work in many of the giant real estate projects have resumed. On the negative side, in 2012/2013 there was a decline in the income from Suez Canal (-3.8%) because of the security unrest. The following table shows total resources and uses of GDP over the last two years in real terms. 5 Item GDP 2011/2012 2012/2013 % to GDP 2011/2012 2012/2013 1575.5 1608.6 100.0 100.0 407.2 402.8 25.8 25.0 1982.7 2011.4 125.8 125.0 1271.0 1307.0 80.7 81.3 Public consumption 179.0 185.2 11.4 11.5 Total consumption 1450.0 1492.2 92.0 92.8 Investments 258.1 233.3 16.4 14.5 Exports 274.6 285.9 17.4 17.8 1982.7 2011.4 125.8 125.0 Imports Total resources Private consumption Total uses At current prices after reaching 22.4% in 2007/2008, the last three years witnessed a decline in the rate of investment from 17.1% to 14.2%, with low domestic savings rate, which led to an increase in the savings gap from about 4.1% during the year 2010/2011 to around 8.4% in 2011/2012, and then a decline to 7% in 2012/2013. The Egyptian economy also experienced a dramatic decrease in net foreign direct investment over the three years following the revolution. From a peak value of $13.1 billion in 2007/2008, the net FDI decreased to only 3 billion dollars in 2012/2013. This significant decline in the rates of investment and net foreign direct investment explains the deteriorating economic growth over the last three years. Over the last four years, the deficit in the balance of trade increased from $25.1 billion in 2009/2010 – a year before the revolution - to $31.5 billion in 2012/2013. Although exports of goods over this period increased by 8.8% from $23.9 billion to $26.0 billion, the problem was in the large rise in imports of goods. Because of the drop in domestic production – resulting from the political uncertainty and the unprecedented labor strikes requesting the adjustment of their salary level, imports of goods increased by 17% from $49.0 billion to $57.5 billion. The surplus in balance of services, on the other hand, decreased from $10.3 billion in 2009/2010 to just 6 $6.7 billion in 2012/2013. The only exception to the deteriorating performance of the foreign exchange indicators is the net worker’s remittances from abroad that increased from $10.5 in 2009/2010 billion to $19.3 billion in 2012/2013. This might be explained by the desire of Egyptian citizens living abroad to participate in redressing the Egyptian economy and helping in overcoming its current difficulties, despite the increasing level of uncertainty facing their country. In balance, these unfavorable changes in external economic transactions resulted in an increase in the current account deficit from $4.32 billion in 2009/2010 to $5.6 billion in 2012/2013. The deteriorated current external balance in the post revolution period, has led similarly to a serious decline in the foreign reserves in US $. The net foreign exchange reserves declined from $36 billion in 2009/2010 to values ranging between $13.4 billion (March 2013) and $16 billion (May 2013). The steady decline in the net foreign exchange reserves during the past three years is attributed to the decline in both the revenues of tourism sector and foreign investments, in addition to the use of international reserves to finance imports and to prevent the deterioration in the value of the Egyptian pound. Despite the declining economic growth since the outbreak of the revolution, consumer spending in current prices continues to occupy a large proportion of GDP. Final consumption expenditure at current prices reached during the year 2012/2013 LE1.6 billion, which represents 92.8% of GDP at current prices, compared to LE1.0 billion in 2009/2010, equivalent to 85.7% of GDP at current prices. With the decline in investments and net exports, the increase in final consumption is still the main source of economic growth. The impact of January revolution on the deficit of general government budget was considerable. During the financial year 2012/2013, total deficit in the state budget reached LE240 billion compared to LE 98 billion in 2009/2010 - the year before the revolution, with a 145% Increase. This resulted in an increase in public debt. Total domestic public debt reached to LE1404.7 billion in 2012/2013, representing 81% of GDP at current prices compared to LE 663.8 billion in 2009/2010, representing 55% 7 of the GDP at the same year. Foreign debts have also become a problem, increased from $34.4 billion in June 2011 to $43.2 billion in July 2010, an increase of 25.6%. Finally, the slowdown of Egypt’s economic activity has aggravated the unemployment problem since the unemployment rate increased from 9 percent during the two years preceding the revolution to around 13.3% in 2012/2013. It also resulted in 8% inflation. The Accounting Framework of the Model The accounting structure and parameters of the model is broken down into two main components; a) an aggregate social accounting matrix (SAM) constructed for the year 2008-09 to support the within-period static part of the model [1,6,9,19] and b) a non SAM socioeconomic