B t - Yingying Dong

advertisement
Why Do the Insured Use More Health Care?
The Role of Insurance-Induced Unhealthy Behaviors
Yingying Dong
Boston College
10/16/2008
A Real Life Story

From the New York Times (Nov. 25, 2002):
Mr. & Ms. Brooks dropped their health insurance because of increased premiums.
Then…
“Mr. Brooks, 50, has stopped taking Lipitor to control high cholesterol and has
started taking over-the-counter herbal supplements. Ms. Brooks no longer takes
Singulair for asthma and has adopted an exercise program intended to regulate
her breathing. Ms. Brooks estimates they are saving $150 a month by not using
prescription drugs. ‘We changed our diets a lot to help the effectiveness of the
supplements, and maybe that’s a good thing,’ she said.”
--Broder, John. “Problem of Lost Health Benefits is Reaching into the Middle Class.”
Also cited by Dave & Kaestner (2006)
1/29
Motivation – (1)

Health insurance is associated with an increased use of health
care. (Yelin et al, 2001; Meer and Rosen, 2003; Pauly, 2005; Bajari, Hong and Khwaja, 2006;
Deb and Trivedi, 2006)

Usually assumed:

Individuals who potentially have a greater need of heath care are
more motivated to get insured (selection effect).

Insurance reduces the effective price of health care and hence
induces individuals to use more.
★
What’s missing:
Insurance encourages unhealthy behaviors, which may cause
increased use of health care.


Unhealthy behaviors: Drinking, Smoking, Insufficient Exercise, and
unhealthy diet
2/29
Motivation- (2)

Intuitions:

Insurance lowers the offsetting cost for the negative health
consequences of unhealthy behaviors. disincentive effect


Car insurance reduces precaution and stimulates car accidents;
Workplace injury compensations increase injuries.

Individuals with health problems substitute medication for
behavioral improvement. substitution effect

Easily accessible health care may distort the perceived risk of
unhealthy behaviors. distorted image
3/29
Illustration of Causalities
Health
Insurance
Health
Insurance
Selection Effect
Use of
Health Care
True Moral Hazard
Selection Effect
Pure Price Effect
Use of
Health Care
Selection Effect
(Ex post) Moral Hazard
Health Related
Behaviors
(1) Causalities traditionally studied
(2) A fuller View of Causalities

True Moral Hazard: the disincentive effect of health insurance on individuals’
healthy behaviors, which may generate additional medical care demand.

Pure Price Effect: the effect that health insurance lowers the effective price of
health care and hence induces individuals to use more care ceteris paribus.
4/29
Literature Review

Most existing literature studies the insurance effect on medical
utilization; a small strand examines the insurance effect on health
behaviors. They do not look at the structural causal relationships
among the three.

Literature examining the insurance effect on medical utilization:


Studies examining the insurance effect on prevention, including
behaviors (discrete outcomes):


Reviews: Zweifel and Manning (2000), Buchmueller et al (2005)
Kenkel (2000), Courbage and Coulon (2004)
A few studies that do consider all three focus on discrete outcomes

Khwaja (2002, 2006) and Card et al. (2004)
5/29
Research Questions & Approaches

(1) What are the effects of health insurance on individuals’ health behaviors?

(2) What is the (total) effect of health insurance on health care utilization?

(3) Within the total effect of health insurance on health care utilization, how
much is caused by the pure price effect, and how much is caused by
individuals’ behavior change when they have insurance?

Start from a theoretical model to derive the structural model for the insurance
decision, health behaviors, and health care utilization

Solve the structural model to obtain the semi-reduced form equations
determining behaviors and care utilization as functions of endogenous health
insurance

Derive the structural parameters of interest: the direct and indirect effects of
health insurance on health care utilization

Empirical analysis adopts the generalized Tobit specification with transformations
on the dependent and lagged dependent variables.
6/29
Contributions


Theoretically,

Set up a two-period dynamic forward-looking model and derive the structural
causal relationship among the insurance, behaviors and health care utilization;

Model continuous choices instead of discrete choices.
Empirically,

Distinguish between the extensive margin (changes in the proportion of the
unhealthy behavior participants) and the intensive margin (changes in the
quantity of unhealthy behaviors given participation) of the insurance effect;

Accommodate the distribution characteristics of the data and adopt flexible
transformations;

Analyze the insurance effects on heavy drinking, and how the insurance-induced
drinking affects medical utilization.
7/29
Basic Theoretical Model – (1)

A two-period dynamic forward-looking model;

The individual draws utility from composite good consumption (Ct),
unhealthy behaviors (Bt), and health (Ht ); Assume rational addiction of
unhealthy behaviors.

