Artikel erschienen in: Kreimer, Margareta (2004): Labor Market Segregation and the Gender-based Division of Labor. The European Journal of Women's Studies, Vol 11 (2), 223-246. Labour Market Segregation and the Gender-based Division of Labour Abstract The article is based on the argument that labour market segregation is an important factor contributing to women’s inequality in the labour market. Therefore any equal opportunities policy has to be combined with a policy to reduce segregation. But up to now segregation has been extremely persistent, as it will be shown in a short empirical overview of segregation in the Austrian labour market. It is argued that the roots of this phenomenon lie in the assignment of men and women to the market area and the reproduction area according to the breadwinner model. Labour market segregation by sex can be seen as a transformation and continuation of the asymmetrical gender relation in the family to the labour market. Most of the mechanisms and processes that occur every day in the labour market work together to preserve sex segregation. Strategies to reduce segregation should look at these historical roots of segregation and at the connection with the overall gender division of labour. Different perspectives on a reduction of labour market segregation will be presented. Keywords Austria, gender division of labour, labour market segregation, perspectives on the reduction of segregation, separated spheres. Biographical note: Margareta Kreimer is assistant professor for economics in the Department of Economics at the University of Graz, Austria. She completed her PhD in 1997 at the University of Graz. Her research interests include labour market theory and policy, the 1 economics of the welfare state, feminist economics, discrimination theory, economic policy. Address: Department of Economics, Universitaetsstrasse 15, A-8010 Graz, Austria. Email: margareta.kreimer@uni-graz.at. 2 Labour Market Segregation and the Gender-based Division of Labour Introduction The labour market integration of women in Austria, as well as in all other industrialised countries, is based to a great extent on gender division. Although the female participation rate is steadily increasing, there are no significant changes in the structure and conditions of female employment. Women get jobs in those sectors where many women are already employed (horizontal segregation), career and income perspectives of women are limited in comparison to men (vertical segregation), and the recent development of increasing atypical employment has clear gender-related aspects (vertical segregation through types of employment) (Charles 1992, Hakim 1993, Rubery and Fagan 1993, 1995, Anker 1998). Sex segregation in the labour market is a significant cause of sexual disadvantage. At the same time, sex segregation itself is influenced and stabilised by gender discrimination. Therefore any equal opportunities policy has to be combined with a policy to reduce sex segregation. It is not surprising that the reduction of labour market segregation is part of the Employment Strategy of the EU (Rubery and Fagan 1998). But up to now, segregation has been extremely persistent: Although specific measures to reduce segregation have been added to labour market policy (e.g. subsidies for girls to take up male-dominated jobs and so on), the level of segregation has not decreased significantly. To be able to develop effective strategies against sex segregation presupposes a detailed analysis of segregation. For this purpose it is important, (1) not to restrict the analysis to the labour market but to use a wide definition of ‘work’ by looking at the 3 gender division in all kinds of work, and (2) to look at the historical roots of segregation. The paper starts with a short empirical overview of sex segregation in the Austrian labour market. Afterwards the question of why segregation is such a problem will be analysed. Strategies to reduce segregation will be developed by looking at the historical roots of segregation and the connection with the overall gender division of labour. Different perspectives of a reduction of labour market segregation will be presented in the last part of the paper. Labour Market Segregation: Some empirical facts for Austria Following the calculations of the ILO (Anker 1998) 61 % of all employed persons in Austria would have to change their occupations in order to reach an equal distribution of women and men in all occupations. This value of the (standardised) index of dissimilarity indicates a level of segregation that lies clearly above the OECD average. National calculations show slightly lower figures (Kreimer 1999, Leitner 2000, Leitner and Wroblewski 2000), but the overall picture is the same: Summary index measures present a picture of persistently high levels of segregation for the past 20 years.1 A more informative analysis of horizontal segregation is obtained by looking at the sex shares of occupational groups and the related dimension of employment concentration for men and women (Rubery and Fagan 1998: 58). Data for Austria confirm the picture of a ‘segregated integration’ of women into the labour market (Kreimer 1999, Finder and Blaschke 1999, Leitner and Wroblewski 2000). The main characteristics of segregation that can be found in most industrialised countries (see for instance Rubery 4 and Fagan 1993, Heintz et al. 1997, Anker 1998) can also be found in Austria: - Female employment is more concentrated than male employment: Leitner (2000: 7) has pointed out that 75 % of all employed women work in 8 from 27 occupational categories, the same share of male workers do their work in 12 occupations. - Male-dominated occupations are more strongly segregated than female-dominated occupations (Leitner 2000): 40 % of male employees work in strongly segregated male-dominated occupations with a share of women below 10 %. Only 9 % of employed women work in strongly segregated female-dominated occupations (share of women more than 80 %). Women in female-dominated occupations are more used to having male colleagues, while men in male-dominated jobs have nearly no chance of meeting female colleagues (Kreimer 1999, Leitner 2000). These trends can be found in different data sources and hold for the last 20 years. 2 That does not mean that the segregated structure of occupations is the same as it was at the beginning of the eighties. Especially highly qualified women are able to gain from the general growth of professional employment, that has contributed to a ‘desegregation’ of the labour market. But, at the same time, other areas have become more segregated as women have entered occupations that were already femaledominated. One important factor behind this tendency is part-time work, because the part-time sector is characterised by high levels of segregation (the share of women in part-time employment is more than 80 %), and of concentration (part-time jobs are offered within few occupations, especially in the trade sector and in social services) (Tálos 1999). The gender wage gap and differences in career possibilities for women and men with a 5 similar qualification level are indicators for vertical segregation. Here empirical studies for Austria show even fewer changes towards a reduction of segregation. The male income advantage in particular seems to be a constant factor that persists, despite the continuous trend of the majority of women reaching higher qualification levels (Frauenbericht 1995, Gregoritsch et al. 2000).3 The various processes of labour market flexibilization are systematically connected with the increasing number of atypically employed persons. Up to now the share of women in atypical forms of employment is very high (about 75 % in Austria). Analyses of these flexible employees show that their incomes are relatively low and the risks connected with these forms of employment are higher than those of standard employment. Therefore vertical segregation is reinforced by the trend of increasing atypical employment (Tálos 1999, Mühlberger 2000). Occupational segregation – what is the problem? The horizontal segregation of the labour market need not have negative consequences for female careers: It can follow from individual preferences, or female-dominated occupations can be niches for women where they don’t have to compete with men. The concentration of women’s employment in relatively