indicators needed to adjust the inter-period module ensuring the dynamic path of the economy. In this specific SAM, activities are broken down into three distinctive accounts; primary, industry and services. This classification is the one adopted in the International Standard Industrial Classification of all economic activities (ISIC), Revision 4 [9]. The disaggregated three productive activities of the SAM are shown in the table below. Commodities are classified into; composite, domestic, imported and exported with each bundle of commodities broken down into primary, industry and services. Factors are represented in the SAM by two groups of accounts; labor compensation accounts and capital services accounts. Labor compensation accounts are broken down by economic activity into; private, public and net worker remittances representing those who work in the private corporations, public corporations and abroad, respectively. The same applies to capital services accounts that are classified into; private, public and investment income representing capital employed in private corporations, public corporations and abroad, respectively. The economy includes three domestic institutions; households, firms and government. Households are represented by two accounts; urban and rural households. Firms or organized corporations are broken down into two separate accounts; private and public corporations. Government is broken down into three accounts; one account for general government income and spending and one account for taxes and another for subsidies. Savings are broken 8 down into two accounts; private savings (households and private corporations) and public savings (public corporations and public government). Investments are also broken down into two accounts; private and public. Finally, there is one current account for the rest-of-world. In total, this will give us (3434) SAM matrix. Economic activities as disaggregated by The proposed scheme of disaggregation Egypt’s National accounts 1. Agriculture 2. Extraction of crude petroleum & Primary natural gas 3. Other extraction 4. Petroleum refinement 5. Other manufacturing 6. Electricity and gas Industry 7. Water 8. Sewerage 9. Building & construction 10. Wholesale and retail trade 11. Financial services 12. Insurance 13. Transportation & storage 14. Communication 15. Information 16. Suez Canal 17. Restaurants and hotels Services 18. Real estate ownership 19. Business activities 20. Social insurance 21. Education 22. Health 23. Other services 24. Government 25. NPISHs The SAM is constructed for the fiscal year 2008/2009 in LE millions. 9 Model Structure and Economic Rationale To support the socioeconomic development planning process in Egypt following the revolution of January 25, 2011 and its second wave in June 30, 2013, the Ministry of Planning (MOP) developed two socioeconomic plans. A 10-year long term plan to capture both the recovery period needed to reach the normal performance of the economy and analyze as well its growth prospects in the post recovery period up to 2021/22 [12]. This long term plan mainly adopts a comprehensive set of policy measures with a target to double the real per capita income as a way to improve the living standards of the Egyptian citizens. Furthermore, to overcome the short/medium term difficulties resulting from the devastating impact of the revolution, the government of Egypt decided to adopt a three-year recovery plan to stimulate the economy in order to accelerate the return back to its normal functioning [18]. To achieve this short term objective, a three-sector five-institution medium term economy wide model was constructed, implemented and used to formulate and test alternative socioeconomic development options and scenarios. The constructed model reflects the structural features of the Egyptian economy along with its modes of functioning and it is implemented using the general algebraic modeling system (GAMS) software [7,10 ,11,12]. The model is particularly designed to project Egypt’s socioeconomic indicators and assess the impact of alternative policy measures and external conditions such as: (1) Investment spending policies reflected in the private and public gross fixed capital formation, (2) foreign direct investment (FDI) flows needed to complement domestic investments in supporting the growth prospects of the economy, (3) government spending policies such as government wage bill and employment policy, final consumption spending as well as public transfers to domestic and foreign institutions, (4) government fiscal policy including various taxes and subsidies, (5) export promotion and subsidy policy, (6) total factors productivity and labor efficiency policies, (7) external balance policies reflected in changes in investment income from abroad, worker remittances, interest on foreign assets and other foreign transfers from abroad , (8) wage rate and 10 commodity pricing policies and (9) alternative population, labor force and unemployment reduction policies. The development planning model represents