12/20/2010 5:24:00 AM Index to the Contracts Outline I. Is there an agreement? ........................................................................ 1 A. Is there an agreement? Lucy v. Zhemer, Embry v. Hargindine .............. 1 B. Is there an offer? §24................................................................... 24 2 1. Content of the communication suggests offer: Nebraska Seed v. Harsh (missing terms) ..................................................... 2 2. Context of the communication suggests offer: Leonard v. Pepsico, §33 Uncertainty = maybe not offer ................................... 3 C. What happens post-offer and pre-acceptance? .................................... 4 1. Party Dies .............................................................................. 4 2. Lapse of Time......................................................................... 4 3. Revocation of Offer: Petterson v. Pattberg, §42 .......................... 4 D. Is there an acceptance? ................................................................... 6 1. Acceptance Defined – Mirror Image Rule: Ardente v. Horan, §61 ................................................................................. 6 2. Acceptance by Counter-Offer or Conditional Acceptance for non-goods: Ardente .............................................................. 7 3. Acceptance by Counter-Offer or Conditional Acceptance FOR GOODS UNDER UCC: Step-Saver v. Wyse, UCC 2-207 .............. 7 4. Acceptance by Silence ............................................................. 7 5. Acceptance by Performance: Petterson v. Pattberg ..................... 9 II. Is there any reason that the agreement should not be enforced? ................................................................................................... 10 A. Do the parties have a material disagreement as to one or more terms of the contract?: ......................................................................... 11 1. Disagreement over one MATERIAL term: Raffles v. Wichelhaus, §201, V. Frigaliment, UCC 2-208 ................................. 11 2. Missing Terms: §204 (court might provide), Sun Printing ............. 12 B. Was There Consideration? ............................................................... 13 1. Was it a gift or was it a bargain? Johnson v. Otterbein ................ 16 2. Was it past consideration? ....................................................... 17 3. Was there moral consideration? Mills v. Wyman.......................... 18 1 4. Was a contract modified with consideration? Stilk, Alaska V. UCC 2-209 ............................................................................. 19 5. Was the consideration adequate? .............................................. 21 C. If there was not Consideration was there Promissory Estoppel? Hoffman v. Red Owl, Goodman v. Dicker ................................................ 23 III. What are the terms of the Agreement? ................................................ 28 A. Can the court go beyond the “four-corners” of the document? §209, Thompson v. Libbey V. UCC 2-202 (contradict) V. Trident v. Conn. Gen. ..... 28 B. What can the external evidence do?................................................... 30 1. External evidence can correct mistakes (typos) .......................... 30 2. External evidence can explain ambiguity.................................... 31 3. External evidence can add to terms of writing if agreement silent as to those terms, as long as the terms do not contradict written agreement .................................................. 31 IV. Has there been a breach? ..................................................................... 32 A. Was the contract performed under good faith? Goldberg v. Levy ........... 32 B. Was there an express waiver of a condition of the contract, rather than a modification of a promise SEE LAST PAGE ..................................... 33 C. Are there implied conditions that were not complied with? (if yes, breach) *situations in which even though one party did not fully perform, he is seeking to enforce the other party’s promise: Kingston v. Preston ............................................................................................... 34 D. (1) Does there need to be perfect performance? (2) What are the damages? (Cost of completion vs. Diminution of Value) Cardozo v. UCC 2-106/Perfect Tender (Ramirez). DV - Jacob and Young; CC - Groves........ 35 1. Services: can only seek damages (not repudiation of contract).................................................................................... 39 2. Sale of Goods: can seek repudiation if you have rejected but if you’ve accepted, then you may only be able to recover damages.................................................................................... 40 E. Was there an anticipatory breach? Hochester v. De La Tour .................. 40 V. Defenses to contractual obligations making a contract voidable ..................................................................................................... 43 A. Obtaining Assent Unfairly ................................................................. 43 1. When Assent was obtained through misrepresentation or fraud as to facts ......................................................................... 43 2 2. When assent is obtained through misrepresentation of opinion, Vokes v. Arthur Murray ................................................... 46 3. Duress, Headley v. Hackley, §175 ............................................. 48 B. Was the contract unconscionable? Williams v. Walker Thomas .............. 50 C. Was there a mistake? ...................................................................... 52 1. Mutual mistake: Sherwood v. Walker, §152, 154 (bears risk) .......................................................................................... 53 2. Unilateral Mistake Tyra v. Cheney ............................................. 53 3. Impossibility/Impracticability (after a contract is made) .............. 54 4. Frustration of Purpose (after a contract is made) Krell v. Henry, §265 ............................................................................... 55 VI. Damage Interests ................................................................................ 56 A. Which damage interest should apply? ................................................ 56 1. Expectation Damages – Default Rule of Damages ....................... 56 2. Reliance Damages [When you are not sure if a contract has been created] (quasi-contracts such as Cotnam OR promissory estoppel such as Goodman) ......................................... 60 3. Restitution Damages [usually the smallest but in rare circumstances can be larger than expectation] ............................... 61 B. Are there any Limitations on Damages? ............................................. 65 1. Foreseeability of Damages Hadley v Baxendale, §351 .................. 65 2. Certainty of Harm Chicago Coliseum v. Dempsey, §352 ............... 66 3. Mitigation: Rockingham County, Parker v. 20th Century, Lost Volume Doctrine (Neri, 2-708) .............................................. 67 : C. How do you contract around ............................................................. 70 1. You have a liquidated damages clause which is enforceable: Wassennaar v. Towne Hotel, §2-719 ........................... 70 2. When damages stated in the contract are out of line with the actual damage foreseeable at the time of the contract, then such a clause shall be deemed a penalty clause and is thus UNENFORCEABLE under contract law ..................................... 70 D. Alternatives to Monetary Damages: Specific Performance ..................... 72 1. Contracts for Unique Goods Scholl v. Hartzell, Sedmark v. Charlie's Chevrolet, UCC 2-716 ..................................................... 72 2. Contracts for Services ............................................................. 73 3 1: IS THERE AN AGREEMENT? 12/20/2010 5:24:00 AM Question 1: Is there an Agreement? Sub-question 1: Is there Mutual assent? Objective Approach – What would a reasonable person expect from the exchange? Rule: If, whatever a man’s subjective/real intention may be, he conducts himself so that a reasonable person would believe he was assenting to the terms proposed by the other party, and the other party upon that belief enters into a contract with him, the man thus conducting himself would be equally bound as if he had intended to agree to the other party’s terms [internal secret understandings don’t matter, only objective manifestations of intent to enter agreement] o Reasonable for B to believe him intent irrelevant o Unreasonable to believe can you prove B intends for A to believe him? o Case 1: Lucy v. Zhemer Facts: Lucy approached Zhemer about purchasing farm, contract on back of check, in a bar, questionable sobriety, Zhemer joking unbeknownst to Lucy, Mrs. Zhemer signed “contract,” Lucy relied on contract in conducting title search and financing payment Holding: a party can be bound to a contract when he secretly doesn’t intend to enter contract but acts in a way such that a reasonable other party thought he was being serious o Case 2: Embry v. Hargindine Facts: Embry employed by D, employment contract expired, P approached D multiple times prior to expiration to extend contract; P then tracked down D and informed that he would leave unless employed for another year; D said to “go ahead you’re fine, get back to work”; P returned to work and was notified 2 months later that he would be laid off Holding: although D may have not intended to have formed a contract, what D said would have been taken by a reasonable man to be an employment contract and since P understood it as such it was a valid contract 1 o Case 3: HYPO Facts: Lucy knew that Zhemer was joking and just played along. Holding: No mutual assent because Lucy must believe Zhemer intends to enter into a contract (§20) o Case 4: HYPO Facts: Zhemer purposely deceives an extra gullible Lucy while not doing enough to make a reasonable person believe it to be true. Holding: This would still be a mutual assent. §19(2) discusses that he must “know or have reason to know that the other party may infer from his conduct that he assents” – so this includes the gullibleness of Lucy. §17. Requirement of a Bargain. – formation of a contract requires a manifestation of mutual assent (based on external dealings and not secret intent) §18. Manifestation of Mutual Assent – requires that each party make a promise or begin to render a performance (either calls for unilateral or bilateral contract) § 19: Conduct as Manifestation of Assent – (1) written or spoken words or action or failure to act creates a manifestation of assent (2) Conduct of a party is not effective unless he intends to engage in the conduct and knows or has reason to know that the other party may infer from his conduct that he assents (3) The conduct of a party may manifest assent even though he may not assent. In such cases a resulting contract may be voidable because of fraud, duress, mistake or other invalidating cause. §20. Effect of Misunderstanding – If party has reason to know that the other side is joking then they cannot enforce a contract even though it objectively appears to a reasonable person that a contract has been made. [rare instance in which court takes subjective intent into account] Sub question 2: Is there an Offer? 2 §24 – Offer Defined: An offer is the manifestation of willingness to enter into a bargain so made as to justify another person in understanding that his assent to that bargain is invited and will conclude it Possibility 1: Content of the Communication suggests offer Rule 1: The more complete an offer is (price, quantity, date) the more likely it is to be an offer o even if not quantified or specified if terms: “all of,” “only,” or “solely” indicate offer to buy o also look to REASONABLENESS of terms--ex: harrier jet is not reasonable Rule 2: Conversely if an offer is missing terms or is nothing more than a invitation it is not an offer (look for words: fair, appropriate, reasonable) o Case 1: Nebraska Seed Co. v. Harsh o Facts: Seller of seeds issue letter stating he has certain quantity for a certain price but did NOT fix delivery time or definite amount he wanted to sell buyer. P wrote back wanting to purchase, but D refused. o Holding: If a proposal lacks key terms, it is an invitation to negotiate, not an offer. Possibility 2: Context of the Communication suggests offer Rule 1: Advertisements are not generally understood as offers to sell. To be transferred into enforceable offer there must be some language of commitment or invitation to take action. §26 Preliminary Negotiation §33 Certainty (3) – The fact that one or more terms of a proposed bargain are left open or uncertain may show that a manifestation of intention is not intended to be understood as an offer or as an acceptance o **Note: Other forms of Advertisements: Catalogues, price lists, radio, o Case 1: Leonard v. Pepsico 3 Facts: Pepsico had promotional campaign encouraging accumulation of “Pepsi points” by consumers. One ad featured exaggerated commercial where one could win a harrier jet in exchange for 7 million Pepsi points. Commercial points consumer to catalogue for further details and order form (harrier jet missing from catalogue). P collects points in combo w/ money for additional points needed (10 cents/point). P sends in points/money and Pepsi rejects. P seeks specific performance of alleged offer. Holding: No offer b/c advertisement lacking specific terms and unreasonable ($700,000 for $42 million jet) and advertisement clearly in jest. Note: Other side could argue that 1) As in Carbolic Smoke, it’s a reward for the buyers. “If a company chooses to make extravagant promises, he probably does so because it pays to make them.” 2) Reasonableness – it’s reasonable as soon as kids take action, so in this unilateral offer, the performance is to buy a lot of Pepsi, which took place. Rule 2: If an advertisement is clear and has complete terms (leaving nothing open for negotiation) it can be considered an offer (Lefkowitz, Carbolic Smoke) § 24: An offer is the manifestation of willingness to enter into a bargain so made as to justify another person in understanding that his assent to that bargain is invited and will conclude it. § 26: A manifestation of willingness to enter into a bargain is not an offer if the person to whom it is addressed knows or has reason to know that the person making it does not intend to conclude the bargain. § 29: The manifested intention of the Offeror determines the persons, or group, or everyone, who is created a power of acceptance § 33: Even though Offeror meant his manifestation of intent is intended to be understood as an offer, a contract is not formed unless the terms of the contract are reasonably certain. 4 UCC Law §2-204: Contract for sale of goods can be in any manner sufficient to show agreement, including conduct by both parties. It can constitute a contract even though the moment of its making is undetermined. UCC Law §2-206: Can accept in any medium reasonable, unless otherwise unambiguously indicated UCC Law §2-305: Parties can intend to conclude a contract even though the price is not settled. A price is a reasonable price at the time of delivery if: 1) nothing is said as to price; 2) the price is left to be agreed by the parties and they fail to agree; 3) the price is to fixed in terms of some agreed market or standard [Unlike in Nebraska, this says you CAN leave price open.] Sub-question 3: What Happens Post Offer and Pre-Acceptance? § 36 Methods of Termination of the Power of Acceptance: An offeree’s power of acceptance may be terminated by (1) death or incapacity of offeror or offeree; (2) Lapse of time; (3) Revocation by the offeror Possibility 1: Party Dies Deal is off Possibility 2: Lapse of Time Deal is off after reasonable amount of time (especially when goods market value fluctuates) Possibility 3: Revocation of Offer (only offeror can revoke) 1. Was there a Revocation? Rule 1: (1) An offeror can withdraw the offer as long as he makes it clear via unambiguous actions or words that he is withdrawing and (2) as long as the offeree receives notice from offeror or third party. (Dickenson) Rule 2 (POLICY justification for Firm Offers for things that are NOT goods): Encouraging people to make offers knowing that if value of offer increases offeror can revoke original offer (HYPO) o Case 1: (Dickenson) Holding: When offeree discovers offeror has revoked he can not attempt to make the offer binding by performing requirements of offer. (offeree’s awareness of revocation kills offer) o Case 2: Hypo 5 Facts: Offer outstanding to sell land and promise to keep open to certain date. In meantime a rumor starts that Britney Spears is going to buy at a heightened price down the road—increasing the current value of your property. Offeror wants to revoke original offer. Holding: Offeror can revoke original offer before he receives any acceptances even if he promised to keep it on the table. § 42 Revocation by Communication From Offeror Received by Offeree – Once offeree receives information that offeror doesn’t intend to enter deal, offeree can no longer accept §43 Indirect Communication of Revocation – Offeree’s power of acceptance is terminated when Offeree finds out that Offeror takes some sort of action inconsistent with intention to enter into the proposed contract. 2. 