Pacific Rebels: California’s Monetary Secession during the Civil War 1 Daniel Barbeau History 572 December 16, 2013 In this 1891 illustration, a populist Senator blows ‘thin air’ into a windmill-powered U.S. Treasury, producing a pipeline exodus of “Unlimited Greenbacks,” accompanied by a sign extolling farmers to “Help Yourselves.” Nearby, wagons filled with paper money pass by a general store with a sign that advertises, “Unprecedented Reduction! 1 Ton of Coal for 1 Ton of Greenbacks!” while another placard asks customers, “Don’t Throw PaperMoney in the Ash Barrel.” From: Worth Robert Miller, Populist Cartoons: An Illustrated History of the Third-Party Movement in the 1890s (Kirksville, Truman State University Press, 2011), 94. 1 1 Abstract: With initial battlefield defeats suffered by Union armies in 1862, federal finances looked precarious while a simultaneous need for an unprecedented need for taxation and centralization of capital emerged as imperative to blunt Southern military aims. However, the wartime financial reorganization of the federal government set off another rebellion, led by the Far West state of California, which legally retaliated with the Specific Contract Act. Californians deeply mistrusted unbacked, paper notes, the federal greenbacks, and other Western states soon followed the state by passing similar measures. These legal countermeasures ensured that California maintained a high level of economic autonomy during the war, and this rebellious monetary attitude stymied federal efforts to bring the state into line. After the war, California’s renegade financial status not only continued, but ultimately emerged victorious over the federal government after the Supreme Court declared the Legal Tender Acts unconstitutional. Through these actions, California led the West in the most successful act of economic secession in American history. During the first heady months of the Civil War, the Union faced a multitude of political and military disasters. The Battle of Bull Run followed the debacle of Fort Sumter, and these crushing defeats stillborned the North’s plans for quick victory and a relatively bloodless resumption of peace. In the chaotic aftermath of the war’s first significant engagement at Bull Run, situated a scant 25 miles south of the national capitol, the Union’s defeated soldiers “came in shambling…while a sullen rain came down, each man a visible proof of disaster, streaked with dirt, almost out of their heads with wariness, [while] a huge [Washingtonian] audience [stood] watching each and all.”2 Soon, eleven states declared their secession from the United States, and coalesced into the Confederate States of America. Years of bloody warfare ensued before an exhausted South acquiesced in surrender before the North’s overwhelming military power at the Appomattox Courthouse in 1865. By that year, much of the South lay in smoldering ruins, its economic model founded on the labor of chattel human slavery had been eviscerated, and more than a half-million Americans lay dead across hundreds of battlefields. The Confederate bid for secession through military rebellion collapsed at the behest of Northern manpower and industrial 2 Bruce Catton , The Coming Fury (New York: Doubleday, 1961), 470. 2 capacity, but the Union’s impressive feat was only feasible through an unprecedented nationwide marshaling of economic and financial resources and centralization that evolved in order to fund the federal government’s massive military juggernaut. However, while the South failed in its bid to succeed from the United States government through military rebellion, another region succeeded in another type of rebellion against wartime financial centralization and monetary consolidation. With the federal passage of laws antithetical to local sentiment and popular sympathy, the remote state of California began a decade long struggle to establish monetary and financial independence against the federal government. While the South’s rebellion sought to uphold human bondage by force, California’s rebellion sought to ensure economic prosperity for citizens through an independent monetary policy. Unlike the disastrous and violent rebellion launched by the Southern Confederates for political independence, the Californian drive for monetary autonomy emerged as relatively successful. Instead of relying on the fighting abilities of regiments and strategic guile of generals, California’s rebellion utilized the rhetoric of lawyers, the pens of editors, and popular sympathies at the ballot box. Ultimately, by 1865, the South’s insurrection would prove futile, while California’s monetary rebellion would be vindicated through legal means and become adopted de jure nationwide. During and in the immediate aftermath of the Civil War, the federal government’s attempts at capital centralization faced rampant open hostility in California. Popular monetary opinions solidified around the protection of the monometallic gold standard, and nearly universal popular sentiment endorsed monetary stability and the gold standard. Using accounts and opinions gleaned from contemporary newspapers, written polemics, and modern empirical data, this essay will first outline how the nineteenth century monetary system functioned in the context of the Civil War, and then argue the several reasons to as why California rejected the fiat 3 greenback standard and sat squarely in the gold standard camp. The paper will then argue that during the years of the Civil War and in the years afterward, Californian courts, legislators, and the general public launched a successful war of monetary secession against the backdrop of the war of political secession waged by the Confederate South, in reaction to the economic and financial revolutions that sought to centralize the nation’s capital for utilization in the war effort. In response to Eastern financial centralization, California emerged as the rebellious epicenter of hard-money sentiment, and garnered little sympathy for federal paper money due to the popular fears of inflationary prices, a desire for a ‘natural’ currency, and a gold-sympathetic judiciary. Wartime Finance Brings Unprecedented Problems The massive wartime transformation of American finance, national economic trajectory, and Californian monetary mindsets were rooted before the dark days of the Civil War when Union military victory looked remote after a string of early Confederate battlefield victories. Financial legislation passed during the era of state-chartered banks placed veritable manacles on the ability of the federal government to transform significant amounts of private capital into public through bonds.3 The Independent Treasury Act of 1846 mandated that government financial assets be held in gold and silver, and all federal payments were mandated to also be denominated in gold or silver. These legal specie holding requirements severely limited the amount and liquidity of public expenditures through the natural scarcity of the precious metals. While adequate for an antebellum nation whose federal government expenditures and tax 3 In total, the federal government spent a total of $3 billion during the course of the war, and only a fifth of this immense sum was paid for with collected taxes. By August of 1865, the national debt stood at $2.8 billion, about half of annual gross domestic product. However, the method of debt issuance varied widely, and included the aforementioned greenbacks, short term notes, certificates of indebtedness, so-called 7-30 loans (which the government had the option to pay after five years, and was forced to redeem in 30) and the controversial 5-20 notes, which bore six percent interest payable in gold, but were ambiguously worded so as that controversy erupted on whether after 20 years the principle would be redeemed in gold or greenbacks. Irwin Unger, The Greenback Era: A Social and Political History of American Finance, 1865-1879 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1964), 16. 4 revenues remained a tiny fraction of total national economic activity, the Civil War would ultimately demand $2 billion in funding, an unprecedented amount of capital for the agrarian and politically decentralized nation. In the summer of 1861, the federal government found itself desperate for the credit and capital necessary to fund a long and bloody campaign against the Southern rebel secessionists. Soon, President Lincoln threw Salmon P. Chase, a veteran Ohioan politician but financial novice was thrown into this cauldron of financial uncertainty. As Lincoln’s treasury secretary and former presidential rival, Chase managed to cobble enough financing to meet temporary wartime expenditures, but the vast sums of capital needed to fund the war effort demanded a complete paradigm shift of government financing. 4 After the expected quick military campaign to subdue the rebels turned into a multiyear endeavor, Chase convinced Congress to approve $250 million in bonds that matured after 20 years at 7.3 percent interest and, more significantly, paper notes that paid no interest but could be technically redeemed into gold through the treasury. Chase intended that these ‘demand notes’ would circulate and act as a national uniform medium of exchange.5 However, by mid-November of 1861, the tenuous financial lifeline of the Union began to tremble. That month, a Union Navy ship stopped a British mail cutter en route to England and forcibly removed two Confederate agents. With British genteel dignity ironically outraged at this apparent disregard of Britain’s high-seas neutrality, the two nations stood precipitously close to a declaration of a war that would have The Union’s financial situation remained desperate in the early months of the war: “The economic Panic of 1857, corruption in the Buchanan administration, and the partial dismemberment of the Union had taken a massive toll on the government coffers. With Congress not in session to authorize new tariffs and taxes, Chase was forced to rely on government loans to sustain war expenditures. Banks held back at first, demanding higher interest rates than the government could afford to pay, but eventually, Chase cobbled together enough revenue to meet expenses until Congress convened.” For an in depth account of the political rivalry between Salmon P. Chase and Abraham Lincoln, see Doris Kearns Goodwin, Team of Rivals: The Political Genius of Abraham Lincoln (New York: Simon and Shuster Paperbacks, 2005), 364-5. Also see: Stephen Mihm, A Nation of Counterfeiters: Capitalists, Con Men, and the Making of the United States, (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2007), 309. 5 However, Salmon Chase did not venture into morass of paper money lightly. In October of 1862, he wrote that “The expenditures everywhere are frightful. The average daily drafts of the Treasury for two weeks past have been a million and three quarters at least [and] largely in excess of its means.” See: Bray Hammond, “The North’s Empty Purse, 1861-1862,” The American Historical Review, Vol. 67, No.1 (1961), 1-18. 4 5 made the Union’s task of subduing the rebellious South immensely more difficult. 6 With the news of several Union reversals in addition to the threat of a wider war, public confidence in Chase’s new demand notes plummeted, and panicked note-holders quickly drained the government’s gold reserves by redeeming notes in mass.7 By December 1861, banks veered toward insolvency with their specie reserves ran dangerously low, and in response, suspended gold redemption in order for the federal government stay financially afloat. With that momentous outcome, the nation had left the gold standard, from which the nation would not return for another 17 years. After the suspension of gold redemption, the country nervously found itself on a purely fiat currency, unlinked to any metallic standard. Meanwhile, with the convenient vacancy of the rebellious Democratic lawmakers in Congress, newly dominant Northern legislators found themselves liberated from Southern legislative obstruction and began to push through a fundamental reorganization of the national banking system. The old system of decentralized state-chartered banks and private issuance of circulating bills of credit that resulted from President Jackson’s refusal to re-charter the Second Bank of the United States was about to come to an end. Prior to wartime overhauls, the American economy relied on privately issued bank notes that were often released by chartered banks with little capital and circulated at deep discount, depending on the distance and reputation of the institution. This morass of shaky notes engendered deep distrust among those who used privately issued banknotes in daily transactions, and the so-called wildcat banks that possessed 6 During the Napoleonic wars half-a-century prior, it was Americans who were outraged at French and British impressments of American sailors upon neutral American ships in international waters. These actions led in part to the Quasi War with France in 1798 and the War of 1812 with Great Britain. Within another half-century, the shoe would again be on the other proverbial foot, with Americans again outraged at the maritime predations of German U-Boats upon neutral American merchant ships. 