Comparison of the Ohlson and Feltham-Ohlson Models for Equity Valuation: Evidence from the British Telecommunications Sector S. N. Spilioti Athens University of Economics and Business, Department of Business Administration, Patission 76, 10434, Athens, Greece G. A. Karathanassis Athens University of Economics and Business, Department of Business Administration, Patission 76, 10434, Athens, Greece Abstract Ohlson (1995) and Feltham and Ohlson (1995) provide a consistent framework for the valuation of accounting numbers, the latter capturing different properties of operating and financial assets. We test the empirical validity of these valuation models for the telecommunications’ sector of the British equity market using panel data techniques. Our empirical findings are not supportive of either model. We interpret our findings as evidence of strong competition in the British telecommunications’ sector. Keywords: Equity valuation, Clean surplus accounting, Book value, abnormal earnings, Operating assets, Financial assets. JEL Classification: G1. 1 1. Introduction Traditional equity valuation models discount expected future dividends in order to arrive at a theoretically correct intrinsic value, which will be then compared to the current market price (Gordon (1959)). However, in their studies (Peasnell (1982), Ohlson (1995) and Feltham and Ohlson (1995)) suggest that security prices should be determined by book value and discounted future abnormal earnings. The Ohlson (1995) and Feltham and Ohlson (FO) (1995), models are landmark works in financial accounting. These models provide a consistent framework for the valuation of accounting numbers. FO show how a valuation model can be used to capture different properties of different assets classes, such as operating and financial assets. They also use their model to illustrate the effect of conservative accounting on the relation between equity value, accounting book value and future earnings. Compared to the traditional valuation models, the Ohlson and FO formulation is superior for empirical purposes as it focuses on the relation between share price and accounting numbers. It is a valuable contribution highlighting the role of stock price fundamentals such as net worth, earnings and growth forecasts. The fact that value can be computed over a few years by forecasting book value and earnings may turn out to be a significant achievement in the theory of investment. Previous empirical studies (see section 2 below) find that these alternative valuation models are reliable for the purpose of equity valuation. The Ohlson approach to share valuation relies heavily on the present value of expected abnormal earnings. In a fully competitive market, however, abnormal earnings are expected to be zero. In that case, excess returns should not exist and their influence on share prices should be eliminated. In this paper, we compare empirically 2 the explainability of Ohlson’s equity valuation model with that of FO approach, using data from the highly competitive telecommunications sector of the London Stock Exchange for the period 2000-2005. We use panel data techniques overcoming a number of frequently encountered estimation problems. Our empirical findings suggest that abnormal earnings, abnormal operating earnings and operating assets are not a significant determinant of share prices in this sector. We interpret this as evidence of a high degree of competition in the British telecommunications sector. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses previous literature, section 3 presents the data and methodology, section 4 presents our empirical findings. Finally, section 5 concludes the paper. 2. Literature review Share valuation models are important both to academics and practitioners. Interest in the determinants of share prices dates back to the days when the first organized stock exchanges were set up. According to the traditional valuation theory the price of a share is equal to the present value of the stream of dividends, expected from the share over its entire life (see for example Williams (1938), Gordon (1959)). Modigliani and Miller (1961), assuming perfect capital markets, rational behavior, and perfect certainty, argued for the Investment Opportunities Approach, according to which the factors that affect the security price are the expected dividends, the growth rate in expected dividends, and factors that proxy for the risk of the security. Alternatively, one could use expected earnings and expected growth rate in earnings instead of dividends. The results of empirical studies (see for example, Durand (1955), Gordon 3 (1959), Fisher (1961), Friend and Puckett (1964), Bower and Bower (1969), Keenan (1970), Karathanassis and Tzoannos (1977), Karathanassis and Philippas (1988), Rees (1997), Giner