Utility function: Ct  U (Bt 1 , Bt , H t ,t , t , st )   [Ct 1  U (Bt , Bt 1 , H t 1 ,t , t 1 , st 1 )]


Health evolution equation: H t 1   H t  H ( M t , Bt , st )
Budget constraint: (Ct  PIt I t  PB Bt  (1  dI t )M t )   (Ct 1  PB Bt 1 )  Wt .







Ht = Initial health status/Health stock;
Mt = medical care utilization;
Bt = (Bt1, Bt2, Bt3)': drinking, smoking and exercise;
st = health shock, which may depend on Ht, Bt;
t = permanent taste parameter;  t = taste shifter;
Wt = present value of total wealth;
It = insurance dummy; dt = the insurer co-payment rate.
8/29
Basic Theoretical Model – (2)

The individual invests in health in 1st period (t), and bears the addiction and
negative health consequences of unhealthy behaviors in 2nd period (t+1).

C: choice set:
{It}
{Ct, Bt, Mt}
{Ct+1, Bt+1}
F: information set: {Bt1,Ht, t,t} {Bt1,Ht, It, t ,t} {Bt,Ht+1,It,t,t+1, st+1}
S: shock set:
{st , st+1, t+1} {st, st+1, t+1}
{st+1}


At the beginning
of 1st period

In 1st period
In 2nd period
Expected Utility maximization
max
 I t ;Ct , Bt , M t 
F


 Ct 1 , Bt 1
s.t.
Est , t 1 , st 1 Ct  U (Bt 1 , Bt , H t ,t , t , st )  Ct 1  U (Bt , B*t 1 , H t 1 ,t , t 1 , st 1 ) 
(Ct  PIt I t  PB Bt  (1  dI t ) M t )   (Ct 1  PB Bt 1 )  Wt .
9/29
Structural & Semi-reduced Form
Equations

Maximizing expected utility by backward induction
 Structural equations (FOC’s) for Mt, Bt and the insurance decision It
M t  f M ( I t , Bt , H t ,t , t )
Btl  f Bl ( I t , B t-1 , M t , H t ,t , t ), for l  1, 2,3
I t  1 f I (Bt 1 , H t ,t , t )  PIt  0


Bt-1, PIt : exclusion restrictions

fI() = PIt*: willingness-to-pay for insurance

Intuitions
(1)
(2)
(3)
Solve (1),(2) for Bt and Mt  semi-reduced form equations
M t  g M ( I t , Bt 1 , H t ,t , t )
Btl  g Bl ( I t , Bt 1 , H t ,t , t ), for l  (1, 2,3)

Assume U() is quadratic and health production function is linear
 linear functions for Bt and Mt and the It index
10/29
(4)
(5)
Direct and Indirect Insurance
Effects on Care Utilization - (1)

Eqs. (1), (4) and (5) imply the following decomposition
Total effect = direct price effect + indirect effect
dM t M t Bt M t


dI t
I t
I t Bt
(I)
13 31
Obtained from Eq. (4)
1
M t  Bt  M t


Bt  Bt 1  Bt 1
To be backed out
31
33
31
Obtained from Eq. (5)
Obtained from the Eq. (5)
Obtained from Eq. (4)
11/29
(II)
Direct and Indirect Insurance
Effects on Care Utilization– (2)

(I)
dM t M t Bt M t


dI t
I t
I t Bt
is a vector form of
dM t M t M t Bt1 M t Bt2 M t Bt3




.
dI t
I t
Bt1 I t Bt2 I t
Bt3 I t
1

(II)
M t  Bt  M t


Bt  Bt 1  Bt 1
is the solution of a linear equation system
M t
Bt1 M t Bt2 M t Bt3 M t



