REGIONAL TRAINING WORKSHOP ON COMETITION POLICY AND LAW 15-17 FEBRUARY, 2007 PRETORIA, SOUTH AFRICA DEALING WITH HORIZONTAL RESTRAINTS Definition of restraints of trade The term restraint of trade may be loosely defined as an act/practice by one or more persons which is intended to or whose effect is likely to eliminate existing business enterprises and/or prevent potential newcomers into a market. These restraints may be perpetrated by one enterprise or by two or more enterprises, which may be vertically or horizontally related, acting concertedly. Restraints of trade attributable to firms which are horizontally related (i.e. agreements between producers or between wholesalers or between retailers dealing in similar kinds of products), are therefore referred to as horizontal restraints of trade. Vertical agreements are those between enterprises at different stages of manufacturing and distribution process, for example, between producers and wholesalers, or between producers, wholesalers and retailers. Horizontal restraints of trade - that is, concerted actions among entities in actual or potential competition with one another - have been considered the most egregious violation of competition laws of many countries. The basic reason for this is that competition laws postulate a competitive marketplace in which rival firms compete with respect to prices, products, and services. Any arrangement which runs counter to this axiomatic conduct among competitive entities is accordingly suspect Practices like horizontal price-fixing (whether selling or purchase price, or, other trading conditions) collusive tendering, Market sharing agreements (customer or territory allocation), collective boycotts are universally condemned. This is mainly because efficiency, technological or other gains associated with such arrangements rarely more than offset jeopardy to competition. Hence, they fall under perse prohibition in many competition law jurisdictions. Other types of horizontal cooperative arrangements and joint ventures are always examined on a case-by-case basis because of the high probabily that such arrangements may spawn gains that outweigh endangered competition. Horizontal agreements or arrangements may be oral or written, formal or informal and may not be intended to be legally binding. Where arrangements are in writing, there can be no legal controversy on their existence, although there 1 might be contest about the meaning. However, enterprises always desist from entering into written agreements especially in jurisdictions where they are prohibited. Even in circumstances where they enter into written arrangement, they always do it in a highly discreet manner and all efforts are put in place to ensure that such physical evidence are kept where laying hands on them is extremely difficult. Because of the difficulty in getting the physical evidence of such agreements, many competition jurisdictions determine such cases basically on circumstantial evidence which involves monitoring and analysis of different parameters SANCTIONS The principal purpose of sanctions in horizontal restraint, just like in any other restraint of trade, is deterrence. An effective deterrent should take away the prospect if gain from anticompetitive arrangements among competitors. The laws of many countries provide for the possibility of large fines against enterprises found to have participated in a cartel. Maximum permissible fines may be expressed either as a specific monetary amount (Australia, Kenya and Canada) or as a percentage of some measure of turnover (France, European Union, Hungary, Italy etc), or, both (Finland UK, Sweden etc) Countries like Canada, Australia, Germany, Japan, among others, impose fines against officers holding positions in enterprises for their role in the cartel. Fewer countries provide for criminal sanction of imprisonment for natural persons. Examples include Canada (5 years), Germany (5 years for collusive tendering), Ireland (2years) and United States (3 years). In some countries it possible for victims of cartel activity to recover for their monetary loss, either in the course of the enforcement proceeding by the competition authority or separately in civil action. Examples include, Australia, Canada, Germany, Denmark and Finland. Because of the difficulty in obtaining reliable evidence that can sustain successful litigation, some competition agencies have resorted to the use of leniency programs to induce cartel members to confess and volunteer such information that can implicate co-conspirators. Leniency could mean any reduction in the penalty compared to what would be sought in the absence of full, voluntary cooperation. The clearest, most complete form of leniency is amnesty. DEALING WITH HORIZOBNTAL RESTRAINTS IN KENYA Sections 6,7,11 and 12 of the Restricive Trade Practices, Monopolies and Price Control Act (Cap. 504 of the laws of Kenya) prohibit both vertical and horizontal restraints of trade. Examples of horizontal restraints of trade prohibited are pricefixing (by manufacturers/purchasers or trade associations), territory/market allocation, restriction of output/supply of goods, collusive tendering and collusive bidding) 2 Complaints can be submitted by offended parties, other government agencies or can be taken cognizance of by the Commission itself. The following are examples trade restraints case handled by the Commission which are horizontal in nature; CASE 1 THE COMMISSIONER OF MONOPOLIES ASSOCIATION OF KENYA INSURERS (AKI) AND PRICES AND THE Introduction The Association of Kenya Insurers (AKI) is one of the strongest industry associations in Kenya in terms of financial might and membership. In fact the association has 100% membership of insurance companies operating in Kenya. This case addresses two main issues relating to (1) the problem created by a powerful trade association in the insurance industry in Kenya and (2) the problem where there is a sector regulator in the particular industry being