and Rees (1999), Akbar and Stark (2003), Ghezzi and Piccardi (2003), Foerster and Sapp (2005), Rutterford (2004), Nasseh and Strauss (2004), Hand and Landsman (2005), indicate that the main explanatory variables of equity prices are dividends, earnings, retained earnings, size, variability in earnings, and debt to equity ratio. Ohlson (1990, 1991, 1995) suggest that, as long as forecasts of earnings, book values and dividends follow clean surplus accounting ( bvt bvt 1 xt d t ), security prices should be determined by book value and discounted future abnormal earnings: Pt bvt R f i Et [ xtai ] (1) i 1 where, dt denotes the dividend per share at time t; Pt denotes the share price at time t, bvt denotes the book value per share at time t, Et represents the expectations operator at time t, xti represents abnormal earnings per share in period t i and Rf is 1 plus the risk free. Finally, Ohlson assumes linear information dynamics, that is, abnormal earnings can be estimated with linear regression analysis. Then, the abnormal earnings for period t+1 are defined as: xta1 xta vt 1t 1 (2) 4 where the non-accounting information for period t+1 is defined as: vt 1 vt 2t 1 (3) If these assumptions hold the price of a security is defined as: Pt bvt a1 xta a2 vt (4) where a1 [ /( R f )] 0 , and a2 [ R f /( R f )( R f )] 0 This specification has three advantages. Firstly, special emphasis is given to book value, thus avoiding any economic hypotheses about future cash flows. Secondly, the treatment of investments is such that they are treated as a balance sheet factor and not one that reduces cash flows (Penman and Sougiannis (1998)). Thirdly, as Bernard (1995) has shown, for shorter horizons the Ohlson formulation is more suitable than the dividends valuation model, as the latter underestimates share value. Previous empirical studies find that book value and discounted future abnormal earnings have an important role to play in the determination of equity prices (see for example, Bernard (1995), Lundholm (1995), Frankel and Lee (1998), Lee and Swaminathan (1998), Penman and Sougiannis (1998), Dechow, Hutton and Sloan (1999), Myers (1999), Barth, Beaver, Hand and Landsman (1999), Francis, Ohlson and Oswald (2000) ), Karathanassis and Spilioti (2003)). Building on the foundation established by Ohlson (1995), FO (1995) model the relation between a firm’s market value and accounting data concerning operating and financial activities within a clean surplus context. We summarize the basic assumptions and observations related to FΟ model. The notation is as follows: 5 fat = financial assets (net of financial liabilities), date t oat = operating assets (net of operating liabilities), date t ox t = operating earnings for period (t-1,t) it = income due to financial activities, for period (t-1,t) bvt fat oat = book value, date t xt it oxt = net earnings Pt = market value, date t ct = (free) cash flows, date t R f = risk free interest rate plus one d t = net dividends xta xt R f 1bvt 1 = residual earnings oxta oxt R f 1oat = residual operating earnings, date t The model is based on four assumptions described by equation (5) to (8) below: 1. Pt equals PVED Pt R f Et d t (5) 1 2. Clean surplus accounting: fat fat 1 it d t ct (Financial assets relation) (6a) oat oat 1 oxt ct (Operating assets relation) (6b) 3. Net interest relation i R f 1 fat 1 (7) 6 4. Linear information dynamics oxta1 11oxta 12oat v1t 1t 1 (8) oat 1 22oat v2t 2t 1 v1t 1 1v2t 3t 1 v2t 1 2 v2t 4t 1 where vkt represents other information relevant in the forecasting of future abnormal earnings. FO impose the following a priori restrictions on the parameters, 11 , 12 , 22 , 1 , 2 , in linear information model: (i) h 1 h 1,2,3 , (ii) 0 11 1, (iii) 1 22 R f , (iv) 12 0 Given these assumptions FO formulation shows that: Pt bvt 1oxta 2oat vt (9) where 1 11 / RF 11 2 12 RF /RF 22 RF 11 and 1 , 2 RF /RF 11 RF 1 , 2 /RF 2 Taking a similar approach, Liu and Ohlson (1999) develops empirical implications of the FO (1995) model. The key issue concerns how one conceptualizes a firm’s expected growth to explain its market value when the model also includes more basic 7 accounting measures reflecting its current performance. It is shown that market value can be expressed in terms of : (i) financial assets with a coefficient of one, (ii) the expected change in operating earnings with a non-negative coefficient, (iii) the expected operating earnings with a positive coefficient, (iv) current (net) operating assets with a no-negative coefficient, and, (v) the expected change in (net) operating assets with a non negative coefficient. One identifies the measure of a firms expected growth by normalizing the last variable with current (net) operating assets. The variable will be relevant if and only if the accounting is conservative. Myers (2000) critiques the above paper and concludes that Liu and Ohlson (1999) provide empirically testable models and interpretations of the resulting coefficients in terms of the underlying information dynamics. Their analysis and practical suggestions regarding empirical proxies should make the FO model more accessible to empirical researchers. On the other hand, Popova (2003) presents a case study of Microsoft Corporation (for the period 1992-2002), where the company is valued separately by both Ohlson (1995) and FO (1995) equity valuations models and under different settings of the input data with the purpose to compare the extent to which the models deal with accounting distortions. The study focuses particularly on the impact of deviations from the clean-surplus principle and comments on other deficiencies in the publicly available accounting data. The FO model was found more suited to cope with such accounting problems, while the Ohlson valuation produced considerably understated estimates of common equity. The case study also indicated that deficiencies in the reporting of employee stock option compensation, investment and derivatives might produce major inconsistencies in the examined valuation frameworks and distort their results. In addition, Callen and Segal (2005) tests the FO model by transforming the undefined ‘other information’ variables into expectational 8 variables, as suggested by Liu and Ohlson (2000). The data cover a sample of U.S stocks for the period 1990-2001. The signs of the estimated coefficients conform to the model’s predictions using panel data techniques, non-parametric estimation, reverse regressions and portfolio regressions. The tests reject the Ohlson model in favor of FO. Nevertheless, the estimated leverage coefficient takes a value of three instead of one for most variations of the model. Also, the 1-year-ahead price predictions of the FO model are no more accurate than those of the Ohlson model or a naïve earnings valuation model. In conclusion, Inchausti (2006) empirically analyses the adequacy of the valuation framework developed by Ohlson (1995) and FO (1995), using conditions with different degree of complexity. The less sophisticated conditions only include the fundamental accounting variables, book value and earnings, while the more complex ones also include additional variables in order to take into account the parameter “other information”. The sample contains nonfinancial companies listed in the Madrid Stock Exchange and indicates the period 1991-1999. The results suggest that Ohlson (1995) outperforms the other models, given that the value obtained in the empirical tests is consistent with its theoretical assumptions and implies lower prediction errors regarded the abnormal earnings component. As for those based on FO (1995), the “conservatism parameter” produces conflictive results because it is not able to capture all the effects of accounting conservatism. 3. Data and Methodology Our empirical analysis is based on data from the London Stock Exchange, available from DataStream, covering the period between 2000 and 2005. The data is expressed 9 in nominal values and annual frequency. Our sample includes companies from the British telecommunications sector. Previous research on equity valuation has typically used either time-series or crosssection methods. Both methodologies, however, have a number of drawbacks. For example, time-series analysis is subject to autocorrelation and multicolinearity problems; on the other hand, cross-section analysis is subject to heteroscedasticity problems and often fails to detect the dynamic factors that may affect the dependent variable. We use a combination of time-series and cross-section data (panel data analysis) a procedure that avoids the problems mentioned above and, in addition, has a number of advantages. For example, a panel data approach not only provides efficient and unbiased estimators but also a larger number of degrees of freedom allowing researchers to overcome the restrictive assumptions of the linear regression model (see e.g Baltagi and Raj (1992) and Maddala (1987)). Our econometric model can be represented as follows: K Yit i t K X Kit it (10) K 1 i 1,......, N t 1,......., T where Yit is the value of the dependent variable for the cross section i at time t, XKit is the value of the Kth explanatory variable for the cross section i at time t, μi is an unobserved cross-section effect, λi is an unobserved time effect and εi is the unobserved overall remainder. Equation (10) can be estimated either under the 10 assumption that μi and λi are fixed so that N i 0 and i 1 T i 1 t 0 , or under the assumption that μi and λi are random variables. The first case describes the well known Dummy Variable Model or the Covariance Model, while the