Nonlinear dynamics in stock market returns: an empirical study of Taiwan stock market Wu-Jen Chuang1 Wen-Chen Lo 2 1 Associated Professor, Graduate Institute of Money, Banking and Finance, Tamkang University, Taiwan, R.O.C. 2 Instructor, Department of Information Management, St. John’s University, Taiwan, R.O.C Graduate Institute of Management Science, Tamkang University, Taiwan, R.O.C Abstract Recent empirical research reports that nonlinear dynamics is present in asset returns because of noise traders involved in the market. This study examines whether there exits any nonlinear dynamics resulting from the irrational investing behaviors in Taiwan stock market. We employ a smooth transition regime switching model to capture the movements of Taiwan stock market returns. The nonlinear dynamics of the stock market differ between large and small returns. Multiple thresholds of regime transition exist due to positive and negative asset returns. The transition variable causing the regime change reveals the influence of the irrational investing behaviors. These results suggest that nonlinear dynamics exists in Taiwan stock market due to the irrational investors’ beliefs. Key words: Stock market returns, Behavioral finance 1. Introduction Stock prices are believed to reflect sensitive to the relevant economic news. Based upon the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) and the arbitrage pricing theory (APT), stock market returns can be predicted by many financial and macroeconomic variables and investors can reward excess returns by taking systematic risks, but not earn extra premium by bearing diversifiable risk1. In multifactor asset pricing models, any variables that affects the future investment opportunity set or the level of consumption (given wealth) could be a priced factor in equilibrium (Merton, 1973 ; Breeden, 1979). However, no satisfactory theory can argue that the relation between financial market and macroeconomy is entirely in one direction (Chen, Roll and Ross, 1986). A 1 CAPM is proposed by William Sharpe (1964) and John Lintner (1965). The CAPM states that the only systematic risk can be priced and that the expected return of a asset is equal to risk-free rate plus a risk premium multiplied by the asset’s systematic risk. Ross (1976) develops the APT which implies that there are multiple risk factors that need to be taken into account when calculating asset returns. number of increasing empirical evidences challenge the EMH and APT. First, theoretically investors are thought rationality under EMH. More and more results show that investors are not rational all the time and that irrational investment behavior has influences on the price formation of securities. Hence, investor psychology provides an alternative view for the investors’ irrational decisions. For example, De Long et al(1990) propose a model to show that investors’ irrational beliefs have influences on price formation of assets. They point out that the irrational beliefs would drive the stock prices further away from the fundamental values, so the deviations of stock prices become more extreme. The process above causes another source of risk, named as “noise trader risk”, assumed to be market-wide and having influence on the stock market. Moreover, Lee, Jiang and Indro(2002) employ a GARCH-M model to show that the conditional volatility and excess returns are affected by investor sentiment. Second, the EMH and APT are both linear models in asset returns. However, recent studies emphasize the models which asset returns are characterized by non-linear dynamics (Abhyanker, Copeland and Wong ,1997). Leung, Daouk and Chen (2000) predict the international stock returns by neural network methods. Perez-Quiros and Timmermann(2000) examine U.S. stock market by a Markov switching model and McMillan (2001) employs the threshold model to predict U.S. stocks returns. To sum up, inconsistent with market efficiency reflects irrational investor behavior and APT does not imply that stock returns are a linear function of multiple economic factors. Hence, this study try to examine whether there exits any nonlinear dynamics resulting from the irrational investing behaviors in Taiwan stock market by employing a smooth transition regime switching model to capture the movements of Taiwan stock market returns. 2. Literatures Review In capital market, only general economic variables have influence on the pricing of stock market. Ross (1976) concludes that macroeconomic variables can affect the real investment opportunities, firms’ cash flows, and the risk-adjusted discounted rates. Hence macroeconomic variables can influence the stock prices. Many literatures have documented that aggregate stock returns are related to economic factors. For example, stock returns are negatively related to inflation and to money growth (Bodie,1976; Fama,1981, Geske and Roll,1983; Pearce and Roley,1983,1985). Moreover, Chen, Roll, and Ross (1986) report another five factors: the monthly growth rate of Industrial Production, Expected Inflation, Unexpected Inflation, a bond Default Risk Premium, and a Term Structure Spread. They conclude that industrial production and risk premium are good risk factors and that inflation shows weaker evidence. Lamont (2000) also concludes that the growth rates of Industrial Production, Consumption, and Labor Income earn abnormal positive returns, but the CPI does