CHAPTER ONE INTRODUCTION 1.1 BACKGROUND TO THE STUDY Theoretically, both fiscal and monetary policies aim at achieving macroeconomic stability (Folawewo and Osinubi, 2006). Over the years, two issues have been subjects of debate in this regard. First is the effectiveness of each of these policies in the achievement of macroeconomic stability. While Keynesians (1956) argued that fiscal policy is more potent than monetary policy, the monetarists led by Milton Friedman (1968) on the other hand believed the other way round. Although the focus of this study is neither to join in nor extend the debate, but based on the country’s experience and the fact that fiscal policy plays a vital role in preventing the occurrence of fundamental disequilibrium in the economy, the study will analyze the impact of fiscal policy in tackling macroeconomic stability in Nigeria. The second relates to the issue of macroeconomic stability. Ocampo (2005), in his study, recommends a broad concept of macroeconomic stability, whereby “sound macroeconomic frameworks” include not only price stability and sound fiscal policies, but also a well-functioning economy, sustainable debt ratios and healthy public and private sector balance sheets. These multiple dimensions imply using multiple policy 1 instruments that involves active use of counter-cyclical macroeconomic policies (fiscal and monetary), together with capital management techniques (capital account regulations and prudential rules incorporating macroeconomic dimensions). It also explores the role of international financial institutions in facilitating developing countries’ use of counter-cyclical macroeconomic policies. In his words, Ocampo (2005) posited that the concept of macroeconomic stability has undergone considerable changes in the economic discourse over the past decades. During the post-war years dominated by Keynesian thinking, macroeconomic stability basically meant a mix of external and internal balance, which in turn implied, in the second case, full employment and stable economic growth, accompanied by low inflation. Over time, fiscal balance and price stability moved to centre stage, supplanting the Keynesian emphasis on real economic activity. This policy shift led to the downplaying and even, in the most radical views, the complete suppression of the counter-cyclical role of macroeconomic policy. Although this shift recognized that high inflation and unsustainable fiscal deficits have costs, and that “fine-tuning” of macroeconomic policies to smooth out the business cycle has limits, it also led to an underestimation of both the costs of real macroeconomic stability and the effectiveness of Keynesian aggregate demand management. 2 This shift was particularly sharp in the developing world, where capital account and domestic financial liberalization exposed developing countries to the highly pro-cyclical financial swings characteristic of assets that are perceived by financial markets as risky, and thus subject to sharp changes in the “appetite for risk”. In the words of Stiglitz (2002), such exposure replaced Keynesian automatic stabilizers with automatic destabilizers. Thus, contrary to the view that financial markets would play a disciplining role, dependence on financial swings actually encouraged the adoption of pro-cyclical monetary and fiscal policies that increased both real macroeconomic instability and the accumulation of risky balance sheets during periods of financial euphoria which led, in several cases, to financial meltdowns Thus, the goal of macroeconomic policies has broadened in recent years. We have only come part of the way, however, to the full recognition that macroeconomic stability involves multiple dimensions, including not only price stability and sound fiscal policies, but also a well-functioning real economy (Ocampo, 2005). A well-functioning real economy requires, in turn, smoother business cycles, moderate long-term interest rates and competitive exchange rates, all of which may be considered intermediate goals of the ultimate Keynesian objective: full employment. Such a broad view of macroeconomic stability should recognize, in any case, that there is no simple correlation between its various dimensions and, thus, that multiple objectives and 3 significant trade-offs are intrinsic to the design of “sound” macroeconomic frameworks. This view would lead to the recognition of the role played by two sets of policy packages, whose relative importance will vary depending on the structural characteristics, the macroeconomic policy tradition and the institutional capacity of the country. The first package involves a mix of counter-cyclical fiscal and monetary policies with appropriate (and, as we will argue, generally intermediate) exchange-rate regimes. The second includes a set of capital management techniques designed to reduce the unsustainable accumulation of public and private sector risks in the face of pro-cyclical access to international capital markets. To encourage economic growth, such interventions through the business cycle would lead to sound fiscal systems that provide the necessary resources for the public sector to do its job, a competitive exchange rate and moderate long-term real interest rates. These conditions, together with deep financial markets that provide suitably priced investment finance in the domestic currency with sufficiently long maturities, are the best contribution that macroeconomics can make to growth (Ocampo, 2005). According to the National Economic Intelligence Committee (1998), fiscal policy measures should aim at achieving an optimal balance between government revenue 4 and government expenditure and at complementing monetary policy in the attainment of macroeconomic stability. Fiscal incentive in support of the policy should be so structured as to promote growth in the various sectors of the economy. Olaloye and Ikhide (1995), in their study concluded that fiscal policy has been more effective in Nigeria, at least for the period of the depression i.e., between 1980 and 1989, and the appropriate fiscal policy variable that the government should act upon is the government expenditure. The total government spending might be more useful as a policy tool rather than the fiscal deficit and the lag in the effect of fiscal policy are shorter than for monetary policy. In other words, a reduction in the public expenditure will take a shorter time (three to six months) to cause a fall in GDP than a similar reduction in money supply. Therefore, judging from the existing literature, it is desirable to undertake an assessment of the impact of the fiscal policy measures (expenditure programmes) on macroeconomic stability indicators (such as output and inflation rate) in order to provide a guide to the restructuring and coordination of fiscal policy instruments (government revenue and expenditure) and monetary policy variable proxy by money supply on the macroeconomy. 5 1.2 STATEMENT OF THE PROBLEM Nigeria witnessed a long history of macroeconomic instability, occasioned by large fiscal deficits to GDP. For instance, this averaged 7.7% in 1994, 8.9% in 1999, 4.0% in 2001, 3.4% in 2005 and 2.9% in 2006. These deficits were accompanied by high level of inflation rate; poor productive public sector investment and considerable debt overhang. More specifically, prior to the recent economic reforms, Nigeria’s economic performance was characterized by large macroeconomic instability for variables such as inflation, exchange rates, etc; hostile business environment for private sector growth and poor governance. The public sector was grossly mismanaged and overbloated (Babalola, 2007). Overall, most economic and social indicators were generally poor, thus, there is wastage and misplacement of priorities (Olofin, 2001). Likewise, the need to bring to recognition that during any fiscal period, numerous policies are jointly implemented and there is a need for the harmonization of these policies (fiscal policy coordination) so as to prevent policy conflicts (Iyoha and Itsede, 2003). Usman (2008) reveals the adverse impact of fiscal policy on the Nigerian economy in the past. He posited that the past failure of fiscal policy in Nigeria has been analyzed within the framework of a commonly known term “Natural Resource Curse”. Where a country endowed with verse amounts of natural resources fails to translate such wealth into meaningful economic growth and development. The fiscal policy failure to 6 insulate the economy from the volatility of oil revenues has led to undue real exchange rate appreciation and pro-cyclical fiscal policy with detrimental effects on investment and growth. Other factors include dead-weight loss from taxes that finance public spending, unproductive public spending on wages and salaries of unproductive employees, and rent-seeking incentives reduce growth by diverting higher human capital away from productive activities. The question of sustainability has become an important issue not because current unsustainable policies must later be reversed, but also because unsustainability becomes a more and more important problem as time goes on and as deficits increase because of debt accumulation (Anyanwu, 1997). Masson (1985) and World Bank (1988) state that “It is precisely a conviction that the government is shortsighted in its policies and biased towards overspending because of the nature of her political economy, that makes sustainability an issue”. Anyanwu (1997) also posited that “with unsustainable deficit, macroeconomic stabilization becomes a top priority but structural economic adjustment cannot occur alongside major macroeconomic imbalances just as stabilization without structural measures to support growth may itself prove unsustainable”. Thus, stabilization and structural adjustment must be coordinated to avoid inconsistency in policy. In this sense, adjustment should allow for complementary fiscal reforms to replace any lost revenue (World Bank, 1988). 7 Olofin (2001) refers to “Stabilization” as an attempt by the government to regulate the overall level of economic activity through definite measures or policies. Essentially, stabilization of the Nigerian economy is the core of macroeconomic stability. Usman (2008) in the 2nd Clement Isong annual memorial lecture said that “Macroeconomic stability yields greater benefits through higher rates of investment and educational attainment as expected rates of return can better be achieved in an environment of low inflation”. He postulated that “Prudent fiscal policy can help enhance factor productivity through the use of endogenous growth theory suggests that fiscal policy can either promote or retard economic growth by its impact on decisions regarding investment in physical and human capital, increased spending on education, health, infrastructure, research and development can boost long-term growth”. Therefore, a concerted effort to institutionalize fiscal policy operations towards achieving macroeconomic stability would eliminate or minimize public sector deficit (Itsede, 2003). To survive and restore sustainable growth and development, Nigeria must ensure sound fiscal discipline that would aid the attainment of macroeconomic stability. Therefore, the forgoing problems make raising the following conceptual and policy questions a necessary exercise: What are the effects of fiscal policy measures (fiscal spending) on the macroeconomic stability indices (GDP growth rate and inflation rate)? How productive is the fiscal policy instruments? And what are the channels 8 through which the impact of fiscal policy measures (expenditure policy) get transmitted within the economy? Pursuit of these issues leads to thorough understanding of fiscal institutions with a careful analysis of the economic principles which underlie budget policy. 1.3 OBJECTIVES OF THE STUDY Broadly, this study seeks to assess the impact of fiscal policy measures (fiscal spending) on macroeconomic stability indices (such as output and consumer price index) in Nigeria. To achieve this, the following specific objectives are to be pursued: (1) Examining the trends of the fiscal operations (expenditure programmes) in the Nigerian economy (1970-2007); (2) Investigating the effect of public expenditure on GDP growth rate and inflation rate in Nigeria; and (3) Identifying the channels through which the effect of fiscal policy measures (expenditure policy) is transmitted in the Nigerian economy. 1.4 JUSTIFICATION FOR THE STUDY Nigeria’s economic performance in the two decades prior to economic reforms was generally poor. Over the period 1992 to 2002, annual GDP growth had averaged about 2.25 percent. With an estimated population growth of 2.80 percent per annum, this implied a contraction in per capita GDP over the years that had resulted in a 9 deterioration of living standards for most citizens. Inflation levels were high averaging about 28.94 percent per annum over the same period. By 1999, most of Nigeria’s human development indicators were worse than, or comparable to, that of any other least developed country (Okonjo-Iweala and Osafo-Kwaako, 2007). Public expenditure profile is highly oil-dependent (Iwayemi, 2009). The Federal, State and local governments that derive the bulk of their revenues from what they get from the Federation Account, budget on the basis of what the price of oil and the volume of oil production are expected to be in the budget year. Consequently, whenever the price or volume assumptions behind the budget turns out to be inaccurate, government experiences serious fiscal disequilibria either in the form of sharp fiscal contraction or overspending. Ariyo (1993) provided an assessment of the sustainability of fiscal deficit in Nigeria between 1970 and 1990. Fiscal policy should be conducted so as to satisfy potentially conflicting policy objectives. Efficient expenditure policy or resource allocation among private and public uses was to be based on a full employment level of output while leaving it to the stabilization branch-acting through tax and transfer measures-to ensure that this level of output is provided. In the case of recession, this procedure will obviate calling for additional expenditures to generate a higher level of employment, if such use of 10 resources would be undesirable at full employment. Under inflationary conditions, it will avoid cutbacks in programmes merely to restrain demand. Although the public sector should contribute its share when expansion or restraint in the total level of expenditure is needed, there is no good reason why the entire adjustment should be in that sector. Priority therefore goes to the tax-adjustment route. Pairing the tax instrument with the stabilization and the expenditure instrument with the allocation target has much merit in principle but must be qualified in practice (Musgrave and Musgrave, 2004). Government expenditure should serve as a form of compensatory financing which implies that when the economy is in a depression and undesirable consequences such as increased unemployment sets in, it needs some compensatory financing to pull it out of depression either by way of increasing government expenditure or reduction in taxes or a combination of both. On the other hand, when the economy is in a boom and inflation among other ills threatens, the government would need to apply necessary breaks on the economy, dampening the boom effect either by reducing direct government expenditure or increasing taxes. This in a nutshell sums up the basic principle involved in conventional government fiscal policy control and how they are expected to work (Olofin, 2001). 11 Public expenditure issues have risen to the top of the agenda of international public finance since the 1980s. Irresponsible expenditure in unproductive activities had stunted growth- this fell in real terms from 4.7 percent in 1991 to 1 percent in 1994 and 2.2 percent in 1995 and to 3.3 percent in 1996. The excess or irresponsible public expenditure has been blamed in good part for the assortment of ills that beset the economy in the 1980s, over-spending leading to over-indebtedness while overindebtedness in turn led to the debt crisis beginning in 1982. Today, these issues occupy the centre stage in the massive adjustment programmes in many developing nations and the reform programmes sweeping Eastern Europe. Public expenditure can simply be seen as the absorption of resource by the public sector (Anyanwu, 1997). On the other hand, public expenditure programming is a comprehensive set of expenditure policy measures designed to achieve a given set of macroeconomic goals, including the restoration of equilibrium between aggregate domestic demand and supply (IMF Institute, 1993). In addressing the issue of fiscal policy and macroeconomic stability, most studies have been carried out on the effectiveness of fiscal policy on macroeconomic variables in Nigeria. Hence, this study is necessitated by the poor performance of macroeconomic stability indicators before, during and after the Structural Adjustment Programmes (SAP) that was introduced in 1986. This study also differs considerably 12 from other studies by developing a small macro econometric model of the Nigerian economy using stochastic equations. Therefore, the structural form of Barro Endogenous Growth Model would be employed to show the relationship between the macroeconomic variables (output, inflation rate, for the purpose of this study) and fiscal policy instruments (government revenue and expenditure) and monetary policy variable proxy by money supply. 1.5 SCOPE OF THE STUDY This study will focus on the effect of fiscal policy and macroeconomic stability on the Nigerian economy over the period spanning 1970-2007. The choice of the period is as a result of data availability and this helps to capture the various fiscal regimes under the different government regimes experienced in Nigeria. Also, this has being informed by the availability of uniform time series data on the variables of interest to the study. Annual time series data will be employed by this study to conduct the investigation. 1.6 METHODOLOGY This study employs secondary data. These were sourced from the various issues of the publications of the Central Bank of Nigeria (CBN) such as Statistical Bulletin, Bullion, Economics and Financial Review and CBN’s Annual Report and Statement of Accounts for various years. Also, other relevant publications from the Federation 13 Ministry of Finance, Federal Office of Statistics, World Bank, IMF Institutes and elibrary were used as sources for data. Therefore, with the use of time series data, the research work employed the methodology which tests for stationarity and co-integration as well as error correction model (ECM). 1.7 PLAN OF THE STUDY The study would be structured into five chapters, with the first chapter being introductory; Chapter two reviews the literature and brief overview on fiscal policy and macroeconomic stability as well as its policy implications for the Nigerian economy; The third chapter devolves on the theoretical framework and methodological issues; The fourth chapter specifies the empirical models and the results coming from the analyses were discussed in the chapter; and The fifth chapter concludes the study with the summary of findings, policy recommendations and suggestion for further research. 14 CHAPTER TWO LITERATURE REVIEW 2.1 THEORETICAL REVIEW Fiscal policy involves the use of taxes and changes in government expenditure to influence the level of economic activity. On the the hand, monetary policy is concerned with the use of changes in money supply and/or interest rates to influence the level of economic activity (Ekpo, 2003). Fiscal and monetary policies are inextricably linked in macroeconomic management as development in one sector directly affects developments in the other. Undoubtedly, fiscal policy is central to the health of any economy, as government’s power to tax and to spend affects the disposable income of citizens and corporations, as well as the general business climate (Okonjo-Iweala, 2003). Fiscal policy is that part of government policy concerning the raising of revenue through taxation and other means and deciding on the level and pattern of expenditure for the purpose of influencing economic activities or attaining some desirable macroeconomic goals. In essence, the primary objective of fiscal policy is to balance the use of resources of the public and private sectors and, by so doing, to avoid inflation, unemployment, balance of payment pressures, and income inequity 15 (Anyanwu, 1997). To attain these objectives, budget must be seen as exhibiting certain features. It is a plan (a financial plan of operation), it is for a fixed period, it must be an authorization to collect revenue and incur expenditure, it must be a mechanism of control of both revenue and expenditure, and it must be objective-oriented. On a broader basis, the budget is not only an instrument of economic and social policies but also as planning tool, instrument for coordination, and an instrument for communication. Therefore, a good budget requires comprehensiveness, a meaningful presentation of the state of budgetary balance and an appropriate grouping of expenditure items (Anyanwu, 1997). There are thus two sides to the effects of the public budget on economic growth. On the one side, there is concern with the impact of taxation upon private capital formation, but on the other, and no less important, there is the strategic contribution made by capital formation in the public sector (Musgrave and Musgrave, 2004). A history of fiscal policy in recent decades cannot be written in a few pages. Indeed, it cannot be undertaken without also examining the changing performance and structure of the economy at large, and without giving equal time to monetary policy as partner in the conduct of stabilization. Nevertheless, the changing role and tasks of fiscal policy have become apparent even from this cursory survey. Bursting on the scene in the great depression of the thirties, fiscal policy had its heyday in the war 16 economy of the forties and once more came into its own in the earlier half of the sixties. Thereafter, the problems of stagflation arose, greatly complicating the task of stabilization by aggregate demand management, be it fiscal or monetary in approach. While the danger of rapid inflation had abated and a reasonable high level of employment had been secured, the trade repercussions of a sustained budget deficit continued, and a faulty mix of stabilization policy remained to be corrected (Musgrave and Musgrave, 2004). A major challenge for the Nigeria economy was its macroeconomic volatility driven largely by external terms of trade shocks and the country’s large reliance on oil export earnings. By some measures, Nigeria’s economy ranked among the most volatile in the world for the period 1960 to 2000 (World Bank, 2003). Public expenditures also closely followed current revenues, implying fluctuations in oil earnings were transferred directly into the domestic economy. Fluctuations in public expenditure reflected both the over-reliance on oil earnings and weak fiscal discipline by previous governments. Volatile fiscal spending also tended to cause real exchange rate volatility. In particular, fiscal expansions financed by oil revenues often resulted in domestic currency appreciation, creating Dutch-disease concerns and reducing competitiveness of the non-oil economy (Barnett and Ossowski, 2002). 