Econ 101: Microeconomics Chapter 14: Economic Efficiency and the Role of Government The Meaning of Efficiency What, exactly, does efficiency mean? • Economic efficiency is achieved when there is no way to rearrange the production or allocation of goods in a way that makes one person better off without making anybody else worse off A trade in which both parties are made better off, and no one is harmed Named after Italian economist, Vilfredo Pareto (1848-1923) • First systematically explored the issue of economic efficiency Helps us arrive at a formal definition of economic efficiency • Achieved when every possible Pareto improvement is exploited Alternatively, we can look at the economy as a whole • If we discover remaining Pareto improvements that are not occurring then we would deem the economy economically inefficient Perfectly competitive markets tend to be economically efficient Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 2 Side Payments and Pareto Improvements There are more complicated situations in which a Pareto improvement will come about • • If an action creates more total benefits for gainers than total harm to losers • Only if one side makes a special kind of payment to the other—called a side payment Situations in which action will benefit one group and harm another Than a side payment exists which—if transferred from gainers to losers—would make the action a Pareto improvement Important implication for economic efficiency • If there is an action that benefits some more than it harms others, and if an appropriate side payment can be easily arranged • Than not taking the action is a waste of an opportunity to make everyone better off When a side payment cannot be made—or for any reason is not made—then event of action might create greater gain than harm, it might not be considered fair Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 3 The Efficient Quantity of a Good Figure 3 combines supply and demand curves for guitar lessons Whenever demand curve lies above supply curve, producing the lesson is a Pareto improvement • • • Whenever demand curve lies below supply curve, producing the lesson cannot be a Pareto improvement Efficient quantity of guitar lessons—the quantity at which all Pareto improvements are exploited—is where the demand curve and supply curve intersect At this quantity, value of the last good produced will be equal to— or possibly a tiny bit greater than—the cost of providing it • Efficient quantity of a good is quantity at which market demand curve and market supply curves intersect Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 4 Figure 3: Efficiency In The Market For Guitar Lessons Price $25 $23 $21 $19 $17 $15 $13 Flo Joe Supply 1. Joe would pay as much as $23 for the second lesson . . . Flo Bo McCollum Martin Gibson Zoe Martin Demand Martin 3. Four lessons is the equilibrium and the efficient quantity. 2. while Martin would offer it for as little as $15. 1 2 3 Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 4 5 Number of Lessons per Week 5 Consumer Surplus Useful to measure the benefits that producers and consumers receive from their economic activities A buyer’s consumer surplus on a unit of a good • Difference between its value to buyer and what buyer actually pays for the unit Total consumer surplus enjoyed by all consumers in a market is called market consumer surplus • • Sum of consumer surplus on all units Market consumer surplus at any price—measured in dollars—is total area under market demand curve and above market price Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 6 Figure 4(a): Consumer Surplus in a Small and Large Market for Guitar Lessons (a) 1. When market price is $19, someone (Flo) gets $6 in consumer surplus on the first lesson . . . Price 2. someone (Joe) gets $4 in consumer surplus on the second . . . $25 $23 $21 $19 $17 3. and someone (Flo again) gets $2 in consumer surplus on the third. Demand The total shaded area is market consumer surplus. Assumed Market Price 1 2 Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 3 4 5 Number of Lessons per Week 7 Figure 4(b): Consumer Surplus in a Small and Large Market for Guitar Lessons (b) Price In a market with many buyers, market consumer surplus is the entire area under the demand curve and above the market price. $19 Market Price Demand 4,000 Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles Number of Lessons per Week 8 Producer Surplus An individual seller’s producer surplus on a unit of a good • Difference between what seller actually gets and additional cost of providing it Total producer surplus gained by all sellers in a market is called market producer surplus • • Found by adding up producer surplus gained by all sellers in market Market producer surplus at any price—measured in dollars—is total area above market supply curve and below market price Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 9 Figure 5(a): Producer Surplus From Selling Guitar Lessons (a) Price 1.When market price is $19, someone (Martin) gets $6 in producer surplus on the first lesson . . . Supply $21 $19 $17 $15 $13 2. someone (Martin again) gets $4 in producer surplus on the second . . . 3. and someone (Gibson) gets $2 on the third. Assumed Market Price The total shaded area is market producer surplus. 