second case describes the Error Components Model (see among others Kmenta (1971), Griffiths et al. (1993), Hsiao (1986), Wallace and Hussein (1969)). Researchers are often faced with the problem of choosing among the two approaches as it cannot be known beforehand whether the μi and λi terms are random or fixed. The Error Components Model will lead to unbiased, consistent, and asymptotically efficient estimators only if the orthogonality assumption holds, i.e. that the explanatory variables are uncorrelated with the cross-section and time-series effects. If that is not true, the Covariance Model estimators will still be consistent, since they are not affected by the orthogonality condition (see for details Madalla (1971) and Mundlack (1978)). To examine whether the explanatory variables are uncorrelated with the cross-section and time-series effects one can apply the testing procedure developed by Hausman (1978) where the null hypothesis is that the Error Components Model is correctly specified, i.e. that μi and λi are uncorrelated with the explanatory variables, XKit. The test statistic, m, is defined as equation (11) below m ( ˆ FE ˆGLS )( Mˆ 1 Mˆ 0 )1 ( ˆ FE ˆGLS ) (11) where βGLS is the generalized-least square Error Component Model estimator, βFE is the ordinary least square Dummy Variable Model estimator, M1 is the covariance 11 matrix of βFE, and M0 is the covariance matrix of βGLS. This m-statistic has an asymptotic k2 distribution. Accepting the null hypothesis suggests the use of the generalized least square estimator. Rejecting the null hypothesis indicates the use of the Covariance Model approach. We estimate equation (10) defining the dependent variable to be the arithmetic average of monthly average closing equity prices. We specify the right-hand side of equation (10) in two alternative ways, representing the Ohlson (1995) and FO (1995) valuation approaches. Concerning the Ohlson valuation model we used as independent variables, book value (BV) and abnormal earnings (AE). BV is the owners’ equity over the number of stocks in circulation, and AE is the difference between current earnings and the opportunity cost of capital. The opportunity cost of capital is defined as the previous period’s BV times the cost of capital (that is, the 3month treasury bill). Alternatively, for the specification representing the FO valuation model, we have defined as independent variables, book value (BV), operating assets (OA) and abnormal operating earnings (AOE). OA is the operating assets net of operating liabilities (accounts receivables, inventory, etc.) and AOE is the difference between current operating earnings and the previous period’s OA times the cost of capital (that is the 3-month treasury bill). Ohlson suggests that for the model to be correctly specified we should obtain a positive relationship between AE and prices. We also, theoretically, expect a positive relationship between BV and prices. According to the FO specification we expect a positive relationship between BV, OA, AOE and prices. 12 4. Empirical findings As a first step in the analysis we examine which approach is appropriate for the estimation of equation (10). To this end we apply the Hausman (1978) criterion discussed above. Table 1 reports the results of the estimation of the Hausman (1978) test. Concerning the Ohlson valuation model, the results seem to suggest that the cross-section and time-series effects can be considered as random variables. In other words, μi and λi are uncorrelated with the explanatory variables, XKit, in which case the Error Components Model is correctly specified and thus, we proceed with its estimation. Alternatively, for the specification representing the FO valuation model, the results appear to suggest that the cross-section and time-series effects can be considered as fixed variables which means that we can proceed with the estimation using the Covariance Model. [INSERT TABLE 1] According to the theoretical relationships predicted by the Ohlson valuation model we expect both book value and abnormal earnings to be positively related to share prices. Our empirical findings (reported in table 2) are not in accordance with the theoretical predictions for the abnormal earnings coefficient. Thus, our ex-ante expectations are empirically validated only for the variable of book value since this variable has a positive and significant influence on share prices. On the other hand, according to the FO model we expect book value, abnormal operating earnings and operating assets to be positively related to share prices. Our empirical findings for abnormal operating earnings and operating assets are not in accordance with the theoretical predictions. 