few sectors has provided women some protection against job loss. Furthermore, high segregation and high female employment may be positively related in countries where part of household work is done now by female dominated private industry and services or public services. Therefore the problem is not horizontal segregation alone, but the coexistence with vertical segregation. It varies between countries, but to some extent horizontal segregation is always followed by a hierarchical differentiation: Female dominated jobs 6 are associated with a relatively high level of part-time work, low pay, few career opportunities and limited access to further training (Grimshaw and Rubery 1997: 6). One of the reasons for these negative consequences of horizontal segregation is the impossibility of making comparisons within segregated structures: The concentration of female employees in female-dominated occupations and branches makes it easy to define and evaluate work as ‘women-specific’, which is always connected with devaluation. Furthermore, in female-dominated areas it is more difficult to see and to prove discrimination, and there are fewer possibilities to switch to other jobs because of narrow specialisation (Finder and Blaschke 1999, Heintz et al. 1997). One of the main trends in the economy, and also in labour markets, is the increasing pressure of competition that follows from flexibilization and globalisation. Competition may have positive consequences for women, because they have more chances to present their qualifications to the ‘market’, to compete with men for the ‘good’ jobs in the labour market. But segregated structures within labour markets hinder competition through a large number of structural and institutional barriers between male and female labour market areas. Competition takes place within such areas, but hardly between them. A third problem lies in the persistency of labour market segregation despite all changes in participation rates, in qualification levels or in work orientation. There are processes of desegregation in some areas, but at the same time the segregated structure is reinforced in other areas, and new forms of segregation come into existence, for example, through the increase in atypical employment. Labour market segregation changes its appearance, but not its level. 7 Within labour market theories (neoclassical as well as theories of labour market segmentation) many explanations for sex segregation can be found. But most of them cannot provide sufficient answers to the questions on the causes and the stability of segregation, because they reduce the analysis to market processes and neglect the impact of the division of labour. Additionally, despite few exceptions (like Bettio 1988, Picchio 1981) they don’t look at the historical roots of sex segregation. The gender division of labour as well as the division between market work and reproductive work4 have had a strong influence on the existing labour market discrimination of women. The exclusion of that part of work that is done primarily by women from economic analysis has fundamentally contributed to make women’s work invisible. It is true that Gary Becker has included reproductive work in his economic theories. But what has been ignored in labour economics and in discrimination theory for a very long time is the fact that the gender division of labour is not only a simple specialisation on different, but adequately valued activities, but an extremely hierarchical assignment of women and men to different types of work. The real problem is the valuation of the two work areas: market work is paid work; domestic work is mostly unpaid work. Sex differentiation fosters the tendency to devalue female activities (Reskin and Padavic 1994). This gender division of labour of paid and unpaid work has clear consequences on the gender division of labour within the market – which means on labour market segregation. On the roots of sex segregation: The ‘doctrine of separated spheres’ A gender division of labour has always been a fact in human development. But in the form of the division of family life and working life it is a historically relatively new fact, 8 which is connected with the development of the capitalist market economy (Kreckel 1993) and follows from the impossibility of organising human reproduction as a profitable production process.5 Therefore reproduction had to be organised unpaid and outside the market. The worlds of women and men became separated; a fundamental division of labour between men and women was installed. The ‘doctrine of separate spheres’ (Reskin and Padavic 1994) defined proper places for men (the world of commerce, the job) and women (the home). Many social actors worked (implicit or explicit) together to make the male-breadwinner-female-homemaker model the social norm, with the family wage as an essential element (Fraser 1994, Creighton 1999). Within the family the man was the breadwinner, which entitled him to obtain a corresponding income (a family wage) and which was used to legitimise the wage gap between the sexes. Women’s unpaid domestic work, although to some extent socially recognised as important work, became more and more invisible, as only market work and the market itself dominated economic theory and practice. Additionally, women were excluded from the political area as well as from higher education until the 20th century. However, the breadwinner system was never in effect for all women. Apart from the facts that more and more families needed a second income and that there was an (increasing) demand for female workers,6 not all women wanted to follow the norms of the breadwinner model. The result was that more and more men and women did the same waged work side by side. The astonishment about the fact that women were able to do nearly all men’s jobs during the First World War was widespread (Münz and Neyer 1986). The more women were able to prove their abilities in formerly male- 9 dominated jobs, the more it was necessary to legitimise the differences in the valuation of male and female work. Although scientifically proven biological and ideologicalpolitical justifications7 for the devaluation of female work were still quite popular, it was no longer possible to treat men and women who did the same work and had similar private conditions (families) differently. The demand for equal treatment and equal opportunities was increasing and the forms of resistance that male workers had traditionally been using against the entry of female workers were eventually broken by the successful struggles of women against these forms of ‘patriarchal closure’ (Walby 1997: 77). The solution to this dilemma was patterned after the former exclusion strategy: prevent women from working side by side with men and veil the fact of equal work. In other words: the solution was the installation of a sex-segregated labour market. The segregated integration of women allows the unequal treatment of equal workers and avoids direct competition between men and women. The aspect mentioned last was important for the male work force, which supported segregation mechanisms for several reasons (Rubery 1978). Labour market segregation was a successful strategy to prevent women from entering men’s jobs or from having similar career possibilities to men. With labour market segregation it was possible to maintain a gender hierarchy throughout society. The stabilisation of labour market segregation works via many different mechanisms. Strategies of exclusion had the aim of limiting the entry of women into the high qualified service sector, as can be seen for instance in the history of medicine (Wetterer 1993). Marriage bars excluded married women from the whole labour market 10 (for USA see Goldin 1990) or from important parts of it (exclusion of married women from jobs in the civil services in Austria, see Münz and Neyer 1986). Health and safety regulations for women always had some excluding effects besides their protective function (Münz and Neyer 1986). Especially in the debate on the inconsistencies of health and safety regulations for women, the connection with the breadwinner model is visible: As long as women were exclusively responsible for the care of small children, special regulations to protect pregnant women and mothers were necessary. But at the same time these regulations led to exclusion from certain