7 Irwin Unger identifies these additional Union problems as the Trent Affair and threat of war with England, Lincoln’s removal of General Frémont from command in the Western theater, and Grant’s reversal at Belmont, and the Treasury’s Annual Report that revealed massive federal deficits. See: Irwin Unger, The Greenback Era: A Social and Political History of American Finance, 1865-1879 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1964), 14. 6 virtually no capital reserves in their vaults blurred the line between legitimate note issuance and fraudulent counterfeiting. The National Banking Act of 1863 granted the federal government the ability to bestow banking charters and required such private banking associations to deposit a set amount of federal bonds with the Treasury, who would then issue 90 percent of those bonds’ market price in federal greenbacks. More significantly, a later 1866 banking regulation measure also mandated a prohibitive 10 percent tax on each private banknote issued, payable in legal tender.8 Since private banks had no way to raise 10 percent of their issuance in legal tendered greenbacks, private banknote issuance virtually ceased overnight. Another piece of reform legislation proved equally transformative. In part to rectify the problem of disreputable monetary media but also to strengthen the power of the federal government to raise money through a stable bond market, Secretary Chase pushed through Congress the Legal Tender Act of 1862. The act revolutionized American finance by turning governmental demand deposits, or bonds, into legal tender. The Act stipulated that the new green notes were “legal tender for all debts public and private, […] and [are] exchangeable for U.S. six per cent. [sic] bonds redeemable at the pleasure of the United States, after five years,” and Chase promised that “the United States notes are made a legal tender and maintained at near the par of gold by the provision for their conversion into bonds bearing six per cent. [sic] interest, payable The Act provided that “every National banking association, State bank, or State banking association, shall pay a tax of ten per centum on the amount of notes of any person, State bank, or State banking association, used for circulation and paid out by them after the 1st day of August, 1866, and such tax shall be assessed and paid in such a manner as shall be prescribed by the commissioner of internal revenue." In 1869, the Supreme Court heard Veazie Bank v. Fenno, which tested the constitutionality of the tax in tow ways. First, by asserting that the 10 percent tax was a direct tax, and thus only able to be apportioned by population, as per Article 1, Section 2, Clause3 of the Constitution, and second, that with the Act, the federal government overstepped its power vis-á-vis the reserved powers of the states by impairing state charters and franchises. The court, led by Chief Justice Chase, affirmed the constitutionality of the banknote tax contained within the National Banking Act. From: Isaac Grant Thompson, National Bank Cases, Containing All Decisions of Both the Federal and State Courts Relating to National Banks with Notes and References (Albany: John D. Parsons Jr., Publishing, 1878) 22-34. 8 7 in coin.”9 Chase first ordered the issuance of $50 million, then an additional $100 million, and quickly thereafter, an additional $500 million in greenbacks as federal expenses ballooned during the opening of hostilities in 1862. With these issuances, for the first time since Jackson, the nation technically possessed a federally issued medium of monetary value, which could be traded on the market without a discount. However, after the suspension of gold convertibility, these new greenback notes could not be redeemed in coin of any metallic composure, but their value instead relied on the stated promise of six percent interest contingent on federal credit, and also an unstated promise of the future restoration of gold convertibility. Instead of representing tangible assets, these new notes’ worth was predicated on the public’s confidence in their unconvertible abstract value. Elbridge Gerry Spaulding, the Congressman who authored the Act in December 1861, later lamented what he saw as the “great mistake [of the Legal Tender Act]— greater than all other mistakes in the management of the war—[which] was the abrogation of the right to fund the greenback currency in gold bonds [but if] the right to fund [greenbacks with gold bonds] had been continued, the greenback currency would have appreciated to par in gold along with bonds.”10 In short, the massive wartime inflationary and subsequent peacetime deflationary episodes could have been avoided if even a tenuous linkage to gold remained. Californians largely agreed with Spaulding’s later sentiment. The Sacramento Daily Union applauded that a national currency would “prove a vast improvement over any circulating which the country has been furnished with since the Bank of the United States was in existence,” but expressed concern that greenbacks “will lack but one element of a perfect national currency, and that is convertibility into specie at the will of the holder.”11 Only after paper greenbacks began to 9 Elbridge Gerry Spaulding , The Legal Tender Act (Baker, Jones & Company, 1875), 8. Ibid., 8. 11 “A National Currency,” Sacramento Daily Union, April 4, 1862. 10 8 lose value at a precipitous rate did public opposition to federal monetary policy growth in strength and ferocity. During the course of the war, Congress authorized an unprecedented amount of public debt to fund military operations, which led to spectacular price increases in consumer goods. 12 Since only a fifth of the roughly $3 billion spent during the war years was allocated through taxation, an additional $2.4 billion worth of bonds, circulating currency, and other debt instruments had been added into the monetary base. 13 When compared to the size of the contemporary monetary base, this figure becomes astounding. In 1867, when the first reliable records were recorded, the public held about $585 million in greenbacks, circulating bonds, and subsidiary coinage, another $729 million in commercial bank deposits, and another $276 million in mutual savings bank deposits, for a total of $1.59 billion in what can be described as money.14 Unsurprisingly, wartime inflation surged as an increased volume of money chased fewer goods in the marketplace. By 1865, average prices had jumped by 85 percent from prewar levels, standards of living had fallen on account of redirection of goods toward wartime needs, and wages failed to keep up with price inflation.15 The decoupling of the greenback dollar from the gold standard precipitated years of inflation and set the stage for decades of postwar deflation while prices settled to pre inflationary lows. However, the steady fall in prices that afflicted the postwar era remained a phenomenon far in the future during the years of ferocious fighting that marked the Civil War. For many, and not just Salmon Chase, gold seemed to be the natural 12 By the end of the Civil War, the Treasury had issued $450 million in greenbacks alone to the public. Unger, The Greenback Era, 15. 13 Ibid., 16. 14 Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz, A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963), 4. 15 Between 1860 and 1865, wholesale prices increased by an average of 85 percent, retail prices by 76 percent, and costs of living by 56 percent. As usual during times of high inflation wages failed to keep pace with other inflationary benchmarks, and increased by only fifty percent during the same time period. See: Wesley C. Mitchell, Gold, Prices, and Wages under the Greenback Standard (New York: Augustus M. Kelley Publishers, 1966 [original 1908]), 279. 9 element placed upon the earth for use as a medium of monetary exchange, and a monetary system unmoored by the natural restraints placed upon it by the finite nature of a metallic standard struck most contemporary observers as radical and unsettling.16 A New Dilemma: California Rejects National Monetary Policy Nowhere did these feelings of unease with the fiat monetary system gain more traction than the remote state of California, which served as the origination of the majority of circulating specie. Within in the state’s founding constitution in 1848, paper money had been outlawed, with the stipulation that “The legislature of this state shall prohibit by law any person or persons, association, company, or corporation from exercising the privileges of banking or creating paper to circulate as money.”17 During the events that ultimately led to federal greenback and gold redemption suspension, public opinion in California remained decidedly against greenbacks and a fiat currency for the understandably valid fear of uncontrollable inflation. The Daily Alta warned that: David Ricardo (1772-1824) reflected common sentiment when he wrote that “[t]hough undoubtedly a variable measure of value, there is no commodity subject to fewer variations [as gold and silver]. This and the other advantages which these metals posses, such as their hardness, their malleability, their divisibility, and many more, have justly secured the preference every where [sic] given to them, as a standard for the money of civilized countries.” From: Piero Sraffa, ed., The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo: Volume 1, On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (Ann Arbor: Edward Brothers, Inc., 2004), 86-7. 17 Bernard Moses, “Legal Tender Notes in California,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 7, No.1 (1892): 125. Drafted in 1848, the constitutional prohibition went even further. Section 34 of Article IV mandated that “The legislature shall have no power to pass any act granting any charter for banking purposes, but association may be formed, under general laws, for the deposit of gold and silver; but no such association shall make, issue, or put into circulation any bill, check, ticket, certificate, promissory note, or other paper, or the paper of any bank, to circulate as money.” The California Constitution of 1880 contained a superficially similar but substantially different paper money prohibition. Article 12, Section 5 stipulated that “The Legislature shall have no power to pass any Act granting any charter for banking purposes, but corporation or associations may be formed for such purposes under general laws. No corporation, association, or individual shall issue or put into circulation, as money, anything but the lawful money of the United States.” By 1880, the revamped California Convention made no mention of the circulating media of gold or silver, and noted the preeminence of the federal government in the monetary realm. See: J. Ross Browne, Report of the Debates in the Convention of California in September and October, 1849, (Washington: Printed by John T. Towers, 1850) and Robert Desty, The Constitution of the State of California Adopted in 1879, (San Francisco: Sumner Whitney & Co., 1879). For a complete reference guide for each of California’s constitutions, see: Joseph R. Grodin, Calvin R. Massey, and Richard B. Cunningham, The California State Constitution, A Reference Guide, (Westport: Greenwood Press, 1993). 