an economy with three productive activities (primary, industrial and services activities), six institutions (urban and rural households, private and public corporations, and general government) and the outside world. Domestic institutions have both current and capital accounts. Factors of production include labor and capital services. Labor factors (or compensation of employees) are broken down by economic activity (private, public and government labor) and household area (urban and rural). Capital services include both public and private accounts. The markets of goods and services in the model are composed of domestic, imported, exported and composite commodities (merging domestic with imported goods), with each of them divided into primary, industry and services. Gross capital formation is composed of private (households and private companies) and public (government and public enterprises) investments as well as foreign direct investments (FDI). Government account disaggregates net tax income into direct and indirect taxes and subsidies. Finally, the rest of the world account includes net transfers from abroad in the form of worker’s remittances, investment income, foreign direct investments, current transfers to domestic institutions as well as imports and exports of goods and services. The Planning model is viewed as a consistent economy wide simulation model equipped with a set of dynamic adjustment mechanisms to ensure the generation of the medium to long term path of the economy [2, 3, 4, 5]. Most of the model structural parameters are computed from the SAM where as the behavior parameters are based on estimates of other models and similar studies for Egypt. The model represents an economy with an investment/saving macroeconomic closure rule that treats public and private gross fixed capital formations as exogenous variables, gross savings as an endogenous variable depending on institutional income and expenditure patterns and the foreign savings that clear the macroeconomic system. Production sectors apply a flexible price clearing mechanisms with an imperfect substitution between 11 domestic and imported goods (Armington Elasticity function). Distribution of gross output between domestic sales and exports is based on a constant elasticity of transformation (CET) function. Transfers from the rest of the world are fixed in foreign currency whereas transfers of the domestic institutions to the outside world are a function of their disposable income. World prices and interest on foreign assets are determined exogenously in the model. Exports of commodities are computed as the equilibrium quantity between supply of and demand for exported goods and services. The ratio of domestic to world price of commodity and the elasticity of trade determine world demand for exports. Government income is composed of direct and indirect taxes, public enterprises transferred operating surplus and transfers from domestic and foreign institutions. Government final consumption spending is fixed in real term and public savings are computed as a residual. Households and companies expenditures are computed as a fixed share of their nominal income and household final consumption spending is computed by a linear expenditure system (LES) . The model is equipped with institutional capital flows matrix that balances exogenous investments with savings and capital transfers. Given market imperfection and high unemployment rates, wage rates are fixed within period but change between periods based on employment and wage policy. Natural growth rate of population and labor participation policies are used to dynamically adjust population and labor force size between periods. The dynamic adjustment of capital stock between periods - by production activity – is based on the initial capital stock, gross fixed capital formation in real term and the consumption of fixed capital. Similar dynamic adjustment mechanisms are derived for investment income from abroad and foreign direct investments (FDI). Development of the recovery Plan Scenarios Based on the Egyptian Cabinet decision in 28/08/2013 to implement a short-term recovery plan with the objective of stimulating the economic performance during the period from July 2014 until June 2017 (3 years), a set of experiments – based on the constructed model – is designed and tested. Given the official plan document, These experiments assume –– that overall objectives of the medium-term plan is to 12 achieve on the one hand a GDP real growth rate between 5% and 7% and reduce on the other hand the unemployment rate to less than 9%, which represents the rate prevailed before January 25, 2011. In order to meet these short-term targets, a comprehensive development scenario is formulated with the following policy measures: (i) Increase the growth rate of private, public and foreign direct investments (FDI) spending during the coming three years up to 2016/17. It is assumed that the Egyptian authorities will succeed to revitalize FDI with respect to both the public and private sectors. This