labour market areas. The expansion of the validity of regulations to men (for instance parental leave for fathers) doesn’t solve the problem as long as the sexual division of labour remains unchanged (Fagan and Rubery 1996). With the development of equal opportunity norms and the related policies it became more and more difficult to use strategies of exclusion. Instead, demarcation strategy came into existence (Witz 1992, Kreckel 1993, Wetterer 1993), for instance internal labour markets and discrimination processes within firms, the definition and legitimisation of so-called female jobs, or different systems of job-valuation.8 A specific kind of demarcation strategies is connected with the definition of so-called ‘standard employment’, a complex system of norms and rules, of characteristics a ‘normal’ or ‘standard’ worker should fulfil. Above all, continuity in labour market participation and comprehensive availability for the work process are required. It is evident that men can fulfil these requirements more easily than women, and that this definition of ‘standard employment’ fits into the breadwinner model. In general, the welfare state has the possibility to weaken or to strengthen the division 11 of labour according to the breadwinner model through social policy, family policy, tax policy, and by influencing the wage setting process. Trade unions, political parties and different lobbies also play an important role in shaping the welfare state. Creighton (1999) describes the different ways welfare states have supported the realisation of family wages as an essential part of the breadwinner model. In welfare states like Austria, where the welfare system is strongly connected to the labour market, this division of labour has far-reaching consequences for social security, as only ‘standard workers’ have full access to the system (Tálos and Wörister 1994, Frauenbericht 1995, Mairhuber 2000). During the 90s some efforts were made to reduce the disincentives for female labour market participation that existed in the social security system, in family policy or in the transfer orientation of the system (Mairhuber 2000). Since February 2000 Austria has a conservative right wing government that is not willing to prolong these efforts, but to support again the breadwinner orientation in the welfare system.9 Despite all the existing differences between welfare states in the development of female employment opportunities (see for instance Gornick et al. 1997, Crompton 1999, Pfau-Effinger 1999) the sex segregated labour market seems to be an universal and persistent phenomenon. Once a segregated structure has been introduced many processes work together to stabilise it (for such processes see Ott 1992, Reskin 1994). The constant behind all these developments and processes has been the gender division of labour – therefore it should be the starting point for any policy aimed to reduce labour market segregation. 12 Perspectives on the Reduction of Labour Market Segregation As we have seen above, labour market segregation is a very persistent phenomenon that changes its appearance but not its level. Because of the historical embeddedness of the gender division of labour and of the complexity of social change and of gender relations (e.g. many workers prefer to work only with their own sex, Cockburn 1991), changing the gender structure of the labour market is expected be a slow and prolonged process. But the costs of maintaining the present sex-segregated structure are high for society, for labour markets and especially for women. Therefore, policies reducing segregation have to be put on the agenda. As Cockburn (1991) stated for equal opportunities policy, reducing segregation practically involves a ‘short’ and a ‘long’ agenda. The short agenda is a minimum position supported by most of the relevant actors (the reduction of segregation is part of the employment strategy of the EU and of the Austrian national action plan for employment). More substantial kinds of change are on the long agenda supported by equality activists, but combated or at least still ignored by the majority of men (Cockburn 1991: 216). However, despite the power of the gendering processes and the male resistance against gender equality, the barriers and structures are not impermeable. Men and women have the capacity to change segregated structures. Reduction of Segregation – examples for the ‘short’ agenda In mainstream labour economic theories segregated structures should disappear as a consequence of market competition. Therefore one could argue that increasing competition in the labour market – a trend that takes place anyway – would contribute to the reduction of segregation. If we look at flexibilization processes as one of the 13 most important ways competition works in the labour market, this expectation holds – but it is only one side of the coin. Flexibilization indeed leads to a weakening and, in some cases, to an elimination of restrictions and barriers for women (e. g. the prohibition to work at night in Austria). Another positive consequence of flexibilization lies in the fact that it also concerns male career paths (e. g. the ‘erosion of standard employment’, see for instance Winker 1998). But on the other side flexibilization is the leading factor responsible for the increasing importance of availability in the labour market (availability in space and time, mobility, see Winker 1998, Yeandle 1999). While the problem of reconciliation of work and family no longer prevents women from participating in waged work, it shapes and restricts the form of participation (Smith and Gottfried 1998). Women with family obligations are not able to fulfil the ideal of a fully available employee. Women without family obligations have increasing chances to catch up with men in their job, to get equal treatment, income and career possibilities. Equal opportunities policies as well as the demand for highly qualified employees in many sectors support this catch up process. This slow but steady alignment of male and female working careers in some labour market segments leads to changes in the structure of segregation: For some women it is possible to overcome gender barriers, for others ‘segregated integration’ is maintained. Labour market segregation shifts from segmentation between men and women to segmentation within the female labour market. The most important criterion for this segmentation is availability for the labour market – and the level of availability depends in any case on the division of labour in the family. Women who are not fully 14 available, but who want to participate in the labour market, are predestined for the growing number of flexible and atypical employment relations. These types of employment don’t provide sufficient income and social security, but as long as there are - at least in principle - male breadwinners, there is no necessity to change these conditions. The modernised breadwinner model provides an ideal background for the growing sector of atypical employment – and with that for a new type of segregation (Meulders et al. 1997, Yeandle 1999, Lutz 2000). Increasing competition contributes to changes in the appearance of segregation, but not yet to its reduction. Additionally, it reinforces processes of differentiation between women (Friese 1995, Walby 1997), which gives rise to new questions for gender research, because ‘private and public spheres can no longer be analysed adequately as separate, gendered spaces but merit consideration as a continuum and with regard for the ethnic and class-specific aspects.’ (Lutz 2000: 7). Another strategy to reduce vertical segregation is based on improving women’s pay through equal value policies. If women would be properly rewarded for the work they do, horizontal segregation need not have negative consequences. Within segregated structures, men and women do not do the same work, but very often they do work of equal value. A consequent equal-pay-for-equal-value-policy would allow segregation to be crossed by reducing wage discrimination (for Austria see Ranftl et al. 20002). Besides the fact that it is still a problem to determine the ‘equal value’, such a strategy cannot solve all the issues linked to segregation (e.g. segregation through atypical forms of employment). “The demand for ‘equal value’ is in contradiction with the functioning of labour markets, in which the weak bargaining power of women with 15 domestic ties is an important advantage to employers.” (Cockburn 1991: 217). And any ‘equal value’ strategy faces limitations when the narrow link between labour market segregation and the gender division of labour in all areas of life is taken into account. Equal pay for equal value is a labour market strategy that may contribute to reach more gender equality in some branches or occupations, but as we have seen above, the sex segregated labour market is a rather far-reaching phenomenon. Reduction of segregation – the ‘long’ agenda A comprehensive strategy to reduce labour market segregation should start with the gender division of labour and has to include an elimination of hierarchies and asymmetries. Starting points for such a de-hierarchisation can be the hierarchical gender relation according to the division of labour, as well as the hierarchical relation between market work and reproductive work: The gender division of labour could be changed to reach a more or less equal distribution of market work and family work for men and women. The functional hierarchy between market work and family work itself could be changed to reach a more or less equal valuation of the two work areas. Both dimensions together produce a matrix of possible objectives instead of only one strategy to reduce gender segregation (see picture 1). Here picture 1 16 Reduction of the functional hierarchy The aim of the vertical dimension is the equality of market work and reproductive work, in other words the de-hierarchisation of the ‘initial segregation’.10 Particularly the relation between paid and unpaid work need to be changed. The market area and the private area are dependent on each other in the sense that the time needed to fulfil one type of work restricts the possibilities to work in the other area. This ‘intra-personal incompatibility’ (Bohnenkamp 1992) is a latent characteristic in modern economies, but the extent of this incompatibility may differ between nations according to the respective welfare state and labour market conditions. One reason for these differences lies in the fact that there are different social norms in which way and to what extent reproductive work may be substituted by market work (outsourcing of domestic work). In general we can expect that the higher the level of prosperity of a nation, the more domestic work will be replaced, or at least supplemented, by market work.11 Financial requirements are often limitations for outsourcing processes, especially if the welfare state is involved. Besides economic conditions, ideological and cultural norms are important, for instance to what extent childcare outside the family is socially accepted. These norms determine the socially desirable level of replacement. Against the background of these various social basic conditions it is necessary to develop differentiated strategies for the aim ‘reduction of functional hierarchy’: In the context of a primarily market-oriented model the predominant strategy would be the substitution of domestic work through waged market work. The functional separation of the two areas would be overcome through the outsourcing of family work and through professionalization. To support such a model we can think of tax17 deductible childcare costs or of tying transfers to a use for services supplied on the market. A rather similar strategy could be pursued in a state-oriented model: The welfare state itself provides social services and care facilities. Both strategies are based on an outsourcing of family work. Former unpaid work would become waged work, either with a private or a public employer (like in the Scandinavian welfare state model, see Leira 1993). Another state model could also be that domestic work is left within the private area, but becomes upgraded through a direct payment. A salary for domestic work or different concepts of payment for care can be used. A communitarist model would be based on the activation of collective strategies to overcome the isolation of the private family. New models of living together, not only in the private area, but also in the market, could be designed. Support and subsidies for collective organisations like alternative child care institutions (‘Kinderläden’); collective kitchens or neighbourhood initiatives could be part of such a strategy. All models have their limitations: The models based on outsourcing have the problem that outsourcing itself is limited, not all family work (especially care work) can be transferred to waged market work. This is also true for the state model of outsourcing; additionally there are financial restrictions. The latter is also the most important limitation for the state model of payments for domestic work. If there is only a rather small payment for family work, the functional hierarchy would not be reduced, but strengthened instead. The criticism of feminist researchers of the concept of basic income is based on similar arguments (Meyer 1997, Robeyns 1998). Finally there are clear limitations with regard to the extent of the replacement of individual action 18 through collective action. Therefore it seems to be necessary to create a mixed model, which has its emphasis on market or state processes, or on individual or collective mechanisms, depending on the national and cultural norms. Such a model would take into account the current (partly large) differences between welfare states.12 Reduction of the gender hierarchy – new gender division of labour The striving for a new gender division of labour interferes radically with the course of men’s lives. Women have already made many adjustments through their participation in waged work in addition to their obligations in the family. Now it is time to change men’s ‘normal’ careers.13 Such a new division of labour may arise without changes in the functional hierarchy. That means, waged work and family work would remain separate areas following their specific mechanism. If it is self-evident for women and men to take over half of reproductive work, the existing gender hierarchy loses its significance. The private area would furthermore have effects on the labour market, but not along the gender line. Instead of a gender-differentiation there would be a differentiation of available and because of family work temporarily not (fully) available individuals. Men and women would be equal in carrying the ‘double burden’ of market work and family work. The ‘initial segregation’ would not be cancelled, but the male breadwinner model would come to an end. According to previous experiences with the male resistance to any significant change of the gender division of labour, we cannot expect to come closer to an equal division of labour without a reduction of the functional hierarchy. The adjustments made by women have practically no effect on the behaviour of men, but they have affected the 19 female labour market in the form of new segregation and segmentation processes. From an economic viewpoint it is understandable that men are not willing to do without their privileges and to take on the ‘double burden’. Promising strategies should take this into account – for as long as men cannot be forced to take over their part of reproductive work. Various models can be developed: A state model would use distribution policy and social policy to change the division of labour. Strategies could be compulsory parental leave periods for men (of the same duration as for women), a rigorously organised individual-based tax system, a binding of transfers and benefits to the division of labour, or binding subsidies to the fulfilment of quotas and so on. A market model would be based on individual strategies. Policy would be reduced to measures to guarantee equal opportunities in the educational system, as well as in the labour market. A strategy for the latter could be to set measures to increase individual mobility. Under the condition of a still existing functional hierarchy, the labour market itself is the main field for strategies to change the gender division of labour. One strategy could be to adapt female professional careers to those of men or, the other way round, to eliminate male characteristics of jobs and careers. In the first case instruments would be affirmative action, in the second case it would be necessary to change the norms behind so-called ‘regular’ employment: New working