,
Bt11 Bt11 Bt1 Bt11 Bt2 Bt11 Bt3
M t
Bt1 M t Bt2 M t Bt3 M t



,
Bt21 Bt21 Bt1 Bt21 Bt2 Bt21 Bt3
M t
Bt1 M t Bt2 M t Bt3 M t



.
Bt31 Bt31 Bt1 Bt31 Bt2 Bt31 Bt3
Three unknowns
12/29
General Data Problems

A significant fraction of zeros (68% zero drinking, 83% zero smoking)


Discrete change between zero & non-zero consumptionextensive margin
of the insurance effect

Continuous change in the positive level of consumptionintensive margin of
the insurance effect
Two part specification:
 Insurance effect on the probability of non-zero consumption
 Insurance effect on the level of consumption, given participation
 Generalized Tobit model (sample selection model)

A skewed distribution of positive observations (nonnormality)


Transformation on the dependent and lagged dependent variables
IHS (Inverse hyperbolic sine), Box-Cox, log
13/29
Empirical Model & Identification

Generalized Tobit (sample selection) model with transformations on
the dependent and lagged dependent variables
I t  1 Xt α  PIt  t  0 ,
1Yt  0  1  Xt b  b1 I t   t  0  ,
T (Yt ,Y )  1Yt  0  ( Xt b  b1I t   t ),



where Yt = Bt or Mt ; Xt  (1, T (Bt 1 ,B ), H t ,t ).
Insurance is endogenous joint estimate It and Bt or Mt .
PIt is an exclusion restriction (Instrumental Variable):
 Age≥65 dummy (Card, Dobkin and Maestas, 2004)
 Self-employment status(Meer and Rosen, 2003; Deb and Trivedi,
2006)
14/29
IV Validity-(1)

Relevance

insurance holding rate:



Age<65 (88.1%), Age≥65 (99.1%)
Self-employed(78.7% ), Non Self-employed (92.6%)
Exogeneity

Measures of medical care utilization and health behaviors would have evolved
smoothly with age in the absence of the discrete change in insurance coverage
at age 65.

Include in all equations a smooth age profile function, tentatively include age dummy in
the outcome equations, coefficients are not significant

Sargan’s and Basmann’s over-identification tests

Hansen’s J test

Using panel data check the transition into/out of self-employment on behaviors
15/29
IV Validity-(2)
Table 2-(a) The impact of transition out of self-employment on health behaviors
Treatment 1
Control 1
Diff.-In-Diff.
P-value
Change in drinking (level)
.271(.300)
-.087(.197)
.358(.359)
.319
Change in drinking (prob.)
-.028(.021)
-.029(.014)
.001(.025)
.965
Change in smoking (prob.)
-.009(.008)
-.014(.007)
.005(.010)
.637
Change in exercising (prob.)
-.050(.033)
-.027(.018)
-.023(.038)
.536
Table 2-(b) The impact of transition into self-employment on health behaviors
Treatment 1
Control 1
Diff.-In-Diff.
Change in drinking (level)
-.509(.419)
-.207(.041)
.301(.421)
.476
Change in drinking (prob.)
-.022(.028)
-.030(.004)
.008(.028)
.787
Change in smoking (prob.)
-.029(.015)
-.012(.002)
-.017(.015)
.267
Change in exercising (prob.)
.029(.041)
-.014(.005)
.043(.041)
.300
16/29
P-value
Sample Description

RAND HRS : 3rd, 4th and 5th (Year 96, 98, 00) waves of data

Not include:





Age>70,
On social security disability insurance,
Deceased within 2 years since being observed in the sample
N=14,289
Dependent variables :
 Dummies: smoking, exercising (3 or more times per week), drinking,
visiting a doctor/hospital (at least once for the past two years)

Levels: # of alcoholic drinks consumed per week
# of doctor/hospital visits per year
17/29
Summary Statistics-(1)
Insured (n=13,016)
Uninsured (n=1,273)
Mean
Std. Dev.
Mean
Std. Dev.
Visiting a doctor/hospital
.941
.235
.811
.391
# of visits
4.35
7.74
3.02
4.98
Current period: Smoking
.167
.373
.262
.440
Exercising
.504
.500
.485
.500
Drinking
.330
.470
.265
.441
7.14
8.50
10.17
12.61
Positive # of alcoholic drinks