4 situations in which Offer CAN NOT be Revoked by Offeror Rule 1: Option Contract Rule 2: Firm Offers o UCC §2-205 – Firm Offers – For sale of goods, Firm Offers (offer to leave offer on the table for a time period) are NOT revocable (Policy: encourage fast buying/selling of goods) Rule 3: Promissory Estoppel Rule 4: Unilateral Contract where performance has begun o § 45 – Option Contract Created by Part Performance or Tender – An offeror can not revoke a contract when he has created an option contract (commencement of performance in response to a unilateral contract offer) and the offeree has begun performance BUT offeree can revoke at any time Sub-question 4: Is there an Acceptance? Possibility 1: Acceptance Defined – Mirror Image Rule §61 – Acceptance which requests change of terms – A response to an offer that doesn’t “mirror” the offer is not an acceptance 6 Rule: A response to an offer constitutes an acceptance if it does not change or add to the terms of the offer but rather “mirrors” its terms o Case: Ardente v. Horan Facts: D offered property to P. P made a bid for property which was communicated to D through a letter with a $20K deposit. The letter also included P’s desire to ensure that furniture items would be included. D refused to additional terms of furniture and did not sign agreement. D argued P’s communication was counteroffer and not acceptance and thus invalid. P argued that added terms not conditional (collateral matter) and thus letter constitutes acceptance Holding: The letter constituted a counter-offer and didn’t “mirror” terms of offer and thus not a binding acceptance. If want acceptance to be valid despite terms, it needs to be clearly stated Policy: If one party wants out we want to give them the option to get out of a contract, otherwise parties won’t be encouraged to engage in contracts Possibility 2: Acceptance by Counter-Offer or Conditional Acceptance for non-goods Rule: If response to an offer bases acceptance on certain conditions (key words: “if,” “provided,” “only if,” “on condition that”) which if not met, are a “deal-breaker,” then response constitutes a counter-offer and NOT an acceptance o Case: See Ardente: seeking “confirmation that the items are a part of the transaction” is far from being an independent, collateral request. So, letter of acceptance was conditional, operated as rejection of original offer, and no contractual obligation was created. Possibility 3: Acceptance by Counter-Offer or Conditional Acceptance FOR GOODS UNDER UCC UCC § 2-207 (1) – Contract exists even if there are additional terms that don’t mirror initial offer 7 UCC § 2-207 (2) – The additional terms become part of the contract UNLESS (a) the offer expressly says no; (b) they materially alter the contract or (2)(c) they are objected to Case 1: Step Saver v. Wyse Technology (Terms that materially alter the contract) p. 457 o Facts: Step Saver is a software/hardware packaging company who sells to end-use consumers. TSL (D) sells computer program to P, ordered over telephone with exchange of buyer/seller purchase orders (containing quantity, price and no warranty disclaimer). Subsequently D sends program with a box-top-license agreement disclaiming any and all warranties. Argument over whether terms of BTL are part of agreement arises when P’s customers have major issues. P argues that original agreement was whole contract. D argues that BTL was conditional acceptance and P’s opening of box constituted acceptance. o Holding: BTL not part of contract because it suggests an additional term (no warranty) which would substantially alter terms of agreement (2-207(2)(b)) and to which (D) objected on numerous occasions (2-207(2)(c)). Original contract was sufficient, b/c there was UCC defaults to fill the holes Not a conditional acceptance because TSL did not demonstrate unwillingness to proceed. If not a conditional acceptance, then must be an additionally proposed term. According to UCC, it does NOT incorporate into the contract if it is material or objected to. Here, it is both. Case 2: HYPO Facts: Similar to Ardente, but Seller decides he wants to get out of contract so he says the furniture isn’t part of the deal. Buyer still wants this contract to go through, so says it wasn’t really a conditional term. Holding: It is a contract: no unwillingness to proceed, so not a conditional acceptance. Possibility 4: Acceptance by Silence 8 §69 – Acceptance by Silence – [1] Silence operates as acceptance (a) where offeree benefits with reasonable opportunity to reject and reason to know that they were offered with expectation or compensation; (b) where offeror has given offeree reason to understand that assent may be manifested by silence and the offeree in remaining silent intends to accept offer; (c) where due to prior dealings it is reasonable that the offeree should notify the offeror if he does not intend to accept [Massasoit whip] [2] An offeree who does any act inconsistent with offeror’s ownership of offered property is bound in accordance with the offered terms unless they are manifestly unreasonable Possibility 5: Acceptance by Performance 1. Can You Accept by Performance? Rule: Under a unilateral contract, the offeree is invited to accept the offer by performance rather than an exchange of a promise to perform (bilateral contract) §30: An offer may invite or require acceptance to be made by an affirmative answer in words, or by performing or refraining from performing a specified act. §62 – Effect of Performance by Offeree Where Offer Invites either performance or promise – If offeror permits either acceptance by promise or by performance offeree can do either § 45 – Option Contract Created by Part Performance or Tender – Option contract is unilateral contract without possibility of promissory acceptance. Comment (e) says an offeror can not revoke a contract when he has created an option contract and the offeree has begun performance BUT offeree can revoke at any time GO BACK TO THIS I FEEL LIKE WE HAVE A CASE ABOUT IT!! Case 1: Petterson v. Pattberg (negative example) p. 362 Facts: P owed D money on a mortgage. D offered P opportunity to pay off the mortgage by a certain date in exchange for a reduction in principal of debt. P collected money owed and tried to repay D by showing up at D’s door with cash in hand. D wouldn’t open the door and said it was too late as he already sold the mortgage. P sued for specific performance. Holding: P did not begin to perform the unilateral contract because he hadn’t exchanged the $ and thus he never accepted prior to the 9 revocation which occurred when D refused to open the door and allow performance. Policy Debate: What constitutes beginning of performance in an option contract (where contract is left open until certain date). Here Court holds that attempting to deliver performance is insufficient but this is debatable. Case 2: HYPO: o Facts: Reward for dog, last minute Offeror calls the whole deal off. o Holding: Might seem unfair but you want both parties to be bound by same deal or neither, in general offeree is allowed to back out of offer at last minute, so it wouldn’t be fair to not allow Offeror the same. Or, alternatively, is this an option contract as illustrated in §45? Case 3: Leonard v. Pepsico II (negative example) p. 356 o Facts: Same as before, but theory is unilateral offer of a reward. o Holding: Court compares to “Carbolic Smoke Ball.” Court says there’s a difference between offer of reward and offer to negotiate. Here, to negotiate b/c it urged them to look at catalogue, and once there need to accept terms of Order Form. So, NOT unilateral, but rather reciprocal. 2. Is Notice Necessary? Rule: Notice is not necessary to secure acceptance by performance unless (1) offeror requests notice or (2) offeror has no other way of knowing of acceptance (such as parties in different states) §54 – Acceptance by Performance: Necessity of Notification to Offeror – (1) where offer invites acceptance by performance notification unnecessary unless the offer requests such notification (2) If an offeree who accepts by performance has reason to know that the offeror has no adequate means of learning of performance with reasonable promptness and certainty, there is not acceptance UNLESS (a) the offeree exercises reasonable diligence to notify the offeror (b) the offeror learns of the performance within a reasonable time (c) the offer indicates the notification of acceptance is not required 10 2: IS THERE ANY REASON THAT THE AGREEMENT SHOULD NOT BE ENFORCED? 12/20/2010 5:24:00 AM Question 2: Is there any reason that the agreement should not be enforced? Sub-question 1: Do the parties have a material disagreement as to one or more terms of the contract? Possibility 1: Disagreement over one MATERIAL term Rule: § 201: When parties disagree as to a single material term in the agreement and (1) more than one possible meaning exists; (2) the parties have distinct meanings; (3) Neither party had reason to know of the other parties interpretation, THEN there was no mutual assent and the contract unenforceable §201 – Whose Meaning Prevails Where parties have attached different meanings, then it is interpreted in accordance with the meaning of the person who is NOT the person who a) “knew” or b) “had reason to know” the first person’s meaning. If this doesn’t happen, then neither party is bound by the meaning attached by the other. UCC §2-208 – Establishes a hierarchy of evidence to be used: First, course of performance is accepted Express terms of agreement Then, course of dealing and usage of trade words [1-205] Case 1: Raffles v. Wichelhaus (no mutual assent b/c parties innocent as to other meaning) o Facts: P Seller agreed to sell a certain quantity of cotton that was to arrive “ex-Peerless.” When Peerless arrived in December D refused payment b/c D thought that October Peerless was meant in contract. Argument over whether parties had reason to know that there were 2 peerlesses. o Holding: There was no mutual assent and therefore no agreement since neither side had reason to know of alternative meaning attached by other party. o Policy: Each party based risk on assessment of different markets for cotton (October vs. December) thus enforcement would be unfair since it wasn’t bargained for. If price was dropping (which it was), then the way this was resolved: Seller lost $, Buyer got a windfall. If we had 11 resolved it the way S understood, no harm done. So this is not necessarily the most efficient. Case 2: Frigaliment v. BNS Int. Sales (mutal assent b/c buyer had reason to know of seller’s meaning) o Facts: P seller contracted to sell “chickens” to D for a certain agreed upon price. Disagreement b/w buyer and seller as to meaning of “chicken.” Buyer argued “chicken” meant “young chicken” and seller argued any bird from that genesis. o Holding: Court took seller’s interpretation of “chicken” to mean any and all chicken based on reasoning that buyer had reason to know and thus it was not an mutual misunderstanding o Reasoning: The court looked to the following factors in determining whose meaning to apply: o 1) Course of performance – buyer argued that the use of the English word “chicken” in place of the German word “huhn” was to mean only young chicken. Seller argued that the first shipment did not contain young chickens but was nevertheless accepted by buyer, showing certainty of terms under §34 (2) (stating acceptance of part performance may remove uncertainty and establish contract enforceability) o 2) Express terms of the contract – buyer argued since one contract was for young chickens then the other contract had to be for young chickens as well—court rejects this! o 3) Trade Usage – buyer and seller offer conflicting expert testimony as to meaning. Seller’s expert was careful to distinguish types of chicken within his own course of dealings thus making his testimony that chicken means one thing—young chickens— unreliable according to court. o How is this different from Raffles—why is there a contract here? In Raffles innocent mutual misunderstanding—no contract. Here buyer had reason to know of seller’s interpretation but not vice versa so seller’s interpretation wins and contract enforceable. o Policy: How clear does a party have to be to ensure their meaning controls? If a party says something in 5 ways which has a 6th meaning is this sufficiently clear to be enforceable? 12 Possibility 2: Missing Terms Gaps in Terms 1. When only one term is missing Rule 1: Based on §204 -- When there is an essential omitted term but the court establishes that the parties intended have a contract, the court will supply a term which is reasonable in the circumstances 2. When multiple material terms are missing—Agreement to Agree Rule 2: Courts will not supply multiple uncertain/missing terms to an agreement when the parties have not necessarily intended for the contract to include such terms but rather have simply agreed to agree later. BUT: UCC § 2-204 – (3) even though one or more terms are left open, a contract doesn’t fail for indefiniteness if parties intended to make a contract and there is a reasonably certain basis for giving an appropriate remedy. (past dealings can be one way of determining a reasonably certain time frame and/or amount) Case 1: Sun Printing v. Remington Paper o Facts: D agreed to sell to P 1,000 tons of paper/month for 16 months. Price set as to first 4 months but then contract left open price and length of term for remainder 12 months. Only restriction was a price ceiling of Canadian Export Paper price. Buyer P tried to enforce remainder of agreement by agreeing to ceiling price renewable each month. D Seller argued that contract unenforceable b/c agreement to agree. o Holding: The contract is unenforceable because it did not set an exact price and length of term for remaining months. o Policy: For the court to supply “reasonable” terms would be unfair since they would be writing a contract that the parties may not intended. This is different from Raffles because in that circumstance court could assume that a contract was intended. Sub-question 2: Was There Consideration? *ALWAYS ASK (KEY questions): (1) Who has been benefited (2) Who is being asked to pay. If (1) and (2) are the same person, then look to doctrine of moral consideration. If (1) and (2) different people, look to doctrine of past consideration. 13 DEFINITION: The formation of a contract requires consideration. §71(1) defines consideration in terms of a bargain. To constitute consideration, a performance or a return promise must be bargained for. §71(2) defines “bargained for” as “a performance or a return of promise is bargained for if it sought by the promisor in exchange for his promise and given by the promisee in exchange for that promise.” §71(3) states that “the performance may consist of . . . (b) a forebearance [not doing something which you have a legal right to do such as in Hammer v. Sidway or not speeding around the area (which is legal, you just have to pay the fines for it if you get caught)] §79 Adequacy of Consideration; Mutuality of Obligation ANY consideration is fine. The Bargain does NOT have to be objectively fair. §81 Consideration as a Motive or Inducing Cause Consideration does not have to be the PRIMARY motive. It just can’t be a NOMINAL motive. §86 Promise for Past Benefit (1) MORAL CONSIDERATION: Restatement §86: Belated compensation for a past benefit is binding to prevent injustice as long as the person promising payment was the same person that received the prior benefit. (Webb v. McGowin) Negative Example: where the person promising to compensate for past benefit is NOT the same person upon whom the benefit was bestowed (such as where the mom promised to pay for the benefit that was conferred upon the son) (Mills v. Wyman) Policy (for moral consideration): An express promise to pay for debts a person accrued is supported by good consideration b/c the promise removes a legal impediment for the recovery of debts honestly due. (2) PAST CONSIDERATION (an exception to moral consideration): Where a benefit was bestowed in the past (consideration) a promise is NOT binding for “moral reasons” when it was clear that such a benefit was a gratuitous gift and the promisor has not been unjustly enriched. 14 Example: When the consideration is executed when an individual renders services such as fortune telling, this consideration cannot be used as consideration for a promise that occurs later when it is not implied at the time the consideration happened that it would be used for a later promise. (Moore v. Elmer, promise to pay for mortgage unenforceable since at the time that fortune telling services occurred there was no implication that that such services would later be used as consideration) Policy in Distinguishing Bargains from Gratuitous Promises: Contract law will not enforce a promise on its own which is not supported by good, sufficient, or adequate consideration (1) Gratuitous Promises: What would parties have done ex-ante: Most likely, if making default rule, both parties would want gratuitous promise NOT to be binding, b/c you want to encourage donations. a. Need for legal enforcement is low b/c people are morally motivated to donate so usually they don’t need incentives to follow through with his/her promise. i. However, if the party seeking enforcement of a charitable gift can prove detrimental reliance, the court is more likely to enforce (Hammer as opposed to Johnson) b. The Fear of Deterring Promises is high b/c we want to encourage people to make charitable donations without fearing that if their financial situation changes, they can’t back out. c. Because the motives of the estate defer from the motives of the deceased, judges will be particularly careful to enforce intent of deceased by upholding charitable promises the deceased has made. (Hammer & Webb as opposed to Johnson) -- This is particularly obvious in the cases of when one’s life or limb has been protected or saved (as in Cotnam v. Wisdom). (2) Commercial Interactions a. Need for legal enforcement is high b/c so as to ensure that when one engages in a commercial exchange, the commercial exchange will be valid. This is particularly true in “one-time bargains” where the party has no motivation to pay once goods are delivered or alternatively the seller might attempt to coerce more money out of the buyer when his back is to the wall. 15 b. Generally we don’t want to deter people from entering into commercial contracts b/c it is good for the efficiency of the economy. (3) Ways to Make Gratuitous Promise Binding: i. $1 nominal exchange ii. Take money, then transfer it back interest-free. Possibility 1: Was it a Gift or was it a Bargain? Rule 1: A promise of a monetary gift may be revoked at any time prior to payment because there is no consideration to form a contract. THUS Gift promises are revocable up until the time that they are delivered (Johnson) Rule 2: A waiver of a legal right at the request of another party may serve as sufficient consideration for a promise (Hammer) Case 1: Johnson v. Otterbein (gratuitous promise; no detrimental reliance) Facts: Johnson signed and delivered an instrument by which he promised to donate $100 to the University (P) at a future time, asking that this donation be applied to help University pay back its debt. However he refused to make such payment when the time came and the University tried to enforce as a contract. Holding: No contract existed because Johnson did not have any consideration for his promise to make a $100 donation. Further, the University did not detrimentally rely upon P’s promise. The University already has an obligation to spend funds properly and pay off debts thus P’s request that his donation be applied to debt is not additional consideration. Case 2: Hammer v Sidway (Bargain and consideration) Facts: Uncle promised to pay his nephew $5,000 in exchange for refraining from smoking, drinking alcohol, swearing, or playing cards for money until the age of 21 (all of which he was legally allowed to do). The nephew consented and fully performed the conditions. He wrote his uncle to request payment on his 21st birthday. Uncle agreed but asked to hold on to the money until the nephew was responsible enough. Uncle died. Nephew’s debt was assigned to a third party. Case was brought by a third party against the estate seeking to enforce the promise as a contract. 