time models, an adequate valuation of work, new forms of work organisation and so on. Flexible working time models compatible with social life or new models of career planning would be 20 necessary to reorganise waged work. Family work would have to be organised on a collective level to a much greater extent than it is now (for instance kindergartens in firms). In all cases the whole infrastructure which represents the connection between the market and the reproduction area plays an important role, and is therefore a starting point for changes: Childcare facilities, opening hours or transport are material factors; social policy regulations and family policy measures as well as social and cultural norms and traditions are non-material factors that have to be part of the changes. Reduction of both hierarchies The reduction of both hierarchies (the diagonal route in the matrix) represents the most comprehensive aim. Because of the interdependencies between the horizontal and the vertical dimension it is necessary to look at the possible consequences each strategy has on the other one. A reduction of the functional hierarchy would change the distribution of power, and with that the structure of dependencies. This would surely have effects on the relational position of men and women. But whether results would include changes in the personal division of labour cannot be guaranteed. In countries where the vertical dimension has been changed through the modernisation of the breadwinner system, there is no recognisable new division of labour between men and women. But there are, however, tendencies towards new distribution of reproductive work between different groups of women as a consequence of flexibilization processes in the labour market (see above). 21 Also, in Scandinavian countries where the reduction of the functional hierarchy has made the most progress, the responsibilities for reproductive work have not really changed. The Scandinavian welfare state has promoted the ‘modernisation of mothering’ through the provision of working places for mothers in the service sector. Therefore the female participation rate is very high, but at the same time horizontal segregation is high (Melkas and Anker 1998). In other words: these countries also have a position on the left side of the matrix referring to the horizontal dimension. Whether changes in the gender division of labour would have effects on the vertical hierarchy cannot be clearly forecast. There are some indications of possible effects, for instance the fact that whenever the proportion of men in a job increased the job was upgraded. Therefore it could be expected that a higher participation of men in the reproductive area would lead to an upgrading of that area too. The case studies presented by Williams (1993), however, indicate that this crossing over of men in female jobs does not necessarily undermine the system of occupational segregation. With labour market related strategies it depends on the direction: Measures to adapt female careers to those of men have caused a segmentation of the female labour market, instead of a reduction of the functional hierarchy.14 Measures following the other direction, that is the adaptation of male careers to those of women, would surely lead to an alignment of the reproductive area and the market.15 Scenarios for the reduction of labour market segregation Based on the previous considerations the strategies of the matrix of possibilities (see picture 1) should now be specified. Picture 2 therefore shows some scenarios. The presented scenarios have partly been developed by researchers from the Netherlands 22 (see Bruyn-Hundt 1996, Brouwer and Wierda 1998, Advisory Council 1996). The main aim of their work was the integration of care work into the official economy, the aim in this paper is something more general. Picture 2 should not be interpreted as a complete list of all possible scenarios; there may be more of them. But a lot of current debates related to changes in the labour market, as well as in the social security system and the welfare state as a whole, can be integrated in the presented scenarios.16 And these scenarios are increasingly part of research on welfare states (Fraser 1994, Esping-Andersen 1996, Duncan 1998). Here Picture 2 In the perpetuation-scenario everything continues in the old, familiar way according to modernised variants of the breadwinner system. Possible changes concentrate on the question of reconciling work and family for women, without questioning their responsibility for domestic work. Current trends make slow progress: Men do some more family work; some outsourcing of family work is supported to the extent necessary for the reconciliation problem (for instance child care facilities oriented on female part-time work). The allocation-scenario is based on a new division of labour between the sexes (therefore this scenario can also be called the ‘sharing-scenario’), which is the result of a redistribution of paid and unpaid work on an individual level. Domestic work will not be attributed to gender any more. For the individual labour market performance it is not important which sex one has, but whether one has family obligations or not. Even if it were possible to induce men to live according to a new division of labour (that means 23 to do their part of family work), such a scenario can have undesirable effects. Without a significant social and public responsibility for family work (a reduction of the functional hierarchy) new dependencies and discriminatory effects may occur, as only two-earner-families with a relatively high income capacity can afford to purchase care services and domestic services. The outsourcing-scenario and the salary-for-domestic-work-scenario are different in many aspects, but their common element is the assignment of domestic work to women.17 Women continue to do most of the family work, either as employees in the outsource social service sector, or as housewives getting some kind of an income. Under current conditions in the service sector and the budget constraints of the welfare state, there are unlikely to be incentives for men to participate in family work, either outside, or within the family. The gender division of labour would remain unchanged. The combination-scenario represents the most ambitious scenario; it requires changes in all dimensions of work for both sexes. A reduction of male market work; an increased participation of women in market work (depending on the current level of participation); a partial outsourcing of family work; and the increased participation of men in the remaining domestic work in the family.18 The objective is something like a ‘half and half’ in both dimensions: Men and women each do half of the market work and domestic work. 19 Cockburn (1991: 227-32) identifies three potentials of transformative change that would fit in such a combination-scenario as it concerns the level of organizations: First, developments in social policy are needed to take off the burden of care responsibilities from women. Second, an economic policy is needed that would move towards a 30- 24 hour standard week for both sexes and consequently implement equal pay for equal value in all branches and occupations. Third, she argues for a strengthening of the law, e.g. positive discrimination of women, quotas, penalties for sex-discriminating firms or subsidies for those with effective affirmative action policies and so on. The advantages of a combination-scenario in comparison to an allocation-scenario would lie in the fact that partial outsourcing has employment effects. This is a precondition for increasing female labour market participation and guarantees the state more revenue that could be used to support outsourcing processes through subsidies, as well as to support the upgrading of the remaining family work. Partial outsourcing of all kinds of family work can lead to a new valuation of these jobs through qualification strategies, new forms of organisation and so on. In an allocation scenario that work would remain informal and invisible. Furthermore, a scenario that leaves the struggle for a new and equal division of labour up to individual responsibility places enormous pressure on men: They have to adapt. But if they do so, they are in conflict with trends on the labour market (like most women are now) - only fully available and