13 Either the ex-ante relationships are empirically validated only for book value. Table 2 suggests that the Ohlson valuation model explains 20% of the variability of the dependent variable while FO valuation model explains a similar proportion (27%). [INSERT TABLE 2] 5. Conclusions Previous studies suggest that changes in security prices are explained by book value and discounted future abnormal earnings (Ohlson (1995) and FO (1995)). This paper, attempted empirically to compare the explainability of Ohlson’s equity valuation model with that of FO approach employing data from the London Stock Exchange and panel data analysis. More specifically, we examine the behavior of equity prices in the British telecommunications sector for the period 2000-2005. Our empirical findings are not supportive of the Ohlson and FO valuation models in the context of the British telecommunications sector. The regression coefficients of abnormal earnings, abnormal operating earnings and operating assets are statistcally insignificant and have an incorect sign. These empirical findings are not surprising given the highly competitive nature of the British telecommunications sector: Our findings suggest that as competition forces abnormal earnings to zero, the influence of excess returns on share prices is eliminated. 14 References Akbar S. and Stark W. A. (2003) “Deflators, Net Shareholder Cash Flows, Dividends, Capital Contributions and Estimated Models of Corporate Valuation” Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, Vol. 30, 1213-1233 Baltagi B. H., and Raj, B. (1992) “A survey of recent theoretical developments in the econometrics of panel data”, Empirical Economics, 17, 85-109. Baginski S. P. and Wahlen J.M. (2003) “Residual Income Risk, Intrinsic Values and Share Prices” The Accounting Review, Vol. 78, 327-351 Barth E. M., Beaver H.W., Hand R.M. J., Landsman R. W. (1999) “Accruals, Cash Flows, and Equity Values” Review of Accounting Studies, Vol. 3, 205-229 Bernard V. L. (1995) The Feltham-Ohlson Framework: Implications for Empiricists, Contemporary Accounting Research, 733-747 Bower D. H. and Bower R. S. (1969), “Risk and the Valuation of Common Stock”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 77, 349-362 Botosan C. and Plumlee M. (2002), “Estimating expected cost of equity capital: A theory-based approach. Working paper, University of Utah, Salt Lake City Callen L. J. and Segal D. (2005), “Empirical Tests of the Feltham-Ohlson (1995) Model”, Review of Accounting Studies, Vol. 10, 409-429 Claus J. and Thomas J. 2001 “Equity premia as low as three percent? Evidence from analysts’ earnings forcasts for domestic and International stock markets” Journal of Finance, Vol 56, 1629-1666 Dechow P., Hutton A. and Sloan (1999) “An Empirical Assessment of the Residual Income Valuation Model” Journal of Accounting and Economics, 26, 1-34 Durand D. (1955), “Bank Stock Prices and the Analysis of Covariance”, Econometrica, Vol.23, 30-45 Easton P., Taylor G., Shroff P. and Sougiannis T. (2000) “Using forecasts of earnings to simultaneously estimate growth and the rate of return on equity investment” Journal of Accounting Research, Vol. 40, 657-676 Fama E. F., French K. R. (1992), “The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns” Journal of Finance, Vol. 47, 427-465 Feltham G. and Ohlson J. (1995), Valuation and Clean Surplus Accounting for Operating and Financial Activities, Contemporary Accounting Research Vol. 11, 689-731 Fisher G.R. (1961), “Some Factors Influencing Share Prices”, Economic Journal, 15 Vol. LXXI, 121-141 Foerster S. and Sapp S. (2005) “The Dividend Discount Model in the Long-Run: A Clinical Study”, Journal of Applied Finance, Vol. 15, 55-75 Francis J. Olsson P. and Oswald D.(2000), “Comparing the Accuracy and Explainability of Dividend, Free Cash Flow, and Abnormal Earnings Equity Value Estimates”, Journal of Accounting Research, Vol. 38, 45-70 Frankel R. and Lee C.M.C. (1998) “Accounting Valuation, Market Expectation and Cross-Sectional Stock Returns, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 25, 289-319 Friend I. and Puckett M. (1964), “Dividends and Stock Prices”, American Economic Review, Vol. LIV, 656-682 Gebhardt W., Lee C. and Swaminathan B. (2001) “Toward an implied cost of capital” Journal of Accounting Research, Vol 39, 135-176 Ghezzi L. and Piccardi C. (2003) “Stock Valuation along a Markov Chain” Applied Mathematics and Computation, Vol. 141, 385-393 Gordon M. J. (1959), “Dividends, Earnings and Stock Prices”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. XLI, 99-105 Griffiths, W.E., Hill, C., and Judge, G.G. (1993) Learning and Practicing Econometrics, John Willey and Sons, INC. Giner, B. and W. Rees (1999), “A Valuation Based Analysis of the Spanish Accounting Reforms” Journal of Management and Governance, Vol. 3, 31-48 Hausman, J. A. (1978) “Specification tests in econometrics”, Econometrica, 46, 