16 10 The masses have at length become very aroused on the subject of the currency…The laboring man, under the existing law, receives every Saturday night a certain sum of gold and silver, which can neither increase of diminish in value before he finds it necessary to spend it [but] now he will receive a bundle of paper, which, at the time it is handed to him, may be worth seventy-five cents on the dollar; but when he comes to lay it out, it may have depreciated to sixty-five or sixty cents.18 Other newspaper editors were even more critical of Chase. Weeks after the federal treasury suspended greenback to gold convertibility, the Los Angeles Star lamented, somewhat histrionically, that: It is to be hoped, for the good of the people at large, and especially for the benefit of the mechanic and laborer, that a change in the aspect of the planets will relieve him [Chase] from the lunacy of his financial hallucinations, and that, restored to the guidance of unclouded judgment, he will do that which is in his power, and relieve us from the oppression of a paper currency.19 In addition to fears of inflation, Californians also mistrusted because of the perception that paper currency was the preferred currency of Eastern capitalists and banking titans, whom they blamed for the fact that“[e]very ten years, for half a century, there has been a financial revulsion in the Eastern States, owing directly to the inflation inseparable from a badly regulated paper currency.”20 From the beginning of the convertibility suspension debacle, Californians remained decidedly against a paper monetary system, since “in a country whose great staples (so to speak) gold and silver, a paper currency would be an absurdity, and that any effort on the part of the General Government, to force paper upon the people there, would be attended with the most disastrous consequences.”21 With adequate hard specie floating within the local economy, the California public rejected and feared the effects of a paper currency and dangerous inflation.22 “The Masses Moving,” Daily Alta California, January 30, 1864. “Our Finances,” Los Angeles Star, January 16, 1864. 20 “The Effects of Repeal,” Daily Alta California, January 31, 1864. 21 “The Controversy between the Treasurers,” Daily Alta Californian, January 5, 1863. 22 As early as 1862, “[t]he leading merchants of San Francisco a circular agreement neither to receive nor pay out notes at any but market standard, taking gold as a standard…Should any one [sic] refuse to pay in gold, his name was to be entered in the black book, and in future dealings he would be expected to pay for goods in gold in advance 18 19 11 A series of legal suits and historic precedents established California as the center for greenback repudiation and highlighted the desire of Californians to retain a specie backed currency. In July 1862, John Perry Jr. brought suit against E.H. Washburn, and after the Fourth District Court ruled in favor of the tax-collector Washburn on July 29, 1862, the action landed before the California Supreme Court as Perry v. Washburn.23 Washburn worked as a taxcollector employed by the city of San Francisco and had refused to accept a tax bill in greenbacks instead of specie, citing the Constitutional mandate that he would accept only “legal coin of the United States or foreign coin at the value fixed for such coin by the laws of the United States.”24 Perry, the plaintiff, argued that state currency law remained subordinate to the federal Legal Tender Act of 1862, which authorized greenbacks as the “lawful money and legal tender in payment of all debts, public and private, within the United States,” and that the definition of a debt included tax payments. 25 Hamstrung by clear federal law but sympathetic to the ideal of a gold-backed currency, the California Supreme Court’s judgment crafted a puzzling and convoluted argument, which differentiated the legal definitions of ‘debt’ and ‘taxes.’ The court defined taxes as a payment which were not mutually agreed upon by two consenting parties, but instead owed: its existence to legislative power and does not depend for its validity or enforcement upon the individual assent of the tax-payer, [taxes] are not debts, within the meaning of that clause of the [Legal Tender] act which provides that the notes shall be ‘a legal tender in payment for all debts, public and private.’ Congress, by these terms, only intended such obligations for the payment as of money as are founded upon contract. of delivery.” Joseph Ellison, “The Currency Question in Oregon during the Civil War Period,” Oregon Historical Quarterly, Vol. 28, No.1 (1927): 39-48. 23 “United States Treasury Demand Note Suit,” Sacramento Daily Union, July 29, 1862. 24 Moses, “Legal Tender Notes in California,” 10-2. 25 The Legal Tender Act of 1862. For an in-depth analysis of the several legal tender acts, see: Wesley Clair Mitchell, “History of the Legal Tender Acts,” (PhD diss., University of Chicago, 1903). 12 Instead, the court established that a “tax is a charge upon persons or property to raise money to raise money for public purposes. It is not founded upon contract, and does not establish the relation of debtor and creditor between the taxpayer and the State.”26 Further, the court determined that the Legal Tender Act “only speaks of taxes due to the United States” and not to “taxes levied under the laws of the State.”27 Thus, despite the federal government’s designations of the depreciating greenbacks as ‘legal tender,’ California’s state government remained legally uninhibited to collect taxes in any monetary denomination so desired, while the state’s citizens could pay any federal taxes not in valuable gold or silver, but in inflationary paper currency. 28 For residents of the state, this court decision provided an especially strong rebuke to federal issuance of paper currency and national power. Not only did Californians preserve the integrity of the metallic standard by upholding its use in local taxation, but also allowed taxpayers to return depreciating greenbacks back to the East through federal tax payments. A proposed bill in the California Assembly to allow tax collection with the legal tendered greenbacks instead of 26 Curtis J. Hillyer, Reports of Cases Determined in the California Supreme Court of the State of California (San Francisco: Law Publishers and Law Booksellers, 1906), 318-51. 27 Hillyer, Reports of Cases, 350. 28 Ibid., 350-1. The court further elaborated this position in the decision, which stated, “The question then presented for determination is this: Are the notes of the United States thus receivable for State and county taxes under the [Legal Tender] Act of Congress? On the argument, the question on whether it is within the constitutional power of Congress to make these notes a legal tender in payment of debt, was ably and elaborately argued by counsel; but from the construction we give to the Act of Congress, this question is not before us. The question is one of great magnitude and importance, upon which the first legal minds of the country differ; and until it is legitimately and directly before us, we have no disposition—nor indeed would it be proper—to express or even intimate an opinion upon it. The Act does not, in our judgment, have any reference to taxes levied under the laws of the State. It only speaks to taxes due to the United States, and distinguished between them and debts. Its language is, ‘for all taxes, internal duties, excises, debts, and demands of every kind due to the United States,’ the notes should be receivable. When it refers to obligations other than those to the Unites States, it only uses the term ‘debts;’ the notes it declares shall be ‘a legal tender in payment of all debts, public and private.’ Taxes are not debts within the meaning of this provision. A debt is a sum of money due by contract, express of implied. A tax is a charge upon persons or property to raise money for public purposes. It is not founded upon contract; it does not establish the relation of debtor and creditor between the taxpayer and State; it does not draw interest, it is not the subject of attachment; and it is not liable to set-off. It owes its existence the action of legislative power, and does not depend for its validity or enforcement upon the individual assent of the taxpayer. It operates in invtium [against one’s will].” 13 silver and gold received little serious consideration, and as greenbacks continued to lose value, local legislators felt little incentive to change current laws.29 Californians’ opposition to paper money and reluctance to abandon gold soon put the state in a collision course with the federal government. With the passage of the Legal Tender Act in 1862, Congress designated greenback dollars as the legal tender of the United States and stipulated the famous maxim that the notes were legal payment for any debt, public or private. On March 17 of 1863, the California state government passed a law anathema to the federal government and the warfare-oriented financial reforms that allowed billions of dollars in capital to be centralized and allocated for the conflict. Titled the Specific Contract Act, California’s legislators, by a vote of 42 to 18 in the Assembly and 22 to 11 in the Senate, affirmed a measure that “provides that all contracts made for the payment of money in a specific form shall be enforced— that men shall be compelled to live up to their agreements in good faith.”30 In other words, the Specific Contract Act allowed private contracts to be specifically denominated in either greenbacks, gold, or silver. For example, before the Specific Contract Act and the Perry decision, if a bank made a loan in 1860, the national Legal Tender Act mandated the debtor to repay the interest and principle of the loan using depreciating greenbacks, which had been deemed legal tender by the federal government. In real terms, any loan repaid with a depreciated currency could prove ruinous to the lender, and future loans would thenceforth incorporate high interest rates to compensate for anticipated future inflation. Californians sought to remedy this problem by allowing contracts to specify if a loan were to be repaid in stable gold or fiat and 29 30 Moses, “Legal Tender Notes in California,” 14-7. “The Contract Bill,” Sacramento Daily Union, April 1, 1863. 14 depreciating greenbacks.31 The Specific Contract Act allowed commercial exchanges to continue without the fear of future inflation and economic disruptions, and provided a heartened reassurance to Californians worried about a flood of federal greenbacks and associated price inflation. Soon, other states began to copy California’s rebellious rejection of central monetary authority. Despite “meet[ing] with very strong opposition,” which “occupied the attention of the Legislature for several days,” a similar Specific Contract Act passed the Oregon legislature on October 7, 1864.32 Then, on December 31, 1864 and against the opposition of federal authorities, Nevada’s state legislature passed a similar measure, titled the Nevada Specific Contract Act, which promised monetary independence from the federal government and protected the validity of gold contracts to an even greater extent than California. Sections 11 and 12 of Nevada’s Act allowed for any contracts made within the state to be denominated in any monetary medium as decided by respective contractual parties, be they in gold, silver, or federal paper, by mandating that “[w]hen the [court] judgment under which the [plaintiff’s] sale has been made is payable in a specified kind of money or currency, said payment shall be made in the same kind of money or currency, and a tender of the money shall be equivalent in law to payment.”33 This clause gave Nevadan courts the specific authority to enforce payment specifications for contracts in litigation in whatever medium of exchange that was specified in the respective contract. The law also specified that “[t]he provisions of this act shall apply to all actions brought to recover any tax, This is an implicit result of the so-called Gresham’s Law, named after the sixteenth-century Englishman, Sir Thomas Gresham, but commented upon by other luminaries, including Nikolas Copernicus. The law states that whenever a government overvalues (through legal tender laws usually) one currency over another concurrently circulating currency, the undervalued currency will disappear into hoards and the overvalued currency will be used for commercial transactions. For example, if a merchant had the choice to either pay for goods with the stable medium of gold or depreciating (and inflating) greenbacks, he would most likely spend the greenbacks and retain the gold. In that way, ‘good money drives out the bad.’ 32 “The Specific Contract Bill in Oregon Passed Both Houses,” Sacramento Daily Union, October 8, 1864. 