1 2 Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 3 4 5 Number of Lessons per Week 10 Figure 5(b): Producer Surplus From Selling Guitar Lessons (b) Price Supply Market Price $19 In a market with many sellers, market producer surplus is the entire area above the market supply curve and below the market price. 4,000 Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles Number of Lessons per Week 11 Figure 6: Total Net Benefits in a Competitive Market for Guitar Lessons Price S Market Equilibrium consumer Price surplus $19 Market producer surplus Total net benefits - Sum of consumer and producer surplus in that market. D 4,000 Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles Equilibrium Quantity 12 Perfect Competition and Efficiency: The Total Benefits View Each time we make a Pareto improvement in a market • • • We make at least one party better off and make no one else worse off Therefore, a Pareto improvement will increase total net benefits available in a market Thus, we have a new way of viewing efficiency • A market is efficient when sum of producer and consumer surplus is maximized in that market In a well-functioning, perfectly competitive market • Equilibrium quantity provides maximum possible benefit to buyers and sellers combined, and is the efficient quantity Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 13 A Price Ceiling Creates greater harm for sellers than gains for buyers • Reduces total net benefits in the market in a perfectly competitive market Welfare loss in a market is dollar value of potential benefits not achieved due to inefficiency in that market Although a price ceiling may benefit consumers as a group it will always reduce total net benefits in the market Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 14 Figure 7(a): Why Price Ceilings and Price Floors Are Inefficient 1. A price ceiling of $15 . . . 2. transfers surplus from producers to consumers. Price S $23 C 3. It also decreases market quantity, taking away some consumer surplus E $19 B D $15 D A 4 . . . . and some producer surplus, which are not transferred to anyone. 2,000 Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 4,000 6,000 15 Figure 7(b): Why Price Ceilings and Price Floors Are Inefficient 1. A price floor of $21 . . . Price 2. transfers surplus from consumers to producers. S C $21 $19 $17 B 3. It also decreases market quantity, taking away some consumer surplus E D A D 4 . . . . and some producer surplus, which are not transferred to anyone. 3,000 Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 4,000 5,000 16 Calculating the Welfare Loss Let’s calculate dollar value of welfare loss caused by price ceiling • Area of unshaded triangle formed by areas D and E together • From high school algebra, area of any triangle is ½ x base x height Welfare loss = ½ x base x height = ½ x $8 x 2,000 = $8,000 When this market is delivering only 2,000 lessons per week instead of the efficient 4,000 • • Guitar teachers and students together lose $8,000 in potential benefits per week or Welfare loss would be 52 weeks x $8,000 per week = $416,000 per year Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 17 A Price Floor In a perfectly competitive market, the price floor will always shrink total net benefits Reduces total benefits in market (causes a welfare loss) Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 18 The Efficiency Role of Government When a well-functioning, perfectly competitive market is permitted to reach its equilibrium, the outcome is efficient • • No opportunities for mutual gain remain unexploited Any government intervention that changes the market quantity (say, a price ceiling or a price floor) will create inefficiency—a welfare loss But government can—and does—contribute to the economic efficiency of markets • • Provides infrastructure that permits markets to function • • Physical infrastructure—bridges, airports, waterways, and buildings Institutional infrastructure—laws, courts, and regulatory agencies Stepping in when markets are not working properly • When they leave Pareto improvements unexploited and therefore fail to achieve economic efficiency Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 19 Market Failures Another vitally important role for government • To intervene in situations of market failure • When a market equilibrium—even with the proper institutional support—is economically inefficient General types of market failures to which economists have devoted a lot of attention • • • Monopoly power Externalities Public goods While economists and policy-makers agree in theory on what causes a market failure • Dealing with real-world market failures remains one of the most controversial aspects of government policy Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 20 Externalities When a private action has side effects that affect other people in important ways, we have the problem of externalities • By-product of a good or activity that affects someone not immediately involved in transaction Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 21 The Private Solution to a Negative Externality Under certain conditions, inefficiency that would be caused by a negative externality will automatically be resolved by the parties