17 Public expenditure, while stressing the end product, is designed to consider the pursuit of policy objectives of government in light of all economic costs of the programmes. Public expenditure programmes stress the relationship between various outputs and the inputs necessary to produce them, facilitating the use of techniques to analyze alternative programmes that will attain the goals and various alternative means of implementing them. This approach seeks to be all-inclusive, recognizing all contributions that the activity makes and all costs incurred, regardless of organizational structure (Due, 1968). The correct measure of public expenditure is therefore an important prerequisite for macroeconomic management. How the public expenditure is measured has an important bearing on an analysis of the macroeconomic implications of deficits (Fischer and Easterly, 1990). 2.2 REVIEW OF EMPIRICAL LITERATURE This sub-section presents a review of the empirical literatures on the linkage between fiscal policy and the macroeconomic stability. The debate on fiscal policy measures in developing countries for sustainable development, especially Nigeria, is not a new issue, as there are studies that have examined it. Sloman (1995) ascribed two main roles to fiscal policy. The first was to remove any deflationary or inflationary gap, that is, to prevent the occurrence of fundamental disequilibrium in the economy. 18 The second role was to smoothen out the fluctuations in the economy associated with the trade cycle. This would involve reducing government expenditure or raising taxes. Prasad and others (2003) posited that there is now overwhelming evidence that pro-cyclical macroeconomic policies and pro-cyclical financial markets have not encouraged growth; they have in fact increased growth volatility in developing countries that have integrated to a larger extent in international financial markets. This has generated a renewed but still incomplete interest in the role that counter-cyclical macroeconomic policies can play in smoothing out, that is, in reducing the intensity of business cycles in the developing world. At the same time, since the Asian crisis, recognition has grown that liberalized capital accounts and financial markets tend to generate excessively risky private sector balance sheets, and that an excessive reliance on short-term external financing enhances the risks of currency crises. Preventive (prudential) macroeconomic and financial policies, which aim to avoid the accumulation of unsustainable public and private sector debts and balance sheets during periods of financial euphoria, have thus become part of the standard recipe since the Asian crisis. This represents, however, only a partial return to a countercyclical macroeconomic framework, for no equally strong consensus has yet emerged on the role of expansionary policies in facilitating recovery from crises. 19 Empirically, a number of studies have investigated the effect of government infrastructure investments on private sector productivity and growth. Using time series data for the United States, Siegel (1976) reported significant and positive values for the elasticity of public infrastructure investment and growth on the order of 0.3 to 0.4. Smith (1978) estimated an elasticity of 0.45 from their cross sectional data on nine OECD countries. He also studied 38 developing countries in 1985 using data covering the period 1980-84 and found that capital expenditure on infrastructure had a significant positive impact on output growth. Teriba and Ajayi (1975) studied the effects of fiscal policy on macro economic variables between October 1967 and May/June 1969. In their study, they discovered that government expenditure as well as fiscal deficit has a negative impact on both inflation and balance of payment. In the case of economic recession and unemployment, the two fiscal policy variables were highly effective to restore them back to equilibrium. Omoruyi (2000) in his study showed that the major cause of macroeconomic instability and low growth in national output were the unsustainable level of fiscal deficits, financed through borrowing from the banking system and poor management of deficit finance which gave little attention to the heavy scheduled debt service obligations. He highlighted that a prudent fiscal policy can contribute to the 20 achievement of macroeconomic stability and growth. However, deficit financing by borrowing from the banking system and poor management of deficit finance can also lead to instability and poor economic performance. Oyejide (1972) believed that rapid economic development is tied to a rapid rate of capital formation and he demonstrated with the aid of data that the methods of financing government deficit in Nigeria have been inflationary. To him, deficit financing may be defined as an increase in the amount of money in circulation where such an excess results from a conscious governmental policy designed to encourage economic activities which would otherwise not have taken place. He said further that deficit financing could be defined as domestic credit creation, which is not offset, by increased taxation, more restrictive bank credit policy and similar deflationary measure. He explained that the most obvious measure of deficit financing is the fiscal deficit on current account, which represents the gap between current expenditure and current revenue. Oyejide explained further in his analysis that fiscal deficit of the government have been finance by drawing upon past and current savings of the economy, foreign assistance and increase simply by borrowing from the banking system. He formulated a regression model with the view to establishing the theoretical relationship between money supply and government expenditure and to be able to quantify the domestic 21 price level, deficit and the rate of capital formation. He concluded that the policy of deficit financing in Nigeria gained strength rapidly between 1957 and 1970. The policy was used as a means of financing capital formation for economic development and was accompanied by a phenomenal increased in the domestic price level, even though the policy of deficit financing also encouraged the process of capital formation as listed in pre-war period. The policy implication, he said, is that in a less developed country, sustained growth of deficit financing can hardly take place without some amount of inflation. Therefore, judging from the existing literature, there seems to be economic problems of stabilization and this requires solution of the macroeconomic disequilibrium phenomenon in Nigeria. Indeed, it is desirable to undertake an assessment of the impact of the fiscal policy measures (expenditure policy) on macroeconomic stability indicators (such as output and inflation rate) in order to provide a guide to the restructuring and coordination of fiscal policy instruments as well as monetary policy measures proxy by money supply on the macroeconomy. 2.3 FISCAL POLICY AND MACROECONOMIC STABILITY 2.3.1 Review of Basic Concepts Macroeconomics is the study of a whole economy. In the study, we are interested in the determination of broad aggregate in the economy such as national 22 output, inflation, money supply, unemployment, balance of payment etc. The present day Macroeconomics has its origin in John Maynard Keynes (1936), in his “General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money”. Keynes repudiated traditional and Orthodox economics which had been built up over a century and which dominated economic thought and policy before and during the Great Depression (see Jhingan, 2001) for its instability to tackle the prevailing problems of unemployment and chronic inflation in Great Britain and USA, particularly in 1930. The main premises of the neoclassical economists (such as Mill, J. S., Alfred Marshall, A. C. Pigou, J. B. Say, etc.) are that market works and price signals bring about the necessary adjustment in the economy in response to economic changes. That is, full-employment of labour, output and price stability would result from the interaction of aggregate supply of labour and aggregate demand for labour such that full employment output generally would be produced and purchased. Thus, market forces of demand and supply generally would ensure equilibrium in the economy and that in the line with marginal physical theory and pricing of inputs, the income distribution would reflect in labour and other inputs’ productivity. Keynes on the other hand, argued that once an economy had moved into a situation of high unemployment, the price mechanism would not work to adjust the economy back to the level of employment. Keynes posited that the government could 23 only raise the demand for output by increasing only government expenditure. Once demand has increased, firms will supply more output and employed more people which would lead to higher demand. In the light of Keynesian revolutionary thinking, they advocated the necessity of government management of the economy by the use of fiscal policy to achieve macroeconomic objectives. Thus, Keynesian economics is sometimes called “demand side economics” because of the central role that the demand (or expenditure) plays in the analysis. However, the theory of increasing government fiscal activities which is based on two schools of thought need to be considered because of the interventionist economy. The first school led by Adolph Wagner (1890), postulated that the expansion in government fiscal activities was as a result of economics, technical and social development. The second school of thought led by Peacock and Wiseman (1961) argued that the expansion was as a result of social upheavals notably wars, epidemic, etc. Considering the proposition by Peacock and Wiseman, it could be seen that it cannot play much significant relevance for our study relative to that of Wagner (1890 and 1893). According to Wagner (1893), there are inherent tendencies for the activities of governments to increase both intensively and extensively. He attributes this to the 24 traditional functions of the State in providing and expanding sphere of public goods. Thus, the traditional functions given by Adolph Wagner’s theory are: the rapidly changing role of the government and the intervention of the state in free market in order to ensure the re-distributive justice (see Bhatia, 2002). The afore-mentioned brought about functional relationship between the growth of an economy and the growth of government expenditure such that the latter grows faster than the former. Nitti (1903) concluded with empirical evidence that the ‘Law of increasing Government activities’ was not only applicable to Germany as posited by Wagner, but to various governments which differed widely from each other. Wagner also distinguished functional government expenditure, which were administrative, economic, services as well as social and community services. Whereas, Enwenze (1974) in his own contribution reported that developing countries tend to increase their expenditure on administration as well as social and community services. However, Lotz (1970), Philips (1971), and Faforiji (1984) did not address the components of total expenditure. Thus, none of the above studies did address the concept of transfer payments. A possible justifiable argument for the omission could be that deficit financing accumulation of which is public debt overhang which transfer payments is directed at servicing was relatively at its low ebb as at that time. 25 In fact, the debt services component of total expenditure relatively to its nondebt component has become a topical issue in Nigeria and other LDCs. The rationale behind this has been the economic implication of relationship. A situation whereby the debt component of total expenditure is substantial will no doubt impede economic growth. This will be better appreciated if we realize that the government through the public sector is the chief agent of economic development in most LDCs including Nigeria. However, there was no clear clarification of the concept that Wagner employed. This made it rather difficult to ascertain whether he was referring to an increase in: (i) absolute level of public expenditure; (ii) proportion of public sector to the total economy, and (iii) the ratio of government expenditure to Gross Domestic Product (GDP). Since any interpretation given to the concept has influenced on whatever results obtained, hence, we adopted the third option with some variation for the purpose of our study. This is because option (i) did not address inflation, which could bias the absolute figures, while option (ii) could run into the difficulty of qualification. However, option (iii) is not only easier but also addresses the shortcomings of the other options. 26 Theoretically, it is argued that total government expenditure adjusts more rapidly than revenue to price level variation in such a way that bank-financed budgetary deficit set in (Aghevli and Khan, 1970). There are several reasons why government expenditure in any developing country (Nigeria is not exempted) is expected to adjust faster than revenue in the face of nominal income increase arising from inflation, and they include: the fact that even if the government in any developing country fully recognizes the need to control its expenditure during period of inflation and the country’s low nominal income elasticities and long lags in tax collection. It should be noted that Aghevli and Khan (1977), using the above reasons developed a model to study Brazil, Columbia, the Dominican Republic, and Thailand ( all developing countries) as closed economies. It is our expectation that these reasons could also be applied in Nigeria as an open economy thereby creating a variant of Aghevli and Khan Model. 2.3.2 Evidence from Developed Nations This sub-section basically serves as an insight into various arguments, views and empirical works that have been developed for fiscal policy analysis both in developed and developing countries. 27 Empirically, a number of studies have examined the impact of public infrastructure investments on private sector productivity and growth. Barro (1979), in the analysis of Swedish data, found that infrastructure investment has a significant productivity effect, leading to lower labour requirements for firms. However, Chowdhury (1991) found no statistically significant relation between infrastructure capital and output growth in the United States. Using data from American States, Mundell (1962), and Jorgen (1973) reported positive, but smaller, elasticity on the order of 0.15 to 0.5. Schlessinger (1986) adopted a more disaggregate approach, drawing on data from American States covering the period 1956-86, to look at the effect of public infrastructure investment not on aggregate productivity but rather on productivity in 12 different two-digit industries. In theory, this approach would allow for the possibility that public infrastructure investment is important for some industries but not other, which could explain the low aggregate elasticity found in the studies. They found that infrastructure investment has a positive effect on total factor productivity in each of manufacturing industries they study, but that the elasticity tends to be small. Asegaer (1988), however, using data on Mexican industries between 1970 and 1983, found that public infrastructure spending has a significant, positive, but small effect on output. 28 In another study, the impact of tax incentives (fiscal instrument) on investment also shed some light on the impact of tax policy on the investment decision. Snyder (1970) review a number of studies that have attempted to analyze the impact of tax incentives for investors in Brazil, Malaysia, Mexico, Korea, the ASIAN Countries as a group, the Philippines, Sri Lanka, Columbia and Thailand. They found that most of these studies concluded that tax incentives in place in these countries do not stimulate new investment but instead provide windfalls for investments that would have occurred anyway. Vashist (1991) examined the impact of tax incentives (specifically the rebate of direct and indirect taxes on exports, investment tax credits, and tax holiday) in Korea and found that tax policy accounted for less than one tenth of Korea’s growth between 1962 and 1982. David and Ansariu (1995) carried out a number of studies on the impact of tax incentives typically resulted in more lost revenue than additional investment, and that the elimination of non-tax disincentive to investment. For example, a lack of adequate infrastructure would do more to stimulate investment than would tax incentives. In addition, Handa (1970) examined the extent to which the pattern of foreign investment in American States was affected by their corporate income tax rates. He found that the higher a states corporate income tax rate, the high is the share of investment that originates from firms located in countries that grant domestic tax 29 credits for taxes paid to American States, and suggesting that states taxes significantly affected the pattern of foreign direct investment. In the study of Darrat (1986), he worked with cross section data from a sample of 20 countries spanning a range of per capital national incomes. He found that tax ratio has significant, negative impact on growth. However, when he included the growth rate of gross domestic investment and the labor force among the independent variables, he found that the coefficient on the tax ratio, while still negative, is significant only at the 10 per cent level. He did not include initial per capital GDP as a control variable. However, when he divided his sample into ten higher-income and ten lower-income countries, he found that the tax ratio had a significant, negative impact on growth rates in low income countries but not in the higher-income countries. For the sample as a whole, he also found that the tax ratio had a significant, negative effect on the growth rate of investment, although among individual categories of taxes only domestic taxes on goods and services and not corporate taxes, personal income taxes, or taxes on foreign trade had a significant effect. He found that only social security taxes have a significant (negative) effect on labor force growth and productivity growth. The negative effect of social security taxes may be due to more generous pension benefits including earlier retirement. 30 Shaw (1986) used data from 107 countries over period 1970-85 and found that changes in the aggregate average tax rate did not have a significant effect on output growth. He did find, however, that increase in the aggregate average tax rate had a negative effect on the marginal productivity of investment in physical capital and to a lesser extent, on labour. Jorgen (1973) used cross-sectional data based on period averages for 1970-73 and observed that the marginal rate of income tax (calculated by regressing a time series data of income tax revenues on a time series data of GDP for each country) had a significant, negative effect on per capita GDP growth, but that no other tax measures did. He did find those income taxes, the ratio of domestic taxes to GDP, and the ratio of domestic taxes to consumption plus investment had significant, negative effects on the share of private investment in GDP. 2.3.3 Evidence from Developing Nations Chowdhury (1991) suggested that growth in government expenditure has a greater impact on changes in nominal income than the growth in monetary base. He added that the effect of a change in the growth rate of government expenditure on nominal income last for a relatively longer period of time, compared to a change in the growth rate of monetary base. Moreover, the magnitude of the effect is also greater 31 in case of the fiscal policy variable. The estimated equation was also found to exhibit structural stability implying its usefulness for the purpose of forecasting and policy analysis. Blejer and Khan (1984) provided a comprehensive attempt at understanding the impact of different types of public investment expenditure on private investment and growth. This study confirmed the hypothesis that investment on infrastructure has a positive effect on private investment and economic growth, whereas a noninfrastructure investment has a negative impact. As was observed by Chibber and Danlami (1990), the results of this study were not conclusive because of the absence of a detailed breakdown of public investment expenditure. Manas-Anton (1986) in his study observed the effect of income taxes on per capital output growth, using a sample of period average data for 39 developing countries over the period of 1973-1982. He discovered that both the ratio of income taxes to GDP and the ratio of income taxes to total taxes collected had significant negative effect on per capita GDP. However, when he included each of the ratios of personal and corporate income taxes to total tax collections in his regression, he observed that while the coefficient on each remained negative neither was significant. Thus, while his results provided some indications that relevance on income taxes 32 tended to correlate with lower output growth, this relationship cannot asserted with confidence (see Packard 1966). 