33 “The Nevada Specific Contract Act,” Daily Alta California, January 6, 1865. 31 15 fine, fee, cost, duty, or impost, where by law such tax, fine, fee, cost, duty, or impost be required to be paid in any particular or specified kind of money or currency,” which specifically enumerated the state government’s power to collect taxes in gold or silver while rejecting taxpayers’ ability to pay state taxes in depreciating greenbacks.34 However, the Nevada Specific Contract Act went even further in challenging the federal government’s monetary authority than did California. In a further rebuke to federal paper money, the law declared that “[t]he provisions of this act shall apply to all actions on implied contracts or obligations contracted or incurred after the passage of this act, when it shall appear on the trial to the satisfaction of the Court, jury, or referee, that the debt or obligation was contracted or incurred upon the basis of any particular kind of money or currency.”35 Unlike California, whose Specific Contract Act only implicitly protected written contracts, Nevada’s version covered unwritten, ‘implied’ contracts negotiated by word of mouth. The Daily Alta approvingly noted that “These [Nevadan specific contract laws sections 11 and 12] are good additions. Our [Californian] law only applies only to written contracts, whereas oral contracts should be protected in the same manner as those in writing,” and predicted that a further protections of the Specific Contract Law would “no doubt get a place upon our statute book at the next session of our Legislature.”36 Around the same time, Washington Territory followed its southern neighbors and adopted a “Specific Contract Law [that] is precisely similar to that enacted by your [Californian] Legislature, and will have a beneficial effect in creating confidence, and regulating the monetary transactions of the two States.”37 The territories of Idaho, Colorado, Montana and Utah also adopted variations of “The Nevada Specific Contract Act,” Daily Alta California, January 6, 1865. “The Nevada Specific Contract Act,” Daily Alta California, January 6, 1865. 36 “The Specific Contract Law of Nevada,” Daily Alta California, December 30, 1864. 37 “Chaos’ Letter from the North,” Daily Alta California, December 11, 1864. 34 35 16 California’s Specific Contract Act during the ensuing years.38 After California’s repudiation of a national paper currency, this regional monetary rebellion promised dire consequences to federal finances during a period of strained wartime budgets by severely limiting the federal government’s power to collect taxes within the Western states and territories. Federal officials realized that their power would have to be reestablished or the West’s vast economic resources might slip from the federal government’s net of taxation. The Union Strikes Back: Federal Attempts at Imposing Central Monetary Authority Federal officials and Unionists reacted with alarm at this apparently flippant violation of national unity during a time of war. From the federal government’s perspective, the National Banking Act, Legal Tender Act, and the circulation of greenbacks existed as wartime emergency measures designed to strengthen the Union and assist in raising war-related revenue through bonds and taxation. With greenback inflation resulting in rising prices and wages, the federal tax code began to embrace more Californians as their inflating incomes crept into higher tax bracket thresholds within the nation’s first income tax. However, if as the Specific Contract Act stood, Californians’ wages could be denominated in gold instead of greenbacks and gold’s price stability would ensure that wages and prices remained consistent. Thus California residents could avoid tax bracket creep that encompassed a greater percent of income with continuing 38 Interestingly, the Idaho Territory faced unforeseen problems with their own state Specific Contract Act when in “1863, [the] influx of greenbacks into the Pacific coast at first had the same result in Idaho as it had in California and Nevada. Lenders denied credit to those who paid in greenbacks. Business sought and won a Specific Contract Act for the territorial legislature. But mercantile experience demonstrated the need for legal tender notes. The circulating medium in Idaho prior to greenbacks was primarily gold dust. But the counterfeiting of gold dust resulted in consistently higher values for notes in Idaho that in the San Francisco market. Hence, Idaho merchants lobbied for a repeal of the Specific Contract At, and business accepted greenbacks at par to avoid losses due to ‘bogus dust.’ I this context, the Idaho court found the Specific Contract Act void. In Idaho the practical business policy question was clearly one of the money supply and certainly of exchange. While California merchants could write contracts for gold coin, Idaho dealers possessed few coins. Gold dust was less reliable because of counterfeiting and federal notes thereby gained value.” From, Gordon M. Bakken, “Law and Legal Tender in California and the West,” in The American West: Interactions, Intersections, and Injunctions, ed. by Gordon M. Bakken and Brenda Farrington, (New York: Garland Publishing Inc., 2001) 323-41. 17 inflation. In response to Californians’ intentions to avoid shouldering higher greenback taxes, the federal government sent “certain Assessors of Internal Revenue” who “in defiance of law and common justice,” proceeded to “screw just twice as much taxes out of [Californian taxpayers]” by convert[ing] the [gold-based] incomes of Californians into greenbacks and compel[ing] them to pay taxes in proportion.”39 By converting tax assessments from stable gold to inflating greenbacks, federal tax assessors managed to increase dramatically the rate of taxation from Californians, despite the protections contained within the Specific Contract Act.40 For Eastern Unionists, a legal or rhetorical assault on the greenback soon became tantamount to an assault on the power of the Union and smacked of treacherous disloyalty during a time of national crisis. Unionists warned that “[t]he good name of the peerless state of California is in peril,” that the an embrace of the greenback was “but another name for patriotism and love of country,” and lamented that “[t]he worst enemies of our State smile with wild joy as they hear boasting Union men strike their blows against National credit.” Some Unionists even pondered whether there were a “great difference […] between the acts of South Carolina Nullification Laws in past years and the laws of California that nullified the currency (the only money making authority of our nation) declares shall be legal?”41 After a vote to repeal failed in the California Senate, the California Farmer and Journal of Useful Sciences snarled that “[a]ll the Copperhead Senators voted against the bill, as was to be expected from their known “No Apology Needed,” Daily Alta California, September 27, 1865. Ibid. The Daily Alta further elaborated an example for the reader. “Let us illustrate: A citizen has returned his income for 1864 at $2,000. The income tax upon $2,000 at 6 per cent. [sic] is $100. One hundred dollars in greenbacks can now be purchased for $76; so the Californian who has $2,000 income will have to pay in addition to all his other taxes, State, county, and the tariff, $75 to the General Government— a very handsome sum, it must be admitted, and in times like the present by no means very easy to contribute. But in the eyes of certain Assessors of the Internal Revenue, that was not enough. They asked for permission to take this $2,000 income for 1864 convert it into greenbacks at the average price of 1864, (50 cents on the dollar) and charge taxes upon the whole — that is to say, raise the $2,000 income to $4,000, and compel the payment of taxes upon that amount — $150 instead of $75.” 41 “California in Peril,” California Farmer and Journal of Useful Sciences, February 12, 1864. 39 40 18 sympathy with rebellion and nullification.”42 Soldiers were one special interest group especially invested in the repeal of the Specific Contract Act. Locally garrisoned soldiers petitioned that “they [who] deemed it their duty to enlist in the army” made only a pittance in government paper, and “were unable to even [spend] their wages without first selling their greenbacks for coin and submitting to a discount for the benefit of brokers.”43 Nevertheless, local constituents’ petitions against the Act’s repeal vastly outnumbered the occasional complaints from federal employees.44 Critics also lambasted California’s Specific Contract act as a blatantly unconstitutional measure that flew against established national law. In a debate that pitted “the Loyal People vs. the Bankers, Copperheads, and avowed Traitors,” the California Farmer and Journal of Useful Sciences asked facetiously: Did Congress exceed the powers granted by the Constitution when it made Treasury Notes a legal tender for all debts—or in other words the currency of the country? If Congress did exceed its powers, then the act was unconstitutional, not binding, and the special contract act which this bill sought to repeal was correct, and ought to remain. But if Congress did not exceed its powers, then the Contract Act was nullification as rank as that of South Carolina.45 Charges accusing the Specific Contract Act of unconstitutionality continued to reverberate elsewhere. The Los Angeles Star lectured readers that “[i]f the act of congress is Constitutional, it is ‘the supreme law of the land,’ and no State legislation or decision of a State Court can affect “The Repeal Bill in the Legislature,” California Farmer and Journal of Useful Sciences, February 12, 1864. The attempt at repealing the Specific Contract Act failed in the state Senate by a vote of 23 to15. The same story reported that “[o]n Monday evening, D. W. Cheeseman, the U. S. Treasurer at San Francisco, who was denied a hearing at the Platt's Hall meeting last week, delivered an address, by invitation, in the Assembly Chamber, to a large audience, urging the repeal of the law, and the introduction of the U. S. currency into this State.” However, federal officials’’ pleadings to locals for acquiescence to monetary authority gained little traction amongst most unsympathetic Californians. 43 “California Legislature,” Sacramento Daily Union, February 1, 1864. 44 Ibid., At the same State Senate hearing, several petitions were read in support of the Specific Contract Act. “Mr. Roberts presented a series of resolutions pastel at a large public meeting recently held at San Francisco against the repeal of the Specific Contract Law, being signed by the President, Mr. Torrey, and the Secretary, Mr. Britton. Mr. Roberts also presented a remonstrance against the repeal, signed by several thousand citizens of San Francisco. Messrs. Pierce and Porter presented similar remonstrances from citizens of the counties of Sonoma and Marin.” 45 “Repeal of the Specific Contract Law,” California Farmer and Journal of Useful Sciences, January 22, 1864. 