effort would result in an average annual increase of FDI ranging from 12 to 14 percent during the plan three years. Furthermore, public and private gross fixed capital formation – in real term – are assumed to reach an average annual growth of 10 and 15 percent respectively, compared to only 5 and 9 percent in the reference path (or business as usual). These figures are estimated considering the prevailing investment capacity of Egypt as well as government effort to mobilize the needed resources. (ii) The plan suggests also an increase in the role of government to revitalize the economy, with respect to government current expenditures and transfers as well as employment strategy. In this respect, government wage bill and purchases of goods and services in real term are assumed to increase respectively by 5 and 7 percent in the stimulating scenario compared to only 2.5 and 4.5 percent considering the reference path assumptions. In addition, the stimulating scenario suggests an increase in government transfers to domestic institution (households and business sectors) to allow for further activation of the domestic demand for commodities. Given the above assumptions, the constructed model was used to compare the performance of the Egyptian economy up to 2016/17 in light of the assumption of the reference path and the stimulating (or recovery) scenarios. 13 Experimental Results and Basic Findings The model results corresponding to the reference path and the stimulating scenarios during the period (2013/14 -2016/17) is summarized in three tables: a) Table (1) records the changes in the sources of financing the growth of GDP. It shows the uses (or applications) of GDP in real term up to 2016/17 which is the terminal year of the short/medium term plan. In the table, consumption and investment is broken down into private and public spending. When net exports (exports less imports) are included, the uses of GDP are completely identified. Note here that the table records the annual growth rate of the plan target year (from 2015/16 to 2016/17) as well as the structural changes in the components of GDP (uses as a percent of GDP). b) Table (2) summarizes the changes in real GDP during the planning period broken down into private, government and public sectors. It can be used then to measure the contribution of each production sector to GDP. The table shows also other important economic welfare indicators such as per-capita GDP, GNP and household consumption. c) Since reducing the unemployment rate represents a major policy option in the three-year plan – or any other policy exercise in Egypt – table (3) shows the impact of alternative scenarios on labor supply and demand divided into private, public and government workers. These indicators are used also to determine the unemployment level at the end of the planning period or equivalently the target year (2016/17). Growth Prospects: Given the assumptions of alternative development scenarios, the structural and behavioral features of the Egyptian economy reflected in the constructed medium term planning model and the projected socioeconomic indicators up to the target year (2016/17), the following analytical results and concluding remarks can be delineated: 14 1. If the government succeeds to mobilize its available resources for enhancing public sector investment opportunities and attracting foreign direct investments to finance public enterprises, and assuming that it will succeed also to adopt various policy measures to encourage private investor and enterprises - with special reference to their participation in national development programs and support to youth projects - Egypt will be in a position to accelerate economic growth, reduce its financial and commercial resource gaps, face labor market structural imbalances and improve the welfare level of citizens. 2. It should be noted however that the selected policy measures need to respect Egypt’s feasibility limits reflected in its structural rigidities and prevailing distortions. Furthermore, in many instances, policy means can have contradicting effects. For example, a surge in investment spending would contribute to enhancing economic growth via its positive impact on capital stock and return on capital, but it might however lead to an increase in the demand for imports of investment goods and then contribute to reducing the growth prospects of GDP. On the other hand, an increase in private and government consumption spending would normally have positive impact on GDP growth as a component of its uses. Further increase of consumption spending would lead meanwhile to reducing the part of the domestic production that can be directed to exports which is a factor contributing to reducing GDP growth and negatively affecting external balance. 