16 Holding: Nephew’s willingness to refrain from legal rights constitutes consideration and thus promise of $5,000 enforceable as this was clearly the Uncle’s intent. Note: This was within the Statute of Frauds since the agreement was to last more than one year. Thus it should have been in writing but this was waived by the (D) and not addressed by the court. Case 3: Kirskey v Kirksey (gratuitous promise) p. 629 Facts: P was sister-in-law of D, P’s husband died, D wrote a letter advising her to sell her land and move onto his, whereupon he would house her and her family. P abandoned her house, but didn’t sell it, and moved to D’s, 60 miles away. After two years, he kicked her out. Holding: Promise on part of D was mere gratuity, no consideration, so no action. Court held for D. Case 4: Dahl v. Hem (Bargain and consideration) p. 635 Facts: P participated in experimental program that was voluntary. Deal was “if you submit to our experiment, we will give you a year’s supply of Ampligen at no charge.” Holding: Court says this was a unilateral contract. Upon completion of tests, there was a binding contract, and D owed P Ampligen. Possibility 2: Was there moral consideration? Rule 1: §86: Generally moral consideration is sufficient consideration EXCEPT when the promisor personally PREVIOUSLY received NO benefit in exchange for his promise. (MILLS) Policy (for this holding): IF we start enforcing this type of obligation against third parties, who have accrued no personal benefit it is a slippery slope b/c what separates this from forcing people in general to do what they always morally ought to do. Rule 2: A moral obligation is a sufficient consideration to support a subsequent promise to pay where the promisor has received a material benefit for which he subsequently and expressly promised to pay. Policy (for moral consideration): An express promise to pay for debts a person accrued is supported by good consideration b/c the promise removes a legal impediment for the recovery of debts honestly due. 17 Case 1: Mills v. Wyman (not directly benefited nor previous encumbrance) Facts: Wyman (D)’s 25 year old son (not a minor), fell ill upon returning from a voyage at sea. Mill’s (P) acting as a good Samaratin gave son shelter and took care of him. He still died. After death, (D) mother wrote (P) caretaker a letter promising to pay for expenses associated with caretaking. But later revoked offer and refused payment. (P) brought suit. Holding: Moral obligation is only sufficient consideration where benefit was previously bestowed upon promisor. Thus there was no consideration since no benefit was directly bestowed upon the mother. Policy (for this holding): IF we start enforcing this type of obligation against third parties, who have accrued no personal benefit it is a slippery slope b/c what separates this from forcing people in general to do what they always morally ought to do. Policy (against this holding): In viewing agreement ex-ante, mother would have likely agreed to pay. o COUNTER: Son is an adult and able to enter into his own promises to pay since innkeeper did not request payment it was likely a gift. Case 2: Webb v. McGowin (personally benefited) Facts: Webb (P) an employee for a lumber company saved McGowin’s life when he was about to throw a piece of timber of the ledge and saw McGowin and thus fell with the timber to avoid serious injury or death to McGowin. Instead P was seriously injured in the fall. McGowin, in exchange for Webb having saved his life, promised to pay $15 every 2 weeks to care for Webb. McGowin did so up until the time of his death at which point payment stopped. Webb sued estate to continue support payments. Holding: McGowin’s moral obligation is sufficient consideration to support his promise of payments since he received the material benefit of his life being saved. Thus contract upheld by court. Examining policy above: (1) There is a need for legal enforcement b/c we want in the future people who are making moral promises to pay for past benefits to know that there was a clear default rule that such agreements are enforceable. THUS avoiding the need for litigation. (2) This will not be deterring these types of promises b/c people usually have moral motives. (3) Ex-ante, we know that the person who received the 18 benefit of his life being saved, would have agreed to payments for such a benefit. Possibility 3: Was it past consideration? Rule: Where a benefit was bestowed in the past (consideration), a promise is NOT binding for “moral reasons” when it was clear that such a benefit was a gift and the promisor has not been unjustly enriched. Case 1: Moore v. Elmer Facts: At Elmer (D)’s request , (P), a clairvoyant, performed fortune telling services. She predicted that (D) would die by a certain date. (D) promised that if he did die by that date, he would pay off (P)’s mortgage. (D) died before that date and (P) sued for mortgage money. Holding: There was no contract b/c there was no consideration when (D) made his promise to pay the mortgage if predication came true SINCE the fortune telling benefit bestowed upon (D) occurred before the promise and was completely separate from it. ****Note: Past consideration is only considered binding for a promise IF at the time of service there is an IMPLIED AGREEMENT to pay. Possibility 4: Was a contract modified with new consideration? UCC §2-209: Modification, Rescission, and Waiver (1) An agreement modifying a contract within this article needs no consideration to be binding… COMMENT 2: For a modification to become binding, it must meet the “test of good faith.” §89 Modification of Executory Contract A promise modifying a duty under a contract not fully performed on either side is binding (a) if the modification is fair and equitable in view of circumstances (not Stilk and Alaska) (b) to the extent provided by statute (c) to the extent that justice requires enforcement in view of material change of position in reliance on the promise. 19 **Difference: Generally UCC gives more weight to enforcing modifications whereas the Restatement only allows modifications to the extent that they are what fair and justice requires. But both involve notions of good faith. Why do we want to be able to modify without new consideration? We are looking at balancing between two situations: o Don’t want to give parties incentive to hold other hostage and make terms better o On the other hand, if placed in that situation, don’t want to not allow the other party to contract to avoid the worse of the two evils. Ex ante perspective: Sailors want to be able to modify. Sailor’s bosses want to be able to modify, too, or else there in the future there will be no reason for sailors to listen to him. POLICY: By having these good faith requirements, both the UCC and the Restatement are balancing the competing interests of “freedom of contract” (present interest) and the desire not to encourage future crimes (future interest). Cases: Stilk v. Myrick AND Alaska Packers (PRE – EXISTING DUTY RULE, no longer applied b/c of UCC and Restatement) Facts: o Stilk: Captain needed increased effort of sailors and promised the sailors the extra pay he would have given the deserted sailors, b/c 2 sailors deserted and captain could not find replacements. o Alaska: Sailors, once at sea, attempted to coerce greater pay from captain and threatened to quit if their demands were not met. Captain agreed to increase pay b/c he was already out at sea and could not find replacements BUT said he didn’t have the authority to make such a decision. Holdings: Neither agreement was enforceable since modifications were not based on any additional consideration of the sailors aside from their pre-existing duty assigned in their original contracts. Policy Differences in Outcomes: o Stilk: 20 Weaker party, captain, was the one offering modification (Katz thinks wrong to not enforce this as consideration) Windfall: Captain was able to pay less for the same amount of work and thus his promise would have given him what he bargained for the same price he initially bargained for it. o Alaska: Stronger party, sailors, attempting to coerce modification. Windfall: if contract was upheld, the sailors would have gotten more money for the contract and work that they had already bargained for. Possibility 5: Was the consideration adequate? Rule 1: The law does not require that consideration be “adequate” meaning that it be commensurate with what the party accepting it is giving up. Slight consideration suffices to make a contract enforceable even though this may be consistent at times with coercion. Exception 1: When nothing is really exchanged for something of value, the court won’t enforce the contract (Newman). In order for a contract to be valid, valuable consideration must be exchanged by BOTH parties. Exception 2: When consideration is CLEARLY nominal as in the case of exchanging unequal monetary values, the Court won’t enforce the agreement. (Schnell v. Nell). A contract will be vitiated for lack of consideration where the consideration is ONLY nominal and is intended to be so. (but WHEN the consideration has subjective value as in the case of the exchange of an heirloom coin). Case 1: Newman & Snell’s State Bank v. Hunter Facts: Bank held worthless collateral of deceased man’s stock note to pay off his debt. Bank convinced the wife to exchange a promissory note stating that she was willing to pay off a certain some of money in the future in order to pay off her husband’s debt and clear his good name in exchange for the WORTHLESS stock note. Holding: One party is not allowed to exchange something valuable for NOTHING. Thus there was no adequate consideration and no contract. The IOU is UNENFORCEABLE. Case 2: Schnell v. Nell 21 Facts: (D)’s widow had promised three people that he would honor his wife’s will in which she left $200 to three parties in exchange for one penny and their promise not to file suit to enforce will. (Wife hadn’t owned any property in her own name and thus money couldn’t originally be given to the three people as it had been assigned in the will). Holding: A court will only look into the adequacy of consideration when it appears that one party’s exchange is nominal OR where the two things exchanged have no subjective value as in the case of money. The Court determined that the beneficaries promise to pay a penny was inadequate consideration in exchange for the $200. Both of which had no SUBJECTIVE VALUE. Policy (Counter): One could argue that the agreement not to file lawsuit to recover based on will was consideration for the $200 settlement. Sub-question 3: If there was not Consideration was there Promissory Estoppel (detrimental reliance)? The doctrine of Promissory Estoppel: An alternative basis on which to enforce a promise that is not quite in the realm of contract law but is necessary in certain situations to avoid substantial Injustice. It is invoked when (1) A promise has been made that would reasonably be expected to induce action or forbearance on the party of the promisee or third person (Jury ?) (2) And which does induce such reasonable action or forbearance (Jury ?) (3) Justice cannot be avoided unless the promise is enforced (**Court policy question) – this step is there as a “catch all” so as to make this doctrine applicable very widely and to guarantee against unequal bargaining power. (§90 Promise Reasonably Inducing Action or Forbearance) Note: If promissory estoppel is used, no need to look to traditional elements of a contract i.e. offer/acceptance/consideration. Only need to show detrimental reliance as a result of negotiations. Default rule of Damages for Promissory Estoppel: RELIANCE b/c there is not an actual contract. Thus, expectation damages would be too harsh. 22 Policy (for) Often negotiations can induce detrimental reliance in such a way that enforcement is neither covered by contracts or torts (tortious misrepresentation) BUT there still exists a need to prevent injustice. This helps to alleviate problems of unequal bargaining power. Some of the time, including maybe franchisee and contractor/subcontractor cases, it is reasonable to place substantial reliance on things outside of contract setting. In those cases only, Section 90 fills a hole. Policy (against) “DEATH OF CONTRACTS”: This doctrine casts a shadow over contracts in the United States b/c people might fear entering into ANY negotiations as a preliminary to contracts for fear that if negotiations fall through, one party will try to invoke detrimental reliance to seek monetary damages. There is something nice about having a bright line rule that defines what is in the realm of contracts i.e. offer/acceptance/consideration and what is clearly not a contract. Where would this stop?? This bright line rule decreases transactions & litigation costs. Problem with applying promissory estoppel to written agreements is the Parol Evidence Rule b/c you would have to prove that the document is not a completely integrated agreement. And even if you proved it wasn’t integrated, you then have to prove that NO contract agreement existed. Rule 1: Justice and fair-dealing require that one who by his language or conduct leads another to do what he would not otherwise had done shall not subject such persons to loss or injury by disappointing the expectations upon which he acted (Goodman & Red Owl) Rule 2 (Damages): (A) P cannot recover for damages that P would have accrued even in the absence of a breach (Red Owl & Hooker, etc.) (B) While third parties which rely on the promise are not normally entitled to recover based on detrimental reliance, in cases where it is reasonably foreseeable that the third party would be injured based on reliance, such damages are recoverable. Case 1: Goodman v. Dicker Facts: Local radio distributors (D) promised to supply prospective franchisees (P) with radios from franchisor. Franchisees were led to 23 believe that the franchise would be granted and thus were induced to incur expenses by hiring salesmen in taking radio orders. BUT no radios were delivered and notice was given that franchise wouldn’t be granted. If there had been a franchise agreement made, the agreement would have included a cancellation clause which entitled the franchisor to end the agreement at will with no penalty. Holding: Despite the fact that there was not a contract, justice and fair dealing require that the radio distributors should be made to pay for the damages incurred by P’s in relying on obtaining a franchise. But no consequential damages (for loss of possible profits). Policy (against this holding): o The court did not even take note of the fact that if a contract had been made it would have included a cancellation clause. Thus there develops a Parol Evidence problem whereby the court is not just looking at the “Four Corners of the Contract” o COUNTER: this wasn’t a contract. How can P been entitled to more than he would have gotten if the contract had been entered into (b/c of cancellation clause) COUNTER: whether there was a contract or not, the Court would have issued reliance damages. o The court could have done the following: used the ordinary tort of misrepresentation b/c the P’s thought that they were directly dealing with the franchisor. Found that there was an oral agreement at an earlier stage of negotiation (and thus a contract) Found that there was option contract. Case 2: Hoffman v. Red Owl Stores Facts: Hoffman and wife owned a bakery but were interested in expanding business and thus entered into discussions with Red Owl about obtaining a franchise. At the encouragement of Red Owl representatives, P sold the bakery and bought a small grocery store to gain experience. P also placed a deposit on a lot where the store was to be located and moved to that new location with his family. Red Owl kept increasing the investment costs which the P would have to pay. Hoffman unable to pay 24 the increased demands terminated negotiations and filed suit for detrimental reliance. Holding: Since Red Owl could reasonably expect that their promises would induce such action in the Hoffmans as selling their store, moving, etc. such expenses are recoverable based on detrimental reliance despite the fact that a contract doesn’t exist and the terms of a potential contract are indefinite. Damages: o (1) Third party (Mrs. Hoffman)’s share of the business was recoverable even though she was not involved in negotiations b/c she was forced to sell her share in reliance on the promise COUNTER-- Mrs. Hoffman stands at the vortex. While her damage is foreseeable, it is also foreseeable that others, such as suppliers or the children, would be damaged by the failure of the contract. BUT there has to be a limit to infinite ramifications. o (2) DOUBLE COUNTING ARGUMENT: Lost Profits of small grocery store NOT recoverable even though Hoffmans sold before busy summer season. If it were, it would be “double counting” b/c presumably the fact that busy summer season that was coming up allowed P’s to get a higher price for the property, taking into account future profits. (same problem in Hooker) Case 3: Cohen v. Cowles Facts: Cohen working for candidate in gubanatorial campaign. He found what he believed to be “dirt” in the form of police records on the other candidate. Cohen contacted various media outlets and said that he would give them dirt in exchange for promising to keep his name confidential. Reporters promised that they would try and keep their name confidential but it was ultimately up to their editors. Newspapers discovered after investigation that “dirt” was in reality not damaging since candidate had reasonable explanation. Thus the story then became Cohen’s attempts at a smear campaign and editors made decision to report his name. MN SC for D. 25 Holding (of US SC): (1) Ruling on promissory estoppel would not violate the first Amendment b/c newspapers cannot break the law. (2) Both parties were morally blameworthy, not just Cohen in his smear campaign but also the reporters in not upholding their promise. Found for P. Holding (of Minnesota Supreme Court on remand) – dealing with justice: The imposition of damages is necessary to avoid an unjust result whereby Cohen relied upon a promise of anonymity and as a result of the breach of the promise lost his job. Policy (against): Informal social agreements are not generally thought to be binding i.e. stop crying and I’ll take you to Disney Land. o COUNTER: This is not a “friends and family” social situation. Politics and news are both serious businesses. 