flexible individuals are sought. Especially given an increasingly flexible labour market, such a scenario doesn’t seem to be realistic. In the combination scenario all participants have to adapt, to change. The last mentioned argument is also an advantage in contrast to the outsourcing- and the salary-for-domestic-work-scenario, but with a somewhat different meaning: In these scenarios women have to carry the whole burden of adaptation, men don't have to change. The analysis of the scenarios has a similar result to that of the more unspecified 25 strategies in the matrix of possibilities. In order to reduce segregation and hierarchy significantly it seems to be best to follow the diagonal route, which means to combine strategies of changing the gender division of labour and of reducing the functional hierarchy. The combination scenario is therefore an optimal solution and should be the objective on the long agenda. Conclusions The implementation and maintenance of sex segregation has influenced the whole development of modern labour markets. The roots of this phenomenon lie in the assignment of men and women to the market area and the reproduction area according to the breadwinner model. Labour market segregation by sex can be seen as a transformation and continuation of the asymmetrical gender relation in the family to the labour market. Most of the mechanisms and processes that occur every day in the labour market work together to preserve sex segregation. Up to now we haven’t had any experiences with ‘discrimination-free’ labour markets. It seems to be very difficult to break through the vicious circle of the labour market participation of women. However, labour markets themselves as well as processes on them are exposed to continuous changes. Therefore we can expect that changes will affect the vicious circle and will result in a reduction of labour market segregation. There are already changes that can be interpreted as movements along the dimensions of the matrix of possibilities. But there is still a long way to go to reach the objectives of a genderneutral division of labour, or of an equal valuation of market work and family work. Some political movements include concepts for a reduction of the functional hierarchy, but the economic tendencies show another direction (increasing importance of 26 markets, of money, decreasing importance of social factors). Due to budget constraints the welfare state has hardly any room for supporting strategies that aim to narrow the gap between the market area and the reproduction area. Till now changes of the gender division of labour have not caused a redistribution of work between men and women, but between different groups of women. The participation of men in family work is still rather low, not only because of their own resistance (why should they give up all the advantages they have in the existing division of labour?). Another reason lies in the increasing demands of market work. The growing importance of being available at any time and at any place makes it very difficult for individuals to live according to new and more gender-neutral roles. Due to the decreasing number of so-called ‘regular’ employment relationships the competition in the labour market will become tougher. The opportunities for the implementation of ‘family-friendly’ workplaces are rather bad. The only group that would be able to push ahead a reduction of segregation are women themselves. With an increasing number of women refusing to live according to the breadwinner model or its modernised variants it would be necessary to reorganise the division of labour. But due to the fact that most women already bear a ‘double burden’, it doesn’t seem to be very realistic to expect great changes in the near future. However, it would be too pessimistic to see women alone struggling for a new gender division of labour. A relatively new actor in this field is the EU: The reduction of sex segregation is part of the employment policy of the EU. This guarantees that sex segregation is a topic in national employment policies, that new instruments and measures to reduce sex segregation are developed and so on. But it is clear that a lot 27 of work has to be done to implement a new model of division of labour following the breadwinner system and with that to reduce labour market segregation. Notes 1 The high level of segregation is not only a problem within occupations, but also within branches or industries, or in firms (Kreimer 1999, Leitner 2000), but it is more difficult to analyse these forms of segregation because of heterogeneity (industries, branches) or because of the lack of data (firms). It has to be said that the measurement of segregation is in any case difficult, because the results depend to a large extent on the unit where segregation is measured (occupations, branches, firms..), from the aggregation level (10 main occupational groups or about 160 detailed occupations) and from the methods (single number indicators like the index of dissimilarity or the sex-ratio index, or more disaggregated analyses). Because of the complexity of segregation it is necessary to use a comprehensive mix of methods and indicators for measurement. 2 Leitner (2000) uses survey data from the Austrian Mikrozensus for 1994 and 1998, based on the ISCO-88 classification of occupations. Kreimer (1999) has used census data from 1981 and 1991, based on a national classification of occupations. 3 Female incomes are on average 28 % lower than male incomes (Gregoritsch et al. 2000: 14). 4 The use of ‘social reproduction’ to describe the daily and intergenerational renewal of human resources, physically and mentally capable to participate in production, has been controversial (see for instance Humphries and Rubery 1984). But this is also the case with other terms, like family work. Social reproduction is not limited to the family or the household, just as family work has to do with practices outside the family, and so on. For the very general purpose of this paper the terms ‘family work’, ‘domestic work’ and ‘reproductive work’ are used interchangeably, with the meaning mentioned at the beginning of this remark. 5 The roots of this division can be located at the end of the feudalistic period. Kenrick (1981) shows this using the example of England: The enclosure movement destroyed the possibilities of small farms to survive and with that the basis for an independent life outside the labor market. But, in contrast to men, women had less chances of getting jobs in the growing urban centers or getting/receiving education and training. The development of the textile industry reduced the demand for home-based work of women. That means that women lost their work in agriculture and in the home-based industry already in the phase of the dissolving of the feudal system, and they only had few opportunities to get jobs in the new 28 and growing industrial sector. 6 This is especially true for the two World Wars; there was an enormous demand for female participation in the industrial sectors. In Austria, in 1910 nearly 39% of the whole labour force and nearly one quarter of the employed in the industry were women (Münz and Neyer 1986). Between 1890 and 1910 the number of non self-employed women greatly increased. At the beginning of the 20th century Austria had one of the highest female participation rates. In 1900 47% of all employed women were married. 7 Dorothea Schmidt (1993) describes justifications of the ‘fine hand’ of female workers, Jutta Schwarzkopf (1993) for the social construction of qualifications. Karin Hausen (1993) shows historical studies of ‘natural’ male and female work in the textile industry or in laundries. Ideological-political justifications came from different institutions: for instance from the Catholic Church (Hausen 1993), from political parties (Münz and Neyer 1986), from economists (Michèle Pujol 1992). 8 In addition to the exclusion and demarcation strategy, Witz (1992: 44ff.) identified two more gendered strategies – inclusion and dual closure – to describe the countervailing responses of groups who are subject to either exclusion or demarcation in professional projects. 