not. Cutler, Porterba, and Summers (1989) find that Industrial Production growth is significantly positively correlated with real stock returns over the period 1926-1986, but not in the 1946-1985 subperiod, which overlaps the sample period (1958-1984) of Chen, Roll, and Ross (1986). Although, many literatures support that macroeconomic variables are priced factors of stock returns. However, Cutler, Porterba, and Summers (1989) do not show that Inflation, Money Supply, and long-term Interest Rates affect stock returns. McQueen and Roley(1993) state that macro factors do not support significant evidence with stock returns because the constant-coefficient models show poor explanatory power. They suggest that a given announcement surprise may have different implications at different points in the business cycle. Moreover, Ferson and Harvey (1991) argue that such poor predictability on stock returns is not due to market inefficient, but due to poor explanatory power of macroeconomic variables. Many empirical studies find nonmacroeconomic factors can affect stocks returns and also provide evidence to support irrational investor behavior. Basu (1977) shows the price earning ratio (P/E) anomaly: stocks with extremely low P/E ratios earn larger risk-adjusted returns than those with high P/E ratios. The anomaly can be resulted from irrational investor behavior. Investors are excessively pessimistic about stocks after a series of bad earnings. Once the future earnings turn out to be better, the prices of stocks with extremely low P/E ratios adjust much more than those of stocks with extremely high P/E ratios. Moreover, Fama and French (1992) conclude that size and market to book ratios do a good job explaining the cross-section of average stock returns. The high market to book ratio also reflects that investors are overconfident about the future profitability of companies with past good performance. Hence, the prices of good-performance stocks go up and diverge away from the fundamental values. Consequently, the stocks with high market to book ratios earn lower returns because of investors’ overvaluation. To conclude, some noneconomic factors, such as the P/E ratio, market to book ratio and dividend yield, can represent as irrational investor behavior. And hence, we put them into the model to predict stock returns. Furthermore, many increasing studies emphasize that financial market is characterized by non-linear dynamics and non-linear models of stock returns can capture investor’ irrational behavior. MaMillan (2001, 2003,2005) employ smooth-transition threshold models to examine non-linear relationship of priced factors and index returns, such as: UK, CAC, Nikki, DAX and so on. The smooth-transaction model (Chan and Tong, 1986; Teräsvirta and Anderson,1992; Granger and Teräsvirta, 1993; Teräsvirta, 1994) can capture two types of asymmetric adjustment. First, the smooth-transition threshold model can capture investors’ different reactions during the bull and bear market. Shiller (2000) has shown that the adjustment of investor sentiment is slow at the beginning of the market cycle. When stock prices keep on rising, investor sentiment will be buoyed. However, when the speculative bubble happens, the initial decline in stock prices discourages investors. As investors reduce their holdings, stock prices decline further. If the downward correction process continues, investors feel extremely pessimistic. Prices are also declining until at a certain point where the downward correction stops. Hence, the investors’ beliefs during the whole stock market cycle seem to be non-linear relations with market returns. The smooth-transition threshold model is suitable to estimate such non-linear relationship. Secondly, the smooth-transition threshold model suggests different dynamics exist different regimes. Such the model can capture more violate of investors’ behavior when stock returns are far away the intrinsic values and gradual movement of investors’ beliefs when the returns show slow mean reversion. To conclude, in order to examine whether irrational investors’ behavior has impacts on stock returns, we employ the smooth-transition threshold model to capture the non-linear relations. 3. The Model and Data This study examines a potential non-linear relationship between Taiwan stock market returns and economic variables by the smooth-transition threshold model. Based upon the CAPM and APT, only undiversifiable risk factors can affect the price formation of market returns. We choose some macroeconomics as section 2 mentioned to predict the market returns, such as the money growth, inflation, the growth rate of industrial production, and the term structure spread. Moreover, we also want to test the effects of irrational investor’ behavior on stock returns, so we add the P/E ratio, market-to-book ratio and dividend yield as Busa(1977) and Fama and French (1992) suggest. Furthermore, we find a proxy for investor sentiment. Lee and Swaminathan (2000) show that investor expectations affect not only the return but also the trading activity of the stock. They point out that past turnover can also be used as a proxy for measuring the fluctuations in investor sentiment. Thus, the change of trading volume can represent the movement in the investor sentiment. The model is as follows: P Rt = a0+ ai Z t 1 + (θ0+ i 1 P i Z t 1 )F (rt-d) +εt i 1 (1) Where Zt are the money growth, inflation, the growth rate of industrial production, the term structure spread, P/E ratio, market-to-book ratio ,dividend yield and investor sentiment index. Rt is stock market returns. F (rt-d) is the transition function. 