26 3: WHAT ARE THE TERMS OF THE AGREEMENT? 12/20/2010 5:24:00 AM Question 3: What are the terms of the Agreement? Sub-question 1: Can the court go beyond the “four-corners” of the document? Rule: Court can use parol evidence to determine whether agreement is integrated (Brown). If it is integrated, parole evidence will not be admitted. §209 Integrated agreement – (1) is a final expression of one or more terms of an agreement (2) the court has the power to determine whether there is an integrated agreement; (3) where the parties reduce an agreement to a writing which reasonable appears to be complete, it is taken to be an integrated agreement UNLESS it is established by other evidence that the writing did not constitute a final expression o Question is: whether we can look to parol evidence to determine if it’s an integrated agreement: Brown YES, Thompson NO §210 – Completely Integrated Agreement: An agreement can be integrated without being complete. §213 – Effective of Integrated Agreement on Prior Agreements (PAROLE EVIDENCE RULE) – (1) a binding integrated agreement discharges prior inconsistent agreements; (2) a binding completely integrated agreement also discharges any prior agreements to the extent they are within the written contract’s scope (an area covered by the agreement) §214 – Evidence of Prior or Contemporaneous Agreements and Negotiations [Exceptions] – agreements and negotiations prior to the contract are admissible to establish (a) that the writing is or isn’t an integrated agreement (b) that the integrated agreement is completely or partially integrated; (c) that the meaning of the writing, whether or not integrated; (d) illegality, fraud, duress, mistake; lack of consideration or other invalidating cause; (e) ground for granting or denying recession, reformation, specific performance or other remedy. §216. Consistent additional terms – (1) are admissible to supplement a non-completely integrated agreement; (2) an agreement is not integrated if the writing omits a consistent additional agreed term which is 27 (a) agreed to for separate consideration (b) such a term as in the circumstances might naturally be omitted from the writing UCC § 2-202 – Final Written Expression: Parol or Extrinsic Evidence – Terms of a final written agreement may not be contradicted by evidence of any prior written agreement or contemporaneous oral agreement BUT may be explained or supplemented by (a) course of dealing or usage of trade (Frigaliment) (b) by evidence of consistent additional terms unless the court finds that the writing was intended as a complete and exclusive statement of the terms of the agreement (Brown) Case 1: Thompson v. Libbey (Four Corners rule- not consistent with restatement) p. 488 o Facts: (P) Seller sells logs to (D) buyer. Buyer refuses to pay full price b/c claims there was a warranty which was not written in the contract regarding the quality of the logs. P brings suit to enforce contract. o Holding 1: Since the contract imports on its face to be a complete expression of the whole agreement it is to be assumed that the parties introduced into it every material term and parole evidence INADMISSABLE to ADD another term to the agreement. o Holding 2: Integration must be determined solely from the document and not outside evidence (FOUR CORNERS RULE) o Policy: We don’t want to allow evidence from one’s “slippery mind” to interfere with written agreement. Case 2: Brown v. Oliver p.489 o Facts: (P) Buyer purchases plot of land with a hotel on it from D. There was oral evidence that sale included hotel furniture. 2 years later when D was leasing hotel from P he took the furniture from the hotel in the middle of the night. The contract was silent as to whether the furniture was included. o Holding: Parol Evidence allowed to establish if written agreement intended to embody whole transaction [ie integrated agreement]. If yes evidence immaterial. If no go to jury. Here, PE was rightfully admitted. Case 3: Pacific Gas v. Thomas p. 494 o Facts: D entered into contract with P to perform work on steam turbine. In contract D agreed to indemnify P from any injury to 28 property. Later when P’s property was damaged they called on D to pay for damage. D argued that the indemnity language only related to damage cause to 3rd party’s property and not to P’s property, based on prior dealings. Agreement actually says this is integrated agreement. o Holding: Extrinsic evidence as to the terms of the agreement is ALWAYS admissible to clarify intent of the parties as long as it does not add to, detract from or vary the terms of the written contract but helps determine the meaning of the contract. Words can only mean what parties intend them to mean. [No contract on its FACE can be PE-proof] Case 4: Trident v. Connecticut General p. 497 o Facts: (P) partnership negotiated with lender (D) to borrow $56 million to buy building. Terms of the contract said that contract can not be repaid in full for the first 12 years. It also included a clause whereby the lender AT ITS OPTION could demand payment in full of loan with pre-payment fee if the borrowers defaulted. (P) brought this suit seeking declaratory judgment that it could pre-pay loan in full now since the interests rates dropped. o Holding: Even though the agreement could not be more unambiguous on its face, Kozinski reluctantly allows parol evidence as to the defaulting clause due to Pacific Gas decision which makes all agreements open to Parol evidence (even if MERGER CLAUSE states that the contract is a complete and integrated agreement) o Policy: PE allowed in, but court is reluctant because (1) it is a waste of the courts time and money in the case of an unambiguous agreement, (2) it leaves a cloud of doubt over all contracts formed in CA, (3) if parties want to contract around it [“this is an integrated agreement”] they should be able to. o Note: Katz says there are 3 reasons FOR Parol Evidence: Truth Finding Efficiency of court system But, not really truth finding, because it may be more accurate to hear the parol evidence. So it’s really about efficiency. So, in the event of 2 parties wanting to contract around PE rule, isn’t it most efficient to let them? 29 Sub-question 2: What can the external evidence do? Possibility 1: External evidence can correct mistakes (214d) Case 1: Hypo Typo o Facts/Holding: Buyer and seller have oral agreement to sell house for $100,000. Written agreement states all material terms but says $90,000. The court can hear evidence to correct typo error. Possibility 2: External evidence can explain ambiguity (214c) Case 1: Frigaliment (what is chicken?) Possibility 3: If agreed that it is not integrated, external evidence can add to terms of writing if agreement silent as to those terms, as long as the terms do not contradict written agreement (216) Case 1: Brown (Agreement silent as to hotel furniture) §214 – Evidence of Prior or Contemporaneous Agreements and Negotiations [Exceptions] – agreements and negotiations prior to the contract are admissible to establish (a) that the writing is or isn’t an integrated agreement (b) that the integrated agreement is completely or partially integrated; (c) that the meaning of the writing, whether or not integrated; (d) illegality, fraud, duress, mistake; lack of consideration or other invalidating cause; (e) ground for granting or denying recession, reformation, specific performance or other remedy. 30 4: Breach 3/9/2016 4:25:00 PM Question 4: Has there been a breach? Sub-question 1: Was the contract performed under “good faith”? If not, breach. Rule: In every contract there is an implied covenant that neither party will do anything that will have the effect of destroying or injuring the right of the other party to receive the fruits of the contract which means in every contract there exists an implied covenant of “good faith and fair dealing.” (Kire La Shelle Co. v. Paul Armstrong) POLICY: o If good faith had to be explicit, (1) you would have to draw out all potential things that could go wrong (2) it might discourage people from entering into that contract. o Tries to enforce what the parties would have done ex-ante had they known that the bad outcome would have resulted UCC §1-203: Every contract or duty within this act imposes an obligation of good faith in its performance or enforcement UCC §1-201: Definition of Good faith: Honesty in fact in the conduct or transaction concerned. UCC §2-103 (1)(b): Good faith in the case of a merchant: means “honesty in fact” and the observance of reasonable commercial standards and fair dealing. UCC §1-102(3): You **can’t contract around good faith requirement BUT you can subject the requirement to standards agreed to by the party. Restatement §205: Every contract imposes upon each party a duty of good faith and fair dealing in its performance and its enforcement. Good faith performance or enforcement of a contract emphasizes faithfulness to an agreed common purpose and consistency with the justified expectations of the other party; it excludes “bad faith” which violates standards of decency, fairness, or reasonableness. Case 1: Goldberg 168-05 Corp v. Levy Facts: P, lessor, entered into a lease to rent property to Levy for a certain amount per month + 10% of gross revenue from business. There was a stipulation that if business didn’t gross in excess of a certain amount, D, tenant, had the right to 31 terminate the lease. P sought damages based on Levy’s intentional divergence of profits to another one of his area’s stores, so as to reduce his rental payments and trigger the stipulation. Holding: Even though tenant didn’t violate the express terms of the contract, there nevertheless exists a requirement of good faith and fair dealing implicit in every contract which the Court found that tenant did violate. Case 2: HYPO: What if the landlord slept with the tenant’s wife? Does that constitute a breach of the good faith requirement? Holding: Look to what the parties would have done ex – ante: they probably would have agreed to a cancellation of the contract in the event of an affair. Sub-question 2: Was there an express waiver of a condition of the contract, rather than a modification of a promise (like Alaska)? Rule 1: § 84 - A non-material condition can be waived without the parties having to renegotiate the contract. Policy: o This is distinct from Stilk and Alaska, where there was a material modification of a promise, the Court required ADDITIONAL consideration. o Waivers are recognized absent consideration or worry of coercion b/c the waiver doctrine is limited to modest modifications of immaterial conditions. o The rationale is that if the contract had been formulated better, the condition would have been more flexible – EX: Courts are willing to permit waivers for time and place of deliver clauses and contracts. o (1) Courts don’t want to give one party an easy out by pointing to a technical difference in performance of the contract (2) Courts want to allow for minor modifications without imposing additional transaction costs upon the parties. Case 1: Chirichella v. Erwin, p. 866 (Not a condition precedent) Facts: Buyers expect to get house on October 1, but clause that said “Settlement of new home in Kettering – Approx. Oct ‘71” was the move-in date. New Kettering settlement never happened, so sellers never moved out. Sellers claimed this settlement was a condition precedent, since it 32 didn’t happen, didn’t need to vacate. Buyers say it’s a “point in time which the parties have contemplated a performance.” Holding: Looking at intent through wording, NOT condition precedent, so Chirichellas need to vacate. Case 2: Clark v. West p. 869 Facts: D West entered into contract with P Clark whereby Clark was to write a multi volume treatise on corporations for West. Contract contained a payment clause which stated that Clark was to receive $6/page if abstained from liquor during the contract or $2/page if he drank. D wrote one book which P accepted and disseminated but only offered $2/page. P claims that there was an express waiver of the sobriety condition. Holding 1 (condition): A condition such as sobriety may be waived because it was not a material part of the contract. The writing for the treatise rather than the abstinence was the bargained for consideration. o Here waiver wasn’t necessarily allowed b/c case was remanded for further fact finding on whether there was an express waiver. So court doesn’t consider damages. Note: Case could be pursued in following manners: o Liquidated Damage: Could this condition ($2/$6) be read as a liquidated damage clause that is reasonable based on the editor foreseeing a $4 cost of editing per page incurred if (P) wrote drunk? Yes, on ex-ante basis. P could argue this is punishment, not allowed. o Contract modification: P could say that the contract was modified, and that no consideration is needed. Sub-question 3: Are there implied conditions that were not complied with? (if yes, breach) *situations in which even though one party did not fully perform, he is seeking to enforce the other party’s promise Rule 1 (Implied Condition Precedent): Conditions in a contract are dependent meaning that a party’s performance is contingent upon the execution of prior conditions by the other party. (Kingston v. Preston) 33 Policy (constructive conditions doctrine): A condition that is not expressly stated in or implied by the terms of an agreement, but is imposed by law, due to considerations of fairness in that it would not be fair to impose only one side of the contract out of fear that the other breach might later become a moot point. Note: If there is something very minor that one has not complied with in terms of his promise, he can still bring suit for the opponent’s breach of performance. Rule 2 (Mutual Conditions): Conditions are such that they are to be performed at the same time. (Exchange of Goods in which if one party does not perform, the other party who is ready to perform may have an action for default of the other which excuses the first party’s non-performance) Common Law (no longer applies): Actions for breach were mutually independent of each other and non-performance by one party couldn’t be used to excuse the ready party’s non-performance. Case 1: Kingston v. Preston (Condition Precedent) p.880 Facts: Preston, silk merchant, agreed to sell his business to Kingston in exchange for a number of things including sufficient security paid by Kingston for the business. Kingston sues Preston when Preston didn’t hand over the business despite the fact that he had not given adequate security. Holding: Security deposit was an implied condition precedent necessary to hold Preston to his promise to hand over the business. Policy (Justice argument): If this court had followed the Common Law rule and enforced Preston’s promise to hand over the business, Preston would not be able to recover his security deposit from Kingston who had no money if the latter ran the business into the ground. o If we only honor one side of the contract and force one to bring a separate lawsuit to deal with a separate breach, the separate breach might become a moot point later on. Case 2: Morton v. Lamb (Mutual Condition) p. 882 Facts: (P) buyer suing (D) seller for non performance of the contract when (D) didn’t deliver corn BUT (P) hadn’t given money. Holding: (P) cannot recover from (D) since the conditions were “concurrent” whereby in order for (P) to sue for non performance, (P) had 34 to have had been ready to pay for the corn at the same time that (D) would deliver the corn. Sub-question 4: (1) Does there need to be perfect performance? (2) What are the damages? (Cost of completion vs. Diminution of Value) Default Rule: One must in good faith attempt to perform with the terms of the contract or correct deficiencies where doing so is not prohibitively expensive. Cardozo Substantial Performance Rule (only where the cost of complying with the terms of the contract would be prohibitively expensive in that the amount expended by the performer would be far greater than the benefit bestowed upon the other party): In such cases, substantial performance is acceptable provided that the breaching party pay as damages any difference in value between what was received and what was contracted for. (Jacob & Peevyhouse) UCC§2-106 & 2-601 Perfect Tender Rule: A buyer is allowed to repudiate the contract if the sellers’ product or delivery does not conform to the terms of the contract. This rule however also gives the seller a chance, before the date of the contract and in certain circumstances for a reasonable period after, to cure any defects. But where the seller fails to cure defects, buyer may repudiate or terminate contract. (Ramirez) Restatement §241 comment (b): Follows perfect tender rule but is more lenient in giving breaching party an opportunity to cure (Groves) POLICY (use these factors where fact pattern says jurisdiction is “divided” as to perfect tender or substantial performance rule): 1. Cardozo/Peevyhouse view of Substantial Performance: ECON/POLICY a. Economic Waste (Inefficiency): If we make it too easy to repudiate or insist upon holding parties to a perfect standard, it will be economically wasteful. The amount of money spent to cure a defect in certain cases is wasteful since the corresponding benefit bestowed is not comparable. COUNTER: Freedom of Contracts: (1) People should have the right to contract for whatever they want. (2) While it may not be materially comparable in value, it may be subjectively comparable COUNTER: Coasean Bargaining: It doesn’t matter if the court’s holding is efficient or inefficient since the parties will come to an agreement 35 whereby whoever values either doing the work or not doing the work more will pay the other party. Also, at the end it doesn’t mean the pipes are going to be replaced, owner will only use the $ to replace the pipes if he REALLY wants the pipes, which doesn’t mean to seem that wasteful. b. Opportunistic Behavior of the Parties in the Course of Setting a Remedy: In determining which is the better default rule, we look to how parties would opportunistically exploit the rule to determine which rule would be better. Under the Cardozo regime, parties will try to exploit the rule by aiming for substantial performance and making up for any difference in value. Under the perfect tender rule, people will be able to get out of contracts by technical minor, non-performances [nitpicking]. Under the later regime, it would be onerous and courts would be flooded with cases whereby every immaterial modification would have to be renegotiated at higher transaction costs to the parties. People would be reluctant to enter into these relationships at all. Thus the opportunistic behavior of parties under the Cardozo rule would be less damaging to society in general. c. Ex Ante Perspective – If owners and contractors got to plan their doctrine, which one would they choose? If cost of completion, contractors will raise the prices a lot. So owners may not want cost of completion. MORAL/DOCTRINAL d. Unjust Enrichment: Where a party does not actually subjectively value the improvements or the condition to the amount that it would actually cost to fix the property, any settlement they received would be a windfall in unjust enrichment: COUNTER: If the other way, the breaching party is receiving a windfall by not fully performing the contract when the party knew in advance what all of the conditions of the contract would cost them and still signed the contract. COUNTER: If there were a perfect tender rule, the contractor charges a higher price for the time, expense, and frustration of effectuating the other side’s perfectionist demands. e. Coherence of Torts: In torts, the measure of damages is based on bringing the person back to where they were before the tort occurred. Cardozo’s view is more 36 coherent with this notion. If you were to apply the Perfect Tender rule in torts it would be akin to strict liability. f. Mitigation of Damages: In contract law, a non-breaching party has the requirement to mitigate damages done. Since the non-breaching party, here, is required to accept the substantial performance and damages are only based on the difference in value, the non-breaching party is forced to mitigate damages. COUNTER: Perfect Tender Rule allows people to contract around mitigation. Also: mitigation rule is to protect against waste. Here, not clear that there is waste to begin with! g. General view that Contract Law Takes Towards Keeping Promises: Contract law does not take the moral view that contracts are sacrosanct. Rather, contract law allows you to either perform or compensate, thus allowing for efficient breaches. 