2.3.4 Evidence from Nigeria Ghosh (1972) supported the relative effectiveness of fiscal policy in an economy. He argued that budgetary policy has a significant effect on income, employment, and output in the long run, even if there is no new money in supply. Public debt is, in fact, as crucial as the stock of money. A rise in the growth of interestbearing debt would lead to a rise in the equilibrium growth of nominal income, without a corresponding rise in the rate of money expansion. Government debt is expansionary and balance budget multiplier can give the economy substantial leadway for growth. He further stated that fiscalists have a non-monetary theory of price. They put forward the view that money is not neutral. In fact, it is possible to change the rate of interest in several ways. The price of money, to a non-monetarist, is thought to be the rate of interest. Due to variations in velocity and output, moneyprice proportionality is not possible in the short run. The acceptance of Philips curve relation depicting a permanent trade-off between unemployment is clear indication of fiscalist proposition of non-neutrality of money. When it is difficult for monetary policy 33 to counteract short run cyclical fluctuations, fiscal policy may prove to be a better device for it has a shorter lag. It is not proper to rely simply on the central bank for controlling the money supply, which is incapable for solving macroeconomic imbalances. Ekeoku (1974) argued that the effective policy instruments in the system relative to the tax rates (that is, personal tax, company tax, and excise duties and others), is the government external borrowing. However, since government capital expenditure as a whole are usually financed by external loans, and government deficits are worsened by these capital expenditures, this may seems to deviate from prior expectations. A point to be clarified here is that only an aspect of total government expenditure is considered and a mere relative strength of the instruments, from the simulation, is being put forward. Thus, in the light of the results, it is expected that the government can bring about increases in the output of different sectors by adequately utilizing this policy instrument (fiscal policy). Gbosi (1995) pointed out that with particular reference to government finances available data indicated that there was a remarkable decline in government revenue for the period. This adversely affected execution of various economic and social programmes. The analysis also highlighted that the Nigeria economy performed fairly 34 well under the deregulation as oppose to regulation. This was seen in the impressive growth in real output under deregulation. Adeyeye and Fakiyesi (1980) regressed prices on money and government expenditure, and obtained a coefficient of 0.84, through which the price level was regressed on individual variable, they obtained no significant result. They concluded that the evidence supported their thesis that inflation in Nigeria is due to the factors of money supply and government expenditure. Madan (1961) made a strong case for fiscal policy because monetary expansion-contraction (brought about by monetary controls) may induce growth. This reason was strengthen by the belief that fiscal investment was much more powerful than monetary tools in the area control consumption and investment, which were the important components of the GDP. Others like Nwachukwu and Adeleke (1992) believed that despite the observed merit of fiscal policy, it should not be seen at the mutually exclusive but as complement policy to monetary policy. Ojo (1982) regressed the rate of inflation on both structural and monetary variables such as shift in demand, variability of exports, foreign exchange scarcity, excess demand, money supply and budget deficit. His useful conclusion is that neither 35 the monetarists nor the structuralists’ model is good enough to be able to explain completely the cause of inflation in Nigeria. Ndebbio(1998) established that an increase in money supply (M2) by 10% resulted in an increased in endogenous variables like government expenditure, government revenue and import, means annual growth rates stood at 23.9 per cent, 12.3 per cent and 9.3 per cent respectively. The result also established a two-way system in which simultaneously, fiscal deficit is caused by inflation and inflation is also caused by fiscal deficit. The simulated results of Ndebbio in the same study for Nigeria, confirmed the fact that government expenditure in less developed countries usually adjust faster than government revenue in the face of nominal income increase arising from inflation [Aghevli and Khan, 1977]. 2.3.5 Fiscal and Monetary Policies Practice in Nigeria Oil has turned Nigeria from revenue generating to a revenue sharing nation. This has led to immense difficulties in enshrining fiscal discipline at all levels of government. Given the underdeveloped nature of the country’s securities market, it is not surprising that monetary policies have consistently been ineffective in this environment of fiscal dominance. Given the fact that both monetary and fiscal policies impact on economic growth and development, it is not surprising that they are 36 entwined. Fiscal and monetary policies are inextricably linked in macroeconomic management as development in one sector directly affects developments in the other. Undoubtedly, fiscal policy is central to the health of any economy, as government’s power to tax and to spend affects the disposable income of citizens and corporations, as well as the general business climate (Ezeoha and Uche, 2006). In this regard, the interrelationship between fiscal spending and private sector performance is of paramount importance. On one hand, Government expenditure can provide an impulse for private sector growth, while on the other, it can be harmful if it results in budget deficits and leads to competition for scarce financial resources from the banking sector as the government seeks to finance the deficit. In such circumstances, the crowding out of the private sector by the Government sector can outweigh any short-term benefits of an expansionary fiscal policy. The key to all theses therefore lies in striking a good balance in fiscal management. Having enough expenditure outlays to meet the needs of Government and support growth, but not so much as to deny the private sector the resources it needs to invest and develop (Okonjo-Iweala, 2003). Furthermore, Government fiscal recklessness resulting in deficit financing can also cause inflation, which contradicts the fundamental monetary policy objective of price stability. This has the potentials of destabilizing the macroeconomic environment thereby retarding economic productivity and development. 37 There is no doubt that the failure of government fiscal policies, rather than the failure of monetary policies, is the main reason why most of the past developmental programmes undertaken by the Government has come to naught (Ezeoha and Uche, 2006). This is so despite the fact that the conventional theory tends to suggest that a central bank uses monetary policy instruments to predominantly influence the general price level. This broadly translates into the monetary theory of the price level, which implies monetary dominance in the determination of the price level. In reality however, fiscal policy is sometimes dominant. This is especially so in countries with underdeveloped securities markets which essentially limit the ability of a central bank to effectively develop and use monetary policy instruments. This has been explicitly explained by Oyejide (2003) thus, “In principle fiscal dominance occurs when fiscal policy is set exogenously to monetary policy in an environment where there is a limit to the amount of government debt that can be held by the public. Hence if the inter-temporal budget constraint must be satisfied, fiscal deficits would have to be magnetized, sooner or later. In fact when the size of the financial system is small relative to the size of the fiscal deficits, a central bank may have no choice but to magnetize the deficits. Thus, in countries with shallow financial systems, monetary policy is the reverse side of the coin of fiscal policy and can only play an accommodative role. In such low income countries, government securities 38 markets are underdeveloped and central banks do not hold sufficient amounts of tangible securities and the central bank’s lack of suitable and adequate instruments of monetary control constitutes one of the factors that induce fiscal dominance. Where fiscal dominance applies, the country’s economic policy is only as good as its fiscal policy and institutionalized central bank independence may not necessarily bring about an independent monetary policy”. There is no doubt that Nigeria clearly meets all the requirements for fiscal dominance. In fact, concerns about the fiscal dominance nature of the country, especially the underdeveloped securities market predates the advent of central banking in Nigeria. Monetary activities in the country have been based on the control of inflation and the need to create a stable macroeconomic environment. Government has, in their desperate measure to control inflation undertaken monetary policies that have had disastrous long-term consequences. For instance the sudden change of currency colour during the Buhari regime in the 1980s. This no doubt reduced the amount of money in circulation and thus impacted on inflation. However, it led to a major loss of confidence in the Naira and damaged its ability to serve as a regional currency for West Africa. This was because huge Naira reserves held outside the country, especially in the West African sub-region, were essentially demonetized in the process (Uche, 2001). The failure of the monetary policy variants to engender the 39 stable macroeconomic environment necessary for economic growth and development in the face of fiscal dominance led to the adoption of The Structural Adjustment Programme (SAP) in 1986. Undoubtedly, the most important factor that has impacted on both the level and character of fiscal policy in the country is the advent of oil as the main stay of our economy. Over dependence on oil resources and the volatility of the oil market has been transmitted to the rest of the economy. This has been explained by Baunsgaard (2003) thus: “With about 75 percent of revenue from oil and gas, fiscal policy in Nigeria has been heavily influenced by oil driven volatility impacting both revenue and expenditure. Since 1970, both revenue and expenditure have been very volatile while increasing over time. In periods with high oil prices, such as in 1979- 82, 1991-92, and more recently in 2000-02, revenue and expenditure have increased sharply. This has typically been followed by the scaling back of expenditure as oil prices subsequently decline, though at times with a lag. The implications of such boom-bust fiscal policies include the transmission of oil volatility to the rest of the economy as well as disruptions to the stable provision of government services. This has added to the failure over the years of public spending, neither facilitating the diversification and growth of the non-oil sector nor reducing poverty”. 40 Aside from the negative impact of the transmission of oil volatility to the rest of the economy, the enormous oil windfalls have helped alter the country’s revenue allocation formula by facilitating the change in focus from revenue generation to revenue sharing. The implication of this is that Nigeria has essentially become a rentier state where sharing of assets is based not on economic justification but political control. The consequence has been the development and growth of an unproductive civil service, proliferation of local governments, states and government agencies and institutions with doubtful productivity value (Ezeoha and Uche, 2006). 2.4 IMPLEMENTATION OF ECONOMIC REFORMS IN NIGERIA Nigeria’s public revenues structure has been dominated by oil revenues since the early 1970s. Oil revenues rose sharply from 26.3% of total revenues in 1970 to reach 82.1% in 1974. The share of oil in government revenues has remained at more than four out of every five naira of government revenue inflow (Iwayemi, 2009). Rapid oil revenue inflows, which accrued largely to the government, underpinned rapid expansion in government fiscal operations. Also of important is the legacy of the military governments, whose philosophy was more centrist/unitary than federalist, has compounded the inefficiencies and inequity in fiscal governance and fiscal sustainability. 41 The issue of fiscal inequalities has generated considerable debate and tension among the federating units. The issue has been highly contentious in the country because the bulk of the intergovernmental transfers are derived from taxation of nonrenewable natural resources that are often concentrated in a few sections of the country because of the inequity in the political redistribution of such centrally collected revenues. Most often, the ‘cake-sharing’ grossly undervalues the serious impact of the negative externalities of natural resource production on the economy and society of the producing areas. In addition, and of importance is the politics of revenue sharing arrangements which neglects or abstracts from the negative incentive effects of intergovernmental transfers on fiscal sustainability of the sub- the transfer system negatively affect fiscal performance at both national and sub-national units, and Nigeria is a case in point. Intergovernmental transfer arrangement is at the heart of Nigeria’s fiscal federalism. Thus, the impact of the of the neglect of the incentive problems created among the different jurisdiction which creates significant economic inefficiency at the expedience of satisfying the narrower political objectives of the dominant ethnic groups should be of analytical and policy interest (Iwayemi, 2009). The current revenue sharing system produces inefficient fiscal and economic outcomes (Iwayemi, 2009). This is hardly contentious among analysts. The design of a more robust revenue sharing system and efficient intergovernmental transfer 42 mechanism is central to long term economic and political stability of federal systems especially in natural resource dependent developing countries. Two issues are often considered important in the design of a robust revenue sharing arrangement. First, the transfer system should provide a risk-pooling mechanism for states or region in the federal system as they alternately experience economic booms and shocks. Economic theory suggests that such risk-sharing mechanism is welfare improving. Second, given that horizontal and vertical inequalities characterize most federal system, such transfers are essential in minimizing inter-state social and economic disparities and support weak fiscal bases. However, weak fiscal bases are not necessarily due to low revenue generating capacity of states and local governments. In Nigeria, the key causal factor efficiency and equity reasons, such free-rider and opportunistic behavior should be minimized, and better still, discouraged (Iwayemi, 2009). 2.4.1 Fiscal Federalism Reform The advent of oil has eroded fiscal federalism systematically in favour of fiscal centralism. The demand for resource control has intensified against the distributional inequity in the sharing of oil rent which has not really favoured the oil producing communities and their lack of basic infrastructure and general state of underdevelopment (Iwayemi, 2009). Oil exploitation has yielded enormous revenue 43 gains to non-oil producing regions which have not been exposed to the devastating environmental externalities of oil and gas communities despite the social and environmental effects of petroleum exploitation and their economic deprivation for almost four decades has and continues to fuel the destabilizing tendencies in the federation. The federal grip over access of the oil the main source of government revenues has been at hearts of Nigeria politics, economics and governance in the last three decades (Phillips, 1991; Ikporukpo, 1996; and Onimode, 2001). More importantly, the political process has absorbed a large amount of oil resources to satisfy conflicting regional and ethnic interests in an underdeveloped economy operating a psendo federal political system. The creation of new states funded from oil wealth became a political solution to appease a people with rising expectations about their share of the “national oil cake.” The financial implications of their administrative and infrastructure development combined with the activist political and social roles of the government have systematically imposed politically sensitive burdens on public finances (Iwayemi, 2009). The major problems identified with the incentive implications of the Nigerian fiscal system are: first, the lack of fiscal correspondence between revenue generation and expenditure at the sub-national levels. So, public spending is not connected in any 44 significant way to internally generated revenue based on local tax effort encourages most state and local governments to believe they do not face a hard budget constraint. Second is the fiscal behaviour at the sub-national level which is highly procyclical and is determined in most states and local government by tax revenue sharing. The sharing of Excess Crude Oil Revenues and the bi-monthly sharing of revenues from the Federation Account continues to pose significant monetary policy challenges for the Central Bank of Nigeria whose key mandates is to keep inflation in check. Thirdly, the issues of optimal mix of taxation, greater efficiency in expenditure and procurement becomes unimportant for the governments when the bulk of their revenue for a tier of government comes from transfer from other tiers, fiscal efficiency will be of low priority. Finally, there is lack of equity and fairness and inefficiency associated with the politically redistributed revenues when the formula is loaded with factors which reflect the preferences of those states with weak tax effort. These factors that are used in sharing revenue have entrenched the imbalance and cheap oil revenues from have encouraged poor tax compliance, weak tax base and tax administration. This has served as a disincentive to fiscal prudence and sustainability (Iwayemi, 2009). 45 Given the foregoing, there are problems associated with revenue sharing that generate significant Pareto inferior revenue distribution with considerable impact on political and economic stability. It is therefore important to explore how some of these emerging problems can be addressed. Thus, there is need to implement Paretoimproving revenue allocation policy. At Pareto-optimal, the revenue allocation formula will provide incentives for any tier of government that want to exert more tax effort to generate more revenues in their specific areas of jurisdiction rather than being a freerider as is currently the case. The revenue sharing problem should be reformulated as a classic principal-agent paradigm under moral hazard conditions (Iwayemi, 2009). Also, the government should overhaul the Nigeria’s fractious revenue sharing arrangement to minimize the anomalies identified in the system. And more importantly, properly design an inter-governmental transfer system that compensates federating units for tax effort are necessary (sine qua non) for both long-term political and economic stability. The bearing of such an approach to fiscal transfer on fiscal prudence, sustainability and political stability of the federation and social harmony should be evident. Enough of opportunistic fiscal behaviour otherwise the ultimate economic and social outcomes may be against the long-term of the federation (Iwayemi, 2009). 46 Therefore, governments are expected to address resource distribution inequity and the associated fiscal imbalances in the environment. Also, they must use transfers to induce some sub-national units to internalize social and economic externalities through the adoption of certain socio-economic programmes, such as the Millennium Development Goals, education, health, environmental quality, and infrastructure. 2.4.2 Macroeconomic Reform The main function of government either democratic or military is to protect and promote the welfare of its citizens. In performing this, government must choose the most suitable economic policy to pursue. Whatever form of the objectives that the government pursued, fiscal and monetary policies play a key role in the promotion of the government macroeconomic goals of promoting the welfare of its citizens. In his budget speech shortly before independence in 1960, the then Finance Minister, late Chief Festus Okotie-Eboh made it explicit that the financial and economic policies of government would be directed towards “the achievement and maintenance of the highest possible rate of increase in the standard of living” (CBN Annual Report, 1960). In 2006 Appropriation Bill, President Olusegun Obasanjo in his speech presented at the Joint Session of the National Assembly stipulated that the budget has been prepared in the context of a Medium-Term Expenditure Framework that looks at 47 projections for years 2007 and 2008 with a focus on “Building Physical and Human Infrastructure for Job Creation and Poverty Eradication”. In addition, the budget pays special attention to social safety nets, and to other important national priorities such as provision for the population census #9billion, modern voting and electoral equipment and techniques #55billion, cushioning the impact of public service reforms #50billlion, and provision for restructuring and monetising parastatals #50billion. The budget also explicitly provides #75billion to cushion the impact of petroleum prices which we expect will be matched by the states and local governments for a total of #150billion. Simply put the budget 2006 gives priority to investments in power, water, roads, security, education and health so that the basic elements needed to make life more comfortable for citizens and provide the essential building blocks for diversification of the economy can continue to be put in place. The budget continues our tradition of more careful and effective management of our financial resources paying due regard to the need to maintain macroeconomic stability and achieved a good fiscal stance in order to avoid unduly heating up the economy. Given the investments in infrastructure, and the relative macroeconomic stability, we expect strong GDP growth of 7% getting closer to our medium term target 48 of 10% per annum compared to the GDP growth of 6% for the year 2005. We expect the exchange rate to be relatively stable with some possibility of minor appreciation of the Naira even experiencing some nominal appreciation from about #132 to $1 in 2004, to #128 to $1 by the end of 2005. With regard to inflation, the objective is to maintain a prudent fiscal stance so that monetary policy will have a chance to work through CBN as it did under the 2004 budget to help bring inflation from the relatively high double digits now to about 9%. The CBN is designing an effective liquidity management system that will mop up excess liquidity and help maintain stability. According to President Umaru Musa Yar’Adua the reforms agenda constitute elements of a larger reform programme, the National Economic Empowerment and Development Strategy (NEEDS-2), and the pronouncement of 7-Point Agenda at the inception of his Administration in 2007. The NEEDS-2 focuses on poverty reduction through employment generation and wealth creation, promoting inclusive growth by concentrating on sectors where the poor and the vulnerable groups are dominant such as agriculture, small- and medium- scale enterprises, and informal sector operation. The Yar’Adua administration has thus focused on setting up the building blocks for a future acceleration of reform. It’s also keen to reach broad consensus on key decisions requiring a more consultative process. This approach holds the promise for more durable reforms. 