12511272. Hand R .M. J and Landsman R. W. (2005), “The Pricing of Dividends in Equity Valuation” Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, Vol. 32, 345-469 Hsiao, C. (1986) Analysis of Panel Data, Econometrics Society Monographs, No. 11. Inchausti, B, G. (2006), “ La capacidad de los modelos Feltham-Ohlson para predecir el resultado anormal: una application empirica” Spanish Journal of Finance and Accounting, Vol. XXXV, Num 132, 729-760 Karathanassis G. and Tzoannos J. (1977) “ The Demand for Money by Business Firms: A Temporal and Cross-Sectional Analysis”, Applied Economics, Vol. 9, 63-76 Karathanassis, G., and Philippas, N. (1988) “Estimation of bank stock price parameters and the variance components model”, Applied Economics, 20, 497-507. 16 Karathanassis, G., and Spilioti, S (2003) “En Empirical Investigation of the Traditional and the Clean Surplus Valuation Model”, Managerial Finance, 29, 55-66 Keenan M. (1970) “Models of Equity Valuation: The Great Germ Bubble”, Journal of Finance, Vol. XXV, 243-273 Kmenta, J. (1971) Elements of Econometrics, Macmillan, New York. Lee C. and Swaminathan B. (1998), Valuing the Dow: A Bottom-up Approach, Working Paper, Cornell University and University of Washington Liu J. and Ohlson A. J.(1999) , “The Feltham-Ohlson (1995) Model: Empirical Implications” Working Paper, Arizona State University and University of California at Los Angeles Lundholm R. (1995), “A Tutorial on the Ohlson and Feltham/Ohlson models” Contemporary Accounting Research, 11, 749-761 Maddala, G.S. (1987) “Recent developments in the econometrics of panel data analysis”, Transportation Research, Vol. 21, 303-326 Maddala, G.S. (1971) “The use of variance components models in pooling crosssection and time-series data”, Econometrica, 39, 341-358 Miller M. and Modilgianni F. (1961), “Dividend Policy, Growth and the Valuation of Shares”, The Journal of Business Vol. XXXIV, 411-433 Mundlak, Y. (1978) “On the pooling of time-series and cross-section data”, Econometrica, Vol.46, 69-85 Myers N. J. (1999) “Implementing Residual Income with Linear Information Dynamics” The Accounting Review, Vol. 74, 1-28 Myers N. J. (2000) “The Feltham-Ohlson (1995) Model: Empirical Implication” Journal of Accounting Auditing & Finance, Vol. 15, 332-335 Nasseh A. and Strauss J. (2004) “Stock Prices and the Dividend Discount Model: Did their Relation Break Down in the 1990s? The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 44, 191-207 Ohlson J. (1990), “A Synthesis of Security Valuation Theory and the Role of Dividends, Cash Flows, and Earnings”, Contemporary Accounting Research Vol. 6, 648-676 Ohlson J. (1991), “The Theory of Value and Earnings and an Introduction to the Ball-Brown Analysis”, Contemporary Accounting Research, Vol. 7, 1-19 Ohlson J. (1995), “Earnings Book Values and Dividends in Security Valuation”, Contemporary Accounting Research, Vol. 11, 661-687 17 Peasnell, K.V. (1982), “Some formal connections between Economic Values and Yields and Accounting Numbers” Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, Vol. 9, 361-382 Penmam S. and Sougianis T. (1998), “A Comparison of Dividend, Cash Flow and Earnings Approaches to Equaty Valuation”, Contemporary Accounting Research Vol. 15, 343-383 Popova I. K. (2003) “Applying the Feltham-Ohlson Models for Equity Valuation: Some Accounting Considerations”, Working Paper, Yokohama National University Rees W. (1997) “The Impact of Dividends, Debt and Investment on Valuation Models” Vol. 24, 1111-1140 Rutterford J. (2004), “From Dividend yield to Discounted cash flow: A history of UK and US Equity Valuation Techniques”, Accounting, Business and Financial History Vol. 14, 115-149 Wallace, T. and Hussain, A. (1969) “The use of Error Components Model in combining cross-section with time-series data”, Econometrica, 37, 55-73. Williams J. B. (1938), The Theory of Investment Values, Harvard University Press 18 Table 1 Telecommunications Sector m-statistic p -value df Model 1 1.95 0.38 2 Model 2 10.12 0.02 3 Notes to Table 1 Model 1: the Ohlson (1995) valuation model Model 2: the Feltham and Ohlson valuation model Null hypothesis: the Error Components Model is correctly specified m-statistic: Hausman’s (1978) test statistic df: degrees of freedom p-value at 95% confidence level 19 Table 2 Telecommunications Sector Independent Variables Model 1 CONSTANT 0.80 (1.06) BV 0.02 (3.42) * AE -0.01 (-0.61) Model 2 0.02 (2.30) * OA -5.01E-10 (-1.39) AOE -4.01E-10 (-1.92) R2 0.20 0.27 D-W 1.19 1.35 RSS 648.95 486.99 Notes to Table 2: BV: Book Value per share AE: Abnormal Earnings per share OA: Operating Assets per share AOE: Abnormal Operating Earnings per share t-statistics appear in parentheses * denotes significance at the 5% D-W denotes the Durbin-Watson statistic RSS denotes the Residuals Sum of Squares 20