9 The most evident indication of the ‘re-discovering’ of the breadwinner model is the strong emphasis the new government lays on family policy, especially on monetary transfers to families for children under three years. Family policy has replaced any kind of women’s policy, a trend that started with the abolition of the Ministry for Women’s Affairs that was one of the first measures the new government has carried out. 10 To complete the picture it must be said that those entries in the matrix connected with a high level of hierarchy (the breadwinner model and also the modernised variants) can also be seen as objectives – as is the case in various interest groups, political parties and so on. These strategies are very popular whenever unemployment is high. In the modernised breadwinner model it is not convenient anymore to ‘send women back home’, but to facilitate the reconciliation of work and family for women. The gender division of labor remains unchanged. But changes in preferences of women (and, increasingly, also of men) as well as economic restructuring, family breakdown and marital instability challenge this model more and more. 11 The outsourcing of domestic work is not only related to higher levels of prosperity but also to income disparities both nationally and internationally. A large part of long-term care in Austria is done by people from abroad (mainly Czech Republic, Slovakia, Hungary). These mostly female foreigners are really ‘cheap’ care persons on the black market who guarantee the well-functioning of the long term care at least in Eastern Austria. They make possible that 29 care is done, but without any social integration. 12 Bilateral comparisons (see for instance von Wahl 1995 on a comparison of the USA and Germany) as well as welfare state typologies (Lewis and Ostner 1994, Duncan 1998) show that there are large differences between welfare states concerning economic and cultural conditions. Therefore a uniform strategy to reduce gender asymmetries and hierarchies would not be successful. 13 This is correct at least for the majority of men and the majority of social classes (see for instance the share of men on parental leave in Austria: bare 2 % of all fathers take a part of the leave, although six months are exclusively reserved for them since welfare state reforms in 1996.) 14 In Austria it is now a common strategy to award a prize to ‘women-friendly’ firms. Prizes are mostly given to those firms that create typical female career paths with part-time work, familyoriented flexibility and career interruptions. 15 Such effects may be the by-product of new flexible work organization models. For instance, the new working time models used by BMW also include possibilities for partner-sharing parttime or for sabbaticals (private leave for a period of 1 to 6 months) and some others too. 16 For instance the following debates in Austria: The debate on untying the connection of parental leave regulation from labor market participation, the discussion about ‘half and half’ of domestic work for men and women, the question of an individual pension right for all women, debates on public subsidies for child care institutions and others. 17 This common characteristic justifies the presentation in the same field of the matrix. But this presentation should not be interpreted as a negation of the meaningful differences between the two scenarios (distribution effects, exclusion effects and so on). 18 Elements of such a scenario could be: A significant reduction of general working time (for instance down to 32 hours per week); This reduced working time has to be the new standard for social security, minimum income and so on (new standard of ‘regular employment’); Elimination of all breadwinner elements in social policy; Integration of care work in the social security system without a gender assignment (explicit and implicit); Public supply (or subsidies) of qualitative social services. 19 The presented suggestions are part of a model to integrate care work in the regular economy in the Netherlands (see Brouwer and Wierda 1998). The measures and instruments have to be completed and put in concrete form. And it has to be said that many questions are still open: What about single parents in this dual-breadwinner-oriented model? How can the quality of outsourced family work be guaranteed? How can it be ensured that men reduce their paid working time and take over their part of family work? Would the gender wage gap 30 disappear automatically or are further measures necessary? References Advisory Council to the Netherlands Government on Equal Opportunity Policy (1996) 'Concerns for a New Security. Recommendations for an Equal Opportunities Income and Social Security Policy', The Hague. Anker, Richard (1998) Gender and Jobs. Sex segregation of occupations in the world, International Labour Office Geneva. Bettio, Francesca (1988): The Sexual Division of Labour. The Italian Case. Clarendon Press, Oxford. Bohnenkamp, Ulrike (1992) 'Europa im Umbruch - neue Dimensionen der Frauenpolitik?' in Susanne Schunter-Kleemann (ed) Herrenhaus Europa: Geschlechterverhältnisse im Wohlfahrtsstaat, pp. 11-28, Berlin: edition sigma. Brouwer, Ina and Eelco Wierda (1998) 'The Combination Model: Child Care and the Part time Labour Supply of Men in the Dutch Welfare State', in Schippers, Joop, Jacques Siegers, and Jenny de Jong-Gierveld (eds) Child Care and Female Labour Supply in the Netherlands, pp 133162, Amsterdam: Thesis Publishers. Bruyn-Hundt, Marga (1996) 'Scenarios for a Redistribution of unpaid work in the Netherlands', Feminist Economics 2 (3): 129-133. Charles, Maria (1992) 'Cross-national variation in occupational sex segregation', American Sociological Review 57: 483-502. Cockburn, Cynthia (1992) In the way of Women. Men’s Resistance to Sex Equality in Organizations, Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire: Macmillan Press. Creighton, Colin (1999) 'The rise and decline of the 'male breadwinner family' in Britain', Cambridge Journal of Economics 23: 519-541. Crompton, Rosemary (ed) (1999) 'Restructuring gender relations and employment. The decline of the male breadwinner', Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press. Duncan, Simon (1998) 'Theorising Gender Systems in Europe', in Geissler, Birgit, Friederike Maier, and Birgit Pfau-Effinger (eds) FrauenArbeitsMarkt. Der Beitrag der Frauenforschung zur sozioökonomischen Theorieentwicklung, pp. 195-228, Berlin: edition sigma. Esping-Andersen, Gøsta (1996) 'Welfare States without Work: the Impasse of Labour Shedding and Familialism in Continental European Social Policy', in Esping-Anderson, Gøsta (ed) Welfare States in Transition. National Adaptations in Global Economy, pp. 66-87, London: Sage. Fagan, Colette, and Jill Rubery (1996) 'Transitions between family formation and paid employment', in Schmid, Günther, Jacqueline O’Reilly, and Klaus Schömann (eds) International handbook of labour market policy and evaluation, pp. 348-378, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Finder, Ruth and Sabine Blaschke (1999) Tendenzen im Dienstleistungssektor. Tendenzen der Frauenbeschäftigung, Projektbericht des Forschungszentrums W. A. S., Wien. Fraser, Nancy (1994) 'After the Family Wage. Gender Equity and the Welfare State', Political Theory 22 (4): 591-618. Frauenbericht (1995) Bericht über die Situation der Frauen in Österreich, Bundesministerin für Frauenangelegenheiten, Wien. 31 Friese, Marianne (1995) '„Die osteuropäische Akademikerin, die im westeuropäischen Haushalt dient.