3. Keeping the above economic rationale in mind, table (1) shows that annual growth rate of Real GDP in 2016/17 increases from 3.4 percent in the reference path to around 4.7 when the stimulating scenario is adopted. The enhanced investment performance (average annual growth rate is assumed to increase from 7.4 to around 13 percent) and the improved government final consumption (annual growth rate is assumed to increase from 2.8 to 5.7 percent on the average), are the major factors for achieving the growth of GDP in real term. The table shows also the negative impact on GDP growth in 2016/17 resulting from the increase in the growth of imports from 6.1 15 percent in the reference path to around 9.9 percent when the stimulating scenario is adopted. It reflects also the stagnated performance of exports with an average growth rate that does not exceed 1.3 to 1.6 percent on the average. This finding suggests that the stimulating policy package should include – in addition to investment, FDI and government spending policies – an export measures. 4. Table (2) shows the contribution of the production sectors to the growth of GDP in real term evaluated at factor cost. According to the stimulating scenario, the private sector appears on top of the list with respect to its contribution to the growth of GDP (5.4 percent growth rate of private sector GDP in 2016/17). Because the general government GDP is composed mainly of real wage bill, its growth rate is reflected directly in the labor market functioning and unemployment rate. Structural Changes Given the short period of analysis (2013/14 – 2016/17), one would expect that the structural changes in the economy resulting from the tested scenarios are limited. The sizable increase in investment and government spending might result however in some changes in the structure of GDP. This is true with respect to total investment spending and demand for imports. In table(1), gross investment spending as a percent of GDP in 2016/17 increased from 25% in the reference path scenario to around 29% when adopting the stimulating scenario. Similarly, imports as a percent of GDP increased considerably from 34% to 38% as a result of applying the stimulation package. 16 Table (1) Uses of GDP in real term Base year (2013/14) Development Scenarios Economic Indicators (Real Term) Reference Path Indicator Structure (%) Private Consumption Public Consumption Stimulating Scenario Target year 2013/14 GDP Target year 2016/17 GDP Growth Structure Growth Structure (%) (%) (%) (%) 880,058 73 997,247 4.0 75 1022,476 5.1 75 145,007 12 157,486 2.8 12 170,618 5.7 13 1025,065 85 1154,733 3.8 87 1193,094 5.2 88 145,313 12 189,678 9.3 14 218,624 15.0 16 128,863 11 149,993 5.0 11 170,085 10.0 13 274,176 23 338,711 7.4 25 388,709 12.8 29 288,654 24 296,314 1.6 22 291,682 1.3 21 375,520 32 463,833 6.1 34 510,462 9.9 38 1212,375 100% 1325,925 3.4 100% 1363,023 4.7 100% Total Consumption Private Investments Public Investments Total Investments Exports (-) Imports GDP uses (Market Price) 17 Table (2) GDP break down by sector and per capita indicators Base year Development Scenarios Reference Path Economic Indicators Target year GDP (2013/14) Structure Public GDP Government GDP GDP Sources (at factor cost) Pre-Capita GDP (Real Term) Pre-Capita GDP (Nominal) Pre-Capita GNP Target year GDP 2016/17 (%) Private GDP Stimulating Scenario Growth Structure (%) (%) 2016/17 GDP Growth Structure (%) (%) 714,821 62 793,488 4.1 63 814,190 5.4 62 322,864 28 344,504 2.5 27 350,902 3.4 27 120,268 10 129,010 2.4 10 139,225 5.0 11 1157,952 100% 1267,002 3.5 100 1304,317 4.8 100 14,247 - 14,625 1.13 - 15,049 1.8 - 22,397 - 25,061 3.96 - 27,056 6.9 - 22,738 - 25,457 3.99 - 27,451 6.9 - 16616 - 18677 4.1 - 20017 6.8 - Per-Capita Household Consumption Table (3) Labor Supply, Demand and unemployment rate Population/Labor Indicators Stimulating Scenario (Thousands) Population Size Labor Force Supply Labor Demand Unemployment Rate (%) 2013/14 2014/15 2015/16 2016/17 85,096 86,883 88,708 90,571 30,209 30,409 31,491 32,605 26,248 26,708 27,900 29,361 13.11 12.17 11.40 9.95 Labor Demand by sector: - Private 18,786 19,056 19,883 20,956 - Public 795 796 818 846 - Government 6,667 6,856 7,199 7,559 18 Per Capita Indicators In the context of this study, per capita indicators can serve two purposes; i) Economic growth adjusted by population size and ii) welfare level of citizens. Per capita GDP in real term slightly increases from LE 14,625 in the reference path to LE 15,049 in 2016/17 due to the adoption of the stimulating policies. The impact on per capita GDP and GNP in nominal term is clearer. The average annual growth rates of per-capita GDP in nominal term witness a sizable increase from 3.96% to 6.9% when applying the stimulation package. Furthermore, the implementation of the stimulation scenario produces a significantly positive effect on the per capita household consumption with an absolute increase from LE 18,677 to LE 20,017 in 2016/17. Labor Market and Unemployment The impact of the stimulating scenario on supply of and demand for labor services as well as unemployment rate is shown in table (3). When carrying on the modeling experiments, we assumed no changes between the reference path and the stimulating scenario with respect to population size and supply of labor force. The demand for