themselves • The outcome is the efficient outcome • Achieves maximization of total net benefits possible in the situation Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 22 The Coase Theorem What if building a theater would create $100,000 of benefits for some but $70,000 worth of harm for others? Whether the theater will or will not be built depends entirely on whether it is the efficient or inefficient outcome • • • Regardless of who holds the legal rights Negative externality is solved by market No government intervention is required, other than the initial assignment of legal rights Rather surprising result is known as the Coase Theorem— named after economist Ronald Coase • • States that private market will solve externality problem on its own, always arriving at the efficient outcome • When side payments can be negotiated and arranged without cost While initial distribution of legal rights will determine allocation of gains and losses among the parties, it will not affect action taken Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 23 The Coase Theorem Requires that side payments can be arranged without cost—or, in practice, that cost is so low relative to gains or losses at stake that it doesn’t matter • This requirement is most likely to be satisfied when all of the following conditions are present • • • Unfortunately, many real world situations do not satisfy these conditions Biggest problem is applying Coase theorem to many real-world externalities is the third condition • Legal rights are clearly established Legal rights can be easily transferred The number of people involved is very small Often, a large number of people are involved When many people are involved, achieving efficiency with side payments is plagued by an often insoluble problem • Free rider problem Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 24 The Free Rider Problem Occurs when efficient outcome requires a side payment but individual gainers—each obligated to pay a small share of the side payment—will not contribute If extensive enough—can shrink the side payment until it isn’t large enough to compensate losers and still leave gainers better off Stands in the way of many Pareto improvements • One of the main reasons why we typically turn to government to deal with important externalities that affect many people Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 25 Market Externalities and Government Solutions A competitive market has many buyers and sellers • A market with a negative externality associated with producing or consuming a good will produce more than the efficient quantity • When a negative externality affects a market, the private solution is unlikely to work Creating a welfare loss Unfortunately, with so many people involved, it would take too much time and trouble for individual producers and consumers to arrange appropriate side payments and production cutbacks • • In any case, free rider problem would effectively destroy the arrangement Efficient outcome requires government intervention in the market Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 26 Figure 11a: A Tax on Producers to Correct a Negative Externality (a) Dollars 1. This market has a negative externality of $0.50 per unit. MSC C 2. The efficient quantity is here . . . $0.50 B S A 3. but the equilibrium quantity is here. $1.00 D 4. In equilibrium, the welfare loss is triangle ABC. Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 100 125 Millions of Gallons per Period 27 Figure 11b: A Tax on Producers to Correct a Negative Externality 5. A(b) tax per unit on producers, equal to the negative externality per unit, Dollars 6. shifts the supply curve upward . . . SAfter Tax B $1.30 SBefore Tax $0.50 A $1.00 $0.80 7. and moves the equilibrium to the efficient quantity. D 100 Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 125 Millions of Gallons per Period 28 Taxing a Negative Externality Government could use a tax on producers to move gasoline market to point B Payment of the externality tax is shared between consumers and producers, as is the payment of any tax, and will depend on elasticities of supply and demand • A tax on each unit of a good, equal to the external harm it causes, can correct a negative externality and bring market to an efficient output level Consider the logic of this result • Tax cures the inefficiency because it forces market to internalize the externality • To take account of the harm caused by gasoline Suggests that a tax on consumers of gasoline would work just as well as a tax on producers Taxes to correct negative externalities have been used in countries around the world • In United States, however, taxes designed to correct negative externalities are less common Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 29 Dealing with a Positive Externality What about the case of a positive externality? • A market with a positive externality associated with producing or consuming a good will produce less than the efficient quantity, creating a welfare loss A subsidy on each unit of a good, equal to the external benefits it creates, can correct a positive externality and bring the market to an efficient output level If a good is rivalrous, efficiency requires that people pay a price for its use • By-product of an activity or a service benefits other parties, rather than harms them In the absence of any market failure, private provision will lead to efficient level of production If a good is excludable, it can be provided by private market Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 30 Figure 12a: A Subsidy for Consumers to Correct a Positive Externality 1.This market has a positive externality (a) of $30,000 per college degree. Dollars 2. The equilibrium quantity is here . . . S $30,000 B $100,000 3. but the efficient quantity is here. A MSB C D 800,000 1,000,000 Number of Degrees per Year 4. In equilibrium, the welfare loss is triangle ABC. Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 31 Figure 12b: A Subsidy for Consumers to Correct a Positive Externality 5. A subsidy per unit for consumers equal to the positive externality per unit(b) ... 6. shifts the demand curve upward . . . Dollars $30,000 B $114,000 $100,000 A 7. and moves the S market to the efficient quantity DAfter Subsidy $84,000 DBefore Subsidy 800,000 Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 1,000,000 Number of Degrees per Year 32 Public Goods Pure private good • • When a good is nonexcludable, people have an incentive to become free riders • In most cases, if we want such a good, government must provide it When a good or service is nonrivalrous, market cannot provide it efficiently • To let others pay for the good, so they can enjoy it without paying When a good is nonexcludable, private sector will generally be unable to provide it • One that is both rivalrous and excludable In absence of any significant market failure, private firms will provide these goods at close to efficient levels Rather, to achieve economic efficiency, good or service would have to be provided free of charge Pure public good • One that is both nonrivalrous and nonexcludable Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 33 Figure 13: Pure Private, Pure Public and Mixed Goods Pure Private Good More Excludable More Rival More Nonrival • food, clothing, housing • sold-out movie • crowded highway • newspaper Mixed Good • software • movie with empty seats • uncrowded highway • cable television • downloaded music file • urban park • crowded city streets • fish in international waters • police and fire protection • national defense, legal system More Nonexcludable Mixed Good Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles Pure Public Good 34 Mixed Goods Goods that appear in upper right and lower left corners of Figure 13 can be called mixed goods • Share features of both public and private goods These goods are becoming increasingly important in our society • Are responsible for some growing tension and controversy Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 35 Excludable But Nonrivalrous Goods Goods near lower left hand corner are excludable but nonrivalrous • • • • Includes most information products Software is an essentially nonrivalrous good, but an excludable one • Neither pure public nor pure private Digital music files are another example of this type of mixed good • Currently, music remains somewhat excludable • • It is against the law to make copyrighted music available online Many people—either because of respect for the law, fear of getting caught, lack of technical expertise, or scarce time—still prefer to buy their music from a store or online shipping service Music industry is desperately looking for ways to achieve greater excludability • Has not yet found a good solution Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 36 Nonexcludable But Rivalrous Goods Tragedy of commons occurs when rivalrous but nonexcludable goods are overuse to detriment of all An economy with well-functioning, perfectly competitive markets tends to be economically efficient • Many types of government involvement are needed to ensure that markets function well and to deal with market failures Cases of government involvement are not without controversy • Debates about public education, Social Security, international trade, and immigration center on questions of proper role for government Some of the disagreement is over government’s role in bringing about a more fair economy • Also debate about the government’s role in bringing about economic efficiency Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 37 Nonexcludable But Rivalrous Goods Information problems • While government may be able to move us closer to efficiency, it can also fall short or overshoot based on inaccurate information Incentive problems for government • Government officials are agents of the general public, and are supposed to serve public interest • However, they can be influenced by lobbies for special interest groups In order for government to have the funds it needs to support markets and do other things, it must raise revenue through taxes Inherent problem with provision of public goods that almost guarantees dissatisfaction about them Other important roles for government besides fostering efficiency • Equity, fairness, justice, and more Anyone studying role of government in the economies is struck by one glaring fact • Most economic activity is carried out among private individuals Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles 38