42 19 its provisions. The right of the Legislature to limit or place conditions upon the exercise of the Congressional act, is based solely upon the ground that the act is unconstitutional and not ‘the supreme law of the land.’”46 After the war, charges of unconstitutionally gained traction in 1866, when opponents of the act reveled in a temporary legal vindication after the Nevada Supreme Court declared the state’s Specific Contract Act unconstitutional after interpreting the definition of ‘debt’ differently than had the courts in California.47 Treasury secretary Chase added his own sentiments to the constitutionality debate by declaring that “[he was] clearly of the opinion that the California gold law [Specific Contract Act] is against National policy, and I shall be much gratified to see California declare herself in favor of one currency for the whole people by its repeal.”48 Nonetheless, legal protections against forcing merchants into commercial exchanges with depreciating greenbacks remained popular throughout the economically rebellious West, but would soon face further constitutional challenges at the Supreme Court of the United States. While the critics of California’s act of monetary rebellion hurled accusations of sedition and unconstitutionality, many Californians fought back and protested their national loyalty and financial rationality. Promoters of the Specific Contract Act avidly denied the accusations of national treachery from the “fireside patriots,” who were “far removed from war and its miseries.”49 Proponents of the Specific Contract Act countered that: “Greenbacks and Loyalty,” Los Angeles Star, August 27, 1864. “The Nevada Decision Against the Specific Contract Considered from a Legal Standpoint,” Daily Alta California, January 9, 1866. “The Nevada Supreme Court decided against the Specific Contract Law, and issued this explanation in their decision, with an emphasis on its interpretation of a debt: The demand for which this action was instituted was a debt, as designated in the act of Congress, liable to be liquidated and cancelled by payment of legal tender notes at their face value. It makes no difference in the eyes of the law that the contract calls for payment in gold coin; the legal character of the demand and the force and effect of the law of Congress still remain impressed upon it. Can a state law withdraw it from the operation of the paramount law? It is a debt which, in virtue of the express mandate of the supreme law, may be paid in those issues which the law itself called into existence.” 48 The author tartly retorted “The people of California can think for themselves, and will not dance whenever Chase whistles.” From, “Chase’s Opinion on the Repeal of the Specific Contract Law,” Sacramento Daily Union, February 10, 1864. 49 “California Legislature,” Sacramento Daily Union, January 15, 1864. 46 47 20 the very men who in the last Legislature denounced the friends of the Specific Contract Act as disloyal, refused to consider a bill to make greenbacks receivable for [local] taxes— and passed, without discussion, (and, if we remember rightly, without objection,) the act quoted above. They thought the payment of contract in gold was disloyal, but they compelled the payment of taxes in gold. They wished to deprive the people of the privilege of paying gold in one case, and of paying greenbacks in another. They wished to repeal an act which does not discriminate against greenbacks; they passed an act which does discriminate against them.50 Proponents also argued that the Act was entirely constitutional and compared the Specific Contract Act to the ability of merchants to receive payment for foreign goods in an international denomination. The Daily Alta protested that “[t]here is nothing unconstitutional in the specific enforcement of a contract; there is nothing unconstitutional in a contract for the payment of foreign coin; there is nothing unconstitutional in a contract for the payment of any legal currency of the United States.”51 The newspaper reasoned that just as contracts dealing across international borders would often be denominated in foreign currency, there was no constitutional mandate that could make illegal commercial transactions in monetary media other than that of a legal tender. Further, proponents countered that the Specific Contract Act did not actually discriminate against any medium of exchange, but only enshrined into law the right of Californians to maintain discretion in their commercial transactions. Proponents also protested that the Act made ensured wage stability for downtrodden workers whose livelihoods sat at the mercy of mercurial employers and wage-labor. Since the greenback currency continued to lose value throughout the war, wage-laborers who worked on contract wages saw their earnings shrink in purchasing power as inflation took an ever-increasing bite from their wages. The Daily Alta reasoned that “it is very clear that the repeal of the Specific Contract Act, and the consequent adoption of greenbacks as the sole currency would break every engagement for labor 50 51 “The Enemies of the Specific Contract Law,” Daily Alta California, August 4, 1864. “The Constitutionality of the Specific Contract Law,” Daily Alta California, August 5, 1864. 21 in the State, or else cause a serious [financial purchasing power] loss to the employé [sic].”52 If the proponents of the national greenbacks succeeded in repealing the Specific Contract Act, wage-laborers working under contract would face frequency unemployment as they would either be forced to search for work that offered competitive wages, or live in destitution as inflation reduced as their contractual earning power from falling relative wages. Californians remained “unanimously in favor of the specific contract law, for the stability and the certainty which it give to all our business transactions, and opposed to their placing the people on tenterhooks of anxiety to know what is to be done, obliging them to lend their business in breathless anxiety.”53 In 1864, the economic repercussions caused by depreciating greenbacks forced even the California Farmer and Journal of Useful Sciences to temper its enthusiasm for federal paper. The California Farmer had been a consistent shrill for greenback campaign, and proudly recounted that “[f]rom the first, we announced that we would receive Treasury Notes at par for Subscriptions to the Farmer.” However, the paper lamented that: the [greenback] notes were rejected, here [in San Francisco], as currency and many of our subscribers have, in conformity with the custom, continued to pay us in gold; yet we have never refused greenbacks at their face value when sent us by subscribers, though it has subjected us to serious loss from our being obliged (from the rejection of the currency as mentioned), to pay gold in our disbursements.54 By accepting revenue in depreciating greenbacks while paying expenses in stable gold, the California Farmer began to suffer the economic consequences brought on by the depreciation of greenbacks and was forced to raise their annual subscription price “to $5 a year, payable in U.S. Legal Tender notes [or] the ruling premium when gold is tendered in payment.”55 In reaction to these fears and realities of economic tribulation, California led the Western states into a state of “The Proposed Exclusion of Gold as Affecting Contracts for Labor,” Daily Alta California, August 8, 1864. “California Legislature,” Sacramento Daily Union, January 15, 1864. 54 “Greenbacks! Greenbacks!,” California Farmer and Journal of Useful Sciences, May 6, 1864. 55 Ibid. 52 53 22 monetary secession that troubled federal authorities but protected local residents from an inflating currency. However, California’s predilection for a hard currency immune to the inflationary impulses of the federal government’s printing presses soon set the state on a collision course with federal policy and against the economic centralization trend that continued throughout the course of the Civil War.56 The next federal attempt at limiting the circulation and price volatility of gold arrived wrapped in the legal guise of the Gold Bill. The measure, signed by President Lincoln on March 21, 1864, included language that proclaimed “all sales or agreement to sell gold, silver, or foreign exchange, are hereby declared null and void, unless the full amount of the purchase money for such gold, silver, or foreign exchange shall be paid at the time of such sale or agreement to sell.”57 The Bill included a further enforcement clause that threatened that “all money paid in partial payment, or as a margin on the sale or agreement to sell gold, silver, or foreign exchange, may be reclaimed at any Court of competent jurisdiction.”58 In other words, the Gold Bill threatened to forbid gold purchased at speculative prices, as was often done by 56 Greenbacks were not the only medium of paper currency under rhetorical attack in California. One newspaper letter-writer lamented the flood of newly-invented postage stamps, satirically titled ‘The Stick Plaster Currency,’ a play on words alluding to ‘shin plasters,’ the worthless paper bills of bankrupt banks that circulated at deep discount during the antebellum years. “‘A thing of beauty is a joy forever.’ Thus wrote the delicate Keats, but Keats never knew the luxury as a stick plaster currency. Postage stamps, gummed with the best adhesive, sticking on sweaty fingers, were unknown in his primitive age. If Congress had not adjourned, it is believed that it would have made molasses candy a legal lender by this time. It seemed to be trying to invent a currency that would stick to people. It is such a general complaint that money cannot be kept, that it was evidently the idea of this Congress to give the people something that would stick to them. Just think, too, how delightful this currency is for my business! With hands still wet with compounding drinks, I am just prepared to finger postage stamps! How they do stick, though! By the way, why not make plug tobacco a legal tender? Have it put up in ‘cuds,’ from one cent upwards in price—it would do just the thing, just the thing that would not stick. Those who use snuff might put it in envelopes after the fashion of postage stamps. If the war s to continue a year or two longer, I go in for ‘the legal tender cuds.’ Away with the postage stamp nuisance. It has caused more profanity since this adoption than can be atoned for in a twelve month. If this is not speedily abolished I shall begin to think seriously about retiring from Behind the Counter.” N.Y. Caucasian, “The Stamp Plaster Currency,” Los Angeles Star, September 27, 1862. 57 “The Gold Bill,” Daily Alta California, March 13, 1864. 58 Ibid. 23 banks and investors as a hedge against future anticipated inflation, and empowered courts to void such transactions. Congress crafted the Gold Bill to tamp down on the “gambling in gold for which Wall street [sic] has become so famous,” but the Bill’s language could also be interpreted as a check against conversions of greenbacks into gold at speculative prices.59 However, the Daily Alta, usually a stalwart opponent of greenbacks and defender of the Specific Contract Act, dismissed the regulatory power of the Bill, and reassured readers that “[w]hen the bill was first introduced fears were entertained that it would render a gold and silver currency impossible here, but a perusal will satisfy every one [sic] that they were without foundation.”60 Meanwhile, the Sacramento Daily Union scoffed at the power of the federal government to institute such prohibitions against gold transactions in defiance of a hostile state judiciary, and predicted that “[t]he Secretary of the Treasury will not employ any agents to carry into effect the power conferred on him by the Gold Bill.61 Despite Congressional attempts, federal power appeared impotent to coerce Californians to embrace federal paper and forgoing gold circulation against geographic distance, popular hostility, and judicial sympathy.62 Return of the Goldbug: California’s Monetary Rebellion Manages an Unlikely Victory Soon, legal decisions by state courts upheld the constitutionality of the Specific Contract Act and stymied federal opposition to the law. In April of 1864, two merchants became involved in a legal tussle after a gentleman named Atherton refused to repay $500 to another merchant named Carpentier in the contractually specified denomination of gold. In lieu of metal, Atherton The Gold Bill,” Daily Alta California, March 13, 1864. Ibid. 61 “By Overland Telegraph,” Sacramento Daily Union, March 21, 1864. 62 Just a few months later, after Secretary Chase’s resignation in July 1864, Congress repealed the unenforceable and impractical law and the whole episode became moot. “Congress gave a parting kick at the dead lion [Chase] by repealing the Gold Bill, one of the straws at which the struggling financier had caught, on the day after his resignation.” From: “Affairs at the Treasury Department,” Sacramento Daily Union, July 30, 1864. 