2. Ramirez/Groves view of PERFECT TENDER: ECON/POLICY a. Only way to help perfectionists: Since courts are weary of awarding liquidated damages, it would be very hard for a “perfectionist” party to get specifically what they want, like the Reading Pipe, since in a contract the court would view a liquidated damage clause that was meant to enforce perfect performance as a penalty clause. b. Encourage better contracts: Perfect tender might not be the right default rule but it will force parties to be more explicit about what they want. By picking the rule that people wouldn’t want, parties will have to be more explicit to get what they do want, whereas substantial performance allows people to be lazy and more ambiguous. MORAL/DOCTRINAL c. Autonomy/Freedom of Contracts: The core aspect of freedom of contracts is violated if we go with Cardozo’s approach since it interferes with party’s ability to bargain since one party can substitute substantial performance in place of what the other party actually bargained for. COUNTER: When completion of the contract is minimally more than the substantial performance, this is not a big problem. (Peevyhouse) A. Services: can only seek damages (not repudiation of contract) 37 Case 1: Jacob and Youngs v. Kent (CARDOZO – diminution of value) p. 883 Facts: Construction company (P) suing homebuyer Kent for nonpayment of balance of $4000. Homebuyer D claiming as defense that P didn’t fully perform, b/c contract said only Reading pipe was to be used in the plumbing. Holding: Since here, in order for P to correct the piping defficiency he would have to knock down a substantial portion of the already built house, where the objective benefit to the homebuyer based on the difference of quality of pipe used would be negligible. Thus, it is sufficient that the contractor had performed substantially and did not breach in bad faith. Thus, the measure of damages is diminution in value. Case 2: Groves v. John Wunder (Deliberate breach – Cost of Completion) p. 929 Facts: Groves leased a tract of land to D for purpose of excavating and screening gravel with the condition that D return the land in a substantially uniform grade. D deliberately breached the contract by removing the richest gravel and leaving the premises rugged and uneven. Holding: EVEN THOUGH cost of completing the contract i.e. returning the gravel to a uniform grade would cost $60,000 which was more than the benefit Groves would receive in terms of value of the land by completion of contract, the court holds that despite substantial performance, (D)’s breach was willful and lacked good faith and measure of damages is cost of completion. Case 3: Peevyhouse v. Garland Coal Mining (Deliberate breach – Diminution of Value) p. 934 Facts: P leased a farm to D for the purposes of mining coal deposits on the land. Incidental to this agreement, D agreed to perform restorative work at the end of the lease. Despite substantial performance of the mining contract, D did not restore the farm. Holding: The main contract was for the mining which was performed. The restoration was merely incidental to the main purpose. Thus, the costs to the D of restoring the farm would significantly outweigh the benefits to 38 the farm owner in terms of property value. Diminution of value is thus the proper damage measure. B. Sale of Goods: can seek repudiation if you have rejected but if you’ve accepted, then you may only be able to recover damages. UCC §2-601: Buyer has right to reject if goods or tender of delivery fail in any respect to conform to contract [perfect tender]. Rejection must take place within reasonable time after deliver (§2-602). UCC §2-606: Buyer can accept by a) signifying acceptance; b) fails to make effective rejection after reasonable time; c) does any act inconsistent with seller’s ownership. UCC §2-608: After acceptance, can only revoke if it substantially impairs its value and he didn’t discover it due to difficulty of discovery or seller’s assurances. Case 1: Ramirez v. Autosport (Perfect Tender) p. 919 Facts: (D) Autosport agreed to sell a camper to P in exchange for a sum of money and their van. Despite P having given their trade-in van and despite several attempts to come to an agreement, Autosport did not deliver the camper as promised but rather in a defective state. P refused to purchase and demanded return of their van or alternatively the reasonable market value of the van. Holding: Under the perfect tender rule of the UCC (§2-601), the buyer had the right to reject goods that did not conform to the contract. Thus P were awarded fair market value of trade in van. Sub-question 5: Was there material breach? Default Rule: Only if a breach is material does it relieve the non-breaching party of its duty of performance under the contract. Case 1: B&B Equipment v. Bowen p. 907 Facts: D used to work for P as an accountant. As part of employment agreement, D was entitled to purchase 100 shares of contract at certain price. D got fired before meeting that price, but still wanted the chance to buy the shares. P said the cause of D’s firing was a material breach, so P didn’t have a duty anymore. 39 Holding: D’s employment was a material part of the contract. Note: Materiality defined by following factors. Katz says they all seem kind of conclusory. o Extent to which injured party will obtain substantial benefit o Extent to which the injured party may be adequately compensated in damages for lack of complete performance o Extent to which party failing to perform has already party performed. o Greater or less hardship on party failing to perform in terminating contract o Willful behavior of party failing to perform o Uncertainty that party failing to perform will perform remainder of the contract Sub-question 6: Was there an anticipatory breach? Rule: UCC § 2-610: If Party A renounces his intention to perform may not complain, Party B, instead of waiting until performance is due, can elect to sue immediately based on the doctrine of anticipatory breach. Note 1: But at the same time the breached against party should have been looking or be in the process of looking to mitigate damages i.e. by looking for another job. Note 2: This doctrine does not require a specific letter or statement to the effect of “I will not perform” (De La Tour), the parties actions just have to be inconsistent with a willingness to perform and reassurance to the other party has to fail. Thoughts re: anticipatory doctrine: Double payment Guesswork of future damage calculations: difficulty of calculating damages. Harder to figure out what the damages MIGHT be in the future than looking at actual data from before. o But how do we figure it out when it’s difficult in Hawkins? Some asset that is going to last for a lifetime, and we’re trying to estimate it now. Same difficulty as here. 40 Premature duty to mitigate: D might not be able to go find another job because he waits until the breach, so this doctrine deprives him of that. Unfair deprivation of opportunity to fix: maybe breach won’t happen. Mutuality – hypothetical disability by Plaintiff: what if plaintiff died, or had something happened such that the contract was void, wouldn’t legally qualify as a breach. Vagueness Case 1: Hochester v. De La Tour p. 892 Facts: P entered into contract with D that he would travel with him as his courier starting June 1st. On May 11th D wrote letter stating that he intended to repudiate the contract on June 1st by not hiring him as a courier. P found new position of similar terms to begin in July but still brought suit based on “anticipatory” breach of contract. Holding: P allowed to recover damages in anticipation of D’s breach. Further, P was allowed to enter into a new contract before June 1st as to not deliberately increase damages. Def. should want mitigation of damages Policy: If P was aware that D intended to breach, it would be counter to the mitigation doctrine if he were to sit on his hands until the actual date that the contract was to begin since he would be building up damages that could otherwise be avoided. 41 5: Defenses 3/9/2016 4:25:00 PM Question 5: Defenses to Contractual Obligations making a contract voidable Sub-question 1: Obtaining Assent Unfairly Possibility 1: When Assent was obtained through misrepresentation or fraud as to facts Fact Pattern: 1. Fraud or misrepresentation? 2. Fraud void regardless of material factor or not 3. Misrepresentation: look to (a) §164 and determine whether it’s a material fact (b) §167 to see if it was an inducing cause. Misrepresentation v. Fraud as to FACTS: Misrepresentation: (§159) “A misrepresentation is an assertion that is not in accord with facts” even if it is not purposefully intended to mislead the other party into assenting. Look to objective standard, not internal mental intent o A misrepresentation makes a contract voidable under §164(1) if it is (a) material and the other party is justified in relying on the misrepresentation and (b) if it induces a reasonable person to manifest assent o Policy: This liability is good for the buyer in that he will be encouraged to engage in goods interactions knowing that he can rely on the truthfulness and accuracy of the seller’s statements and repudiate if he finds out they are false. If there were no misrepresentation liability, the buyer would have a heavy burden of investigating purchases on his own which might be costly and impede contracts. o Policy Problem: There’s a tension with WARRANTIES (guarantees that seller will be liable for defects): if there’s a warranty, a buyer has to give the seller a chance to make good on the warranty in the event of a defect. BUT if there’s no warranty and just a 42 misrepresentation, then the buyer can bring suit immediately to get out of the contract without having to give the seller an opportunity to correct the problem. Ideally, the seller wouldn’t want innocent misrepresentation liability out of fear that anything he says will be subject to this liability BUT his fear is mitigated by the ability to simply say “I don’t know” or further investigate. Fraud: (§162 (1)) A misrepresentation is fraudulent if the maker intends his assertion to induce the party to manifest his assent and the maker (a) knows/believes his assertion to not be in accord with the facts; (b) doesn’t have the confidence he states or implies in the truth of his assertions; OR (c) knows he has no basis for his statement or implication for the assertion. o A fraudulent misrepresentation makes a contract void under §164(1) (a) whether it is material or not; and (b) if it induces the manifestation of assent of the other party. o Policy: This broadly includes both knowledge and beliefs as they are both dishonest and fabricating your level of certainty is also dishonest. Fraud liability is good for both buyers and sellers because: for a seller it gives their promises legitimacy and thus reduces transaction costs seller would incur if he had to convince the buyer of the seller’s truthfulness for a buyer, it likewise gives them peace of mind in relying upon seller’s promises or alternatively knowing that they can repudiate. Third party Misrepresentation/Fraud: Under §164(2), a contract is voidable based on the misrepresentation or fraudulent misrepresentation of a third party not involved in the contract when it induces assent by one of the party’s UNLESS the other party to the transaction in good faith and without reason to know of the misrepresentation gives value or relies materially on the transaction o Policy: This doctrine warns a seller to correct any known third party misrepresentations. 43 If a misrepresentation induces a party to assent, any kind of misrepresentation should not be valid, even if it is a third party misrepresentation. o Example: Media writes article on company inducing stock purchases but article contains misrepresentations. Thus, if company doesn’t correct misrepresentations but knows about the article, that article is an inducing cause of assent and the contract is voidable. §167: When a Misrepresentation is an Inducing Cause: A misrepresentation is an inducing cause if it substantially contributes to a party’s decision to manifest assent. (i.e. “but for” the misrepresentation would buyer have actually bought the house) Case 1: Halbert v. Rosenthal Facts: Seller (P) brings suit against (D) for specific performance or damages based on difference btw. price of house contracted for and price eventually sold for. Buyer (D) cross-claims to return his deposit on a house based on the fact that the seller, Real Estate Agency, misrepresent the fact that there were no termites in the house (even though seller was innocent in his misrepresentation). Holding: Even though the misrepresentation was innocent, since it was a substantial factor in the buyer’s decision, rescission is available. When a (D) has induced another, through his innocent misrepresentation, to act, the person who should bear the loss is the speaker, not the actor who relied upon the words. (based on §164 AND §167) Two ways to read this case: (1) Crystal clear to the buyer that the sellers know no more than they do. Then NO liability and contract is NOT voidable (2) Buyer’s trust sellers know more than they do and rely on their knowledge because they are in a better position. It doesn’t matter if the seller’s misrepresentation is completely innocent. Here, contract voidable. Hypo1: Stock Prospectus Facts 1: Company X issued stock prospectus including warnings such as “their continued existence is questionable, be prepared to suffer an immediate and total loss.” No representation that the president or any of the other employees can prevent loss. Is this fraud? Holding 1: (1) If you were induced not to buy the stock then you have no case since §164 requires the manifestation of assent to a purchase. (2) If you buy some 44 stock BUT were induced to not buy more, then you may have a case for fraud based on §164 grounded on the stock that you did buy. This however would be a very difficult case to make b/c all of the restatement sections center around “inducing assent” NOT “inducing NON assent” Hypo2: Fake Painting Facts: Owner of a fake painting sells to Y, representing painting as a “real Van Gogh.” Y resells to Z who doesn’t know much about art but likes the painting and purchases under guise that it is a real Van Gogh. Once it comes out that painting is fake, can Z void the contract with Y? Holding: Courts don’t normally pierce the adequacy of contracts and assume that people subjectively value the goods that they are buying at the price they are buying them for because if courts did pierce the adequacy then no sales would take place. BUT in this situation, where a misrepresentation is an “inducing cause” under §167, in that it’s a substantial factor contributing to the parties’ decision to enter into the contract, the contract may be voidable under §164. Possibility 2: When assent is obtained through misrepresentation of opinion §168 & 169: Reliance on assertion of opinion: It is reasonable for A to believe B ONLY IF a) relationship of trust; b) special skill or expertise to subject matter. If it is reasonable, A can expect that a) the facts B knows are not incompatible to what B’s opinion is, and b) that he knows fact sufficient to justify him in forming it. §168: Reliance on Assertion of Opinions: (1 – what an opinion is): Assertion of a belief is an opinion without certainty as to existence of facts OR only a judgment as to quality, value, authenticity or similar matters (2- assumptions one can make about X’s opinion): It is reasonable to interpret an assertion as an opinion as either (a) facts known to the person are not incompatible with his opinion, or (b) that he knows facts sufficient to justify him in forming it. §169: When Reliance on an Assertion of Opinion is Not Justified (*situations where an opinion constitutes a misrepresentation) 45 General Rule: A contract is NOT voidable based on an opinion that turns out to be wrong UNLESS: (a) the person asserting the opinion stands in a relationship of trust and confidence to the person whose opinion is asserted and the recipient is reasonable in relying on it (b) the person asserting the opinion has a special skill, judgment or objectivity with respect to the subject manner Note: people that fall in this category are generally professionals like doctors, accountants, lawyers (and in Vokes case extended to a dance instructor) (c) for some other special reason when the recipient is particularly vulnerable to the misrepresentation of the type involved (also like Vokes, recent widow trying to recreate herself into a ballerina) Hypo1: Reverend Facts: A popular reverend with a television show who raises funds for various religious causes is embarrassed when information comes to light based on his diary that he is an Atheist and a Cynic. Holding: There was no misrepresentation in terms of the money for the religious causes. §168(2): Are we dealing with reverend’s assertion of his belief, or reverend’s assertion that God exists? If the second, it would be hard to prove reverend knew facts that showed He doesn’t exist. If the first, it’s hard to prove that customers relied on reverend’s own personal belief in God [subjective opinion.] Contract law would rather focus on the objective outward opinions. Policy: Contract law is concerned with the objective outward opinions of people not their inner subjective opinions. Case 1: Vokes v. Arthur Murray, Inc. p. 991 Facts: Vokes (P) was convinced to sign up, under a number of contracts, for dance lessons based on her reliance on the instructor’s opinions that she was a promising student and her dancing skills were improving. P brought suit to void the remainder of her unused dance lessons. Holding: P able to rescind the remaining contracts b/c D had superior knowledge as to whether P was really improving, had “dance potential” and their comments went beyond mere sales “puffery” into the area of undue influence and the suppression of truth. 