49 2.4.3. The Reforms Agenda/Fiscal Strategies In order to enhance economic reform in Nigeria, Usman (2007) states the reasons why fiscal responsibility and public procurement legislations should be enacted in the economy. He posited that “fiscal responsibility legislation strengthens fiscal policy design and implementation, and changes from the tradition of short term fiscal perspective to medium/long term fiscal sustainability and Improve budgetary process”. On the other hand, he asserted that “public procurement legislation improves public sector spending behaviour, value for money, reduce corrupt practices and inefficiency, and track down public sector investment spending”. He further defined ‘fiscal rules’ in macroeconomic context, as institutional mechanisms that are intended to permanently shape fiscal policy design and implementation. Fiscal responsibility legislation has been implemented by different countries, thus: Alberta in 1990; Venezuela in 1999; Norway in 2001; Ecuador in 2002; Mexico in 2006 and Nigeria in 2007? The Fiscal Responsibility Bill (FRB) consists of 16 parts, but some of these are discussed in this subsection. Briefly, the medium-term fiscal framework contains- a macroeconomic framework setting out macroeconomic outlook for a medium term horizon (3 years), stating the underlying key assumptions for the 3year forecast, In-depth analysis and evaluation of the 3-year forecast. A fiscal strategy detailing- the government’s financial objectives, the government’s policy under the 50 medium term expenditure and revenue frameworks, and the fiscal risks. For the Annual Budget, the FRB states that, the medium-term fiscal framework shall be the basis for the annual budget, these consist of: medium term expenditure framework, medium term revenue framework, and medium term sector strategies. The key assumptions variables are: fiscal oil price rule, Inflation rate, Exchange rate, GDP growth rate, Target fiscal account balance and fiscal risk evaluation (Usman, 2007). The Public Procurement Bill is responsible for the monitoring and oversight of public procurement, and harmonising the existing government policies on procurement. The Act outlined in greater detail the procedures in government procurement and disposal of property, including the need to: Install due process, monitor and track down investment in public goods, maintain strict adherence to budget provisions by ministries, departments and agencies (MDA). Overall, the Bill and the Act are aimed at ensuring fiscal sustainability and quality of spending for economic growth (Usman, 2007). The macroeconomic reform packages embarked on by the immediate past administration had as its key objectives the need to provide macroeconomic stability for private sector growth, improve planning and implementation of government capital expenditures, increase public savings and reduce public debt (Babalola, 2007). The key policy measures introduced include prudent oil price-based fiscal rule, 51 improved implementation of government budgets, improved implementation of monetary policy by the Central Bank of Nigeria and greater coordination between fiscal and monetary authorities. A significant policy measure that achieved considerable success was an improved debt management system that led to Nigeria’s successful exit from Paris Club and London Club Debts through the issuance of par bonds, promissory notes, oil warrants, etc. On the domestic debt front, there were regular bond issuance programmes and contractor arrears and pension arrears issues were addressed. As at now, the savings from debt relief is being used for MDG-based programmes. At the Federal level, various legislative initiatives were embarked upon. The two significant ones as mentioned earlier were the Fiscal Responsibility Act and the Public Procurement Act. Overall, the aims of the two Acts were to ensure fiscal sustainability and quality of spending for economic growth (Babalola, 2007). The Fiscal Responsibility Act was particularly aimed at strengthening fiscal policy design and implementation, by moving from the tradition of short term fiscal perspective, to medium/long term fiscal sustainability, thereby improving the budgetary process. It is meant to ensure prudent management of the nation’s resources, ensure long-term macroeconomic stability, accountability and transparency in fiscal operations (Usman, 2007 and Babalola, 2007). 52 The Bill, as originally conceived by the Executive, was meant to apply to the three tiers of government in the conduct of their economic activities. The Bill as passed by the National Assembly, however, makes it applicable to only the Federal Government, with exceptions in the areas of oil-based fiscal rule, framework for debt management and public borrowing. These exceptions are equally applicable to the states and local governments. The provisions in respect of the Medium-Term Expenditure Framework (MTEF) and Fiscal Transparency and Accountability are not applicable to the States and Local Governments in the passed Bill (Usman, 2007 and Babalola, 2007). It is, however, settled that it is in the overall interest of public governance in Nigeria that all sub-national units adopt the features of these Acts and incorporate them in their own legislations (Babalola, 2007). The issue of fiscal coordination between the Federal and State Governments in Nigeria is of paramount important. Although the 1999 Constitution provides for fiscal Federalism, meaning that, States are independent in all areas of fiscal policy: revenue allocation; expenditure choices; and other financial decisions. The Constitution also charges Mr. President with stewardship of the Nation’s economy. To achieve this will require a relationship with States based on: transparency; adherence to the rule of law; and full cooperation between the three tiers of government in achieving 53 economic development and wealth creation, as well as macroeconomic stability (Usman, 2007). A number of major challenges hinder the attainment of the sound fiscal policy management in Nigeria. These include: lack of coordination among the three tiers of government; lack of agreement over broad macroeconomic objectives to be achieved; and the issue of management of oil windfall. Effectively, about 50 per cent of total revenue goes to State and Local Governments. This means that all tiers of governance have at their disposal considerable financial resources that determine fiscal policy in Nigeria. At this moment, it is important for all of us to realise that there is only ONE economy (Babalola, 2007). To achieve fiscal and macroeconomic coordination among the three tiers of government, there is need for adoption of fiscal responsibility legislation by all tiers of government, adherence to budget implementation, public procurement legislation, due process, accountability and transparency. At the Federal level, efforts are being made to include subnational governments in the process of setting the key assumptions underpinning the national budget. This is expected to engender a sense of ownership, commitment to decision outcome and instilling discipline at micro level. The National Economic Council (NEC) plays the coordinating function in the economy. NEC at its meeting on September 4, 2007 agreed to initiate and facilitate the passage 54 of similar legislations in each state. This would assist in integrating the states’ fiscal strategy into the overall fiscal framework, improve transmission mechanism of policy initiatives, increase policy feedback, accountability, transparency and due diligence, and enhance long run macroeconomic stability. The Debt Management Office (DMO), as regard coordination strategy, held a Sub-National Debt Management Workshop with Development Partners and State Governments in October 2007. This was part of DMO’s strategic focus to inculcate responsible debt management in all States of the federation. The main objective is to eventually have debt management offices in all the States of the federation. Also, the use of the Irrevocable Standing Payment Order (ISPO) that supports borrowing by the State Goovernments from the banking system has been stopped by President Umaru Musa Yar’Adua. There is a positive correlation between effective/good governance and development (Babalola, 2007). Nigeria has been recognised in a report by Goldman Sachs as one of the 11 countries in the world with the people and resources that have the potential of being one of the 20 biggest economies by the year 2020, hence the tag Vision 2020. To achieve this strategic objective, there is need for efforts aimed at: poverty reduction; instituting strategic national fiscal framework; development of national institutions; enhancing the human development agenda; investments in 55 education and health; and continuous focus on the millennium development goals (MDGs). 2.4.4 Reform Measures The central objective of the macroeconomic reform was to stabilize the Nigerian economy, to improve budgetary planning and execution, and to provide a platform for sustained economic diversification and non-oil growth. A major challenge was to de-link public expenditures from oil revenue earnings by introducing an appropriate fiscal rule. In addition, as has been the practice in other countries, the adoption of such a rule could enable the accumulation of government savings, which would be valuable, whether for precautionary reasons, for smoothening public expenditures or for ensuring intergenerational equity (Barnett and Ossowski, 2006; IMF 2005a). In the case of Nigeria, an oil price-based fiscal rule was introduced in which government expenditure was based on a prudent oil price benchmark. Any revenues that accumulated above the reference prices were saved in a special excess crude account. In recent years, government budgeting has been based on conservative oil prices of $25 per barrel in 2004, $30 per barrel in 2005, and $35 per barrel in 2006, despite higher realized prices of $38.3 and $54.2 in 2004 and 2005, respectively, and an estimated average price of $68 for 2006. Adoption of this rule has ensured that 56 government expenditures are de-linked from oil revenue earnings, thereby limiting the transmission of external shocks into the domestic economy. There was a marked improvement in the government’s fiscal balance, with the previous deficit of 3.5 percent of GDP in 2003 turning to consolidated surpluses of about 10 percent of GDP in 2004 and 11 percent of GDP in 2005 (Government of Nigeria and IMF, 2005b). Adoption of the fiscal rule also resulted in significant public savings for the government. Gross excess crude savings totaled about $6.35 billion at the end of 2004 and about $17.68 billion by the end of 2005. Over the period 2003 to 2006, foreign reserves also increased by more than fivefold, from $7.5 billion at the end of 2003 to about $38 billion in July 2006 (Okonjo-Iweala and Osafo-Kwaako, 2007). The implementation of monetary policy was similarly fairly disciplined, with the central bank adhering to various monetary targets and reducing inflation. End-year inflation declined from 21.8 percent in 2003 to 10 percent in 2004 but increased slightly to 11.6 percent at the end of 2005 and reduced sharply to a single digit in 2006 and 2007 with 8.2 percent and 5.4 percent respectively. Similarly, interest rates, although relatively high, are gradually declining: prime lending rates have declined from about 21.3 percent at the end of 1999 to 17.6 percent at the end of 2005. Finally, the adoption of the Wholesale Dutch Auction System facilitated the convergence of foreign exchange markets and the elimination of a previous black market premium. 57 The improved implementation of fiscal and monetary policies has provided a stable macroeconomic environment, which is crowding in private sector participation in the domestic economy (Okonjo-Iweala and Osafo-Kwaako, 2007). As an example, in 2005, credit to the private sector grew by 30.8 percent to N2.01 trillion (US$15.1 billion), exceeding the target growth rate of 22.5 percent. In addition, net credit to the federal government declined by 37 percent to N306.0 billion (US$2.3 billion) compared with the target decline of 10.9 percent. The fall in lending to the federal government was attributed mainly to a decline in the central bank’s holding of treasury securities. Overall, the attainment of macroeconomic stability has provided a platform for improved growth performance in recent years. Growth rates have averaged about 7.1 percent annually for the period 2003 to 2006. This is a notable improvement on the performance over the decade before reform when annual growth rates averaged about 2.3 percent. More importantly, the recent strong growth rates have been driven by strong growth in the non-oil sectors, which is needed for employment creation. Growth in the non-oil sector for 2003, 2004, and 2005 was 4.4, 7.4, and 8.26 percent, respectively. Progress in oil revenue management and implementation of monetary policy was complemented by improvements in debt management and the budget preparation process. Public debt declined substantially from about 74.8 percent of 58 GDP in 2003 to about 14.2 percent in 2006, largely because of a successful debt relief agreement with the Paris Club. Nigeria paid its outstanding arrears of $6.4 billion, received a debt write-off of $16 billion on the remaining debt stock (under Naples terms), and purchased its outstanding $8 billion debt under a buyback agreement at 25 percent discount for $6 billion. The entire debt relief package totaled $18 billion, or a 60 percent write-off in return for a $12.4 billion payment of arrears and buyback. The exercise involving the buyback was unprecedented in the Paris Club for a low-income country and was the second largest debt relief operation in the club’s 50-year history. Other external debt, particularly debt owed to London Club commercial creditors, are similarly being restructured and paid off. Strengthening the budget preparation and execution process was also urgently needed in order to improve the efficiency of government spending and improve service delivery to the Nigerian public. In the past, weaknesses in budget implementation and monitoring had resulted in a low quality of government expenditures and many incomplete projects. The current improvements are being supported by the preparation of a fiscal strategy paper laying out options and tradeoffs for budgetary spending, as well as improved management of government finances by a Cash Management Committee chaired by the finance minister. In addition, medium term expenditure frameworks (MTEF) and medium term sector strategies 59 (MTSS) have been introduced to ensure that sectoral spending programmes reflect government development priorities and also remain within projected resource envelopes (Okonjo-Iweala and Osafo-Kwaako, 2007). 2.5 APPRAISAL OF ECONOMIC POLICY MEASURES From the foregoing review, it is clear that the Nigerian experience confirms the problems of uncertainty and unpredictability which the developed countries central banks have found to beset the task of fiscal and monetary policies formulation and implementation. In theory, it is expected that the manipulation of fiscal and monetary policy instruments will help ensure that the ultimate macroeconomic goals pursued by the society are attained. In practice, however, several factors militate against the effectiveness of monetary policy. Those operating in the Nigerian case are thus: the perennial problem of monetary policy lags usually involving recognition, action and effect lags. The linkage between monetary policy actions and results are far from direct and immediate and not precisely known. Because of this, and the fact that other economic policies also influence the pace and direction of change of major macroeconomics variables that form the targets of official policies, it is a frustrating 60 exercise to seek to isolate the impact of monetary policy on the economy (CBN 20 Years of Central Banking: 1959-1979). Far from being traceable to any fundamental mistakes in policy formulation, the specific problems facing monetary policy in Nigeria are largely attributable to strong exogenous factors. The first factor is the inability to use the conventional techniques of monetary policy because of the lack of financial markets of the required breadth and depth. For example, open market operations cannot be applied because the volume of eligible securities in the economy is inadequate. In addition, transactions in government t securities which represent the bulk of money market securities are not fully exposed to money market forces since the CBN is required to guarantee their repurchase at par. Thus, as long as this guarantee is operative, effective open market operations which require market sensitive interest rates are precluded. As a second-best approach, monetary policy performance is generally evaluated by concentrating on its impact on the financial sector since the measures are expected to work through the financial markets. For instance an increase in money supply, given less than full employment, is expected to lead to expansion in output and employment by lowering interest rate (where the financial markets are 61 sensitive) and stimulating investment. Interest being a cost of investible funds is assumed to have an inverse relationship to investment spending although investment decisions are influenced more by the expected rate of return than the cost of borrowing per se. However, where growth is considered the focus of policy, the implication for monetary policy would be to maintain relative price stability (CBN 20 Years of Central Banking: 1959-1979). Closely associated with the above factor are the rigidity and the conservatively low level of the structure of interest rates in the country arising from government interventionist policies in the operations of the money market. The attempts to use interest rate changes as a tool of monetary policy did not make any significant impact largely, because the changes were small and infrequent. The structure of interest rates has persisted at an unrealistically low level and hence does not reflect the scarcity value of capital funds in Nigeria. The deposit rates for all types of financial institutions have maintained the most unrealistically low level which could be expected to stimulate saving mobilization. Furthermore, the low interest rates on government debt instruments (treasury bills, certificate, stocks and bonds) have largely been conducive to inflationary monetary expansion, partly because they failed to attract enough private sector savers and more importantly because the CBN is required by law to 62 absorb the unsubscribed proportion of government debt instruments (CBN 20 Years of Central Banking: 1959-1979). Also, interlocking with the phenomenon of low and inflexible interest rate structure is government fiscal operations which have preponderantly determined the rate of monetary expansion in the Nigerian economy. In particular, movement in government expenditure especially in the 1980s represented the single most important factor influencing the growth of the money stock. In the 1970s when government budgetary deficits were financed largely by borrowing from the CBN, the need to borrow cheap and minimize debt service burden dominated monetary policy and influenced the low level of interest rates than administered by the monetary authorities. For most of the 1990s excessive liquidity characterized both the public and private sectors of the economy as a result of increased oil revenue. A disproportionately large part of government revenue comes from tax on mining industry especially oil and is earned in the form of foreign exchange. The rapid monetization of such inflow of funds to finance an unsustainable level of government expenditure has posed the greatest threat to economic stability in the 21 st century. In between 1999 to 2007, when the flow of oil funds began to descend from its 63 unprecedented heights, the government has reverted to the earlier practice of financing a growing budgetary deficit by excessive borrowing from the central bank– a practice which has serious inflationary implications. The ever present conflict between the objectives of fiscal as well as monetary stability and growth constituted an important challenge to macroeconomic management throughout the decades under review. It would appear that the tradeoff between growth and inflation was usually resolved in favour of the former in view of the fact that the process of agrarian and industrial revolution of the economy is yet to reach a take-off stage. Similarly, in pursuit of the objective of fostering the growth of a sound financial system to mobilize adequate development oriented finance, the CBN has been obliged to be less restraining on the credit operations of the banking system than it otherwise would have been. One final challenges facing monetary management that should be mentioned here is the shortcomings of the most popular instrument of monetary regulation in Nigeria- Credit guidelines. Apart from the fact that the banking system failed on a number of occasions to attain full compliance with the various CBN credit guidelines, the problem of “window dressing” the figures of their