59 60 24 offered to repay Carpentier in rapidly inflating greenbacks. This dispute set the stage for a constitutional assessment of the Specific Contract Act through the state’s Supreme Court. In July 1864, while displaying a judicial velocity unimaginable in modern courts by reaching a judgment only four months later after the dispute arose, the California Supreme Court heard the case of Carpentier v. Atherton and upheld the contentious law by ruling that “enforcement in terms of contracts made payable in a specified kind of money or currency is not in derogation of, nor does it conflict with the laws of congress making United States notes lawful money and legal tender in payment of debts.” However, the court specified that for any contract made before April 27, 1863, but which did not specify a monetary medium of payment, the federal government “has no power to annex to the judgment rendered an order or direction specifying the kind of money in which payment must be made in satisfaction of the judgment.”63 In other words, not only was the Specific Contract Act compliant with federal law and constitutional, but the government had no jurisdiction over the monetary medium used by private parties engaged in legal contracts prior to the passage of the Act. The court’s decision immediately won praise among the local Californian press, with the Daily Alta justifying that: The notes of the Unites States, issued by the authority of the laws of the National Legislature, are a lawful and authorized currency, and in that sense a lawful money and a legal tender in the payment of private debts. But it does not follow that every kind or any kind of money which by law is legal tender in the payment of debts may be tendered in satisfaction of every obligation capable of performance by the transfer and delivery of property in satisfaction of it.64 In effect, through the Specific Contract Act, Californian legislators sequestered the state from monetary union with the remainder of the United States, and largely inoculated local citizens from the disruptive effects of wartime inflation. In the process, the ‘Golden’ state demonstrated 63 A. L. Rhodes, California Digest: A Digest of the Reports of the Supreme Court of California (San Francisco: A. L. Bancroft & Co., 1882), 1352. 64 “The Opinion of the Supreme Court on the Specific Contract Act,” Daily Alta California, August 17, 1864. 25 its affinity with metallic standards, and rejected the monetary centralization trend dominating Civil War financial politics. Soon, the defiant Specific Contract Act would again find itself before a judicial tribunal, this time headed by a familiar foe—Supreme Court Chief Justice Salmon P. Chase. In June 1864, a peevish Secretary of the Treasury Salmon Chase tenured his fourth letter of resignation to President Lincoln after a series of minor slights and petty insults, but assumed that, like his previous three resignation threats, the president would refuse and humbly request Chase’s continued service. After a series of comic misunderstandings and errors, Lincoln unexpectedly accepted Chase’s resignation and nominated William Pitt Fessenden, a radical Republican senator from Maine, who was unanimously approved by his Senate colleagues on July 1.65 However, the ever ambitious former war financier soon found himself nominated by Lincoln as Chief Justice for the Supreme Court in December 1864. Once reviled within California for his issuance of paper currency, Californians cheered Chase’s appointment with a different attitude. The Sacramento Daily Union proclaimed that: Goodwin, Team of Rivals, 635-7. Fessenden’s short tenure was followed by Secretary McCulloch, who initiated another war of words with Californians over their defiant monetary stance. He blasted the state’s policies, as reported by the Sacramento Daily Union: “The Secretary of the Treasury, McCulloch. in a recent letter to Thompson Campbell, says that he has no hesitation in asserting that in his judgment California would have been a much richer and more prosperous State if her circulation had been a mixed instead of a metallic one; that she has not only failed to co-operate properly with the other States in maintaining the Government credit, but has misapprehended her own in discountenancing the use of paper money within her limits. No country can prosper for any considerable time where money commands so high a rate of interest as it does in California, and nothing would tend more directly to reduce that rate of interest than the introduction of a sound paper circulating medium.” The Daily Union quickly struck back, replying that “We cannot imagine what McCulloch means by saying that California would have been much richer and more prosperous ‘if her circulation had been a mixed instead of an exclusively metallic one.’ He cannot surely have intended to say that the use of bank notes would have benefited California, since he advocates the tax on our State circulation with a view to suppress it. He cannot believe that that which he considers an evil to the other States would have been a benefit to California. He must, therefore, mean that California would have been benefited by a mixed circulation of gold and legal tender notes. But this is an impossibility, because it is a natural law that where two or more currencies circulate, the poorest or cheapest invariably drive out all others. Had California ever permitted legal tender notes to circulate, they would have suppressed the use of gold there just as effectually as they have suppressed it there.” “Secretary McCulloch on California,” Sacramento Daily Union, May 18, 1865. 65 26 Next to the issuance of the Emancipation Proclamation, no public act of President Lincoln has given such general satisfaction as the appointment of Salmon P. Chase to the proud position of Chief Justice of the Supreme Court of the United States [...which] is being reorganized in the interests of freedom, and as time and death causes breaks in the bench, the gaps are filled with men of purity, probity, and love of liberty.66 In 1868, Chief Justice Chase presided over a groundbreaking case that tested the legality of informal specific payment contracts across the nation, which granted the architect of the nation’s uniform currency a chance to strike down the legality of gold contracts. The case originated in New York in 1851, when Christian Metz borrowed fourteen hundred dollars from Arthur Bronson at seven percent interest and payable in gold coin. After partial repayment, and a change in debtors, Peter Rodes repaid the remaining principal plus interest of the amortization mortgage to a total of $1507 in greenbacks in 1865. The dispute, legally known as Bronson v. Rodes, landed at the feet of the Supreme Court in 1868, and Chase penned the 8-1 majority decision. The former treasury secretary, architect of the greenback revolution and nemesis of self-styled hard-money men, delivered a startling opinion. He declared that “[w]hen, therefore, contracts made payable in coin are sued upon, judgments may be entered in coined dollars and parts of dollars; and when contracts have been made payable in dollars generally, without specifying in what currency payment is to be made, judgments may be entered generally, without such specification.”67 Chase then cast doubt against the Specific Contract Act’s detractors’ cries of unconstitutionality, and reasoned “[n]or do we think it necessary to examine the question whether the clauses of the currency act making United States notes a legal tender are warranted by the Constitution in this case.”68 The unexpected decision appeared to surprise even the aging Chief Justice himself, and he later recounted in his memoirs that “[t]here was a good deal of talk “Letters from Washington: Chief Justice Chase,” Sacramento Daily Union, January 11, 1865. William B. Dana, editor, The Merchant’s Magazine and Commercial Review, Volume 60 (New York: William B. Dana Publisher and Proprietor, 1869), 268-75. 68 “The United States Supreme Court on Gold Contracts,” Daily Alta California, March 18, 1869. 66 67 27 which manifested in a determination on the part of the present majority of the Court to force the rehearing of the legal tender questions with a [fixed determination] as I fear to reverse the decision already made.”69 Despite his previous affiliation with unbacked currency and wartime denouncement of California’s monetary rebellion, Chase affirmed the legality and propriety of private contracts using alternatives to the federal dollar, which further undermined the power of the federal government to monopolize the monetary medium.70 Soon, the ‘father of the greenback’ would go much further in destroying the legal basis from which government paper could be issued. Californian newspapers righteously applauded Chase’s decision. The Daily Alta cheered that “[h]ere is the California Specific Contract Law established for the Union without troubling Congress. Common sense and justice have triumphed at last, and contracts between man and man mean what they express, and not what pettifogging political lawyers would have them express.”71 The irony of Chase’s presiding over both the birth and death knell of greenbacks did not fail to resonate on contemporary observers. In the wake of the ruling, the Daily Alta crowed that “Mr. Chase has swallowed his own sophism,” and mused that: Chief Justice Chase, the author of the sophism of “the premium on gold,” which sent the country on such a “swinging around the circle” of finance, has just discovered that the principle of common honesty is imbedded in the National Constitution, and that the man who promises to pay gold is bound by that instrument to live up to his agreement. So, 69 John Niven, editor, The Salmon P. Chase Papers, Volume 1, Journals, 1829-1872 (Kent: The Kent State University Press, 1993), 651. 70 However, the court’s decision was not unanimous: “Justice Miller dissented, holding that, although it was the intention of the parties that gold should be paid, it was only so because gold was then the currency of the Government, the lawful money of the United States, mentioned in the contract. There was nothing in the contract to make it differ from any her ordinary contract payable in dollars. When treasury notes became lawful money of the United States, their tender was sufficient to discharge the contract, and within its terms and within the understanding and intention of the parties. This decision in no way affects the legal tender cases argued by Potter and the Attorney General at the present term of the Court, although reargued at the time of the argument of those cases.” From the, “Atlantic Intelligence: Important Decision of the United States Supreme Court,” Sacramento Daily Union, March 12, 1869. 71 “Financial and Commercial,” Daily Alta California, February 17, 1869. 28 after all this wild excitement and fierce struggling, we have got back to the position from which we started, viz., that contracts are inviolable.72 Meanwhile, the Sacramento Daily Union commenting that “the ‘father of greenbacks’ himself, and those who most stoutly upheld the Government in its war use of them, now most strenuously insist upon their voluntary disuse by the people, and a general resort to the true standard.”73 Relieved of their constant worry of a perpetual peacetime greenback currency, Californians looked forward to the return of overseas gold and a healthy resumption of commerce. The Sacramento Daily Union predicted that “[w]ere our paper currency retired or made redeemable, this foreign specie would flow back to us, instead of being augmented yearly by our own exports of gold, which go abroad because we will give it no chance to be of use at home.”74 The prewar gold standard appeared to be approaching a legal resurrection, in part to the efforts of a newly sympathetic Chief Justice. Chase’s apparent change of heart was motivated by several factors. First, by 1868, the fiscal emergency in which the federal government found itself in the dark days of 1862 had given way to fiscal stability and a steady postwar decline in the federal debt. Instead of the dire need of issuing masses of treasury bonds and greenbacks, the government’s most pressing financial goal was now aimed at retiring circulating paper currency and debt. National debate now centered on how and when greenback to gold convertibility would be restored within the nation, and with what speed to contract the monetary supply. The Sacramento Daily Union theorized that “it is probable that their decision was influenced largely by the conviction that the public necessities of the case are now diametrically different from what they were during the war — the use of “The History of a Mischievous Sophism,” Daily Alta California, February 17, 1869. “Let Government Set the Example,” Sacramento Daily Union, March 15, 1869. 