investigated by the Competition Authority. The Kenya Transport Association wrote to the Monopolies and Prices Commission on 25th January, 2003 and reported that AKI was engaging in cartel like activities by setting minimum premium rates for various categories of insurance covers as well as terms and benefits that would apply to all motor policies issued or renewed from 1st July, 2002. This had resulted in a major increase in premiums. AKI went ahead to issue threats of disciplinary action against all non-compliant members. This practice in the insurance industry caused uproar with insurance brokers and players in the transport industry protesting. At one time, all matatus (minibuses used by majority of citizens as public passenger transport in Kenya) threatened to remove their vehicles from the Kenyan roads. The Association of Kenya Insurers called a meeting and started negotiating with the Matatu Welfare Association quietly regarding reduction of the fixed prices. Investigations The Commission managed to get a copy of the AKI Motor Rating Schedule dated 4th June 2002, which sets rates, terms and benefits to apply to all motor policies issued after 1st July 2002. The Commission also obtained a copy of AKI Resolution 07/2002 whereby it was resolved and agreed that other supplementary rates would apply with effect from 1 st January 2003. This contravened the Restrictive Trade Practices, Monopolies and Price Control Act section 7(1)(b)(i) and (ii). The allegations impinging upon AKI was that: 3 1. AKI had been making, directly or indirectly recommendation to their members, which relates to the prices charged or to be charged by their members. On 7th February 2003 the Monopolies and Prices Commission wrote to AKI in accordance with section 15 of Restrictive Trade Practices, Monopolies and Price Control Act, Cap 504 of the laws of Kenya, informing them that allegations had been made and that specific evidence had been presented to substantiate the allegations. Hence AKI was required to comment on the allegation and indicate the remedies they proposed to undertake to bring their trade practices into conformity with the Act within a fortnight. On 19th February, 2003, AKI replied to the Commission claiming that their actions were exempted under section 5 of the Insurance Act, that allows the Commissioner of Insurance to approve tariffs and rates of insurance in respect to any class or classes of insurance and section 5 of the Restrictive Trade Practices, Monopolies and Price Control Act, that exempts trade practices that are associated with government agencies with authority conferred on them by an Act of parliament. AKI considered both Commissions to be agencies of the government and as a matter of fact, both fall under the Ministry of Finance. They claimed that the review of premiums was necessary to protect the consumer and not the insurance firms and to guarantee sustainable solvency of the companies, which in turn would enhance the protection of the policyholder who is the consumer. AKI also provided a letter dated 20th August 2001, in which the Commissioner of Insurance had requested AKI to come up with premium guidelines. AKI took advantage of the innocent requests to justify and to practice price fixing. The Monopolies and Prices Commission did not agree with AKI that when fixing prices or when recommending prices their Association was exempt from the application of Restrictive Trade Practices, Monopolies and Price Control Act. Therefore on 5th March 2003, the Monopolies and Prices Commission wrote to AKI inviting them to come, negotiate and sign a satisfactory Consent Agreement in accordance to section 15(3) of the Act, and the date was set to be 25 th March, 2003. The Commission of Insurance was also invited as a witness. On 23rd April 2003, a Consent Agreement was signed between the Commissioner of Monopolies and Price Commission and the Association of Kenya Insurers in the presence of the Commissioner of Insurance. The Consent Agreement stipulated the following: 1. That the Association of Kenya Insurers undertakes to withdraw, with immediate effect, all its present and past decisions on premium rates which purport to recommend prices chargeable for insurance services by its members. The Association of Kenya Insurers also undertakes to desist 4 from making such decisions and from issuing such premium rates recommendations in future. 2. That the Association of Kenya Insurers undertakes to observe, with effect from the date of this Consent Agreement, all the provisions of the Restrictive Trade Practice, Monopolies and Price Control Act. 3. That the Association of Kenya Insurers will diligently and strictly observe the terms of this Consent Agreement in order to compensate for the past effects of the said past decisions. On 23rd April 2003, Monopolies and Prices Commission caused the Consent Agreement to be published in the Kenya Gazette in accordance with Section 15(4) of Restrictive Trade Practices, Monopolies and Price Control Act, Cap 504. In spite of the Consent Agreement, where AKI was required to desist from recommending the premium rates for all classes of insurance services, the Commission continued to receive complaints from consumers of mega risks, suggesting that AKI had only withdrawn premium rate-fixing of motor vehicles. This action led to the making of an Order by the Minister in accordance to section 16 of Restrictive Trade Practices, Monopolies and Price Control Act, Cap 504, in the year 2005 on the advise of the Commissioner for Monopolies and Prices. CASE 2 COMMISSIONER AND CYBER CAFE OPERATORS ASSOCIATION OF KENYA Introduction When the first generation of Internet Service Providers (ISPs) entered the Kenyan market in the mid 90’s, their facilities were reserved for the elite who could afford the exorbitant user fees. However, with the expansion and liberalization of the sector, more service providers entered the market thus drastically reducing the margins previously enjoyed by the operators. In a