“ Neue soziale Ungleichheiten und Arbeitsteilungen zwischen Frauen', in Modelmog, Ilse and Ulrike Gräßel (eds) Konkurrenz & Kooperation. Frauen im Zwiespalt? pp. 171-194, Münster: Lit Verlag. Goldin, Claudia (1990) Understanding the Gender Gap: An Economic History of American Women, New York: Oxford University Press. Gornick, Janet C., Marcia K. Meyers, and Katherin E. Ross (1997) 'Supporting the employment of mothers: Policy variations across fourteen welfare states', Journal of European Social Policy 7 (1): 45-70. Gregoritsch, Petra, Monika Kalmár and Michael Wagner-Pinter (2000) Einkommen von Frauen und Männeern in unselbständiger Beschäftigung, Endbericht, Bundesministerium für Wirtschaft und Arbeit, Wien. Hakim, Catherine (1993) 'Segregated and Integrated Occupations: A New Approach to Analysing Social Change', European Sociological Review 9(3): pp. 289-314. Hausen, Karin (ed) (1993) Geschlechterhierarchie und Arbeitsteilung. Zur Geschichte ungleicher Erwerbschancen von Männern und Frauen, Göttingen: Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht. Heintz, Bettina, Eva Nadai, Regula Fischer and Hannes Ummel (1997) Ungleich unter Gleichen. Studien zur geschlechtsspezifischen Segregation des Arbeitsmarktes, Frankfurt/ New York: Campus. Humphries, Jane and Jill Rubery (1984) 'The Reconstitution of the Supply Side of the Labour Market: The Relative Autonomy of Social Reproduction', Cambridge Journal of Economics 8: 331-346. Kenrick, Jane (1981) 'Politics and the Construction of Women as Second-class Workers', in Wilkinson, Frank (ed) The Dynamics of Labour Market Segmentation, pp. 167-192, London: Academic Press. Kreckel, Reinhard (1993) 'Doppelte Vergesellschaftung und geschlechtsspezifische Arbeitsmarktstrukturierung,' in Frerichs, Petra and Margareta Steinrücke (eds) Soziale Ungleichheit und Geschlechterverhältnis, Schriftenreihe „Sozialstrukturanalyse“, Band 3, pp. 5164, Opladen: Leske und Budrich. Kreimer, Margareta (1999) Arbeitsteilung als Diskriminierungsmechanismus. Theorie und Empirie geschlechtsspezifischer Arbeitsmarktsegregation, Frankfurt: Peter Lang. Leira, Arnlaug (1993) 'The 'woman-friendly’ welfare state?: The case of Norway and Sweden', in Lewis, Jane (ed) Women and social policies in Europe. Work, family and the state, pp. 49-71, Aldershot: Edward Elgar. Leitner, Andrea (2000) Frauenberufe – Männerberufe: Zur Persistenz geschlechtshierarchischer Arbeitsmarktsegregation, Institut für Höhere Studien, Wien. Leitner, Andrea and Angela Wroblewski (2000) Chancengleichheit und Gender Mainstreaming. Ergebnisse der begleitenden Evaluierung des österreichischen NAP, Institut für Höhere Studien, Reihe Soziologie Nr. 41, Wien. Lewis, Jane and Ilona Ostner (1994) 'Gender and the Evolution of European Social Policies', ZeSArbeitspapier Nr. 4/94, Universität Bremen. Lutz, Helma (2000) 'At your service Madame! Migrant workers as domestic workers in Europe', Paper presented at the international conference 'Gender and the Future of Work', University of Bremen, 30th June – 1st July 2000. Mairhuber, Ingrid (2000) Die Regulierung des Geschlechterverhältnisses im Sozialstaat Österreich, Frankfurt: Peter Lang. 32 Melkas, Helinä and Richard Anker (1998) Gender equality and occupational segregation in Nordic labour markets, International Labour Office, Geneva. Meulders, Danièle, Olivier Plasman, and Robert Plasman (1997) 'Atypical Labour Market Relations in the European Union', in Dijkstra, Geske and Janneke Plantenga (eds) Gender and Economics. A European Perspective, pp. 75-85, London, New York: Routledge. Meyer, Traute (1997) Ungleich besser? Die ökonomische Unabhängigkeit von Frauen im Zeichen der Expansion sozialer Dienstleistungen, Berlin: edition sigma. Mühlberger, Ulrike (2000) Neue Formen der Beschäftigung. Arbeitsflexibilisierung durch atypische Beschäftigung in Österreich, Wien: Braumüller. Münz, Rainer and Gerda Neyer (1986) 'Frauenarbeit und Mutterschutz in Österreich. Ein historischer Überblick,' in Münz, Rainer, Gerda Neyer, and Monika Pelz (eds) Frauenarbeit, Karenzurlaub und berufliche Wiedereingliederung, pp. 13-76, Linz: Veröffentlichungen des österreichischen Instituts für Arbeitsmarktpolitik. Ott, Notburga (1992) Intrafamily Bargaining and Household Decisions, Berlin: Springer. Pfau-Effinger, Birgit (1999) 'The modernisation of family and motherhood in western Europe', in Crompton, Rosemary (ed) Restructuring gender relations and employment. The decline of the male breadwinner, pp. 60-79, Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press. Pujol, Michèle A. (1992) Feminism and Anti-Feminism in Early Economic Thought, Vermont, Aldershot: Edward Elgar. Ranftl, Edeltraud, Birgit Buchinger, Ulrike Gschwandtner and Oskar Meggeneder (2002) (eds) Gleicher Lohne für gleichwertige Arbeit. Praktische Beispiele diskriminierungsfreier analytischer Arbeitsbewertung. München und Mering: Hampp. Reskin, Barbara (1994) 'Sex Segregation: Explaining Stability and Change in the Sex Composition of Work', in Beckmann, Petra and Gerhard Engelbrech (eds) Arbeitsmarkt für Frauen 2000 – Ein Schritt vor oder ein Schritt zurück? pp. 97-115, BeitrAB 179, Nürnberg. Reskin, Barbara and Irene Padavic (1994) Women and Men at Work, London, New Dehli: Pine Forge Press. Robeyns, Ingrid (1998) 'An emancipation fee or hush money? The advantages and disadvantages of a basic income for women’s emancipation and well-being', Paper presented at the 7th BIEN international conference on basis income, Amsterdam, September 10th – 12th, 1998. Rubery, Jill (1978) 'Structured Labour Markets, Worker Organisation and Low Pay', Cambridge Journal of Economics 2 (1): 17-36. Rubery, Jill and Colette Fagan (1993) Occupational Segregation of Women and Men in the European Community, Social Europe Supplement 3/93, Luxembourg. Rubery, Jill and Colette Fagan (1995) 'Gender segregation in societal context', Work, Employment and Society 9 (2): 213-240. Rubery, Jill and Colette Fagan (1998) Equal Opportunities and Employment in the European Union, Report for the Federal Ministry of Labour, Health and Social Affairs and the Federal Minister for Women’s Affairs and Consumer Protection of Austria, Vienna. Schmidt, Dorothea (1993) 'Die „Herren der Technik“ und die „feine Hand“ der Arbeiterinnen', Prokla 93, Vol. 23 (4): 585-612. Schwarzkopf, Jutta (1993) 'Die soziale Konstruktion von Qualifikation. Eine historische Untersuchung der Weberei von Lancashire zwischen 1885 und dem Ersten Weltkrieg', Prokla 93, Vol. 23 (4): 612-632. Smith, Vicki, and Heidi Gottfried (1998) Flexibility in Work and Employment: The Impact on Women', In: Geissler, Birgit, Friederike Maier, and Birgit Pfau-Effinger (eds) 33 FrauenArbeitsMarkt. Der Beitrag der Frauenforschung zur sozio-ökonomischen Theoriebildung, pp. 95-125, Berlin: edition sigma. Tálos, Emmerich (1999) 'Atypische Beschäftigung in Österreich,' in Tálos, Emmerich (ed) Atypische Beschäftigung. Internationale Trends und sozialstaatliche Regelungen. Europa, USA, pp. 252284, Vienna: Manz. Tálos, Emmerich and Karl Wörister (1994) Soziale Sicherung im Sozialstaat Österreich, BadenBaden: Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft. von Wahl, Angelika (1995) 'Geschlecht und Arbeitsmarkt. Gleichstellungspolitik in den USA und der Bundesrepublik', Prokla 99, Vol. 25 (2): 221-234. Walby, Sylvia (1997) Gender Transformations, London and New York: Routledge. Wetterer, Angelika (1993) Professionalisierung und Geschlechterhierarchie. Vom kollektiven Frauenausschluss zur Integration mit beschränkten Möglichkeiten, Kassel: Jenior & Preßler. Williams, Christine L. (ed) (1993) Doing ‘Women’s Work’. Men in Nontraditional Occupations, Newbury Park, London, New Dehli: Sage. Winker, Gabriele (1998) 'New Perspectives for Women Through Flexible Working Arrangements in the Information Society', in Bundesministerin für Frauenangelegenheiten und Verbraucherschutz (ed) Employment 2002 – The Future for Women, pp. 142-167, A Documentation of the EUConference September 3 – 4 1998 in Linz. Witz, Anne (1992) Professions and Patriarchy, London and New York: Routledge. Yeandle, Sue (1999) 'Gender Contracts, Welfare Systems and Non-Standard Working: Diversity and Change in Denmark, France, Germany, Italy and the UK', in Felstead, Alan and Nick Jewson (eds) Global Trends in Flexible Labour, pp. 141-165, Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire: Macmillan Press. 34 Picture 1: Matrix of possibilities to change sex segregation Reduction of functional hierarchy Reduction of gender hierarchy – New division of labour between men and women Breadwinner model Modernized Breadwinner Systems Scandinavian model or Marketsubstitution-model Segmentation in the female labor market depending on the extent of functional hierarchy Equivalence of market work and domestic work in different models Picture 2: New division of labor, ‘equal burden’ for both sexes ‘family-oriented working life’ for both sexes Complete elimination of hierarchies Scenarios on the reduction of segregation Reduction of functional hierarchy Reduction of gender hierarchy – New division of labour between men and women ‘Perpetuation-scenario’ ‘Allocation-scenario’ Modernised variants of the breadwinner system Individual redistribution of paid and unpaid work ‘Outsourcing-scenario’ (market or state version) ‘Salary-for-domesticwork-scenario’ ‘Combination-scenario’ Social responsibility for unpaid work without changing the gender division of labour Social responsibility for unpaid and paid work, redistribution of work for both sexes 35