74 “Senator Cole’s Speech,” Sacramento Daily Union, August 1, 1868. 72 73 29 greenbacks was a necessity; now, the use of specie is equally a necessity.”75 Ironically, Chase’s legal decision cut from the federal government much of the legal punitive measures needed to enforce the adoption of a standard national currency. With the 1868 decision, California’s adoption of a duel the monetary media of gold and greenbacks became de jure throughout the nation. After the apparent victory of specie-backed currency, gold again appeared triumphant as the dominant legal currency, national monetary debates swirled around the methods of readoption of a strict gold standard. The Chase Court’s decision in Bronson v. Rodes upheld the right of Americans to engage in legal contracts without the use of governmentally designated legal tender, and extended that right nationwide. Soon, the entire edifice of the greenback system would come crashing down as the Supreme Court rendered a shock to the legal foundations of government paper. In 1870, two years after the Bronson decision, the Supreme Court rendered a controversial decision in Hepburn v. Griswold. The case originated in Kentucky, and involved years of litigation over whether prewar debts made in gold could legally be repaid in greenbacks. While the Chase Court could have declined to hear the suit and declare the matter settled law, they instead accepted the hearing, likely to redress lingering issues on the constitutionality of certain aspects of the Legal Tender Act and subsequent laws. In the majority decision again penned by Chief Justice Chase, the court presaged the overturning of settled law by reminding readers that “[n]ot every act of Congress, then, is to be regarded as the supreme law of the land; nor is it by every Act of Congress that the Judges are bound.”76 With that caveat in place, the majority decision continued, “[i]t has not been maintained in argument [...] that there is in the Constitution any express grant of legislative power to make any description of credit currency a legal tender in “Let Government Set the Example,” Sacramento Daily Union, March 15, 1869. “The Legal Tender Act—The Decision of the United States Supreme Court,” Sacramento Daily Union, February 19, 1870. 75 76 30 payment of debts.”77 Chase soon turned against the concept of fiat paper money itself, writing that whatever its limited benefits, they are “more than outweighed by the losses of property, the derangement of business, the fluctuations of currency and values, and the increase of prices to the people and the Government, and the long train of evils which flow from the use of an irredeemable paper money.”78 The Court threw doubt onto the unconstitutionality of the legal tender laws and, by implication, the issuance of greenback currency from several constitutional standpoints. First, the Court concluded “that a law not made in pursuance of an express power, which necessarily and in its direct operation impairs the operation of contracts, is inconsistent with the Spirit of the Constitution.”79 In other words, since the Constitution never implicitly stated that Congress possessed the power to print paper currency, the federal government had acted improperly when issuing such paper. Secondly, since the Constitution explicitly forbade state issuance of paper currency, the judges deduced that “it [is] clear that those who framed and those who adopted the Constitution intended that the spirit of this [paper currency] prohibition should pervade the entire body of legislation.”80 Finally, the Court found conflict between the designation of paper currency as legal tender and the Fifth Amendment’s ‘due process’ and ‘takings’ clauses. Abrogation of gold-backed liabilities with paper substitutes represented an unjust ‘takings’ of private property, and forced people “to accept in payment of currency of inferior value [and] deprives such persons of property without due process of law.”81 With this momentous legal decision, the monetary rebellion led by California managed to undermine the legal framework from which greenbacks could be issued. As per the Chase Court’s logic, the 77 The Legal Tender Act—The Decision of the United States Supreme Court,” Sacramento Daily Union, February 19, 1870. 78 Ibid. 79 Ibid. 80 Ibid. 81 Ibid. 31 federal government possessed no legal authority to print unbacked currency. Greenbacks, for all intents and purposes, became null and void overnight. Buoyed by a remarkable string of judicial victories, the hard-money advocates in California rejoiced at this latest ruling. The Daily Alta declared that the court acted “in accordance with the plain principles of justice” and noted that “[f]ortunately for this State, we have never resorted to the disreputable expedient of paying our State or County bonds in greenbacks, though we believe the interest on some of the bonds of an interior town wore paid in that currency.”82 The Daily Alta’s perennial rival, the pro-greenback Californian Farmer, also embraced the decision with optimism, but countered that “[o]ur neighbor of the Alta, in its wisdom, thinks the result of this decision will be to depreciate the value of Greenbacks. We believe it will be just the reverse, for this decision in our opinion makes them of more value.”83 The Court also recognized oral contracts as equally valid as those written, extending nationwide legal protections beyond even that of California’s Specific Contract Act, and as a result, even “the specific contract law of California is repealed in so far as it implies that oral contracts for 82 The Daily Alta also commented that: The decision made a great sensation in Wall street, because it requires coin payment of the principal and interest of large amounts of Railroad, City, County and State bonds issued before 1862, which have heretofore been paid in currency; and it is thought that North Carolina and Tennessee may repudiate because the burden of taxation will be too heavy for them to bear. The ruling is just, whatever the result may be. These large State debts are bad proof of the management of political cliques, and of the importance of having constitutional checks, limiting the amount to which obligations may be incurred by legislatures. One of the most beneficental [sic] clauses in the Constitution of California is that restricting the State debt; and when our Constitution is revised, the clause should be made more comprehensive, for it has already been evaded in several cases. “The Last Legal Tender Decision,” Daily Alta California, February 9, 1870. 83 The California Farmer used a curious method of reasoning to deliver such unexpected conclusions: The recent decision of the Supreme Court of the United States has now settled the “Currency Question.” It establishes contracts, all made before the war, as payable only in Gold, and the issue of Greenbacks being a necessity, it does not and cannot vitiate contracts among men. Our Specific Contract and t general understanding among all business men, supported by this decision, is, Gold only is understood as legal tender. Our neighbor of the Alta, in its wisdom, thinks the result of this decision will be to depreciate the value of Greenbacks. We believe it will be just the reverse, for this decision in our opinion makes them of more value. The present rapid reduction of be National debt, and the certainty that the entire property of the United States is pledged for their redemption, with the knowledge that the interest on United States Bonds is always paid promptly in Gold, and always will be, and the evidence that every dollar of the National indebtedness will be paid in Gold, must most certainly increase their value, for there is no better security in the world than U. S. Bonds and U. S. Securities. From, “The Currency Question,” California Farmer and Journal of Useful Sciences, February 10, 1870. 32 payment in a specific currency shall not be enforced.” 84 With the apparently conclusive conclusion of the Hepburn case, the monetary rebellion begun by the citizens of California with the Specific Contract Act vanquished the monetary framework of fiat currency, and re-anointed gold as the reigning monetary unit of the nation. California’s monetary rebellion not only managed to shield the traditional rights of private commercial contract from federal power, but also ultimately reestablished those traditional prerogatives throughout the nation. In short, California’s battle against the central monetary authority of the United States government emerged as the era’s most successful rebellion. Gold’s Epilogue For even the few California proponents of greenbacks in the years after the Civil War, time for the unbacked currency was growing short, and the pertinent political quandary remained when and under what circumstances gold convertibility would be legislatively resumed, and not whether resumption would indeed happen. However, the sudden legal termination of the federal government’s authority to print greenbacks stemming from Hepburn case was overturned by the Knox v. Lee decision in 1872. The Daily Alta noted that they possessed “a copy of the dissenting opinion of Justice Field in the case of Knox vs. Lee, before the United States Supreme Court, in in which he takes the ground that the Legal Tender Act is unconstitutional. It is the most complete and forcible summary of the arguments upon that side yet published, and will for that reason possess a permanent interest to lawyers and legislators,” but that the: Legal Tender Act was necessary as a war measure, and has served the main purpose for which it was designed; but its sudden overthrow by judicial decision, however consistent it might be with the Constitution, would be very severe upon debtors who have incurred “Important Decision of the U.S. Supreme Court on Gold Contracts,” Daily Alta California, March 8, 1872. Yet another case, Trebilcock v. Wilson established that the specific monetary contracts “appl[ied] not simply to contracts mode before the passage of the legal tender Act, but to all contracts without reference to date.” 84 33 obligations in a depreciated currency. When the change must be made to an exclusive gold legal tender, it can be best managed under legislative enactment.85 With greenback to gold resumption all but politically assured, the Daily Alta felt little threat from the weakened greenback movement, and instead warned against radical monetary measures brought on by an over-activist judiciary instead of a gradual program of greenback retirement stemming from a carefully considered legislative plan. The most remorseful sentiment in the wake of the Knox decision seemed to be Chief Justice Chase, who dissented with the minority. He lamented in his private diary that “[i]t is, I think, a sad day for the [country] & for the cause of constitutional government…The only thing that I regret in connection with my administration of the Finances is that I expressed even a qualified opinion that the making the United States notes a legal tender was necessary.86 If Chase could prophesize the approaching economic turbulence and decades of grinding deflation set in course by unstable monetary policy, he would likely be even more regretful, if not mortified, of his role that set the nation on tortuous monetary rollercoaster.87 The devastating financial Panic of 1873 convinced most Californians that a return to stable to a tangible, stable gold standard was prerequisite to economic stability. Amid bank failures, a precipitous drop in property value and sudden mass unemployment, the Daily Alta warned that “the dread penalty of using depreciated greenback paper currency must be paid “Important Decision of the U.S. Supreme Court on Gold Contracts,” Daily Alta California, March 8, 1872. John Niven, editor, The Salmon P. Chase Papers, xlviii. 