bid to rescue themselves from the inevitable reduced margins, the cyber cafe proprietors decided to form a price fixing cartel under their umbrella organization called Cyber Cafe Operators Association of Kenya. The other reasons cited for the formation of the Cyber Operators Association was the lack of regulation by the sector regulator, Communication Commission of Kenya (CCK). They decided to raise the prices by about 300% which was reported in one of the daily newspapers. The action also drew strong condemnation from a consumer welfare body, the Consumer Information Network (CIN), who having taken cognizance of the matter in the press, wrote to Monopolies and Prices Commission. CIN was of the view that the cyber operators wanted to take 5 advantage of the increasing internet users who had no access to computers or who had no alternative mode of communication such as the telephone. The consumer body stated that Information and Communication Technology (ICT) had become an increasingly critical tool in information transfer and it would be unjustifiable for the operators to drastically increase the user fees without proper reasons. The Commission took up the case on behalf of millions of actual and potential consumers of internet services who would be affected by the decision of the cyber cafe operators to jointly increase internet access charges by 300%. As in the previous case, the practices of this Association violates the Restrictive Trade Practices, Monopolies and Price Control Act, section 7, which outlaws concerted practices of traders who engage in fixing prices charged or to be recommendation of prices and other terms of trade by trade associations. Investigations The first step in the investigations of this case was to try and locate offices of the association and its officials. As soon as that was established, a letter was dispatched to them highlighting the illegality of their intended trade practice. They were required to comment on the allegations made in the press and by CIN. They were also required to submit, from the State Law Office (Registrar’s Office), a list of their membership, and their Articles of Association together with minutes of the meeting that endorsed the increment of user fees for purposes of verifying the press report. Further investigations revealed that the Cyber Cafe Association had not been officially registered. The operators however denied engaging in the indicated malpractice and blamed the press for quoting them out of context. They said their meetings only discussed ways of enhancing their services to the consumers within the parameters of the Law and with this they sought to have a meeting with the Commissioner of Monopolies and Prices to explain the reasons for their existence and activities. Later on, in a memorandum sent to CCK by the operators, a copy of which was availed to the Commission, the association tried to justify the increment of user fees. They claimed that user fees had tremendously dropped from a high of thirty (30) shillings to a low of fifty (50) cents per minute. According to the operators, this had been prompted by large cyber cafe operators who wanted to drive potential entrants and small-scale cyber operators from doing the same business. The operators further intimated that some of the cafes charging ‘unusually’ low user fees had very low speed computers contrary to what they had advised their members to install. This meant that the consumers were spending a longer time before accessing the internet and so ended up paying more for less. So fixing user fees would in a way serve the consumers interest by protecting them from such unscrupulous businessmen as they awaited the 6 intervention of the sector regulator. The three (3) shilling fee was deemed to be ideal as it would not only stem price wars amongst the operators but be also adequate to cover all operation overheads of the cyber cafe operators. The Monopolies and Prices Commission and CCK dismissed this argument. Conclusion CCK informed the Cyber Cafe Operators Association that their trade practice did not only violate the Restrictive Trade Practices, Monopolies and Price Control Act, but also the Kenya Communication Act that prohibits business conduct that is anti competitive. It further ordered all cyber operators to register with them for a one- time fee of one thousand (1000) shillings. Though these directives were communicated to the Association it was apparent from the market that some operators had already hiked their fees to 3 shillings. In the end, the market achieved stability and the user fees at some outlets went down to one (1) shilling per minute just as it had been the case prior to the 300% increase. The decline in user fee was also attributed to the fact that the Association had not been registered and not all operators were members at the time. The Monopolies and Prices Commission continued to monitor the market. Group Case Work This is a case of a presumed cartel among the major players in the petroleum industry. The complaints have been triggered by: (1) the supposedly high prices of the petroleum products in Kenya, (2) similarity in the pump prices of different oil companies and, (3) the simultaneous upward changes in such prices almost by the same margin. This tendency caused concern with in Kenya’s Competition agency and a lot of outcry in the country. It was even discussed in parliament where they strongly condemned the existence of cartel by the multinationals in Kenya. Note: 1. The petroleum market in Kenya is largely oligopolistic despite the incorporation of numerous small independent oil companies. The major oil companies (Total, Shell/ BP, Caltex, Mobil & Kenol/Kobil) control 85.3% of the market share for petroleum products as of September 2005. 2.Kenya imports 100% of all its petroleum products requirements Assuming you are the case officer, how would you go about investigating and analysing the allegation? (Benson O. Nyagol - Monopolies and Prices Commission –Kenya) 7