4. Expected Results First, we want to check which type of smooth-transition threshold models is suitable for Taiwan stock market. LSTR? ESTR? QLSTR? Secondly, we expect multiple thresholds of regime transition exist due to positive and negative asset returns. Finally, we expect the transition variable causing the regime changes reveals the influence of irrational investing behavior. More specifically, we expect the investor sentiment index is the transition variable and we can suggest that nonlinear dynamics exists in Taiwan stock market due to the irrational investors’ beliefs. Reference Abhyankar, A., Copeland, L. S. and Wong, W., 1997, “Uncovering nonlinear structure in real-time stock market indices”, Journal of Business and Economic Statistic, Vol. 15, pp.1-14. Bodie, Z., 1976, “Common Stocks as a Hedge Against Inflation”, Journal of Finance, Vol.3, pp. 459-470. Breeden, D., 1979, “An Intertemporal Asset Pricing Model with Stochastic Consumption and Investment Opportunities”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol.7, pp.265-296. Boyd, J. H., R. Jagannathan, and J. Hu, 2001, “The Stock Market’s Reaction to Unempolyment News : Why Bad News is Usually Good for Stocks”, Working Paper 8902, NBER. Basu, S. (1977), “Investment performance of common stocks in relation to their price-earnings ratios: A test of efficient market hypothesis”. Journal of Finance, Vol. 32, pp.663-682. Chan, K. and Tong, H., 1986, “On estimating thresholds in autoregressive models”, Journal of Time Series Analysis, Vol.7, pp.179-194. Chen, N. F., R. Roll, and S. Ross, 1986, “Economic Forces and the Stock Market”, Journal of Business, Vol.59, pp.383-403. Cutler, D. M., J. M. Poterba, and L. H. Summers, 1989, “What Moves Stock Prices?”, Journal of Portfolio Management, Vol.15, pp.4-12. De Long, J. B., Shleifer, A., Summers, L. H., Waldmann, R. J.,1990, “Noise Trader Risk in Financial Markets”, The Journal of Political Economy, Vol.98, pp.703-738. Fama, E. F., 1981, “Stocks Returns, Real Activity, Inflation, and Money”, American Economic Review, Vol.71, pp.545-565. Fama, E.F. and French, K. (1992). “The cross-section of expected stock returns”, Journal of Finance, Vol.47, pp.427-465. Fama, E.F. and French, K. R. (1993). “Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol.33, pp.3-56. Geske, R. and R. Roll, 1983, “The Fiscal and Monetary Linkage Between Stocks returns and Inflation”, Journal of Finance, Vol.38, pp.1-34. Granger, C.W.J. and Teräsvirta, T., 1993, Modeling nonlinear economic relationships, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Lamont, O. 2001, “Economic Tracking Portfolios”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 105, pp.161-184. Lee, M. C. and Swaminathan, B. ,2000, “Price Momentum and Trading Volume”, Journal of Finance, Vol.55, No.5, pp. 2017-2069. Lee, W. Y., Jiang, C. X., Indro, D.C., 2002,”Stock market volatility, excess returns, and the role of investor sentiment”, Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol.26, pp.2277-2299. Leung, M. T., Daouk, H., and Chen, A-S. 2000, “Forecasting stock indices: a comparison of classification and level estimation models”, International Journal of Forecasting, Vol.16, pp.173-190. Linter, J., 1965, “Security price, risks, and maximal gains form diversification’, Journal of Finance, Vol.20, pp.587-615. McMillan, D.G., 2001, “Nonlinear predictability of stock market returns: evidence from nonparametric and threshold models”, International Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 10, pp. 353-368. McMillan, D.G., 2003, “Non-linear predictability of UK stock market returns”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 65, pp. 557-573. McMillan, D.G., 2005, “Non-linear dynamics in international stock market returns”, Review of Financial Economics, Vol. 14, pp. 81-91. McQueen, G. and V. Roley, 1993, “Stock Prices, News, and Business Conditions”, Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 6, pp.683-707. Merton, R., 1973, “An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model”, Econometrica, Vol.41, pp.867-887. Pearce, D. K. and V. V. Roley, 1983, “The Reaction of Stocks Prices to Unanticipanted Changes in Money: A Note”, Journal of Finance, Vol.38, pp.1323-1333. Pearce, D. K. and V. V. Roley, 1985, “Stocks Prices and Economic News”, Journal of Business, Vol.58, pp.49-67. Perez-Quiros, G. and Timmermann, A., 2000, “Firm size and cyclical variations in stock returns”, Journal of Finance, Vol.55, pp.1229-1262. Ross, S. A., 1976, “The Arbitrage Theory of Capital Asset Pricing ”, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol.13, pp. 341-360. Sharpe, W., 1964, “Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk ”, Journal of Finance, Vol.19, pp.425-442. Shiller, R., 2000, Irrational exuberance, Princeton, NJ. Teräsvirta, T.,1994, “Specification, Estimation and evaluation of smooth transition autoregressive models”, Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol.89, pp.208-218. Teräsvirta, T. and Anderson, H.M.,1992, “Characterising nonlinearities in business cycles using smooth transition autoregressive models”, Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 7, pp.S119-S136.