46 Policy: This case extends the “special skilled professionals category” under §169b to include those experts who are highly knowledgeable in a field in which plaintiff is generally unfamiliar. Possibility 3: Obtaining Assent Improperly: Duress Rule 1: Contract modification is voidable on the grounds of duress when (1) the party claiming duress establishes that its agreement to the modification was obtained by means of a wrongful threat from the other party which precluded the first party’s exercise of free will AND (2) the threatened party could not obtain the goods from another source of supply; AND (3) the ordinary remedy for breach of contract would be inadequate §175: When Duress by Threat Makes a Contract Voidable (1) If the party’s manifestation is induced by improper threat, which leaves the victim no reasonable alternative, the contract is voidable. (2) Applying to third parties: if a third party’s threat induces assent, the contract is voidable UNLESS the other party to the transaction, in good faith, without reason to know about the duress, relies or gives value to the contract. What kinds of threats are so improper as to make the contract voidable §176(1): Improper threats intending to benefit the threatening party (a) what is threatened is a crime or a tort, or the threat itself would be a crime or a tort if it resulted in obtaining property: (b) what is threatened is a criminal prosecution (c) what is threatened is the use of civil process and the threat is made in bad faith *i.e. someone who threatens to bring a frivolous lawsuit (d) the threat is a breach of the duty of good faith and fair dealing under a contract with the recipient *Alaska and Loral but NOT Stilk because in Stilk there was no threat made and in Alaska and Loral there was a threat of refusing to perform and thus breaching the duty of bad faith. §176(2): A threat is also improper and thus can void a contract if it is not on fair terms AND 47 (a) the threat is made to be spiteful and does not actually benefit the threatening party (b) the effectiveness of the threat is significantly increased based on prior unfair dealings, (c) what is threatened is otherwise use of power for illegitimate ends B/c the above framework is confusing, academics have tried to frame other ways to distinguish when a contract is voidable based on the existence of a threat: 1.) When each party is happy about the presence of the other person, then the contract is not voidable. However if one party is not happy about the existence of the other party, then the threat constitutes duress and the contract should be voidable. Problem: In Loral, while the (P) is not happy about making the extra money, they are happy that Austin exists so that they can fulfill their military contract. Likewise in Alaska, the captain is happy that the sailors are there b/c he doesn’t have anyone else to do the work but he is unhappy about paying the extra money. Therefore this is not a good duress test b/c all contract modifications would pass muster. 2.) Triangular Relationship btw. husband, wife and blackmailer. The blackmailer diverts money that is due to the wronged wife for himself and thus this contract is based on duress and voidable. POLCIY PROBLEMS 1. Pre-Existing Duty rule/Duress – address the same issue but come out with different conclusions because of weak-strong party issue: UCC 2-209 allows contract modification without additional consideration unless there is existence of bad faith BUT the restatement looks down upon contract modification without new consideration. HOWEVER, instead of invoking the pre-existing duty rule (2-209), courts today look to the Restatement §175, section on duress, to determine whether a contract’s modification is voidable based on the existence of duress. Policy: Both Stilk and Alaska were decided under the pre-existing duty rule and both were found to be void. Where, under the duress rule, it’s likely that the Stilk contract could not have been voidable since it was the 48 weaker party who offered to modify the contract and not the threats of the stronger party. 2. Virtually anything can be constituted as duress: particularly economic duress. If Headley turned out the other way, no incentive to settle. Case 1: Hackley v. Headley: p. 1000 Facts: P Headley did some work for D Hackley, but when he went to ask for payment, D said he would only pay $2000 less and wouldn’t pay anything if P didn’t agree to take it as full consideration. P had the option to refuse and sue, but P needed the $ immediately so agreed. Later tried to sue for economic duress. Holding: If party’s threat is his legal right to perform, then it’s not duress. Here, it is D’s legal right to fail to pay (P’s recourse traditionally is just to sue.) Policy: If allow Headley, then no incentive to settle (P can later just claim economic duress and get out of it.) Better to allow some bullying. Could probably use ex ante perspective here. Case 2: Austin Instrument v. Loral Corp. Facts: Loral Corp. (D) is radar set producer with military contracts. The military contracts contain a liquidated damage clause for late delivery and a cancellation clause. (D) awarded Austin (P) a sub-contract to supply some of the parts. Subsequently, Austin threatened to cease delivery of the parts unless Loral consented to substantial increase in the sub-contract price and unless Loral consented to a second contract. Whether the contract modification, increasing price of the contract, makes the contract voidable on the ground of duress. Holding: The contract is voidable since (P) was precluded from exercising their free will and even though they attempted to secure the parts from other companies, they were unable to and had no choice but to assent to the defendant’s price increases in order to keep their initial contract with the military. Sub-question 2: Was the contract made unconscionabilily (procedural issue) or is the contract substantively unconscionable? Procedurally Unconscionable: Oppression or surprise, unequal bargaining power, or the absence of choice by one of the parties, contracts of adhesion (form 49 contracts where the purchaser doesn’t have the chance to bargain for terms), whether each party understood the extent of the terms of the agreement, whether deceptive sales practices were used. Substantive Unconscionable: Even though the person made the choice freely and openly to enter into the agreement, we can nevertheless void the contract if it appears overly harsh or one-sided terms. *problem: Courts don’t normally pierce the adequacy of contracts and thus substantive unconscionability is in conflict with this notion. *policy: In the prisoner’s dilemma, each individual’s immediate self-interest is in conflict with the collective good. Each individual who is engaging in a contract might think that it’s in their immediate self-interest to enter the contract and agree to its terms, but when something goes wrong, they realize that it would be in their best interest if all consumers banned together against such agreements. Thus unconscionabiltiy is a solution to this “prisoner’s” dilemma. *Counter: Consumers have other means of changing a term of agreement besides courts paternalistically protecting them through this doctrine i.e. they can boycott a company and force them into fairer terms. Rule: If there’s found to be procedural, substantive or both types of unconscionability, the contract is voidable. USE THIS DEFENSE if HYPO doesn’t rise to the level of misrepresentation, mistake, duress or coercion. Case 1: Williams v. Walker Thomas Facts: P, buyer, entered into “rent-to-own” agreement with D, storeowner, which included a repossession clause that contracted around the general default rule of repossession (Default rule: in a case of defaulted payment, the store can invoke the power of the court to instituted a repossession proceeding). This clause stated that any outstanding payments would be distributed among all products purchased from the store so that the products would remain in the ownership of the store until all payments were furnished. THUS, the store sidestepped the litigation process and was able to repossess all of plaintiff’s purchased when she defaulted. HOWEVER, there was no windfall for D storeowner since he would only be entitled to keep the money collected that applied to the outstanding balance and anything in excess had to be remitted to plaintiff. 50 Holding: Case remanded for further findings on unconscionabiltiy. Policy Problems: If we don’t allow the enforcement of the Walker Thomas contract, then it may be good for the plaintiff in this case, but it will be bad for plaintiffs like her in the future who are similarly poor and unable to buy on credit absent such clauses which give the seller confidence that he won’t be insured by default. Policy: If we allow this agreement to be enforced, the problem is that the seller doesn’t have an incentive to sell the repossessed items at a high enough price so that plaintiff gets money back because he is only concerned with recovering the balance. Case 2: Gatton v. T-mobile USA Facts: Customers bringing class action against T-mobile on behalf of all customers alleging contract unconscionable in terms of 1. Early termination fee 2. Locked handsets 3. Clause compelling arbitration and waiving the right to bring a class action. Court only dealing with third issue. Holding: Court found a minimal procedural unconscionability in terms of the adhesive nature of the contract, the limited choices, AND a high degree of substantive unconscionability arising from the class action waiver. Policy: If we didn’t allow class actions, T-Mobile could skim a few dollars off of each customer gaining a windfall and be essentially judgment proof since people won’t typical bring litigation for claims under a thousand dollars. Policy Problem: Price reflects the cost of doing business and if T-mobile is subject to class actions, their costs will go up with will then be passed on to the consumers in the form of higher prices for phones and plans. Sub-question 3: Was there a mistake? Possibility 1: MUTUAL MISTAKE MISTAKE DEFINED: (§151) “A mistake is a belief that is not accord with the facts.” Mistake, as opposed to other forms of mistake i.e. impracticability and frustration of purpose, refer to facts as they exist at the time of contract. MUTUAL MISTAKE: (§152) (1) Where a mistake of both parties, at the time of contract formation, as to a basic assumption (so obvious that neither party would 51 think to include it in the contract and thus usually risk not allocated) on which the contract was made, and has a material effect on the exchange, the contract is voidable unless under §154 the party bears the risk. (2) Even if the contract is voidable, the court has discretion in assigning damages. §154 When A Party Bears the Risk of Mistake: (a) risk is explicitly allocated to him in the agreement (b) party is aware at the time of the contract that they have limited knowledge with respect to the facts to which the mistake relates but nevertheless proceeds (c) the court allocates the risk to the party based on reasonableness. Damages: Can be restitution or reliance according to §158 Case 1: Sherwood v. Walker Facts: Seller (D), owner of farm, agreed to sell a certain cow, which he believed to be barren to (P) banker for $80 (going price for meat). When the P went to pick up the cow, the buyer wouldn’t hand it over since it was discovered that the cow was pregnant and thus worth considerably more than they had agreed for. Holding: The contract was built around a mutual material mistake regarding the basic assumption that the cow was barren and thus the contract is voidable. Dissent: P did believe that the cow would breed and thus under §154, the D should bear the burden of the mistake since the risk was allocated to him as he knew he had limited knowledge. Possibility 2: Unilateral Mistake UNILATERAL MISTAKE (§153): Where a mistake of one party, (1) at the time of contract formation, (2) as to a basic assumption (so obvious that neither party would think to include it in the contract and thus usually risk not allocated) on which the contract was made (3) has a material effect on the exchange of performances that is adverse to him, (4) if he does not bear the risk under §154 AND (5) (a) the effect of the mistake is such that enforcement of the contract would be unconscionable, [this is circular] or (b) the non-mistaken party had reason to know of the mistake or his fault caused the mistake (good-faith requirement). THEN 52 the contract is VOIDABLE by the mistaken party. **Note: Burden of proof is on the mistaken party is that they must demonstrate by a “preponderance of evidence” that the non-mistaken party was aware of the mistake at the time of the contract. ** Note 2: There are very few circumstances where there is going to be one party who makes a mistake and another party who in good faith doesn’t know there’s a mistake. §154 When A Party Bears the Risk of Mistake: (a) risk is explicitly allocated to him in the agreement (b) party is aware at the time of the contract that they have limited knowledge with respect to the facts to which the mistake relates but nevertheless proceeds (c) the court allocates the risk to the party based on reasonableness. Case 1: Tyra v. Cheney Facts: There was a mistake in the contract between builder and D, they unknowingly excluded an item in the estimate, leading to an underestimate of $963. The D was seemingly aware of this omission and attempted to hold contractor to lower price Holding: Cannot hold to lower price, D responsible for difference RULE: Where one party to a contract is unilaterally mistaken as to an essential contract term and the other party is aware of his error, the agreement fails to constitute a binding contract. o one cannot snap up an offer or bid knowing that it was made in mistake Possibility 3: Impossibility/Impracticability (after a contract is made) – When Impossibility Makes Contract Voidable (Discharged by Supervening Impracticability): Rule §261: In a contract There occurred an event, the non-occurrence of which was material THEN, there is an implied condition that the a party’s performance is discharged. Case 1: Paradine v. Jane: p. 1083 Facts: Contract between landlord and tenant to pay rent. Army invades and takes over tenant’s land, question of whether tenant still has to pay. 53 Rule: If duty by law, then impossibility would void it. But if duty by contract, then you’re NOT excused in event of impossibility, because you could have contracted around it. Holding: tenant had to pay rent. o Note: But I suppose this may not excuse the situation of an “implied” covenant in the contract regarding impossibility (?). §261: Discharged by Supervening Impracticability When, after a contract is made, a party’s performance is made impracticable without his fault by the occurrence of an event the non-occurrence of which was a basic assumption on which the contract was made, the contract is voidable (essentially the same as mistake, just as to facts as they existed AFTER contract formation instead at the time of formation) §263: Destruction, Deterioration or Failure to come into existence of thing necessary for performance makes contract voidable due to impracticality. Hypo: Cattle rancher contracts with farmer to buy the offspring of a particular cow for his ranching business. However, after formation of contract, the cow catches a disease, which renders her infertile. This doctrine would apply and make the contract voidable due to the supervening event of infertility/disease, which was a basic assumption on which the contract relied. Case 1: Taylor v. Caldwell Contract was found void based on §263 when the music hall, which plaintiff contracted to rent from defendant owner, was destroyed, thereby rendering performance impracticable/impossible. The existence of the music hall was necessary for the performance. Hence, its destruction made such performance impracticable. Possibility 4: Frustration of Purpose (after a contract is made) Frustration of Purpose (§265): When after a contract is made, a party’s principal purpose is substantially frustrated without his fault by the occurrence of an event the non-occurrence of which was a basic assumption on which the contract 54 was made, a contract is voidable. Parole evidence can be admitted to prove purpose if not explicitly mentioned in contract (Krell) Case 1: Krell v. Henry (see also mutual mistake) Facts: Advertised room with view of coronation, P agreed to rent the room. For some reason the coronation was delayed indefinitely, P wanted to still collect rent, D didn’t want to pay. Holding: Contract voided Notes: This is like Sherwood, because this is an unforeseeable event, except it’s a mistake occurring after time of contract. But it follows the same logic as mutual mistake. Hypo: Cattle rancher contracts with farmer to buy the offspring of a particular cow for his ranching business. Seller delivers offspring to buyer but buyer’s business collapses and he wants to cancel all orders for anything cow related. This doctrine would apply and make the contract voidable due to the frustration of purpose. BUT seller can sue on DAMAGES because the risk of defendant’s business failing was not out of the blue. PRACTICE FOR EXAM: Shirley McClaine: 1. Misrepresentation In response to studio’s mitigation claim, McClaine could say that the studio represented to her in the contract that they were only asking for her presence and option to use her in the film. 2. Duress the studio in offering her the western were trying to force her into mitigating or else not being able to recover the full amount 3. Mistake 4. Impossibility 5. Frustration the studio had contracted her to be a singing and dancing actress and the purpose was to advance her musical movie star career so appearing in a 55 western film wouldn’t achieve that purpose. Thus the “destruction” of the musical movie would cause a frustration of purpose for McClaine. 