credit operations cannot be ignored. More importantly, there is the problem of inability to control the ultimate use 64 into which a borrowed fund may be put. The more prescription of a sectoral distribution of credit may not ensure that funds borrowed for production cannot be applied for consumption expenditures (See Parliamentary Debate on CBN Draft Act, 1958). A popular solution for putting an end to Nigeria’s fiscal policy recklessness, which has been championed by World Bank Economists, is that what Nigeria needs is a fiscal policy rule, which would commit the government to a certain level of conduct in fiscal and budgetary management. Along these lines, it has been asserted that “Better management of the oil revenue cycle would have to be a central element of any effort to put Nigeria on a part of fiscal sustainability”. Historically, fiscal policy in Nigeria has been extremely pro-cyclical with expenditures ratcheting out of control on the upswing of the oil price cycle. This has contributed to the observed deficit bias in the conduct of fiscal policy. One option is to put in place a fiscal policy rule. A fiscal policy rule makes sense in Nigeria, given the complete absence of a tradition of fiscal discipline. Because a fiscal rule commits government to a certain level of conduct in fiscal and budgetary management, it will help begin to build government credibility in fiscal management and over time, promote strong fiscal discipline across all tiers of government. A rule, based on oil prices, will also help address the issue of the vulnerability of all tiers of government to oil price swings and reduce the pro-cyclicality 65 in the budget. This will allow savings to build up financial assets in periods with high oil prices that can be used to finance the desired expenditure programmes when oil prices are low (Kwakwa, 2003). Ezeoha and Uche (2006), there is however no guarantee that rules will work in Nigeria. Subsequent Governments have had no respect for rules, be it monetary or fiscal policy rules. Take for instance the already mentioned regulation, which limits the amount of credit a central bank is allowed to advance to government. A Government that flouts one rule can easily flout another. Finding a solution to this problem is therefore much more complex. Specifically there will be little progress towards fiscal prudence until some powerful pro-stability stakeholders strong enough to challenge government fiscal recklessness emerge. The people, if and when provided with a proper democratic structure, have the potentials of constituting such an interest group. Under such a scenario, elections could be used to get rid of pro-inflation governments. Financial institutions also constitute another pro-stability interest group. Unfortunately, the indigenization exercise of the 1970s severely decimated the powers of this group. With majority Government ownership of the main banks, it became difficult to differentiate between the views of government and the views of the bank. The new N25 billion bank capitalization required by the CBN, despite its flaws may well 66 turn out to have some unintended positive side. Mega banks will no doubt be in a much stronger position to make the point that Government’s reckless fiscal policy and its attendant macroeconomic instability is the main cause of financial instability. Until the fiscal recklessness of the Government is checked, the use of monetary policies to achieve macroeconomic stability will remain nothing more than an illusion (Ezeoha and Uche, 2006). The costs of macroeconomic volatility were significant for Nigeria”. The adverse consequences occur via two channels: first, unsteady revenue flows tend to reduce the quality and productivity of government expenditures; and second, private investments tend to be reduced in a volatile environment. Both effects occurred in Nigerian’s case. So, expenditure volatility resulted in low quality government public spending, often with many incomplete capital projects, as well as the accrual of arrears for civil servant salaries and government contractor payments. Macroeconomic instability also hindered long-term planning by the private sector and resulted in a concentration of economic activity in various short-term arbitrage opportunities (particularly in retail trade) rather than productive long-term investments. Overall, a pro-cyclical expenditure pattern coupled with poor management of oil earnings resulted in low growth, and persistent fiscal deficits (Okonjo-Iweala and Osafo-Kwaako, 2007). 67 Furthermore, improvement in fiscal management has been at the centre of recent economic reform agenda in Nigeria. These include achievement of long term fiscal sustainability which is imperative to the enhancement of efficiency and quality of public expenditure; improve management of oil revenue; strengthen fiscal coordination among the three tiers of government; through implementing the fiscal responsibility legislation and Public procurement legislation. Despite recent successes of reform measures, Nigeria faces many challenges in sustaining economic growth and improving its broad development indicators. An historic opportunity exists for Nigerian policymakers to consolidate recent gains from reform and to address outstanding areas of reform in the future. The key issues that Nigerian policy makers must address in future administration are to: extend reforms to the sub-national levels; strengthen domestic institutions (investment in education), focus on non-oil growth and employment generation; improve the domestic business climate; expand and maintain investments in infrastructure; tackle unrest in the Niger Delta; and increase the quality of social sector spending. 2.4.5 THE CHALLENGES AHEAD Much progress has been made, but much remains to be done, and this is that critical juncture when maintaining the momentum is both vital and challenging. We 68 are not yet at the point where we can be confident that Nigeria's current growth performance will be sustained over the longer term. That requires continuing progress on lowering inflation. It also requires continuing progress towards debt sustainability: and that means not just meeting the government's primary surplus target but doing so in a sustainable way, through a better tax system and expenditure management. And it requires continuing reform on a wide range of structural issues. The government's reform programme, of course, envisages doing just that. It is reassuring to see the government's unwavering commitment to further reductions in inflation; to maintaining a primary surplus sufficient to reduce Nigeria's employment and poverty levels; to broader fiscal reform; and to reform and consolidation of the financial sector. Credibility matters in the global economy, perhaps today more than ever. The high-speed transmission of information that we all take for granted, and from which we all gain, also means that markets can act quickly. The markets can be harsh judges, as emerging market economies have painfully discovered. It is important that economies, and economic policymakers, are equipped to exploit the benefits that market discipline can bring. The rewards can be 69 substantial, in terms of lower interest spreads and more foreign investment, for instance (Krueger, 2004). Further progress is also vital because there is clear evidence that the returns to economic reforms increase sharply as more of them are undertaken. This really is an area where the whole is far greater than the sum of the parts. All reform is welcome, of course: but the full benefits will not come through if reforms elsewhere in the economy are overlooked, or postponed. Despite the gains and heavy investments made in the past 10 years, infrastructure, both human and physical, remains weak; also, evidence from the decay energy situation, especially electricity generation and distribution; the poor road conditions; the post system remains underdeveloped; and the railway has become almost irrelevant to the Nigeria’s transportation needs. Now, most of the government projects are substandard because government has failed to ensure that the final output meets demand specifications for cost recovery. Therefore, capable human capacity and effective management and organizational structures are necessary and critical to achieving this Administration’s vision. 70 According to Krueger (2004), a reform agenda is challenging because governments can find it difficult to press on with politically difficult reforms when economic performance has already started to pick up. But difficult reforms are far more painful when implemented in a downturn or, even worse, in the middle of an economic crisis. The current upturn, both in Nigeria and in the global economy, is the ideal opportunity for all countries—not just Nigeria—to implement the changes needed to deliver rapid growth that is sustainable in the longer term. 2.6 CONCLUDING REMARKS Let me not give the wrong impression. It would be wrong to view the challenges in a negative way. The desire for reform, and the determination to deliver it, is evident. And the benefits to be had are enormous. Let me remind us of what could be within Nigeria's grasp if the reforms are followed through successfully. The macroeconomic stability is worth striving for. It is the prerequisite for the rapid sustainable growth in income and employment that raises living standards and reduces poverty. Low inflation makes economic decision-making easier for all citizens, and benefits the poor disproportionately. Sound fiscal policies give governments and citizens more choice. A sustainable fiscal position makes it easier 71 for society to decide on its priorities (Krueger, 2004). Increased economic resilience makes it easier to cope with unexpected shocks. These will always come, we just cannot predict when or in what form: the stronger the economy, the less harm those shocks do to a country's citizens, especially the poor. Indeed, economic reform will be in the interests of all Nigerian citizens. Living standards will rise, poverty will be reduced, and life will become more predictable, or at least less vulnerable to ups and downs. The policy-makers should know that reforms build on each other. The returns rise more rapidly the more widespread and the more co-coordinated they are. For any country that is ill-prepared, the modern global economy can seem harsh. For those with sound policies, the rewards are great indeed. Perseverance is worth it. The short-run target for the economy must be able to consolidate economic reforms through continued pursuance of sound macroeconomic management and fiscal prudence. In the medium-term, government should empower micro units of productive activities to utilise the benefits from the macroeconomic reforms. In the long-run, government must strive to attain the growth objectives as set out in our NEEDS 2 in order to reduce poverty by at least 30% by 2011, and attain annual GDP 72 growth rate of at least 13% so as to make Nigeria one of the 20 largest economies in 2020. Finally, Nigeria needs to ensure better value for money, manage the recurrent spending of the government, seek better participation of the private sector, especially in the provision of infrastructure, strengthen monitoring, auditing and reporting processes and strengthen fiscal co-ordination amongst the 3 tiers of government. 73 CHAPTER THREE THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK AND METHODOLOGY 3.1 THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK In an economy in which fluctuations are partly due to the combination of aggregate demand effects and nominal rigidities, fiscal policy has the potential to reduce fluctuations in aggregate demand and thus increase welfare. This has long been a theme of Keynesian macroeconomics. Whereas for monetary policy the major tradeoff is between price and output stability, the trade-off for fiscal policy is between output stabilization and the distortions from tax and spending policies (Blanchard and Fisher, 1989). In order to examine the effect of fiscal policy upon the level of aggregate demand, Musgrave and Musgrave (2004) begin with a situation of substantial unemployment, where changes in overall expenditure are reflected in changes in real output rather than in prices. Concern with the budget as an active ingredient of stabilization policy, it began in the great depression of the thirties, when Keynes’ (1936) General Theory and its message of fiscal expansion burst onto the scene. To be sure, little was done during the thirties to apply this approach. Roosevelt’s New Deal started out on a platform of budget balance, and such modest recovery as emerged during the thirties was largely private-sector based (Brown, 1956). However, the massive fiscal expansion generated 74 by World War II demonstrated the potential force of such a policy. In the course of the war, the budget rose from 10 to 45 percent of GNP, with half thereof deficit-financed and a supporting monetary policy which held interest rates at 3 percent. Real output rose by 50 percent and unemployment disappeared. While inflationary effects were delayed by price control, even the resulting postwar inflation was moderate by recent standards (Musgrave and Musgrave, 2004). In order to stimulate growth and maintain a healthy external balance, which is what is generally referred to as macroeconomic stability, Busari et al, (2006) concluded that monetary policy stabilizes the economy better under a flexible exchange rate regime may look like an over statement. It is observed that monetary policy stimulates growth better under a flexible rate regime but it is accompanied by severe depreciation, which could destabilize the economy. In other words, monetary policy would better stabilize the economy if it is used to target inflation directly than be used to directly stimulate growth. Other policy measures and instruments are therefore required to complement monetary policy in macroeconomic stabilization. Much of the literature on monetary policy in open economies has been based on the premise that the internal and external balance of an economy is instantaneously affected by movement in exchange rates (Svensson, 2000 and Ball, 1998). 75 Buchanan and Wagner (1977) argued that the pre-Keynesian presumption that the budget should at all times be balanced was replaced by Keynes with an agnosticism that permitted deficits to become arbitrarily large – which with a remarkable long lags, they duly become in the 1980s in the United State. In fact Keynesians and others (e.g., Friedman 1948) have argued for a cyclically balance budget, with deficits in recessions offset by surpluses in booms. Romer (1988) has used the model of perpetual youth to assess the social welfare costs of protracted deficits when the economy is below the modified golden rule capital stock. The argument has been made that the tax cuts of the early 1980s in the United State were in part implemented to force reductions in spending, through the political pressure resulting from large deficits. One may ask what the welfare cost of these deficits may be if these reductions do not lead to decreased spending but have to be financed by higher taxes later (Blanchard and Fisher, 1989). Okonjo-Iweala and Osafo-Kwaako (2007) posited that “The costs of macroeconomic volatility were significant for Nigeria”. There is considerable theoretical and empirical evidence on the adverse effects of volatility for growth (Fatas and Mihov, 2003; Servén, 2003; Bleaney and Greenaway, 2001). These adverse consequences may occur via two channels: first, unsteady revenue flows tend to reduce the quality and productivity of government expenditures; and second, private 76 investments tend to be reduced in a volatile environment. Both effects appear to have occurred in the case of Nigeria. First, expenditure volatility resulted in low quality government public spending, often with many incomplete capital projects, as well as the accrual of arrears for civil servant salaries and government contractor payments. Indeed, by 2003, accumulated arrears to domestic contractors alone amounted to about N150 billion (US$1.17 billion). Second, macroeconomic instability also hindered long-term planning by the private sector and resulted in a concentration of economic activity in various short-term arbitrage opportunities (particularly in retail trade) rather than productive long-term investments. Overall, a pro-cyclical expenditure pattern coupled with poor management of oil earnings resulted in low growth, persistent fiscal deficits, and the accumulation of debts (Okonjo-Iweala and Osafo-Kwaako, 2007). For this study, the theoretical framework is based on Barro Endogenous Growth Model in a simplified form. The model assumes that growth is influenced by policy variables other than the technical relationship between capital and labour (Barro, 1990). Such policy variables include public spending and taxation which are proxies for fiscal policy in this study. The model is based on the following basic assumptions: (i) There are two sectors in the economy: Private (P) and Public (G); (ii) The output of these sectors depend on Labour (L) and Capital (K); and 77 (iii) The output of G has some externalities effects on the output in P. The constant functions of the two sectors therefore appear thus: P = p (Lp, Kp, G) --------------------------------------------------------- (3.1) G = g (Lq, Kq) --------------------------------------------------------- (3.2) The total input functions would therefore appear thus: Lt = Lp + Lq --------------------------------------------------------- (3.3) Kt = Kp + Kq --------------------------------------------------------- (3.4) The total output (Y) will then be the sum of equations (3.1) and (3.2) or (3.3) and (3.4): Y=P+G --------------------------------------------------------- (3.5) Or Y = p (Lp, Kp, G) + g (Lq, Kq) Or Y = L t + Kt + G -------------------------------------- (3.6) ----------------------------------------------- (3.7) Since G is government policy, it can be fiscal policy and monetary policy, thus, the introduction of money supply as concurrent policy variable. Among the reasons for this is that government often prints money to finance some of its developmental programmes and in financing fiscal deficits. Following this trend and coupled with what Anderson and Carlson (1972) discussed on the central role of expectations in the Saint Louis Model. The model could be used for policy analysis, specifically for studying the effect of fiscal and monetary policy on inflation, output and interest rate. The St. Louis Model specified that any 78 macroeconomic variable is a function of fiscal policy and monetary variables. Here, each of the fiscal policy variables would be treated separately to avoid the problem of serial correlation and to evaluate their impact on macroeconomic variables. Therefore, the structural form of Barro Endogenous Growth Model states that macroeconomic variables (output, inflation rate, for the purpose of this study) depends on fiscal policy instruments (government revenue and expenditure) and monetary policy variable proxy by money supply. To many researchers and policy makers, this discussion represents both an opportunity and a constraint on optimal fiscal and monetary policy measures. Although various schools of thought exist on the subject, the opinions expressed are logically consistent. 3.2 METHODOLOGY This study adopts E-Views 4.1 version for the single equation models using ordinary least square (OLS) estimation techniques to investigate the impacts of fiscal policy (expenditure policy) measures on economic growth (proxy by GDP growth) and inflation rates in Nigeria. Therefore, with the use of time series data, the research work employs the methodology which tests for stationarity and cointegration as well as error correction mechanism (ECM). 79 3.2.1 Description of the Macro Models Following from the theoretical framework, the empirical models for this research study are explicitly formulated and described as: LnGDPt = α0 + α1LnGEt + α2LnMts + ε1t , α 1, α 2 > 0 ------------------- (3.8) LnGDPt = β0 + β1LnGRt + β2LnMts + ε2t , β1, β2 > 0 ------------------- (3.9) INFt = η0 + η1LnGEt + η2LnMts + ε3t , η1 < 0, η2 > 0 ------------------- (3.10) INFt = τ0 + τ1LnGRt + τ2LnMts + ε4t , τ1 < 0, τ2 > 0 ------------------- (3.11) Where: GDP is the gross domestic product which is used as a proxy for economic growth; GE is the government expenditure; MS is the broad money supply (M2) which is our proxy for the monetary policy; GR is the Government Revenue; INF is the inflation rate which is our proxy for composite consumer price index; Ln is the natural logarithms of the variables; ε is the random term independently and identically normally distributed with mean zero and constant variance which also control other variables that influenced economic growth; the parameters (α0, α1, α2, β0, β1, β2, η0, η1, η2, τ0, τ1, and τ2) represent the magnitude and size of the coefficients that are necessary to measure the nature and extent of the variables in use and t is the time subscript. 80 However, it is expected that an increase in GE, MS, and GR will cause GDP to rise by the values of the coefficients (α1, α2, β1, and β2 > 0). Also, a positive effect is expected through MS on Inflation rates (η2, τ2 > 0), while an inverse relationship is anticipated through GE and GR on Inflation rates (η1, τ1 < 0). 3.2.2 Estimation Techniques In this analysis, we explore the long-run properties of the time series data. The stationarity test of the series was examined using Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test statistics to investigate the presence of unit root under the alternative hypothesis that the series is stationary around a deterministic or fixed trend. The ADF test is carried out using OLS technique to estimate the equation below: ∆Xt = δ0 + δ1t + δ2Xt-1 + øi ∑ni=1 ∆Xt-i + εt -------------------------------------- (3.12) Where ∆ is the first-difference operator, Xt is nonstationary but its first difference is stationary, ∆Xt = (Xt-Xt-1) is the first difference of Xt, ∆Xt-1= (Xt-1-Xt-2), ∆Xt-2 = (Xt-2 - Xt-3) etc., are the lagged difference terms, δ is a drift parameter, and ε is a pure white noise error term. Note that the null hypothesis of non-stationarity is rejected if δ2 is less than zero (0) and statistically significant. 