The insured are more likely to visit a doctor or hospital, and they also have
more visits on average than the uninsured.
Insurance
is associated with healthier behaviors; e.g., The insured are less
likely to smoke; more likely to drink, but on average drink much less.
★ These may not be causal: confounding factors or selection effects.
18/29
Summary Statistics-(2)
Insured (n=13,016)
Mean
Std. Dev.
Mean
Std. Dev.
.184
.387
.274
.446
Exercising
.523
.499
.516
.500
Drinking
.353
.478
.295
.456
7.01
8.46
10.58
15.29
.065
.246
.048
.214
Hypertension
.367
.482
.342
.475
Heart disease
.119
.324
.072
.259
Lung disease
.050
.218
.038
.191
61.65
5.19
59.48
4.97
Last period: Smoking
Positive # of alcoholic drinks
Last period diagnosed disease*: Cancer
Age
Uninsured (n=1,273)
The insured have healthier behaviors ex ante (last period);
 The insured are in general older, tend to have chronic diseases;

* This list leaves out some chronic diseases due to space limit.
19/29
Summary Statistics-(3)
Insured (n=13,016)
Uninsured (n=1,273)
Mean
Std. Dev.
Mean
Std. Dev.
Male
.406
.491
.341
.474
Hispanic
.067
.251
.235
.424
Last period health status: Fair/ Poor
.166
.372
.269
.444
Good/Very good
.652
.476
.571
.495
Excellent
.182
.386
.159
.366
.192
.394
.437
.496
High-school or GED
.386
.487
.311
.463
College or above
.422
.494
.252
.434
Income($1000)
62.80
86.19
36.27
65.93
Number of children
3.45
2.05
4.01
2.54
Education: Less than high-school

The insured also tend to have higher income, higher education…
20/29
Estimated Insurance Effects
Table 1 Insurance effects on the probabilities of using health care and health behaviors
Dependent variable
Coeff. Of Insurance
(SE)
Marginal Effect
Visiting a doctor/hospital (0/1)
.037
(.146)
.008
Exercising(0/1)
-.112
(.127)
-.045
Smoking(0/1)
.166
(.192)
.017
Drinking(0/1)
-.187
(.145)
-.065
Table 2 Insurance effects on the levels of health care utilization and drinking
HIS
Box-Cox
Log
% change (SE)
#
% change (SE)
#
% change (SE)
#
# of visits / year
.367(.069)***
1.67
.365(.069) ***
1.66
.368(.056) ***
1.68
# of alcoholic drinks/week
.122(.100)
.900
.120(.098)
.886
.108(.095)
.794
# of visits / year
.347(.069)***
1.58
.359(.068) ***
1.63
.348(.057) ***
1.58
# of alcoholic drinks/week
.043(.097)
.318
.041(.095)
.302
.029(.093)
.214
Model (1)
Model (2)
Model (1): Two-part Model ; Model (2): Sample selection Model; ***Significant at .01 level;
21/29
Further Investigation on Drinking

Puzzle 1: Insurance may decrease the probability of drinking, although it
may increase the amount of drinking by the drinkers.

Puzzle 2: The insurance effect on the probability of drinking and that on
smoking have opposite signs.

Unlike smoking, a low level of drinking is generally considered as healthy.

In the data, the insured have a smaller proportion of smokers, but a larger proportion of
drinkers; whereas the insured drinkers tend to be light drinkers.

Distinguish between light drinking and heavy drinking

Disincentive effect of insurance on healthy behaviors: Does insurance
holding encourage heavy drinking?
22/29
Further Investigation on Heavy
Drinking
Table 3 Insurance effects on heavy drinking
Heavy drinking
Probability
Weekly # of drinks (IHS model)
Cutoff
percentile
# of
drinks
Sample
mean
Coeff.(SE)
Marginal
effect
Marginal
effect (SE)
Change in
level
50th
>4
12.8
.093(.175)
.011
.131(.066) **
1.67
60th
>6
14.9
.190(.165)
.013
.155(.071) **
2.31
70th (mean)
>7
16.8
.127(.168)
.007
.120(.070) *
2.02
80th
>12
21.4
.229(.188)
.005
.177(.074) **
3.79
85th
>14
27.2
.307(.211)
.003
.232(.100) **
6.31
90th
>15
28.5
.330(.278)
.002
.255(.099) **
6.98
* Significant at .1 level; **Significant at .05 level; ***Significant at .01 level
23/29
Increased Number of Visits due to
Insurance-Induced Drinking