56 12/20/2010 5:24:00 AM Question 6: What are the Damages? Sub-question 1: Which Damage interest should apply? Possibility 1: Expectation Damages – Default Rule of Damages Rule: Expectation Damages seek to put the promisee in the position he would have been had the promise been performed in full [benefit of the bargain] §347 – Measure of Damages in General – The injured party has a right to expectation damages, measured by: o (a) difference b/t what P received and what P should have received, PLUS o (b) any other incidental or consequential loss caused by the breach, MINUS o (C) any cost or other loss avoided by non-performance Case 1: Hawkins v. McGee (Hairy hand case) o Facts: Dr. McGee claimed he could perform skin graft and make P’s hand “100% perfect.” D botched-up surgery leaving P worse off than before the surgery. P sues D for breach of contract. o Holding: Recovery based expectation damages (value of perfect hand – value of hairy hand PLUS consequential damages (such as lack of ability to work). Court declined to award pain and suffering since no EXTRA pain beyond that which is expected with hand surgery. Problems with expectation damages— o (1) Computational difficulty in assigning quantitative value to a “perfect hand” vs. value of imperfect hairy hand o (2) Expectation damages are too harsh COUNTER 1: when parties enter an agreement the court assumes that the parties will fulfill the agreement and thus when a breach occurs, it is only fair to award the nonbreaching party with what he expected to gain from the bargain o (3) Disincentivizes parties from entering into contract, excess caution on part of doctors. Also not really adhering to Harm- 57 Compensation Principle: We are only liable for what we’ve actually done in harm. Counter: Theft analogy, it depends on what you consider is the “harm” done. o (4) in case of instantaneous breach it seems crazy to enforce expectation damages Advantages to Expectation o (1) Discouraging Breach of contract (strong motivator), promisekeeping o (2): Theft analogy: The only difference between “stealing” a car that you have already sold and delivered to a party and breaching a contract to sell a car to another party is that in the later case no physical delivery has been made. And in stealing at least you have the power of physical force. o (3) Expectation rarely fulfills the actual full benefit of the bargain thus when the court shoots for expectation they actually protecting reliance interest (when take into consideration cost of lawsuit) Applying Expectation Damages Rule 1: FIXED COSTS associated with a business are not recoverable as part of expectation damages while variable costs are (Hooker) Rule 2: MARKET LOSS RULE: In an action for a breach of contract for the sale of goods the proper measure is the difference b/w the market value for the goods and the contract price agreed upon (even when the injured party is a MIDDLEMAN and is thus protected from market fluctuations) (Tongish) Case 1: Hooker & Sons v. Roberts o Facts: Hooker, a contractor entered into a sub-contracting agreement with Roberts to provide construction service and removal services. Dispute arose over which party had the duty to dispose of the cabinets. Hooker canceled contract with Roberts and then Roberts sued Hooker for expectation damages based on (1) administrative costs; (2) storage costs; and (3) lost profits. o Holding: (1)The court allowed recovery of administrative costs (since the employees could have been working on other assignments—thus they were VARIABLE costs); (2) the court also awarded lost profits consistent with expectation damages (3) the 58 court rejected damages for overhead costs (secretaries, storage) because they were FIXED costs that Roberts would have had regardless of the breached contract Case 2: Tongish v. Thomas – collateral benefits – beyond Expectation o Facts: Tongish contracted to sell sunflower seeds to Coop who had a further arrangement to sell to Bambino. Coop only bargained to receive the delivery costs and sold to Bambino for the price he paid Tongish. The market price of sunflower seeds increased and Tongish breached in order to sell to a higher bidder. o Holding: Market Loss rule – difference between market price at the time of breach and contract price. Even though Coop was a middleman who was not exposed to market fluctuations the court wanted to discourage breaches, so awarded expectation damages. This is an EXCEPTION to UCC §2-712 and §2-713 o Policy 1: Windfall Argument: If we allowed Tongish to breach he would get a windfall (Counter: Coop is getting a windfall that he didn’t bargain for) o Policy 2: Inefficiency Argument: It would be inefficient to allow Tongish to breach b/c this would encourage breaches of contract (Counter: Coop has nothing to complain about since he wasn’t injured by the breach) o Policy 3: Precedent Argument based on breaching party’s good or bad-faith intent: Allied was a middleman also. Seller breached contract because of extenuating weather circumstances. Court held that if the seller knew the buyer had a resell contract for the goods, and the seller did not breach the contract in bad faith, the buyer was limited to actual loss of damages under §1-106. o Policy 4: Just because a party is insured against a loss it doesn’t mean that the breacher should be off the hook. (Counter: Because the party insured himself, he doesn’t deserve to get a windfall) o Counter 1: Academic Argument (Fairness/ HarmCompensation principle): If in Hawkins, the hair hand miraculously recovered, we would not want to hold the doctor to full expectation damages since it is out 59 of proportion with the harm caused. Likewise, in Tongish it is unfair for (P) to be liable for a greater amount of damages than was actually caused. o UCC §1-106: General Damage Rule: Expectation damage (here, it would just be Coop’s middle man handler fee) o UCC §2-712: “Cover”; Buyer’s Procurement of Substitute Goods: (only for goods) – (1) Buyer can, in the case of a breach, buy substitute goods to “cover” for the goods seller didn’t deliver (2) The buyer may then recover the difference btw. market price for new goods and the contract price, in addition to any additional or consequential damages which flow from the breach LESS expenses saved. o UCC §2-713: Buyer’s Damages for Non-Delivery or Repudiation – If the seller breaches and the buyer chooses not to buy substitute goods he is nevertheless entitled to damages based on the market price at the time of the breach minus the contract price PLUS any consequential damages and LESS any expenses saved. Possibility 2: Reliance Damages [When you are not sure if a contract has been created] (used for quasi-contracts such as Cotnam OR promissory Estoppel such as Goodman) OR some malpractice cases Rule: Breached against party is put in the position in which he was before entering into the contract §349 Damages based on Reliance Interests – Damages based on reliance interests, including expenditures made in preparation for performance LESS any loss that the party in breach can prove with reasonable certainty that the injured party avoided Case: Sullivan v. O’Connor o Facts: D Surgeon performed multiple nose jobs on professional entertainers nose, expected two surgeries but wound up having 3. Initially nose was straight but protruding after final surgery nose was bumpy and deformed. P sued doctor claiming mental and physical suffering and inability to obtain future work. 60 o Holding: Court awarded: (1) Out of pocket surgery expenses (reliance); (2) Pain of third unexpected surgery (expectation and reliance). Court did NOT award (1) Physical pain caused by first and second surgery b/c (P) expected it) [(P) did not ask for expectation and did not ask for emotional damage so court did not address either in opinion] Policy: Disadvantages of Reliance o (1) Lack of incentive to engage in contract for potential nonbreaching parties o (2) Surprise factor—if injured party had an unknown special talent or special circumstance reliance damages could be unforeseeably high Policy: Advantages o (1) in the case where it is debatable if a contract has been made but it would be unfair not to award any damages, reliance is a good alternative to expectation o (2) Ability for courts to apply reliance damages dissuades doctors or other practitioners from making promises that they can not necessarily follow through on in order to gain business while not making them liable for patient’s crazy expectations or warped sense of promises Possibility 3: Restitution Damages [usually the smallest but in rare circumstances can be larger than expectation] Rule: The return or restoration of what the (D) has gained in a transaction to prevent the unjust enrichment of that (D). §371: Measure of Restitution Interests – May be measured by (a) the value of what has been given (b) the value of the unjust enrichment to the (D) When the non-breaching party is seeking restitution Damages §373: Restitution when the Other Party is in Breach – (1) The injured party may get back any benefit bestowed upon the breaching party (Bush); (2) The non-breaching party has no right to restitution (i.e. getting his goods back) if he has performed all of his duties under the contract and no performance by the breaching party remains due other 61 than payment of a definite sum of money for that performance (in this case, breaching party must pay, but doesn’t have to return goods) Case: Bush v. Canfield o Facts: Canfield breached contract it had with Bush to deliver goods by NOT delivering. Goods declined in price from the time the contract was entered to the time the Seller breached the contract. Buyer had put down deposit and now wants it returned (restitution would put Buyer at better position than if expectation would). Seller argues that he does not have to give whole deposit back b/c the goods price went down and the buyer would have suffered a loss had the contract not been breached. o Holding: If the seller breaches a contract by not delivering goods and has been paid in advance he must return the money paid in advance and any interest incurred even if the (P) would have lost money had the (D) not breached. (Restitution) o Policy: Discourages seller from breaching when he sees that the price is going down and does not allow him to keep the deposit in excess of the lower market price. [prevents unjust enrichment of breaching party] When the Breaching Party is seeking restitution damages §374 Restitution in Favor of Party in Breach – (1) If a party justifiably refuses to perform, the party in breach is entitled to restitution for any benefit he has conferred by way of part performance or reliance in excess of the loss that he has caused by his own breach (Britton); (2) If parties contracted around restitution damages by allowing non-breaching party to keep benefit of partial performance as “liquidated damages” and such damages are reasonable (since actual harm is difficult to calculate) then there are to be no restitution damages. Case: Britton v. Turner o Facts: P contracted with D to perform house construction work for 1 year for a salary of $125 due in a lump sum at completion of performance. P left at 10 months prior to completion. P breaching party sues D for pro-rated salary. o Holding: P entitled to the amount of value which the D received MINUS the amount of damage P has caused D (such as cost to find new laborer to finish job beyond final 2 months salary pro-rated) 62 o Policy: Arguments For Restitution damages for Breaching Party [Quantum Meruit] (1) Windfall argument: Employer should not be unjustly enriched (COUNTER: encourages breach since employee can receive partial payment) (2) Moral Hazard: Do not want to incentivize employer to bully employee into quitting job before completion so that he can have free labor (COUNTER: it is unfair to make employer pay when he did not IN FACT bully anyone) (3) Comparative Unfairness: The situation of an employer/employee is different from the situation of a builder (where expectation damages would be appropriate). In the former situation the employer receives benefit every day whereas in the later the buyer of the house has nothing to live in if the building is incomplete. (COUNTER: What if the employee was the only person working on a project and failed to complete it. Hard to make distinction, eh?) (4) Implicit understanding of partial payment. (COUNTER: implicit understanding of payment only when performance is done.) (5) Inequity of early vs. late breach: but relativity isn’t a moral judgment. Can’t compare. (6) Returnability of Goods: if you decide not to return the good, then you should have to pay for the use of the good that you did use and order. COUNTER: But in this case you can’t “return” the labor. (7) If it is important to the parties not to reward partial performance in the form of restitution damages, they can then contract around by dressing it up as a “liquidated damage” in the case of anything other than complete performance. §374(2) Quasi Contracts and Restitution Damages Rule: When there are contracts that cannot be bargained for because one is unconscious and cannot communicate explicitly what he wants a quasi 63 contract can be created, restitution damages are awarded to the performing party to avoid unfairness. Case 1: Cotnam v. Wisdom o Facts: D decedent thrown from street car and is rendered unconscious. P doctors come to assist and rendered emergency operation to try and save D’s life. P is ultimately unsuccessful. D dies and a suit is brought by Ps against his estate to get paid for their services. o Holding: P is entitled to be compensated for services. When party lacks capability of communicating his wishes and we can determine ex-ante what he would have wanted (the doctors to save his life) then the court can assume that a quasi-contract exists and award restitution damages. o Rule 1: The financial condition of a patient/estate (no kids) can not be considered where there is a quasi contract in determining the damages Policy: P should only be paid an objective amount determined by the jury to be enough to compensate the doctors for their services (but profit motives usually incorporated into doctor pricing should not apply where damage is restitution and not expectation). This is all about bringing DOCTOR to T0, not patient. Case 2: Hypo (Runaway dog) o Facts: Dog runs away, finder brings him back, wants a reward. How is this different from dr? Objective intent would say it is obvious that person would want to be saved by surgery. Quasicontract between finder and dog owner? o Holding: No, the court would not enforce a quasi contract in this situation even though the parties were prevented from the exchange due to an inability to communicate since this is treated as being DIFFERENT from unconsciousness. Court does not like to construct contracts generally, only in special circumstance of consciousness. Sub-Issue 2: Are there any Limitations on Damages? 