81 The analysis is based on standard technique provided by Engel and Granger (1987). Since some variables are not stationary, then cointegration tests were carried out using Augmented Engel and Granger (AEG) test. In event some variables are I(0) and some I(1). We basically solve for the lagged residual in the long-run equation and substitute into the error-correction model. This suggests that the F-statistic test for joint significance of the lagged level variables were carried out. If they are found to be jointly significant, it means there is a single level relationship between the dependent variable and the independent variables (i.e., they adjust jointly towards fullequilibrium). Also, using Cointegrating Regression Durbin-Watson (CRDW) test, we applied Durbin-Watson d obtained from the cointegrating regression such as the null hypothesis is that d=0 rather than the standard d=2. If the computed d value is above the critical value suggesting that the variables are cointegrated. Once cointegration is established, the long run effects of independent variables on the dependent variables are inferred by the size and significance of the coefficients. An error correction mechanism (ECM) was estimated for the models in order to restrict the long-run (static) behaviour of the endogenous variables to converge to their cointegrating relationships while allowing for short-run adjustment dynamics. The ECM was first used by Sargan (1984) and later popularized by Engel and Granger (1987) corrects for disequilibrium known as Granger representation theorem. 82 Error Correction Term (ECT) is the one-period lagged value of the residual from the static model. 3.2.3 Data types and Sources The study made use of secondary data. Time series data on macroeconomic variables of interest for the study spanning from 1970 to 2007 were collected. Data were obtained from the Central Bank of Nigeria Statistical Bulletin, Bullion, Economics and Financial Reviews and Annual Reports and Statement of Accounts for various years. Data on public expenditure, revenue, output and inflation were obtained from the Central Bank of Nigeria publications mentioned earlier. Also other relevant publications from the Federal Office of Statistics (FOS), World Bank, the International Monetary Fund (IMF), and e-library, books, periodical journals and articles were used as sources for data. 83 CHAPTER FOUR EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS 4.1 INTRODUCTION In order to effectively analyze the impact of fiscal policy measures (fiscal spending) on the macroeconomic stability indices (GDP growth and inflation rates), there is a need for models specification which was dealt with in the previous chapter. In this chapter, therefore, we deal with the estimation procedures and issues of the empirical models specified, the analysis of results generated, trends analysis and transmission mechanisms of fiscal operations as well as policy implications of results thereof. 4.2 ESTIMATION PROCEDURES As a preliminary step to estimating the model, stationarity test was performed since spurious regression and the attendant misleading inferences are inevitable when nonstationary variables are used for estimation. Hence, Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) unit root tests were employed for the study. The relationships among the key fiscal policy and macroeconomic stability variables were examined. The long-run relationships among the variables were studied by analyzing the existence of cointegration which governs their long-run, or equilibrium association. Relatively short-run dynamics were also investigated using error correction mechanism (ECM) to 84 reconcile the short-run behaviour of the economic variables with its long-run behaviour. 4.2.1 UNIT ROOT TESTS The tests for stationarity were carried out using ADF unit root tests on the residuals obtained from the estimated models (3.8, 3.9, 3.10 and 3.11). The time series behaviour of each series in the models is represented in the tables below: Table 4.1: Stationarity Test for model (3.8) Stationarity Test t-statistic for (levels) at 5% critical value (-2.9434) Variables ADF test statistics Log(GDP) 0.2604 Log(GE) -0.7204 Log(Ms) 0.4008 Source: Researcher’s Computation, 2009. From the table 4.1, the ADF test statistic values for the variables (Log GDP, Log GE and Log Ms), in absolute terms, are less than the critical value (-2.9434) at 5% level, so, we reject the null hypotheses that the variables are nonstationary. Therefore, the results indicate that the series are integrated of order zero, i.e., I(0). (See Figure 4.1 and Appendix 1 for detail). 85 Table 4.2: Stationarity Test for model (3.9) Stationarity Test t-statistic for (levels) at 5% critical value Variables ADF test statistics Log(GDP) 0.2604 Log(GR) -0.6687 Log(Ms) 0.4008 Source: Researcher’s Computation, 2009. From the table 4.2, the ADF test statistic values for the variables (Log GDP, Log GR and Log Ms), in absolute terms, are less than the critical value (-2.9434) at 5% level, so, we reject the null hypotheses that the variables are nonstationary. Therefore, they are stationary or integrated of order one, i.e., I(0). (See Figure 4.1 and Appendix 1 for detail). Table 4.3: Stationarity Test for model (3.10) t-statistic for (levels) at 5% critical value t-statistic for (1st Difference) 5% critical (-2.9434) value (-2.9604) Variables ADF test statistics ADF test statistics INF -3.0530 -2.7785 Log(GE) -0.7204 - Log(Ms) 0.4008 - Stationarity Test Source: Researcher’s Computation, 2009. 86 From the table 4.3, the ADF tests show that the null hypothesis of nonstationarity would not be rejected for the variable (INF) at 5% level, while it was rejected for both Log(GE) and Log(Ms) at levels. However, differencing the nonstationarity INF series once, led to the rejection of the null hypothesis. Hence, the results in the table indicates that the variable (INF) is integrated of order one, i.e., I(1). Whereas the variables (GE and MS) are integrated of order zero, i.e. I(0). (See Figure 4.1 and Appendix 1 for detailed results). Table 4.4: Stationarity Test for model (3.11) t-statistic for (levels) at 5% critical value t-statistic for (1st Difference) 5% critical (-2.9434) value (-2.9604) Variables ADF test statistics ADF test statistics INF -3.0530 -2.7785 Log(GR) -0.6687 - Log(Ms) 0.4008 - Stationarity Test Source: Researcher’s Computation, 2009. 87 From the table 4.4, the ADF tests show that the null hypothesis of nonstationarity would not be rejected for the series INF at 5% level, while it was rejected for both Log(GR) and Log(Ms) at levels. However, differencing the nonstationarity INF series once, led to the rejection of the null hypothesis. Hence, the results in the table indicates that the variable (INF) is integrated of order one, i.e., I(1). Whereas the variables (GR and MS) are integrated of order zero, i.e. I(0). (See Figure 4.1 and Appendix 1 for detailed results). 4.2.2 COINTEGRATION TESTS The results from the unit root tests conducted revealed that at levels, the variables (GE, GR and MS) did not show any tendency towards reverting to their mean values while the variable (INF) did. The variables that are not stationary have some linear combinations of them that are stationary, thus, they are said to be cointegrated. This implies that there is a long-run or equilibrium relationship among the variables, so, we conduct cointegration tests. Here, we used the Johansen’s procedure which utilizes vector autoregression (VAR) approach to test the models for cointegrating in the following tables: 88 Table 4.5: Cointegration result for model 3.10 Data: 08/27/09 Time: 16:10 Sample(adjusted): 1972 2007 Included observations: 36 after adjusting endpoints Trend assumption: No deterministic trend (restricted constant) Series: INF LOG(GE) LOG(MS) Lags interval (in first differences): 1 to 1 Unrestricted Cointegration Rank Test Hypothesized Non of CE(s) None** At most 1 At most 2 Trace Eigenvalue Statistic 5 Percent Critical Value 0.507285 41.7258 0.288213 16.24410 0.105283 4.00493 34.91 19.69 9.24 1 Percent Critical Value 41.07 24.60 12.97 *(**) denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 5%(1%) level Trace test indicates 1 cointegrating equation(s) at both 5% and 1% levels Source: Researcher’s Computation, 2009. From the Table 4.5, the trace statistic test suggests the existence of one cointegrating equation at both 5% and 1% critical levels for model 3.10. Since there is at least one cointegrating relation, we assert that the time series variables are cointegrated. Although the time series variables individually exhibit random walks, there is a stable long-run relationship among them; they will not wander away from each other, which is evident from Figure 4.1. 89 Table 4.6: Cointegration result for model 3.11 Data: 08/27/09 Time: 16:13 Sample(adjusted): 1972 2007 Included observations: 36 after adjusting endpoints Trend assumption: Linear deterministic trend Series: INF LOG(GR) LOG(MS) Lags interval (in first differences): 1 to 1 Unrestricted Cointegration Rank Test Hypothesized Trace Non of CE(s) Eigenvalue Statistic 5 Percent Critical Value None* At most 1 At most 2 0.444104 0.267156 2.50E-05 32.32877 11.19050 0.000901 29.68 15.41 3.76 1 Percent Critical Value 35.65 20.04 6.65 *(**) denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 5%(1%) level Trace test indicates 1 cointegrating equation(s) at both 5% level Trace test indicates no cointegration at 1% level Source: Researcher’s Computation, 2009. From the Table 4.6, the trace statistic test suggests the existence of one cointegrating equation at 5% critical level and no cointegration at 1% critical level for model 3.11. Since there is at least one cointegrating relation, we assert that the time series variables are cointegrated. So, there is a stable long-run relationship among them; they will not wander away from each other, which is evident from Figure 4.1. Thus, they are modeled in what follows. 90 4.3 ESTIMATION ISSUES 4.3.1 LONG-RUN MODELS (STATIC MODELS) Having checked for cointegration among the contemporaneous macroeconomic variables in levels, we then obtained the long-run results of the impact of fiscal policy measures (fiscal spending) on the macroeconomic stability indices (GDP growth and inflation) by estimating the general models (3.8, 3.9, 3.10, and 3.11). All these are presented in the tables below: Table 4.7: Long-Run Model 3.8 Dependent Variable: LOG(GDP) Method: Least Squares Date: 08/27/09 Time: 12:19 Sample: 1970 2007 Included observations: 38 Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. C LOG(GE) LOG(MS) 1.488297 0.684824 0.330585 0.191290 0.136498 0.128129 7.780335 5.017092 2.580091 0.0000 0.0000 0.0142 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid 0.991208 0.990706 0.241033 2.033398 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion 12.59725 2.500219 0.067894 0.197177 Log likelihood 1.710016 F-statistic 1973.052 Durbin-Watson stat 1.043927 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000000 Source: Researcher’s Computation, 2009. 91 Results Interpretation: The results of the estimated equation 3.8 in the table 4.7 above shows that the explanatory variables (GE and MS) are significant in explaining observed variations in the GDP growth. The analysis reveals that the explanatory variables in the model accounted for 99.1% variations in the GDP growth. The explanatory variables depict the right signs (i.e., positively related to GDP growth) as anticipated from the a priori expectation. The Durbin-Watson d-statistic value (1.0439) confirms the absence of autocorrelation or serial correlation among the variables. Overall, the high value (1973.05) of F-statistic in the model indicates the joint significance of the explanatory variables. Therefore, the long-run model shows that the explanatory variables (government expenditure and money supply) are quite able to explain the variations in GDP growth. Thus, this implies that fiscal and monetary policy measures impact positively on economic growth in Nigeria. 92 Table 4.8: Long-Run Model 3.9 Dependent Variable: LOG(GDP) Method: Least Squares Date: 08/27/09 Time: 13:36 Sample: 1970 2007 Included observations: 38 Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. C LOG(GR) LOG(MS) 2.127782 0.663234 0.276204 0.143533 0.085308 0.089917 14.82437 7.774568 3.071763 0.0000 0.0000 0.0041 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood Durbin-Watson stat 0.994458 0.994141 0.191380 1.281926 10.47557 0.797204 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) 12.59725 2.500219 -0.393451 -0.264168 3139.924 0.000000 Source: Researcher’s Computation, 2009. Results Interpretation: The results of the estimated equation 3.9 in the table 4.8 above shows that the explanatory variables (GR and MS) are significant in explaining observed variations in the GDP growth. The analysis reveals that the explanatory variables in the model accounted for 99.4% variations in the GDP growth. The explanatory variables depict the right signs (i.e., positively related to GDP growth) as anticipated a priori expectation. The Durbin-Watson d-statistic value (0.7972) confirms the absence of serial correlation among the variables. Overall, the high value (3139.92) of F-statistic in the model indicates the joint significance of the explanatory variables. Therefore, the 93 result implies that fiscal and monetary policy measures have positive effect on economic growth in Nigeria. Table 4.9: Long-Run Model 3.10 Dependent Variable: INF Method: Least Squares Date: 08/27/09 Time: 16:24 Sample: 1970 2007 Included observations: 38 Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. C LOG(GE) LOG(MS) 15.70025 -2.293906 2.635216 13.5724 9.684836 9.091024 1.156778 -0.236855 0.28987 0.2552 0.8141 0.7736 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood Durbin-Watson stat 0.007422 -0.049297 17.10182 10236.53 -160.2462 0.852399 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) 19.94474 16.69526 8.591904 8.721187 0.130849 0.877777 Source: Researcher’s Computation, 2009. Results Interpretation: From the table 4.9 above, the estimated model (3.10) result suggests that the independent variables are quite unable to explain the variations in the levels of inflation. This is evident by the insignificance and low value of adjusted R2 for the model which stood at -4.9%. Also, the low value of F-statistic (0.1308) for the model indicates that the explanatory variables are jointly insignificance. 94 Table 4.10: Long-Run Model 3.11 Dependent Variable: INF Method: Least Squares Date: 08/27/09 Time: 17:30 Sample: 1970 2007 Included observations: 38 Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. C LOG(GR) LOG(MS) 12.73054 -4.326632 5.015346 12.7773 7.594138 8.004431 0.996341 -0.569733 0.626571 0.3259 0.5725 0.5350 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood Durbin-Watson stat 0.014966 -0.041322 17.03671 10158.73 -160.1012 0.86059 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) 19.94474 16.69526 8.584274 8.713557 0.265884 0.768062 Source: Researcher’s Computation, 2009. Results Interpretation: From the table 4.10 above, the estimated model (3.11) result suggests that the variables are quite unable to explain the variations in the levels of inflation. This is evident by the insignificance and low value of adjusted R2 for the model which stood at -4.1%. Also, the low value of F-statistic (0.2659) for the model indicates that the explanatory variables are jointly insignificance. 4.3.2 SHORT-RUN MODELS (Error Correction Models) Based on the cointegration results, it is evident that there is a long-term or equilibrium relationship among the variables of the models (3.10 and 3.11) estimated. 95 In using these results, we employed ECM to reconcile the short-run behaviour of the variables with its long-run phenomenon. As a result, we present dynamic models here starting with the over-parameterised models that we tested down until we arrived at our preferred parsimonious models. These are reported in the following tables: Table 4.11: Over-Parameterised Short-Run Result for Model 3.10 Dependent Variable: D(INF) Method: Least Squares Date: 08/31/09 Time: 12:03 Sample(adjusted): 1973 2006 Included observations: 34 after adjusting endpoints Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. C LOG(GE) LOG(MS) LOG(GE(-1)) LOG(GE(+1)) LOG(GE(-2)) LOG(MS(-1)) LOG(MS(+1)) LOG(MS(-2)) D(INF(-1)) D(INF(-2)) D(INF(+1)) ECTINF(-1) -4.486049 -18.32584 48.71729 -14.43987 0.253678 1.936923 24.30692 11.97529 -56.84959 -0.170423 -0.107035 -0.302879 -0.435287 11.96403 10.48454 26.6053 10.9837 9.764183 10.07795 32.02973 20.86522 19.61136 0.181448 0.164312 0.175587 0.181745 -0.374961 -1.747892 1.831112 -1.314663 0.02598 0.192194 0.758886 0.573935 -2.898809 -0.939239 -0.65141 -1.724949 -2.395042 0.7114 0.0951 0.0813 0.2028 0.9795 0.8494 0.4564 0.5721 0.0086 0.3583 0.5218 0.0992 0.0260 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood Durbin-Watson stat 0.679897 0.496981 11.49634 2775.481 -123.0816 1.480554 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Source: Researcher’s Computation, 2009. 96 0.147059 16.20941 8.004802 8.588410 3.716989 0.004181 Results Interpretation: From the tables 4.11, the dynamic over-parameterised model for the estimated equation 3.10 depicts that the exogenous variables explained 49.7% of the variations in the inflation rates. The p-values of all the variables were not significance except money supply at lagged 2 and the error correction term [ECTINF(-1)]. As a result, we then tested down until we arrived at our preferred parsimonious model. The parsimonious interation involves dropping those insignificant variables from the shortrun over-parameterised macro model. So, the numbers of the exogenous variables in the model was reduced by imposing zero coefficients on the insignificant ones. Through simplification, the parsimonious model is shown in the Table 4.12 below: 97 Table 4.12: Parsimonious Short-Run Model 3.10 Dependent Variable: D(INF) Method: Least Squares Date: 08/31/09 Time: 12:17 Sample(adjusted): 1972 2006 Included observations: 35 after adjusting endpoints Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. C LOG(GE) LOG(MS) LOG(GE(-1)) LOG(MS(-2)) D(INF(-1)) D(INF(+1)) ECTINF(-1) -3.612884 -15.30506 67.75057 -11.30805 -43.26115 -0.098736 -0.336305 -0.522088 9.68976 7.747215 13.34397 8.599571 8.722092 0.144593 0.131032 0.131981 -0.372856 -1.975557 5.077241 -1.314955 -4.959951 -0.682858 -2.566586 -3.955776 0.7122 0.0585 0.0000 0.1996 0.0000 0.5005 0.0161 0.0005 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood Durbin-Watson stat 0.662242 0.574676 10.512 2983.555 -127.4595 1.443869 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Source: Researcher’s Computation, 2009. 98 -0.222857 16.11851 7.740543 8.096051 7.562713 0.000046 Results Interpretation: Judging from the table 4.12, the dynamic parsimonious result reveals that the independent variables accounted for 57.5% variations in the level of inflation. The value of the feedback effect for parsimonious short-run model (3.10) is 0.5221. This means that 52.21% of the discrepancy in the macro variables in the previous period will be eliminated in this period. This suggests that if the INF rate was higher more than expected a priori in the last period, this period it will be reduced by 52.21% points to restore the long-run relationship among the variables. Besides, the short-run changes in the explanatory variables are quickly reflected in the dependent variable, as the slope coefficients of the variables are shown. Statistically, the absolute value of [ECTINF(-1)] i.e. 0.5221 decides how quickly the equilibrium is restored. The equilibrium error term is zero, indicating that INF rate adjusts to change in exogenous variables (GE and MS) in the same time period. As a result, the short-run changes in the M2 money supply have a positive impact on the short-run changes in the inflation rates, while the government expenditure has a negative effect. 99 Table 4.13: Over-Parameterised Short-Run Result for Model 3.11 Dependent Variable: D(INF) Method: Least Squares Date: 08/31/09 Time: 12:37 Sample(adjusted): 1973 2006 Included observations: 34 after adjusting endpoints Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. C LOG(GR) LOG(MS) LOG(GR(-1)) LOG(MS(-1)) LOG(GR(-2)) LOG(MS(-2)) LOG(GR(+1)) LOG(MS(+1)) D(INF(-1)) D(INF(-2)) D(INF(+1)) ECTIN(-1) -41.25582 -15.29972 41.81469 -11.66617 16.73405 -5.308451 -53.08436 3.316608 24.54017 -0.072455 0.014144 -0.385737 -0.597331 16.69007 9.016266 26.56715 8.944992 31.1863 8.11882 18.25683 6.590271 22.50072 0.160396 0.157087 0.173132 0.167113 -2.471877 -1.696902 1.573924 -1.304212 0.536583 -0.653845 -2.907644 0.503258 1.090639 -0.451724 0.09004 -2.227997 -3.574417 0.0221 0.1045 0.1305 0.2063 0.5972 0.5203 0.0084 0.6200 0.2878 0.6561 0.9291 0.0369 0.0018 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood Durbin-Watson stat 0.694330 0.519662 11.23417 2650.336 -122.2973 1.350816 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) 0.147059 16.20941 7.958664 8.542273 3.975132 0.002820 Source: Researcher’s Computation, 2009. Results Interpretation: From the tables 4.13, the dynamic over-parameterised model for the estimated equation 3.11 depicts that the exogenous variables explained 51.96% of the variations in the inflation rates. The p-value of the error correction term [ECTINF(-1)] was 100 significance. From this result, we then tested down until we arrived at our preferred parsimonious model. The parsimonious interation involves dropping those insignificant variables from the short-run over-parameterised macro model. So, the numbers of the exogenous variables in the model was reduced by imposing zero coefficients on the insignificant ones. Through simplification, the parsimonious model is shown in the table 4.14 below: Table 4.14: Parsimonious Short-Run Model 3.11 Dependent Variable: D(INF) Method: Least Squares Date: 08/31/09 Time: 12:43 Sample(adjusted): 1972 2006 Included observations: 35 after adjusting endpoints Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. C LOG(GR) LOG(MS) LOG(GR(-1)) LOG(GR(-2)) LOG(MS(-2)) LOG(MS(+1)) D(INF(+1)) ECTIN(-1) -35.46818 -12.30545 48.31468 -10.35144 -4.274631 -42.5677 21.99635 -0.40144 -0.611916 12.65577 7.222141 17.04809 7.588577 6.862557 8.098289 17.35298 0.136751 0.119236 -2.802531 -1.703851 2.834023 -1.364082 -0.622892 -5.256383 1.267584 -2.935558 -5.131962 0.0095 0.1003 0.0088 0.1842 0.5388 0.0000 0.2162 0.0069 0.0000 R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood Durbin-Watson stat 0.687067 0.590779 10.31107 2764.273 -126.1236 1.379323 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Source: Researcher’s Computaion, 2009. 