Increased medical utilization due to insurance-induced drinking:
(I)
(II)
dM t M t M t Bt1 M t Bt2 M t Bt3

 1


dI t
I t
Bt I t Bt2 I t Bt3 I t

dM t M t Bt M t


dI t
I t
I t Bt
1
M t  Bt  M t



Bt  Bt 1  Bt 1
Bt1 M t M t

Bt11 Bt1 Bt11
1

M t Bt1  Bt1  M t Bt1


Bt1 I t  Bt11  Bt11 I t

Among the above-the-median drinkers, the increased number of visits caused by
insurance-induced drinking is at most 0.3%.

Averaging it over the whole population will make it even smaller.

If the number of visits caused by the insurance-induced changes in smoking and
exercise is of the same magnitude, then the increased number of visits caused by
insurance-induced unhealthy behaviors as summarized by drinking, smoking and
insufficient exercise is less than 1%.
24/29
Conclusions

Health insurance encourages individuals’ unhealthy behaviors, in
particular, heavy drinking, but this does not induce an immediate
perceivable increase in their use of health care.

The insurance effects at the extensive margin are in general less
significant than those at the intensive margin.

Eg. The effects on the probabilities of smoking, drinking/heavy
drinking, and visiting a doctor/hospital are small and insignificant; The
effects on the quantity of heavy drinking and on the number of visits
are more considerable and statistically significant.

Within the total effect of insurance on health care utilization, the
pure price effect is dominant.

Policy implications
25/29
Kept Back to Get Ahead?
Kindergarten Retention and Academic Performance
Kept Back to get ahead? – Kindergarten
Retention and Academic Performance

Basic facts from the Early Childhood Longitudinal Study –Kindergarten Cohort (ECLS-K):

Not every school allows children to be held back in kindergarten;

Children in retention schools (schools that permit repeating kindergarten)
and non-retention schools are significantly different in terms of parents
and family characteristics.

We observe children being held back in K if and only if 1) they attend
a school that allows for repeating K, and 2) receive the treatment of
repeating K.

The two decisions are jointly determined: common observed and
unobserved parental/family characteristics may affect both.
26/29
Kept Back to get ahead?— Repeating K
Decision

School choice (S):
S = I(XS' + s > 0)




S = 1 if attending a retention school; S = 0 otherwise;
XS = vector of observables; s = unobservable;
XS' + s =a child’s propensity of attending a retention school.
Decision of repeating kindergarten (D*):
D* = I(XD' + D > 0)



(1)
(2)
XD = vector of observables; D = unobservable;
XD' + D = a child’s propensity of repeating kindergarten.
Observed repeating kindergarten status (D);
D = SD* = SI(XD + D > 0)

D=1 if repeating kindergarten; D=0 otherwise
27/29
(3)
Kept Back to get ahead?— Performance
Outcome Equation

Suppose for each child, we can observe his test scores
when he repeats kindergarten and when he does not.
Denote the two potential outcomes as Y1 and Y0:
Y1 = XY'1 + Y1
Y0 = XY'0 + Y0

The observed test score is
Y = DY1 + (1  D)Y0
= D(XY'1 + Y1) + (1 D)(XY'0 + Y0)

For simplicity, assume 1 and 0 are different only in constant
terms, but not slopes 
Y = XY' + D + DY1 + (1  D)Y0
28/29
(4)
Kept Back to get ahead?– The Full Model

A double hurdle model:




S = I(XS + s > 0)
(1)
D*= I(XD + D > 0)
D = SD*
Y = XY + D + DY1 + (1  D)Y0
(2)
(3)
(4)

Parameter of interest:
 ATT = E(Y1 – Y0 | D=1)=  + E(Y1  Y0 | D = 1)

Develop a control function estimator

Main results:

Repeating K has positive but diminishing effects on academic performance
over time;

Controlling for unobservable makes a difference, simple matching method
underestimates these effects.
29/29
^_^
Thank you !!!
Download