64 Possibility 1: Can it be limited by Unforeseeability of Damages Rule: Foreseeable Damages are recoverable. Unforeseeable damages are only recoverable if there is notification prior to contract. §351 Unforeseeability and Related Limitations on Damages o (1) Damages are not recoverable if the party in breach did not have reason to foresee as a probable result of the breach when the contract was made o (2) Loss may be foreseeable as a probable result of a breach because it follows from the breach (a) in the ordinary course of events, or (b) as a result of special circumstances beyond the ordinary course of events that the party in breach had reason to know o (3) a court may limit damages for foreseeable loss by excluding recovery for loss of profits Reasons for Foreseeability Limitation It’s the definition of expectation damages Fairness: seems to demand it being within contemplation of contract Inadequate consideration: Promisor only prices for what is foreseeable, so he would’ve charged more if this wasn’t the case. Default rule means that promisee has incentive to disclose risks to other side [contract around it] o High prices for everyone otherwise. Reasons Against: Because you can contract around it, this gives advantage to the Man and screws small-time businesses and innocent consumers. Case 1: Hadley v. Baxendale (unforeseeable) o Facts: Ps are millers whose shaft broke. They arranged to have shaft mailed by a carrier services and repaired. The P informed mail clerk that it must be sent immediately. Delivery was delayed causing loss of profits based on the mill having come to a halt in the absence of the shaft. o Holding: P cannot recover for lost profits since it was not foreseeable to a “reasonable man” that a delay of the shaft’s 65 delivery would cause the mill to shut down, and wasn’t told otherwise explicitly. o Policy: Incentivize Hadley to be more responsible. Case 2: Hector Martinez v. Southern Pacific (reasonably foreseeable) o Facts: P’s agent delivered a dragline via D’s train to TX. The dragline was damaged in transit and delayed. P sues for (1) recovery for the repairs to dragline; (2) refund for shipping and (3) compensation for lost profits due to (a) delayed delivery and (b) delay from dragline repairs o Holding: Court awarded damages for lost profits for delay when not delivered [since it was reasonably foreseeable that machine had “use value” or rental value] but not for repair delay since that element of the claim was already settled. o Policy: It is not important that what occurred was the MOST FORESEEABLE only that it was reasonably foreseeable. Here since a dragline has a rental value in and of itself it was foreseeable to D that a delay would cause P lost profits (as opposed to the shaft in a Hadley which was a machine PART) Case 3: Morrow v. First National Bank – TACIT AGREEMENT – minority rule. o Facts: Morrow signs contract to rent safety deposit box from D bank to store his collector coins. Safety boxes not installed yet and D promises to alert P as soon as they become available. P is robbed and coins stolen. Bank failed to tell P that boxes became available before robbery. P sues D for price of stolen coins. o Holding: Under the “TACIT AGREEMENT TEST” consequential damages for a breach of contract can only be recovered if (1) there is injury from the contract breach; (2) special circumstances were told to (D); (3) D agreed to the special circumstances. Court holds that these circumstances were not met by the contract b/t Morrow and First National o Policy: This test is more restrictive than the foreseeability test used in Hadley in which only items 1 and 2 needed to be met. Trying to deal with someone driving around with sign that says “If you hit me you owe me $10,000” 66 Possibility 2: Can be Limited by Uncertainty of Harm Rule: In order to recover special damages the damages must be definite and certain [i.e. you must be able to prove profits to reasonable certainty] §352: Uncertainty as a limitation on Damages – Damages are not recoverable for loss beyond an amount that the evidence permits to be established with reasonable certainty §349: Damages based on Reliance Interest – The injured party has a right to damages based on his reliance interests including expenditures made in preparation for performance or in performance LESS any loss that the party in breach can prove with reasonable certainty the injured party would have suffered had the contract been performed Definite and Certain damages which can be recovered: (1) Costs incurred in preparing for performance of contract (post-contract formation) (Chicago Club); OR (2) ALL wasted expenditures when it is wasted by reason of a D’s breach (Anglia) Uncertain damages which are NOT recoverable: (1) Costs incurred in preparing a contract; (2) attorney’s fees and court costs; (3) Lost profits unless such damages are definite and certain (Chicago Club and Anglia) Policy: o How much more does “certainty” doctrine bring to the table? Recall that you need to prove all evidence beyond a preponderance of a doubt. o Maybe certainty restriction is really to deal with situation when profits are uncertain (and thus damages are uncertain). In this situation, P is given the option to ask for most conservative estimate of their profit, ie $0 (or else they wouldn’t have agreed to enter into contract.) Case 1: Chicago Coliseum Club v. Dempsey p. 112 o Facts: P entered into a contract with D to fight against another boxer. Before this contract P entered into contract with the other boxer and contracted with a promoter to organize match. D repudiated the contract. P brought multiple suits to try to enforce. o Holding: P can NOT recover for: (1) lost profits due to uncertainty; (2) expenses incurred by P prior to D signing the contract; (3) expenses incurred in attempting to restrain D from boxing in other 67 matches. BUT P can recover expenses incurred after the signing of the agreement and pre-breach if they relied upon the event happening (temp. secretaries and sending of insurer to examine Dempsey) Katz think here Court messed up in trying to apply zeroprofit way of determining damages, applied reliance instead. Should have included pre-contract expenses to be zero-profit calculation. Case 2: Anglia Television v. Reed o Facts: P contracted with Reed to appear in a televised play. D Reed breached contract and P Anglia could not find a replacement and sues D for damages. o Holding: P Anglia could recover for any damages, pre- or postcontract formation, as long as it was made in reliance of D’s performance (§349 and §352) Possibility 3: Mitigation 1. Avoidability of Harm Rule: Injured party must do everything reasonable to mitigate the harm done to him (and lessen damages) §350 Avoidability as a Limitation on Damages – (1) Damages are not recoverable for loss that the injured party could have avoided without undue risk, burden or humiliation; (2) The injured party is not precluded from recovery to the extent that he has made reasonable but unsuccessful efforts to avoid loss. Case 1: Rockingham County v. Luten Bridge o Facts: P Board of Commissioners brought suit against D bridge contractor for continuing to build a bridge despite fair notice that the bridge was not longer desired and the contract was called off. D continued building bridge and attempted to rack up damages beyond what was due at the time of the breach. o Holding: D not entitled to expenses beyond point at which he was advised of breach because he was given notice that he should have stopped construction. o Policy: D’s decision to continue building bridge is puzzling since he was entitled to expectation (benefit of the bargain) damages at the moment of breach. Maybe he did because he thought it was easier 68 to prove [this way they are owed whatever contract promised, versus having to show what they saved by NOT building the bridge, etc.] Case 2: McClaine v. 20th Century Fox o Facts: P actress entered into contract to star in a musical production in LA with D. D notified P that they were no longer creating film but offered her a part in a western film. McClaine turned down western role and sued for expectation damages for breach of initial contract. D argued that P failed to mitigate damages by refusing western role and thus should not be entitled to full expectation damages. o Holding: Court found that P only has a duty to mitigate where the replacement role is not “different and inferior” to prior role. The court held that the western role was both different and inferior to the musical role and thus McClain was due expectation damages w/o a duty to mitigate. o Policy: If D could have somehow gauged how much it would have taken to get McClain to do the Western apart from the musical then they could have offered into evidence that sum and only been liable for the difference. o Counter-argument: Traditionally these contracts put some sort of clause that says actress gets complete discretion. So, McClaine had this option and didn’t use it, why not? 2. Lost Volume Doctrine Rule: Where seller is in the business of selling a large volume of goods even if he is able to re-sell a good post-breach of initial buyer, the seller is still owed expectation damages since it is argued that he would have sold a larger volume had the initial buyer not breached UCC § 2-708 – Seller’s Damages for Non-Acceptance or Repudiation – (this is default where lost volume not shown) (1) Seller is due expectation damages UNLESS this is not enough and (2) Seller can point to a different part of the UCC that applies. UCC § 2-710 – Seller’s Incidental Damages – Seller allowed incidental damages (costs of resale). UCC § 2-718 – Liquidation or Limitation of Damages; Deposits – allows buyer to set forth in agreement the amount of liquidation damages that will be paid in the 69 case of a breach as long as they are reasonable (such as 20% of value of the total performance or $500—whichever is smaller) Case 1: Neri v. Retail Marine Corp. o Facts: P contracts to purchase a boat from D and gives a deposit. Subsequently P becomes ill and seeks return of his deposit. Seller resells boat 4 months later but does not return deposit based on the lost volume doctrine. o Holding: Court accepts sellers’ argument and awards seller lost profits (§2-708) and incidental damages (§2-710) (cost of resale) upon the buyers repudiation BUT returns remainder of deposit to the buyer. This is because the subsequent sale was not in replacement of, but rather in addition to the original sale. o Policy: Lost volume doctrine is exception to mitigation of damages rule - where the seller has a high volume business and one sale does not merely replace another but they are each considered additional sales. In this case it could have been debated that the seller was not engaged in a sufficiently high volume business to the point of where mitigation was impossible. Sub-question 3: How do you contract around Possibility 1: You have a liquidated damages clause which is enforceable. Policy (for liquidated damages): Lessen risk involved in entering contract by decreasing uncertainty and delay when a breach occurs and increasing economic efficiency. Ex-ante: likely that both parties would want policy for liquidated damages clauses, because if not, seller would just raise prices to take this possibility into consideration. Freedom of contract Policy (against liquidated damages): Such damages become punitive or unfair under certain circumstances. i.e. little man gets screwed. 70 Maybe doesn’t increase efficiency, because it some cases it’s more efficient to both parties to breach. [But general efficiency of contract system might still be adversely affected.] You can contract around it easily by turning finishing on time into a bonus. If so easy, why make it a default rule? Possibility 2: When damages stated in the contract are out of line with the actual damage foreseeable at the time of the contract, then such a clause shall be deemed a penalty clause and is thus UNENFORCEABLE under contract law. UCC §2-719: Contractual Modification or Limitation of Remedy b. Liquidated Damages vs. Penalty Clauses: Liquidated damages are allowed to be written into contracts as long as the liquidated damages reflect what might have been the appropriate damages when the contract was entered into initially §356: Liquidated Damages and Penalties (1) Liquidated damages reasonable only for the amount that can be anticipated as a loss and can help the difficulty of calculating this loss. If too high, unreasonable. TEST to determine reasonableness (If yes, then reasonable) (Wassaner) – This is a combination of a prospective and retrospective test (1) Did the parties intend to provide for damages [vs. a penalty]? Maybe too subjective to apply. (2) Is the injury caused by breach one that is difficult or incapable of accurate estimation at the time of the contract? (3) Are the stipulated damages a reasonable forecast of the actual harm? Case 1: Wassennaar v. Towne Hotel Facts: Employment agreement b/w P and D for three years contained a liquidated damage clause in which if employee fired before those three years, he would be paid yearly salary until end of three year contract. Employee fired after 21 months and sued to enforce stipulated damage clause. D raises claims that P found new job after 2.5 months and thus P shouldn’t have to pay him after those 2.5 months (b/c getting this job was mitigation). 71 Holding: Since the stipulated damage clause is reasonable, and valid, the D is still responsible to pay the full damage clause amount and subsequent earnings of P do not free D from his duty to pay. Apply test to this: (1) Parties intended to provide for damages b/c wanted to ensure that employee would have incentive to work (2) Hard for court (and parties) to estimate actual harm to employee – such as harm to reputation, difficulty in finding new employment, etc. (3) Yes they are reasonable b/c it is simply his salary he would have gotten had there been no breach. Sub-question 4: Alternatives to Monetary Damages: Specific Performance **Courts are reluctant to enforce specific performance and only do so when there is a strong subjective value component (such as in “unique goods” – why in Property specific performance is allowed). Note: Katz thinks not really good evidence that SP is generally inefficient, given the fact that Coase means people who want it more will get it. BUT this assumes limited transaction costs, which we don’t have, so we do need to think carefully through who should get this right in the first place. Possibility 1: Contracts for Unique Goods RULE: When would the court invoke specific performance for unique goods rather than monetary damages: (1) Where damages are difficult to ascertain (2) Where substitute goods cannot be found without considerable expense, trouble, loss, great delay, and inconvenience UCC §2-716: Buyers’ Right to Specific Performance or Replevin (1) Specific Performance may be ordered where the goods are unique OR in other proper circumstances (2) The judgment for specific performance may include such terms and conditions as to payment of the price, damages, or other relief as the court may deem just. (3) Specific performance is granted where owner is unable to cover for goods or it is unlikely that he will be able to cover (E.g. B orders specific special car from A and 72 B either cannot find a substitute car for the same price or it appears unlikely that he will be able to do so). Case 1: Scholl v. Hartzell – p. 206 Facts: P entered into a contract for a car, gave deposit of $100. When P called to tender rest of money, D breached and wanted to give him deposit back, presumably because he realized this was a bad deal for him. Holding: P hasn’t proved car is unable to be covered, or that it’s a unique good. So, damages only, not specific performance. Case 2: Sedmark v. Charlie’s Chevrolet – p. 208 Facts: Sedmarks claimed that they entered an oral contract with D to purchase a limited edition Corvette for $15,000. A $500 deposit was placed on the car and several changes were made according to P’s request. When the car arrived, D informed Ps that they would have to bid on the car since the demand had escalated. P sued requesting specific performance based on oral agreement. Holding: The court held that there was a oral agreement and granted specific performance because the Ps had no adequate legal remedies given that a substitute item could not be obtained without substantial cost or delay. Policy: The Car is not unique in a traditional sense but due to mileage, ownership, and appearance, finding a replacement would be a hardship on Ps. This ruling assures that the D could not take advantage of the P just because they all of the sudden could potentially get more money for the car (guarantees against an efficient breach). Note: The Court’s ruling just gives Ps the upper hand in bargaining but parties can Coasean bargain so the person that values it the most winds up with it. Possibility 2: Contracts for Services Rule 1: Contracts for services will not be enforced through specific performance (Mary Clark/Kidney club) Rule 2: The court will not enforce specific performance BUT, to get around this, they will enjoin a defendant from performing for others where contract was for “exclusive performance.” (Lumley) Policy 1: One has an inalienable right not to be forced into servitude. 73 Policy 2: Government limits people’s ability to act on monentary temptations for their long-term well being. [But paternalistic] Policy 3: Enforcing specific performance is not efficient – you can make people perform BUT not well. Policy 4: Our Constitution voids indentured servitude of “Negro or Mulato.” Case 1: The Case of Mary Clark, A woman of Colour Facts: Clark entered into an agreement with Johnson whereby she voluntarily agreed to render services as a house servant for 20 years. Johnson wanted SP. Clark tried to get out of agreement and claims she was “illegally indentured” by Johnston. Holding: The court may not order specific performance of a contract for personal services. To do so would be to enslave the performer. Case 2: Kidney Club HYPO Facts: A is part of a kidney club that supplies one with kidneys in the case that yours fails. The consideration for entering into this club is entry into a raffle whereby if your number is picked you have to donate your kidney. Holding: Court would claim that one cannot be forced to specifically perform the donation of one’s body part. One cannot physically take a kidney out of one’s body. How to contract around: Entry into the club costs $1 million BUT you get $1 million back by participating in and abiding by the rules of the raffle. Thus someone who did not willingly participate would effectively be penalized $1 million. Case 3: Dallas Cowboys v. Harris: p. 232 Facts: D Harris was signed in June 1958 to play for the Los Angeles Rams, and his contract included an option for Club to renew the contract for similar terms. Harris, while still under options clause, signed a contract to play for Dallas Texans Football Club. Cowboys, who had bought option from Rams, sued not for SP but for injunction. Holding: Injunction can only be granted in a personal service contract if employee is of exceptional and unique knowledge, skill, and ability. Uniqueness is defined here as “The same service could not easily be 74 obtained from others.” Court ordered new trial to see if D satisfied these qualities. Case 4: Lumley v. Wagner: Facts: Wagner entered into a contract with Lumley to provide opera singing services subsequently Wagner wanted to get out of the contract and perform for another theatre. Based on the contract between P and D that Wagner would not perform in any theatre for the period of the contract, P sought order prohibiting D from singing in any other theatre. Holding: While the court won’t demand specific performance, they will grant a negative injunction restraining the party from performing for any other employer during the contract period If breach is of consideration, then breach of entire contract If breach is of a condition precedent: If material and therefore non-waivable w/o consideration, then modification without consideration, then breach of K If modification with consideration Valid if modification is fair under the circumstances or justice requires enforcement Invalid if modification is not in good faith If immaterial, then, if waived, then continue contract (no damages) if not waived, then if substantial performance, then figure out difference, either cost of completion for damages diminution of value for damages if perfect tender, then breach of K A wants K, B doesn't. So, A will argue that it's waived. B will argue that it was material and thus couldn't be waived §84, Clark v. West. A will then argue that if it was material, then there was consideration, Pre-existing Duty Rule, Stilk and Alaska Packers. B will argue that there was not consideration, or that it was in bad faith, UCC 2-209. Or, B will argue that you don't need consideration at all, UCC 2-209. 75