labor services is meanwhile affected by the economic policy measures included in the stimulating scenario. On the average, the demand for labor – which reflects in a way the job opportunities offered by the productive sectors of the economy – increases by around 4 percent per annum resulting in a growth of demand from 26,248 thousand laborers in 2013/14 to around 29, 361 thousands in 2016/17. As a direct consequence, unemployment rates decreases from 13.11 percent in 2013/14 to around 9.95 percent which represents approximately the prerevolution performance (the prevailing official unemployment rate in 2010 was around 9 percent). Table (3) shows also the breakdown of labor demand by production sector. Given the short term nature of the analysis, the impact on demand for labor is felt in the private and government sectors more the public enterprises. The discussion of this point needs some micro analysis that goes beyond the scope of this study. Based on the results of the model, average annual growth rate of demand for labor has increased by 3.85% and 4.4% in the private and 19 government sector, respectively. The demand for labor in public enterprises increases only by 2.14% per annum on the average. References [1] Aboul-Einein, S. and Motaz Khorshid (2009) “A Social Accounting Matrix to Assess the Strategies for achieving the Millennium Development Goal in Egypt” Unpublished Working Paper, Regional Project for Assessing Development Strategies to Achieve the Millennium Development Goals in the Arab region, UNDP-RBAS, UN-DESA and World Bank. [2] Dervis, K., J. De Melo and S. Robinson (1982) “General equilibrium Models for Development policy.” Cambridge University Press, New York. [3] Drud, A., W. Grais and G. Pyatt (1986) “Macroeconomic Modeling Based on Social Accounting Principles. “Journal of Policy modeling. Vol. 8. No. 1:111-145. [4] Khorshid, M. (1994) “A Dynamic Multi-sector Economy-wide Model for Egypt: Database, Structure and Policy Analysis.” The IBK Papers. The Industrial Bank of Kuwait. No. 41: 1-68. [5] Khorshid, M. (1996) "A Multi-sector Population Economy-wide Simulation Model for Egypt" Finance and Industry. The Industrial Bank of Kuwait, No. 12: 39-155. [6] Khorshid M. (2002) “Issue-Oriented Social Accounting Matrices for Development Policy: Experience from the Middle East and North Africa Region”, The proceedings of the 14th International Conference on Input-Output Techniques, Montreal, Canada, October 10-15. [7] Khorshid M . (2003) "Alternative Socioeconomic Development Scenarios for Egypt: Results from an Economy-Wide Simulation Model", published by the 20 Economic Research Forum (ERF) for the Arab Countries, Iran and Turkey, December. [8] Khorshid M. (2008) "Social Accounting Matrices for Modeling and Policy AnalysisDevelopment Issues from the Middle East" Proceedings of the International Conference on Policy Modeling, Berlin, Germany, July 2-4. [9] Khorshid, M. and A. El-Sadek (2010) "An ICT Economy Wide Interaction Social Accounting Matrix for Egypt – Structure, Economic Rationale and Analytical Indicators" Proceedings of the International Conference on Policy Modeling, EcoMod10, Istanbul, Turkey, July 7-10. [10] Khorshid M. and A. El sadek (2011) "An ICT Economy Interaction Model for Egypt – Impact on Growth and Productivity" Proceedings of the International Conference on Economic Policy Modeling (EcoMod11), Azores, Portugal, June 27-29. [11] Khorshid M. and A. El sadek (2012) "A multi-sector ICT Economy Interaction Model For Egypt – The Path to Information Society" Proceedings of the International Conference on Economic Policy Modeling (EcoMod12), Seville, Spain, July 4-6. [12] Khorshid M. and A. El sadek (2013) "Egypt’s Post Revolution Development Path From A Dynamic Economy Wide Model – A Goal Seeking Analysis" Proceedings of the International Conference on Economic Policy Modeling (EcoMod12), Prague, July 1-3. [13] Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation (2010), "Strategic Framework for Socio-economic Development Plan until 2022", Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation, Cairo. [14] Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation (2011), "Follow up report – 2010/2011", Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation, Cairo. 21 [15] Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation (2012), "Follow up report – 2011/2012", Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation, Cairo. [16] Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation (2013), "Follow up report – 2012/2013", Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation, Cairo. [17] Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation (2009), "National Accounts 2008/2009", Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation, Cairo. [18] Ministry of Planning and International Co-operation (2013), "An urgen plan for economic recovery", Ministry of Planning and International Cooperation, Cairo. [19] Pyatt, G. and J. Round (1985), "Social Accounting Matrices: A Basis for Planning, World Bank Publication.", Washington, D.C. 22