101 -0.222857 16.11851 7.721348 8.121294 7.135596 0.000055 Results Interpretation: Inferring from the table 4.14, the dynamic parsimonious result reveals that the independent variables accounted for 59.08% variations in the level of inflation. The value of the feedback effect for parsimonious short-run model (3.11) is 0.6119. This indicates that 61.19% of the discrepancy in the macro variables in the previous period will be eliminated in this period. That is, if the INF rate is higher more than expected a priori in the last period, this period it will be reduced by 61.19% points to restore the long-run relationship among the variables. Besides, the short-run changes in the explanatory variables are quickly reflected in the dependent variable, as the slope coefficients of the variables are shown. Statistically, the absolute value of [ECTINF(-1)] i.e. 0.6119 decides how quickly the equilibrium is restored. The equilibrium error term is zero, indicating that INF rate adjusts to change in exogenous variables (GR and MS) in the same time period. As a result, the short-run changes in the M2 money supply have a positive impact on the short-run changes in the inflation rates, while the government revenue has a negative effect. 102 4.4 TRENDS IN FISCAL OPERATIONS AND MACROECONOMIC STABILITY INDICES IN NIGERIA 1970-2007 The fiscal operations in the last three decades (1970-1999) resulted in overall fiscal deficits which were evident in each of the period under review except in six years (1971, 1973, 1974, 1979, 1995 and 1996) when surpluses were recorded. So, these trends of the imbalances continue from year 2000 to 2007 the periods of these reviews. The immediate effect of oil-price volatile increase in the Nigerian economy was an expansion in government revenue over the years. This was evident by the 1978 oil price shock that accounted for the raised in total revenue from 14.99% of GDP to 26.18% in 1980. In 1981, the oil revenue declined to 64.4% from 81.1% in 1980 of the total oil revenue due to the oil glut in the international market. However, oil revenue resumed an upward trend in 1982 when it contributed 68.3% of the total revenue to 73.5% in 1984. The total revenue grew at an average of 28.7% of GDP between 1990 and 2001. And this trend continued till 2007 (see appendix table 4.15 and figure 4.1) The pattern of public expenditure during the period under review was largely influenced by expected performance of the oil sector. The high oil earnings enhanced government to raise expenditure to unsustainable levels. The onset of recession in 103 1981 led to the decline in total expenditure to 22.6% of GDP from 30.2% in 1980. The downward trend continued until 1985 when it resumed an upward movement. By 1993, expenditure had risen to 27.6% over the preceding year’s level and by 1999 the total expenditure increased to 29.4% of GDP. The upward trend was maintained and by 2001 a new threshold was reached when the level of expenditure peaked representing 18.6% of GDP (see appendix table 4.15 and figure 4.1). Therefore, from the foregoing, as a result of the higher growth in the public expenditure compared to the raise in government revenue, the fiscal operations resulted in overall deficits continuously from 1980 to 1995 while overall surpluses were recorded in 1996 and the deficits later increased from 1997 to 2001. The overall deficit as a percentage of GDP average 8.25% between 1980 and 1994 and 4.1% between 1997 and 2002 (see appendix table 4.15 and figure 4.1). 104 Figure 4.1 Trends in Fiscal Operations and Macroeconomic Stability indices in Nigeria: 1970-2007 80 70 60 50 Gov.Exp/GDP(%) Gov.Rev/GDP(%) 40 MS/GDP (%) 30 GDP Growth (%) INF Rate (%) 20 10 0 -10 From figure 4.1, after pursuing formal tests, we plot the time series under study for the data given in the table 4.15. This gives a clue about the nature of the time series. The GDP time series shown that over the period of study it has been increasing, that is, showing an upward trend, suggesting that the mean of the GDP has been changing. This indicates that the GDP series is not stationary. This is also more or less true of the other Nigeria economic time series shown in the figure. Hence, this intuitive feeling is the starting point of the more formal tests of the stationarity and cointegration tests conducted in the subsection 4.3 above. 105 Figure 4.2 Selected Macroeconomic Indicators (1970-2007) 45 40 35 30 GE/GDP (%) 25 GR/GDP (%) 20 MS/GDP (%) CPI Inflation (%) 15 GDP Growth (%) 10 5 0 1970 1980 1990 2000 2005 2006 2007 As is evident from the illustration of this subsection, there are many ways in which the functioning of the public sector bears on economic growth and may do so in both a helpful and a harmful way (see appendix table 4.16 and figure 4.2). The general view of the challenge is provided in figure 4.2 above, which relates public sector share in GDP to the rate of economic activity and growth. Including a sample of M2 money supply, inflation rates, fiscal spending and revenue as well as covering the decades of 1977-2007, we find little or no evidence of a systematic relationship. This is perhaps is as may be expected since so much depends on the context of public expenditures, and 106 many other factors, unrelated to the budget, enter as well. Nevertheless, it is important to note that no ready judgment, pointing one way or the other can be made. But a closely look at the empirical analyses in the previous subsections (4.2 and 4.3) will shed more light and provide appropriate policy measures on the issues in relation to fiscal and monetary policies effect on the macroeconomic stability in Nigeria. 4.5 THE TRANSMISSION MECHANISMS OF FISCAL POLICY The channels through which fiscal policy measures affects economic growth and development in Nigeria are reflected in macroeconomic stability that yields numerous benefits including; higher rates of return on investment, infrastructural development, technological advancement and human capital development (educational attainment) which are better achieved in an environment of low inflation. In the period under review, Nigeria experiences high rates of inflation with little or no growth in economic activities. This resulted in poor standard of living and poverty at every level. As a result, there is serious macroeconomic instability in the economy which is damaging to the populace (the poor) since their earnings are not indexed to inflation; and inability to invest in assets that provide a hedge against inflation. 107 Thus, it is evident that the fiscal system plays multifaceted roles in the process of economic growth and development. Firstly, the distributions of tax burdens play a large role in enhancing equitable distribution of economic resources. For instance, the structure and the level of taxation affect the level of public and private savings as well as the volume of resources available for capital formation. Also, the tax treatment of investment from abroad affects the volume of capital inflow and the rate of reinvestment of earnings there from as well as the pattern of taxation on exports and imports relative to that of domestic products will affect foreign trade balance. Therefore, a good system of tax incentives and penalties must be designed to influence the efficiency of resource utilization. The role of expenditure policy in macroeconomic stability has been explored more extensively than that of tax policy in this study due to difficulty in obtaining comparative data. We obtained some evidence regarding the role of GDP in economic growth as well. The low-income earners direct a higher share of expenditures to education and health services and lower share to transfers. The higher share for education to some degree reflects the higher cost of educational services in this nation. The higher share of transfers in high-income earners reflects the more developed social security systems they achieve. The particular importance of this form 108 of capital formation, it is essential that the educational inputs be designed to meet the country’s need for specific labour skill. Moreover, the rent-seeking incentives by the government reduce growth by diverting higher human capital away from productive activities with adverse impact on productivity and resulted in lower economic performance. However, prudent fiscal policy can help enhance factors productivities. The endogenous growth theory suggests that fiscal policy can either promote or retard economic growth through its impact on decisions regarding investment in physical and human capital; increased fiscal spending on education, health, infrastructure, research and development will boost long-term growth; while government expenditure on infrastructure and private sector productivity complementary public inputs. The strategic role of public investment in economic growth and development is based in part on the underdeveloped state of private capital markets and in part on local scarcity of entrepreneurial talent; it is also based on the fact that the type of investment needed at the earlier stages of development frequently includes very large outlays on infrastructure investment which call for public provision. Therefore, huge public investment is needed to provide for the infrastructure types of investment. 109 Hence, the distribution of expenditure benefits plays a large part in promoting equitable distribution of the fruits of economic development. Finally, ineffective fiscal policy harms the growth process through dead-weight loss from taxes that finance public expenditure and the associated adverse factorsupply effects as well as the inefficiently and inequitably used of public resources. Therefore, Growth is important for poverty reduction, whereas poverty reduction constitutes an essential ingredient to achieving high quality growth. But entrenched poverty and inequality can themselves be impediments to growth. So, from the foregoing, redistribution policies are relevant in eradicating poverty or at least alleviating some of its most adverse effects, particularly when income inequality is severe. 4.6 POLICY IMPLICATIONS The results obtained from the analysis reveals that fiscal spending, revenue and money supply positively related with the growth in national output. This implies that both fiscal and monetary policy measures will impact positively on economic growth. As such, fiscal and monetary policies that are not properly targeted to the happenings 110 within the macroeconomy will have adverse effects on economic growth as well as raises inflationary effects. Finally, the research study finds out that adequate and prudent expenditure policy together with healthy monetary policy raises economic growth in a good policy environment. Thereby, public resources would be used efficiently and equitable in order to sustain the economy. Therefore, fiscal prudent as reflected in appropriate fiscal sustainability tend to reduce the risk of economic crises and prevents interest expenditure from squeeze out critical social spending. Hence, proper funding of education and health directly impact on socio-economic outcomes which are important for poverty eradication that will enhance economic growth and sustainable development. It is not just the level of spending that matters, but also the efficiency of the outlays and how well they are targeted to the poor in the society. 111 CHAPTER FIVE SUMMARY, CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATION 5.1 SUMMARY/CONCLUDING REMARKS This study attempted to assess the impact of fiscal policy (fiscal spending) measures on macroeconomic stability indices (GDP growth and inflation rates) in Nigeria. This was meant to determine whether the level and dynamic behaviour of expenditure policy measures coupled with monetary policy during the period under review have effectively and efficiently led to economic growth and reduced inflationary pressure. Thus, the discussion in this chapter summaries the entire study in what follows: Chapter one of the studies dealt with the historical background, problem statement, research objectives, justification, scope, methodology and the plan of the study. In chapter two, we reviewed the related literature under which the followings where considered: the theoretical and empirical literatures on fiscal policy and macroeconomic stability as well as monetary policy practices; implementation of economic reforms; appraisal of economic policy measures; the challenges ahead and concluding remarks. 112 The third chapter presented the basic theoretical framework for fiscal relations and the methodological issues such as the macro models description, estimation techniques, data types and sources. However, chapter four examined the estimation procedures and issues of empirical analyses (including the long-run and short-run models), the trends in fiscal operations, transmission mechanisms and the policy implications of results. Thus, the discussion in this subsession summaries the findings as follows; we evaluated critically both trend and regression analyses. The trend result indicated that: The pattern of public expenditure was largely influenced by the revenue generated during the period under review. High oil revenue earnings encouraged government to raise expenditure to unsustainable levels, thus the fiscal operations resulted in overall fiscal deficits continuously from 1980 to 1994 while surplus was recorded in 1996 and it later increases from 1997 to 2007. Also, the relationships among the variables were examined by analyzing their long-run properties and short-run dynamics. The macroeconometric results from the long-run models showed that the explanatory variables are significant in explaining the observed variations in the GDP growth. This implies that the fiscal and monetary policy measures impact positively on economic growth in Nigeria. But surprisingly, the 113 explanatory variables were quite unable to explain the variations in the levels of inflation. Similarly, the macroeconometric results from dynamic short-run (error correction models) revealed that the independent variables accounted for the variations in the level of inflation. This suggests that INF rate adjusts to change in exogenous variables (GE, GR and MS) in the same time period. As a result, the shortrun changes in the money supply have a positive impact on the short-run changes in the inflation rates, while the other variables have negative effects. Finally, this last chapter of the research works centre on summary of findings, conclusions and recommendations. Lessons for public policy from the analysis and suggestion for further studies are presented. 5.2 CONCLUSIONS The improvement in fiscal management has been at the centre of recent economic reform agenda. To achieve a long term fiscal sustainability, it is imperative to enhance efficiency and quality of public expenditure, strengthen fiscal coordination among the three tiers of government, through Implementing the fiscal responsibility legislation, Public procurement legislation and Improve management of oil revenue. Growth, wealth creation and poverty reduction are all undermined when public 114 financial management and taxation are weak. Fiscal policy’s full potential will not be realized until good and accountable expenditure and taxation systems are put in place. The policy-makers should understand that the goal of macroeconomic policies has broadened to the full recognition that macroeconomic stability involves multiple dimensions, including not only price stability and sound fiscal policies, but also a wellfunctioning real economy. A well-functioning real economy requires, in turn, smoother business cycles, moderate long-term interest rates and competitive exchange rates, all of which may be considered intermediate goals of the ultimate Keynesian objective: full employment. Such a broad view of macroeconomic stability should recognize, in any case, that there is no simple correlation between its various dimensions and, thus, that multiple objectives and significant trade-offs are intrinsic to the design of “sound” macroeconomic frameworks. This view would lead to the recognition of the role played by two sets of policy packages, whose relative importance will vary depending on the structural characteristics, the macroeconomic policy tradition and the institutional capacity of the country. The first policy package involves a mix of counter-cyclical fiscal and monetary policies with appropriate exchange rate regimes. The second includes a set of capital management techniques designed to reduce the unsustainable accumulation of public and private sector risks in the face of pro-cyclical access to international capital 115 markets. To encourage economic growth, such interventions through the business cycle would lead to sound fiscal systems that provide the necessary resources for the public sector to do its job, a competitive exchange rate and moderate long-term real interest rates. These conditions, together with deep financial markets that provide suitably priced investment finance in the domestic currency with sufficiently long maturities, are the best contribution that macroeconomics can make to growth. In the context of the overall objective of accelerated economic development, monetary policy has had to grapple with the major challenges, thus: the maintenance of a healthy balance of payments and relative price stability. The relative success or lack of it, in the attainment of such demand management objectives should not be arrogated to or blamed on the monetary policy because other policies and factors simultaneously influence the macroeconomic goals of income, employment, prices and balance of payments equilibrium. However, the monetary authority should look back into its short history of monetary management with the satisfaction that it has so far skillfully made a selective use of the available and applicable techniques to suit the dynamic economic and financial conditions of the emerging modern economy of Nigeria. 116 Overall, fiscal policy reveals more about the political priorities underpinning our country’s development strategy than any other area of policy making. The major problem with our government and leaders is that they have concentrated more on how to share poverty than how to create wealth. The intensity of the government struggle has been so fierce, divisive and selfish that they have succeeded in improving themselves. 5.3 RECOMMENDATION Given the foregoing situation, to turn the scales, the government must invest and fund education; increased productivity in agricultural sector; investments in infrastructure to support the growth of the private sector and create jobs as well as ensuring that the state and local governments live up to the challenge of ensuring transparent accountable and responsible governance in order to broaden and deepen the reforms, therefore delivering the benefits of the reforms to the Nigerian populace, especially the poor and underprivileged. The policy-makers in Nigeria need to implement Pareto-improving revenue allocation policy. This is necessary because the Pareto-optimal for the revenue allocation formula would provide incentives for the three tiers of government that 117 want to exert more tax effort to generate more revenues in their specific areas of jurisdiction rather than being a free-rider as is currently the case. The revenue sharing problem should be reformulated as a classic principalagent paradigm under moral hazard conditions to overhaul Nigeria’s fractious revenue sharing arrangement in order to minimize the anomalies identified in the system. More importantly, our leaders should properly design an inter-governmental transfer system that compensates federating units for tax effort sine qua non for both long-term political and economic stability. The bearing of such an approach to fiscal transfer on fiscal prudence, sustainability and political stability of the federation and social harmony would be evident. Enough of opportunistic fiscal behaviour otherwise the ultimate economic and social outcomes may be against the long-term of the federation. Therefore, governments are expected to address resource distribution inequity and the associated fiscal imbalances in the environment. Also, they should use transfers to induce some sub-national units (local and state governments) to internalize social and economic externalities through the adoption of a certain socioenvironmental quality, and infrastructure. 118 Adopting performance-based budgeting, that will link envisaged outcomes to budgetary allocation, promoting citizens participation in public budgeting, and expenditure monitoring and rigorous application of the provisions of the Fiscal order to: review taxes to make them fewer in number, more broad-based and higherrevenue yielding; shift the focus of tax system from direct taxation to indirect taxation; and avoid multiple taxation by various tiers of government on income, property, imports, production and turnover. For the future, there are obvious indications that the CBN would continue to face a complex financial situation featuring, among other things, a destabilizing monetary expansion from factors largely outside its direct control. This been the case, there is a critical need to employ monetary policy more flexibly to counteract the destabilizing effects of exogenous factors and steer the economy along the desired path of socio-economic progress. The persisting practice of annual frequency of monetary policy formation as if it was a mere component of the government budgetary exercise, is not only peculiar but also represents an inadvertent compounding of the problem of action lag in policy formation. This is clearly unsatisfactory in a dynamic and rapidly changing society such as Nigeria. Although the Nigerian financial and economic conditions do not as yet admit of such frequency of monetary regulation as their counterpart advanced countries, there 119 is obviously a convincing case for taking an immediate monetary policy action as soon as the need is recognized rather than wait for the beginning of every fiscal year before formulating monetary policy. Furthermore, as financial adviser to the government, the CBN should not relent its efforts in emphasizing the need for a more integrated approach to macroeconomic management in order to minimize the pursuit of conflicting objectives by the various organs of governmental machinery responsible for policy formation and implementation. Also, government should recognize that the great responsibility of the CBN is to safeguard the national money which requires that it must keep itself liquid at all times and hold only first class assets. Therefore, its management must be above sectional politics, that is, the need to insulate the CBN from partisan politics. Thus, CBN should be kept absolutely free to give impartial advice to government on the use of monetary policy instruments based solely upon the good of the economy and never upon political experiences. The policy-makers should know that reforms build on each other. The returns rise more rapidly the more widespread and the more co-coordinated they are. For any country that is ill-prepared, the modern global economy can seem harsh. For those with sound policies, the rewards are great indeed. Perseverance is worth it. 120 The short-run target for the economy must be able to consolidate economic reforms through continued pursuance of sound macroeconomic management and fiscal prudence. In the medium-term, government should empower micro units of productive activities to utilise the benefits from the macroeconomic reforms. In the long-run, government must strive to attain the growth objectives as set out in our NEEDS 2 in order to reduce poverty by at least 30% by 2011, and attain annual GDP growth rate of at least 13% so as to make Nigeria one of the 20 largest economies in 2020. On a final note, Nigeria needs to ensure better value for money, manage the recurrent spending of the government, seek better participation of the private sector, especially in the provision of infrastructure, strengthen monitoring, auditing and reporting processes and strengthen fiscal co-ordination amongst the 3 tiers of government. 