87 Many contemporary accounts laid part of the blame for the Panic of ‘73on years of inflation and greenbacks distorting financial fundamentals. “The stock bubble has bursted as a thousand bubbles of similar general nature have done before. Any attempt to obtain money, to render paper firm, when there is no value received back of it must of necessity be a failure. [John] Laws, failure, the Mississippi scheme, the paper expansion preceding the French Revolution—all are instances [of economic Panics following a monetary expansion]. The government of the time, and the laws bolstered them up as best they could, their machinators [sic] concealed the absence of a value received back of their paper; but all was useless the bubble burst as it always will sooner or later. Money represents value of some kind. You may make a pretended value; you may call n dollar, a million, but it makes not it a million. Every dollar becomes but a millionth part of a real 'dollar. You may buy stocks until they sell for a hundred times their value, but when return interest is not commensurate with their price, they must fall - the bubble must burst.” From, “The Financial Panic,” Los Angeles Herald, October 3, 1873. 85 86 34 sooner or later, and if Congress takes warning now, and returns to honest dealing, much future trouble may be saved.”88 The masses of circulating greenbacks were thought to distort the ability of businesses to invest and save by replacing valuable assets with intrinsically worthless paper, of which “our mushroom financiers have inflated their financial balloon to a degree of tension beyond its power of resistance [which left the financial balloon] exploded and collapsed.”89 Another commenter noted that once “a greenback bank fails it always knocks down a whole row of its brethren, and these in turn floor scores of mercantile houses that depend on them,” while California financiers had “already practically recovered from a shock which would have prostrated us utterly had we been doing business on a greenback basis.”90 For hard-money advocates in California, paper greenbacks seemed to be behind the root cause of the severe Panic of ’73 by disguising true value behind inflated promises of wealth, and the only way to reestablish financial stability and prosperity was an immediate and complete return to the prewar gold standard via Congressional action. A political resolution to rectify the lingering problem of circulating greenbacks was soon enacted with legal instruments. In January 1875, the Specie Payment Resumption Act passed Congress and was signed by President Grant. The Resumption Act sought to begin redeeming greenbacks in four years’ time, beginning January 1, 1879, and reduce the current level of “The Panic,” Daily Alta Californian, September 25, 1873. Bank failures also occurred nationwide, and mass layoffs ensued. The California Farmer reported that “This [report of layoffs is but one case in hundreds, probably 20,000 to 40,000 workmen will be discharged from the manufactories before this Panic is over, and great suffering must be the result.” From, “Effects of Panic Upon Labor,” California Farmer and Journal of the Useful Sciences, November 6, 1873. In addition, land values plummeted nationwide, such as in New York, where assessed land values shrunk by 24 percent. From: “Effects of the Panic Upon Property Values,” Sacramento Daily Union, August 21, 1874. 89 “Peculiarities of the Panic,” Sacramento Daily Union, September 26, 1873. 90 “Rag-Money Versus Specie,” Sacramento Daily Union, September 7, 1875. The Daily Union further alleged that had “we been doing business on a greenback basis; which would in that case have smashed every bank in San Francisco; bankrupted fifty per cent. of the strongest firms; stopped our manufactures and improvements; and plunged thousands of our people into destitution and ruin. Let the rag-money advocates examine the phenomena of the California financial (situation carefully, for there is a nut here which cannot be cracked by their methods.” 88 35 circulating currency by 80 percent, down to $300 million.91 The steady contraction of the nation’s monetary base through redemption initiated decades of falling prices as Congress set the legal level of a dollar against gold at antebellum prices. In combination with higher productivity brought on by mechanization and industrialization, consumer prices began to fall and years of wartime price inflation reversed into decades of price deflation.92 In California, this combination of deflation and a consistent public desire for ‘real money’ would soon about a political movement that called for the free and unlimited coinage of free silver, and which would constitute the next phase of Californian public monetary sentiment. Conclusions at the end of a Monetary Saga This paper has attempted to bring to light several historical processes. First, in the whirlwind financial drama that threatened the Union with fiscal bankruptcy, California and neighboring Western states initiated a set of economic and political actions that resulted in monetary and economic secession contemporaneous with the Southern drive for political secession. Second, Californians rejected the influx of circulating greenbacks because of previous experiences with antebellum inflationary wildcat banknotes and a deep-seated fear of inflation and federal taxation. Third, the federal government waged a legal campaign against California’s monetary secession with a series of bills, acts, and laws that attempted to bring the rebellious West back into the legal framework that the wartime Union utilized to consolidate national “General News Items,” Pacific Rural Press, January 16, 1875. The Rural Press elaborated: The New Currency Bill.—The bill for the resumption of specie payment which has just passed both Houses of Congress, provides: First—A redemption of legal tenders, and of resumption of specie payments four years hence, on the 1st of January, 1879. Second —Free banking, in the widest sense of an unlimited issue of National Bank Currency. Third—A withdrawal of 80 per cent. [sic] of the amount issued in new bank currency from the volume of greenbacks, until the amount of $300,000,000 for United States notes is reached. Fourth—A substitution of small silver coin for fractional currency. Fifth—An abolition of the mint charge. 92 With steady deflation hurting debtors and farmers, in 1878 Congress ordered the Treasury to halt the redemption of greenbacks into gold, and kept $347 million of greenbacks in circulation. This seemingly innocuous action had outsized ramifications, for it was the first time that Congress asserted the power to regulate the size of the monetary base during peacetime for economic, and not governmental budgetary, reasons. For a more detailed history of the legal history of monetary issues, see: James Willard Hurst, A Legal History of Money in the United States, 17741970 (Lincoln, University of Nebraska Press: 1973), 183. 91 36 capital for military financing. Finally, not only was the federal onslaught against California monetary independence a failure, but the hard-money stance adopted by Californians eventually managed a legal coup d’état against the federal government’s financial system with the Supreme Court’s sanctioning of the Specific Contract Clause, and its subsequent nationwide adoption via judicial means. With that legal revolution, the Court cast the legal die that eventually set the political stage for Resumption and restitution of the gold standard. That the gold standard could be politically reactivated in the aftermath of the war was owed in no small part to the stubborn holdouts of hard-money sentiment in California, and the state’s preservation of a specie-backed monetary regime. For several decades after Resumption, the dollar remained imbued with a tangible promise of conversion into gold, and monometallic orthodoxy was enshrined into national law with the Gold Standard Act of 1900. Not until 1933 were the guarantee of dollar to gold convertibility unilaterally abrogated and the ownership of nontrivial amounts of gold by private citizens declared illegal by Franklin Roosevelt via executive order. During the intermediate era, the stability of a gold backed dollar helped propel American industrialization and establish global American financial dominance. With the steady legal and legislative victories of the California-led postwar gold standard revolution, the ‘Golden State’ monetary rebellion emerged as the most successful act of secession in American history. 37 Bibliography Dissertations Wesley Clair Mitchell. “History of the Legal Tender Acts.” PhD diss., University of Chicago, 1903. Monographs Bakken, Gordon. “Law and Tender in California and the West,” in The American West, Law in the West, ed. by Gordon Bakken and Brenda Farrington. New York: Garland Publishing, Inc., 2000. Barnes, Donna A. Farmers in Rebellion: The Rise and Fall of the Southern Farmers Alliance and the People’s Party in Texas. Austin: University of Texas Press, 1984. Browne, J. Ross. Report of the Debates in the Convention of California in September and October, 1849. Washington: Printed by John T. Towers, 1850. Catton, Bruce. The Coming Fury. New York: Doubleday, 1961. Dana, William B., editor. The Merchant’s Magazine and Commercial Review, Volume 60 New York: William B. Dana Publisher and Proprietor, 1869. Desty, Robert. The Constitution of the State of California Adopted in 1879. (San Francisco: Sumner Whitney & Co., 1879). Friedman, Milton and Schwartz, Anna. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963. Goodwin, Doris Kearns. Team of Rivals: The Political Genius of Abraham Lincoln. New York: Simon and Shuster Paperbacks, 2005. Grodin, Joseph R., Massey, Calvin R., and Cunningham, Richard B. The California State Constitution, A Reference Guide. Westport: Greenwood Press, 1993. Hicks, John D. The Populist Revolt: A History of the Farmers’ Alliance and the People’s Party. Omaha: University of Nebraska Press, 1961. Hillyer, Curtis J. Reports of Cases Determined in the California Supreme Court of the State of California. San Francisco: Law Publishers and Law Booksellers, 1906. Hurst, James Willard. A Legal History of Money in the United States, 1774-1970. Lincoln, University of Nebraska Press, 1973. Mihm, Stephen. A Nation of Counterfeiters: Capitalists, Con Men, and the Making of the United States. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2007. 38 Miller, Worth Robert. Populist Cartoons: An Illustrated History of the Third-Party Movement in the 1890s. Kirksville, Truman State University Press, 2011. Mitchell, Wesley C. Gold, Prices, and Wages under the Greenback Standard. New York: Augustus M. Kelley Publishers, 1966 [original 1908]. Niven, John, ed. The Salmon P. Chase Papers, Volume 1, Journals, 1829-1872. Kent: The Kent State University Press, 1993. Rhodes, A. L. California Digest: A Digest of the Reports of the Supreme Court of California. San Francisco: A. L. Bancroft & Co., 1882. Sraffa, Piero, ed. The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo: Volume 1, On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. Ann Arbor: Edward Brothers, Inc., 2004. Spaulding, Elbridge Gerry. The Legal Tender Act. Baker, Jones & Company, 1875 . Thompson, Isaac Grant. National Bank Cases, Containing All Decisions of Both the Federal and State Courts Relating to National Banks with Notes and References. Albany: John D. Parsons Jr., Publishing, 1878. Unger, Irwin. The Greenback Era: A Social and Political History of American Finance, 18651879. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1964. Newspapers California Farmer and Journal of Useful Sciences Daily Alta California Sacramento Daily Union Los Angeles Herald Los Angeles Star Pacific Rural Press Scholarly Articles Ellison, Joseph, “The Currency Question in Oregon during the Civil War Period.” Oregon Historical Quarterly, Vol. 28, No.1 (1927): 39-48. Hammond, Bray, “The North’s Empty Purse, 1861-1862,” The American Historical Review. Vol. 67, No.1 (1961), 1-18. 39 Moses, Bernard, “Legal Tender Notes in California.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 7, No.1 (1892): 1-25. 40