5.4 SUGGESTION FOR FURTHER RESEARCH On one side, there is the vast array of fiscal institutions such as tax system, expenditure programmes, budget procedures, stabilization instruments, debt issues etc., and there is an endless stream of issues arising in the operation of these institutions. Further issues in fiscal and stabilization policies which need to be explored extensively and demand the attention of the researchers are: tax-structure policy and incentives; shares of education and transfers; spatial aspect of stabilization; federal 121 grant and equalization; fiscal solvency and debt issues; earnings indexation and inflation; term structure of rate theory; and coordination of income, expenditure and stabilization. The forgoing non-exhaustive issues make rising further conceptual and policy researchable questions, thus: What taxes are to be chosen and who really bears their burden? How the fiscal functions should be divided among levels of government? How big a share of GDP should be included in the public sector and how should the choice of public expenditures be determined? How can a high level of employment be reconciled with stable prices? How does inflation enter into the rate structure? To what extend can earnings of populace be indexed to inflation? And does debt finance burden future generation? Pursuit of these issues will lead from one end of economic analysis to the other. In conclusion, therefore, the application of economic theories, principles, and policies to an imperfect world such as Nigeria is not only challenging but also stimulating analytically and policy-wise. What this study has done is to apply modern macroeconomic theory to an important issue in fiscal sustainability of expenditure policy in Nigeria. However, there are several areas of research in Nigeria Sub-Saharan Africa that would benefit immensely from this application of public finance. The 122 pervasiveness of macroeconomic instability in the region reveals that wide range and fruitful research can be undertaken in all areas of economics from microeconomics to public sector economics, development, international, monetary, industry, financial, environmental, petroleum and energy, econometrics, political economy, information economics and macroeconomics. 123 BIBLIOGRAPHY Adeyeye and Fakiyesi (1980), “Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments Blending with other Lines of Analysis,” International Monenary Fund (IMF) survey, 7, 152-185. Aghevli, B. B. and M. S. Khan (1970), “Inflationary finance and Economic Growth,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 85, No. 4. Alade, S. (2003), “Fiscal Adjustment in Nigeria: Issues in Capital Expenditure”, the Bullion, Volume 27, Number 2: 8-16. Anderson, L. C. and K. M. Carlson (1972), “An econometric analysis of the relation of monetary variables on the behavior of prices and unemployment.” In Otto Eckstem, ed., 1972 ‘the econometric of price determination’ Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Anyanwu, J. C. (1997), Nigeria Public Finance, Anambra: Joanee Educational Publishers Ltd. Anyanwu, J. C. (1993), Monetary Economics: Theory, Policy and Institutions, Onitsha: Hybrid Publishers Ltd. Ariyo, A. (1993), “An Assessment of the Sustainability of Nigeria’s Fiscal Deficit: 1970124 1990” Journal of African Economies, Vol. 2, No. 2, 262-282. Ariyo, A. (1996), “Economic Reform and Macroeconomic Management in Nigeria”. Ibadan: Ibadan University Press. Asegaer, David (1988), “The Equilibrium Approach to Fiscal Policy,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, February 20, 41-62. Babalola, Remi (2007), “The National Council on Finance and Economic Development (NACOFED),” An address by the Honourable Minister of State for Finance at the Annual Conference, holding at Zaranda Hotel, Bauchi on 14th-15th November. Ball, Laurence (1998), “Policy Rules for Open Economies” NBER d.p 6760. Ball, Laurence (2000), “Policy Rules and External Shocks” NBER d.p 7970. Barnett, Steven and Rolando Ossowski (2002), “Operational Aspects of Fiscal Policy in Oil-Producing Countries,” Working Paper No. WP/02/177, Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. Barro, R. J. (1979), “On the Determination of the Public Debt,” the Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 5, No. 3. Barro, R. J. (1987), “Government Spending, Interest Rates, Prices and Budget Deficits in 125 the United Kingdom, 1701-1918”. Journal of monetary Economic, Vol. 20, 2 September: 221-447. Barro, R. J. (1990), “Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth,” Journal of Political Economy. Vol. 15, No 2. Baunsgaard, T. (2003), “Fiscal Policy in Nigeria: Any Role for Rules?” International Monetary Fund Working Paper Number WP/ 03/ 155. Bhatia, H. L. (2002), Public Finance, New Delhi: Vikas Publishing House, pp. 212-239. Blanchard, O. J. and S. Fischer (1989), Lectures on Macroeconomics, Cambridge, MA.: MIT Press. Blejer, M. and M. S. khan (1984) “Government Policy and Private Investment in Developing Countries,” Staff Papers, IMF, Vol. 13, pp. 379-403. Bleaney, M. and D. Greenaway (2001), “The Impact of Terms of Trade and Real Exchange Rate Volatility on Investment and Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa,” Journal of Development Economics, 65(2): 491-500. Brown, E. Cary (1956), “Fiscal policy in the thirties: A Reappraisal,” American Economic Review, December. Busari, T. D. P. C. Omoke, and A. B. Adesoye (2006), “Monetary Policy and 126 Macroeconomic Stabilization under Alternative Exchange Rate Regime: Evidence from Nigeria”. Retrieved 5th May, 2009 from http:// www.unionbanking.com/busari.pdf Busari, T. D. and K. W. Olayiwola (1999), “Stabilization Policy in Nigeria Under Alternative Exchange Rate Regimes: A Postulated Empirical macro-Model Approach.” Central Bank of Nigeria Economic and Financial Review, 37 (1) March: 21-35. Central Bank of Nigeria Ordinance (1958) Central Bank of Nigeria (1979), Twenty Years of Central Banking in Nigeria: 1959-1979, Research Department, CBN Lagos. Central Bank of Nigeria Act (1991) Central Bank of Nigeria (Various Dates), CBN Statistical Bulletin Central Bank of Nigeria (1995), Monetary Policy in Nigeria, CBN Briefs, Research Department Series 95/03. Central Bank of Nigeria (Various Dates), Annual Reports and Statement of Accounts. Central Bank of Nigeria (2006a), “First Quarter Economic Report 2006”, Abuja: Central Bank of Nigeria (CBN). Central Bank of Nigeria (2006b), “2006 Annual Report”, Abuja: CBN Chibber, A. and Mansoor Danlami (1990), “Fiscal Policy and Private Investment in 127 Developing Countries, Recent Evidence on Key Selected Issues”. Recherche Economiche, Vol. 91, 651-652. Chowdhury, A. R. (1991), “A Note on the Relative Impact of Monetary and Fiscal Actions in India”, the Indian Economic Journal, Vol. 34, No. 1. David, M. O. and M. M. Ansariu (1995), “Measuring Fiscal Performance of the Central and State Government in India: A Study in Resource Mobilization”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 33, No. 4. Darrat, A. F. (1986), “The Dominant Influence of Fiscal Actions in Developing Countries”, Eastern Economic Journal, Vol. X, No. 3, July-Sept., 272-284. Dickey, D. A. and W. A. Fuller (1979), “Distribution of the Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root”. Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 74. Due, F. J. (1993), Government Finance: Economics of the Public Sector. Richard D. Irwin Inc., Illinois. Ekeoku, N. I. (1974), “A Macroeconomic Simulation Analysis of Fiscal Policy Effectiveness in Nigeria”, Nigerian Journal of Economic and Social Studies,Vol10 Ekpo, A. (2003), “The Macroeconomic Policy Framework: Issues and Challenges,” in 128 Central Bank of Nigeria Third Annual Monetary Policy Conference Proceedings on Issues in Fiscal Management: Implications for Monetary Policy in Nigeria, 11-12 December 2003 (Lagos, Central Bank of Nigeria Publications). Engel, R. F. and C. W. Granger (1987), “Co-integration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing”. Econometrica, Vol. 55, 251-276. Enwenze, C. (1974), “Structure of Public Expenditure in Developing Countries”, the Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, Vol. 40. Ezeoha, Abel and Chibuike U. Uche (2006), “Rethinking Monetary and Fiscal Policies in Nigeria,” Retrieved on May 5, 2009, from http://www.jsd- africa.com/Jsda/Summer_2006/PDF/ARC_RethinkingMonetaryFisicalPolicies.pd f. Faforiji, R. A. (1984), “Public Expenditure Growth in Nigeria: Growth and Evidence”, Department of Economic, O. A. U. Ile-Ife, Mimeo Fatas Antonio and Ilian Mihov (2003), “The Case for Restricting Fiscal Policy Discretion,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 118 (November): 1419-47 Federal Government of Nigeria Budget Speeches (Various Years) Fischer, S. and W. Easterly (1990), “The economics of the government budget Constraint”, the World Bank Research Observer, Vol. 5, No. 2, July, 127-142. Folawewo, A. O. and T. S. Osinubi (2006), “Monetary Policy and Macroeconomic 129 Instability in Nigeria: A Rational Expectation Approach”. J. Soc. Sci., 12(2): 93100. Friedman, Milton (1948), “A Monetary and Fiscal Framework for Economic Stability” Reprinted in Milton Friedman, Essays in Positive Economics, 2nd ed., Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1953. Friedman, Milton (1968), “The Role of Monetary policy.” American Economic Review 58, 1 Mar., 1-17. Gbosi, A. N. (1995), “Economic Reforms and Stability of Nigeria’s Financial Institutions” Upper Standard Ltd., Lagos. Gbosh, B. N. (1972), “Monetary VS. Fiscalist: A Reconciliatory Approach”, Vol. 30. Gujarati, D. N. (2006), Basic Econometrics, 4th Ed., and New Delhi: Tata McGraw-Hill Publishing Co. Ltd. Chap. 21, PP. 792-834. Handa, J. (1970), “A Theoretical Framework for the Monetary and Fiscal Analysis of Underdeveloped Economies”. Journal of the Institute of Developing Economies, Vol. VIII, No. 3, Sept. Ikporukpo, C. O. (1996), Federalism, Political Power, and the Economic Power Game: Conflict over Access to Petroleum Resources in Nigeria”. Environment and Planning Volume 14, Pp. 159-177. IMF (2001), “Nigeria: 2001 Article IV Consultation”, IMF Country Report No. 01/131, 130 Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. IMF (2003), “Nigeria: 2002 Article IV Consultation”, IMF Country Report No. 03/3, Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. IMF (2003), ”Fiscal Adjustment in IMF-Supported Programs”, Independent Evaluation Office, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. IMF (2004a), “Public Investment and Fiscal Policy”, Document presented to the Board, March 12, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. IMF (2004b), “Assessing Sustainability”, Document presented to the Board, May 28, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. IMF (2005a), “Nigeria: Selected Issues and Statistical Appendix”, Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. IMF (2005b), “Nigeria: Request for a Two-Year Policy Support Instrument”, Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. Iwayemi, A. (2009), “Incentivizing Fiscal Federalism: An Economic Analysis of Intergovernmental Transfers and Revenue Allocation in Nigeria” paper presented at the Department of Economics, University of Ibadan, Ibadan, May 21. Iyoha, M. A. (2002), Macroeconomics: Theory and Policy. Benin City: Mindex Publishing. Iyoha, M. A. (2004), Applied Econometrics, 2nd ed., Benin City: Mindex Publishing 131 Iyoha, M. A. and C. O. Itsede (2003), Nigerian Economy: Structure Growth and Development, Benin City: Mindex Publishing, Nigeria. Jhingan, M. L. (2001), Advanced Economic Theory: Micro- and Macro Economics, 11th Ed., Delhi: Mayur Vihar, Vrinda Publications (P) Ltd. P. 792 Jorgen, R. (1973), “Some Economic Effects of Increasing Public Expenditures: An Empirical Study of Selected Developed Countries”. Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 8, No. 1. Keynes, J. M. (1936), “General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money”. Reprinted in Harbinger, Harcourt Brace and World, 1964. Keynes, J. M. (1939), “Relative Movements in Real Wages and Output,” Economic Journal, 34-51. Krueger, Anne O. (2004), “Pursuing the Achievable: Macroeconomic Stability And Sustainable Growth in Turkey”, in Economic Congress of Turkey, IMF External Relations Department, International Monetary Fund, Izmir, May 5. Kwakwa, V. (2003), “A Framework for Assessing Fiscal Sustainability: Application to 132 Nigeria”, Third Annual Monetary Policy Conference Proceedings on Issues in Fiscal Management: Implications for Monetary Policy in Nigeria, 11-12 December (Lagos, Central Bank of Nigeria Publications). Lotz, J. R. (1970), “Patterns of Government Spending in Developing Countries”. The Manchester School of Economics and Social Studies, Vol. 33, No. 2. Manas-Anton (1986), “On the Empirical Definition of Fiscal Policy”. The Nigerian Journal of Economics and Social Studies, Vol. 16, Sept. Marfán, Manuel (2005), “Fiscal Policy, Efficacy and Private Deficits: A Macroeconomic Approach”, in José Antonio Ocampo (ed.). Beyond Reforms: Structural Dynamics and Macroeconomic Vulnerability. Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA, and Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean, Santiago: 161-188. Masson, P. R. (1985), “The Sustainability of Fiscal Deficits”. IMF Staff Papers, 32.4: December, 577-605. Mundell, R. A. (1962), “The Appropriate use of Fiscal and Monetary Policy for Internal and External Stability”. IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 9, No. 3. Musgrave, R. A. and P. B. Musgrave (2004), Public Finance in Theory and Practice, 5th Ed., New Delhi: Tata McGraw-Hill Publishing Co. Ltd. National Economic Intelligence Committee (1998), “Economic Recovery Programme, 133 1996-1998: An Alternative to the Medium-Term Programme of the World bank/ IMF”. Abuja, Nigeria. National Planning Commission (2004), “The National Economic Empowerment and Development Strategy (NEEDS)”, Abuja, Nigeria. Ndebbio, J. E. U. (1998), “Fiscal Policy and Inflationary Process in an Open Economy: The Case of Nigeria”. Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 40, No. 3. Nitti, F. S. (1903), Principidi Scienza delle Finanze. Nwachukwu and Adeleke (1992), “Military Expenditure and Macroeconomic Performance in Nigeria”. The Nigerian Journal of Economics and Social Studies, Vol. 8, Dec. Ocampo, José Antonio (2002), “Developing Countries’ Anti-Cyclical Policies in a Globalized World,” in Amitava Dutt and Jaime Ocampo, José Antonio, and Juan Martin (2003), “Globalization and Development,” Stanford University Press, Stanford: CA, and Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean, Santiago. Ocampo, J. A. (2005), “A Broad View of Macroeconomic Stability, Economic and Social Affairs”, DESA Working paper 1, ST/ESA/2005/DWP/1, New York: Development of Economic and Social Affairs, Retrieved March 29, 2009, from http://www.un.org/esa/desa/papers/2005/wp1_2005.pdf. 134 Ojo, M. O. (1982), “Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payment”. IMF Staff Papers 7, 132-151. Okonjo-Iweala, N (2003), Issues in Fiscal Management: Implications for Monetary Policy in Nigeria, Third Annual Monetary Policy Conference Proceedings on Issues in Fiscal Management: Implications for Monetary Policy in Nigeria, 11-12 December 2003 (Lagos, Central Bank of Nigeria Publications). Okonjo-Iweala, N and P. Osafo-Kwaako (2007), “Nigeria’s Economic Reforms: Progress and Challenges,” in Global Economy and Development Programme, the Brookings Institution, Washinton, D. C. Retrieved 5th May, 2009 from http://www3.brookings.edu/views/papers/20070323okonjo=iweala.pdf. Olaloye A. O. and S. I. Ikhide (1995), Economic Sustainability and Role of Fiscal and Monetary Policy in a Depressed Economy: The case of Nigeria. Olofin, Sam (2001), An Introduction to Macroeconomic, Lagos: Malthouse Press Ltd. Omoruyi, O. T. (2000), “Monetary Policy in the 1980s and Prospects in the 1990s,” Central Bank of Nigeria, Economics and Financial Review, 30. Onimode, B. (2001), “Fiscal Federalism in Nigeria: Options for the 21 st Century”, Volume 1, Research Report, NISER, Ibadan. Oyejide, T. A. (1972), “Demand for Money in Nigerian Economy.” The Nigerian Journal 135 of Economic Studies, 6, March. Oyejide, T. (2003), “The Challenges of Monetary Management in an Environment of Fiscal Dominance”, Third Annual Monetary Policy Conference Proceedings on Issues in Fiscal Management: Implications for Monetary Policy in Nigeria, 11-12 December (Lagos, Central Bank of Nigeria Publications). Packard, P. C. (1966), “A Note on Gross Domestic Investment and Fiscal Policy”. The Nigerian Journal of Economics and Social Studies, Vol. 8, No. 2, May. Phillips, A. O. (1971), “Nigerian Public Consumption Expenditure”. The Nigerian Journal of Economics and Social Studies, Vol. 13, No. 3. Phillips, A. (1991), “Managing Fiscal Federalism: Revenue Allocation Issue,” Publius 21, PP. 103-111. Romer, C. (1986), “New Estimates of Pre-war Gross National Product and Unemployment,” JEH June, 341- 352. Romer, David (1988) “What are the Costs of Excessive Deficits?” NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 63-98. Ros (eds), “Development Economics and Structuralist Macroeconomics: Essays in Honour of Lance Taylor,” Edward Elgar, Aldershot, UK: 374-405. Sanusi, J. (2003), Keynote Address, Third Annual Monetary Policy Conference 136 Proceedings on Issues in Fiscal Management: Implications for Monetary Policy in Nigeria, 11-12 December (Lagos, Central Bank of Nigeria Publications). Sargan, J. D. (1984), “Wages and Prices in the United Kingdom: A study in Econometric Methodology”. In Wallis, K. F. and D. F. Hendry, eds., Quantitative Economics and Econometric Analysis, Basil Blackwell, Oxford, U. K. Servén, L. (2003), “Real Exchange Rate Uncertainty and Private Investment in LDCs,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol 85(1): 212-218. Shaw, G. K. (1986), “Monetary-Fiscal Policy for Growth and Balance of Payment Constraints”. Economica, Vol. 34, No. 134. Siegel, J. J. (1976), “Stability of Keynesian-classical Macro Economy System”, Journal of Monetary Economic, 2: 257-266. Sloman, J. (1995), Economics. U. K.: The Edinburg Press Ltd. Smith, W. (1978), “Monetary and Fiscal Policies for Economic Growth,” Readings in Money, National Income Stabilization Policy, Richard Inwin Inc., illinosis. Snyder, W. W. (1970), “Measuring Economic Stability: 1955-65”. American Economic Reviews, December, Vol. 60, 924-33. Stiglitz, J. E. (1974), “Incentives and Risk Sharing in Sharecropping,” Review of 137 Economic Studies. 41, 219-55. Stiglitz, J. E., and Amar Bhattacharya (2000), “The Underpinnings of a Stable and Equitable Global Financial System: From Old Debates to a New Paradigm”. In Proceedings of the Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics 1999. World Bank, Washington, DC: 91-130. Stiglitz, J. E. (2003), “Whither Reform? Toward a New Agenda for Latin America”, CEPAL Review, 80: 7-38. Svensson, Lars E. O. (2000), “Open-economy Inflation Targeting”. Journal of International Economics 50: 155-183. Teriba, O. and S. I. Ajayi (1975), “Demand for Money in Nigeria: Analysis of Distributed Lag Structure,” the Nigerian Journal of Economic and Social Studies 25, June. Uche, C. U. (2001), “The Politics of Monetary Sector Cooperation among the Economic Community of West African States Members”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Number 2647 (Washington DC, World Bank) Usman, Shamsudden (2007), “Improving Fiscal Coordination between the Federal and State Governments”, Presentation at the Department for International Development (DFID) Country Partnership Strategy Retreat by the Honourable 138 Minister of Finance October 3, Retrieved on 29/05/2009, from http://www.fmf.gov.ng/FMF_News.aspx?id=54. Usman, S. (2008), “Fiscal Policy, Poverty and Growth: The Nigerian Perspective,” Speech Delivered at the 2nd Clement Isong Annual Memorial Lecture, Uyo, Akwa Ibom State. 15th February. Vashist, B. K. (1991), “Macroeconomic Policy: A Meade-Mundel Synthesis and Extension”, the Indian Economic Journal, Vol. 36, No. 3. Wagner, Adolph C. (1890), Finanzwissenschaft, Leipzig, 3rd Ed. Part 1, p.16 Wagner, A. C. (1893), Grandlegung der Politischen Oekonomie, 3rd Ed. William,Easterly, Roumeen Islam and Joseph E. Stiglitz (2001). “Shaken and Stirred: Explaining Growth Volatility”. In Boris Pleskovic and Nicholas Stern (eds). Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics 2000. World Bank, Washington, DC: 191-212. Wiseman, Jack and Allan T. Peacock (1961), The Growth of Public Expenditure in the United Kingdom, 1890-1955, Princeton University Press. World Bank (1988), World Development Report, New York: Oxford University Press for the World Bank, 182-185. World Bank (2003), “Nigeria Policy Options for Growth and Stability”, Report No. 139 26215-NGA, Washington DC: The World Bank. 140