15 The Asian Miracle and the Asian Crisis INTRODUCTION THE CHARACTERISTICS OF THE MIRACLE Economic variables are often highly correlated and a difficult problem is to identify cause and effect. To one observer, for example, high savings cause high investment and therefore rising incomes, while to another rising incomes have been the consequence rather than the cause of rapid growth. Standard statistical tests provide some help but will not give unambiguous answers. In this section we will identify the characteristics of the “miracle” and leave until later an examination of the extent to which this is attributable to policy and institutional factors. High and Persistent Economic Growth Growth with Increasing Equality A Rapid Demographic Transition A Rapid Accumulation of Human Capital Sharp and Sustained Increases in Savings Rates ECONOMIC FEATURES OF THE MIRACLE A High Rate of Private Investment Providing Access to Capital. Directed Credit. Development Bank The Limited Role of Stock and Bond Markets. Tax Policies. Low Capital Goods Prices. Bounding Risks Controls on the Export of Capital Repression of Interest Rates. Export Growth High Labor Productivity Growth THE DEBATE OVER THE MIRACLE The Market, or Neoclassical, Explanation East Asia’s success is due to the similar rewards for selling in the domestic and foreign markets. Because variation of incentives across sectors, as measured by the effective rate of protection of value added, has been limited, inputs have flowed to sectors roughly on the basis of static comparative advantage, and international competition has provided an impetus for cost discipline and technological upgrading. Traded inputs have been made available to exporters at international prices, and exporters have faced an international price regime in making their decisions. Finally, factor markets have been roughly competitive, so positive real rates of interest have prevailed, and there has been an absence of duality in the wage structure by size of firm or sector of production. 1 The Revisionist Critique The “Market Friendly” Approach The market friendly approach captures important aspects of East Asia’s success. These economies are stable macroeconomically, have high shares of international trade in GDP, invest heavily in people, and have strong competition among firms. But the characteristics are the outcome of many different policy instruments. And the instruments chosen particularly in the north-east HPAEs, Japan, Korea, Taiwan, China, sometimes included extensive government intervention in markets to guide private sector resource allocation.2 Augmenting the Market through Competition. INSULATING THE BUREAUCRACY. The Role of Trade. The restriction on imports and foreign direct investment [into] Japan was probably the most important policy until the early 1970s (as regards innovation). Restricting the growing Japanese market, already the second largest in the capitalist world in the late 1960s, to the Japanese firms who were competing intensively among themselves gave a strong incentive to invest in plants, equipment and R&D. 3 THE SUSTAINABILITY OF THE MIRACLE First, factor accumulation has been much more important than total factor productivity growth, especially in comparison to earlier epochs of rapid catch-up growth in western Europe and Japan; nonetheless, 1 2 See World Bank, The Asian Miracle, 82. See World Bank, The Asian Miracle, 85. Rodrik, Dani, “King Kong Meets Godzilla: The World Bank and the East Asian Miracle,” in Miracle or Design? Lessons from the East Asian Experience, ed. Albert Fishlow et al. (Washington, D.C.: Overseas Development Council). 3 productivity performance has been stronger than has been allowed by critics of the east Asian experience. Second, a temporary demographic advantage of rising labor force participation has given these economies an added boost to economic growth during recent decades. Third, development has taken place rapidly from an initial position of economic backwardness, which has generated its own legacy of financial and other institutions4. What caused the crisis? 4 Crafts, Nicholas, “East Asian Growth: Before and After the Crisis,” IMF, 1998, WP/98/137. Policy response to the crisis Of course, not everyone agrees with the international community's approach of trying to cushion the effects of such crises. Some say that it would be better simply to let the chips fall where they may, arguing that to come to the assistance of countries in crisis will only encourage more reckless behavior on the part of borrowers and lenders. I do not share the view that we should step aside in these cases. To begin with, the notion that the availability of IMF programs encourages reckless behavior by countries is far-fetched: no country would deliberately court such a crisis even if it thought international assistance would be forthcoming. The economic, financial, social, and political pain is simply too great; nor do countries show any great desire to enter IMF programs unless they absolutely have to5. The second criticism is that the fiscal and monetary policies urged on the governments in the region contributed to the crisis by causing a shop drop in demand and creating more economic contraction, bankruptcies and unemployment. In a potentially recessionary situation, the IMF’s critics maintain, steps should be taken to bolster demand – not to reduce it. Again Fischer has articulated the IMF position. Other observers have advocated more expansionary fiscal programs to offset the inevitable slowdown in economic growth. The balance here is a fine one. As already noted, at the outset of the crisis, countries need to firm their fiscal positions, to deal both with the future costs of financial restructuring and--depending on the balance of payments situation--the need to reduce the current account deficit. Beyond that, if the economic situation worsens, the IMF generally agrees with the country to let automatic stabilizers work and the deficit to widen somewhat. However, we cannot remain indifferent to the level of the fiscal deficit, particularly since a country in crisis typically has only limited access to borrowing and since the alternative of printing money would be potentially disastrous in these circumstances. The Aftermath As noted above the long term effect of the crisis has been less than was feared at the time, an especially surprising outcome when viewed against the problems of the European and US economies during 2000-2002. These difficulties included a major US market collapse and a sharp fall in all kinds of information technology related equipment that dealt a sharp blow to the economies of Korea and Taiwan. Growth has been positive for 5 The Asian Crisis: A View from the IMF, Address by Stanley Fischer, First Deputy Managing Director of the International Monetary Fund at the Midwinter Conference of the Bankers' Association for Foreign Trade, Washington, D.C., January 22, 1998 almost every country in the region for every year except 2001. The exceptions have been Taiwan and Singapore in 2001 and Japan in 1998, 2001 and 2002, Foreign investment inflows are now positive into the region, although (except for China) they are running at about the half that they were in 1996 and 1997. The economies do still face major problems. The non-productive loans (NPLs) on the still considerable; in Indonesia in early 2002, some 50% were non performing with almost 30% in Thailand. Nevertheless, it can be said that the road to recovery6 has been started down. The question is whether the developmental model should change, and whether this will occur as natural consequence of the crisis or will require policy intervention. 6 East Asia: The Road to Recovery, Washington : World Bank, 1998 THE LESSONS OF THE MIRACLE 1. Macroeconomic stability is an important prerequisite for sustained economic expansion. Growth is not possible in a hyperinflationary situation, or for that matter in one of widely fluctuating demand. However, single-digit inflation is not a necessity; moderately high inflation rates have been associated with rapid growth in South Korea and elsewhere. 2. Government action is essential in establishing the preconditions of growth, especially in transportation, communication, and education. As Patrick found in Japan, macroindustrial policy creating infrastructure and human capital does work. 3. The record of microeconomic industrial policy has been mixed. Some apparent successes have been counterweighed by some very notable failures. Problems are more likely the closer the economy gets to the cutting edge of new technology. In the early stages of industrialization it is easier to predict the most appropriate sectors to favor, since changes in the industrial structure can follow an established pattern of comparative advantage. In later phases of growth it becomes harder to “pick winners,” as the Japanese experience with inter alia HDTV shows. 4. Reliance on directed credit may have adverse consequences for the banking sector, which can be left with a portfolio of losers. If they are not guided by bureaucrats, bankers will pay care to assess the risks associated with a loan. The direction of credit by planning agencies distorts the allocative efficiency of financial markets and removes discretion from the bankers. Being forced to lend to politicians’ favorites, rather than the most potentially productive firms, can upset the stability of the financial sector, as experiences in South Korea and Japan showed in the Asian financial crisis. 5. Education expenditure is generally worthwhile, but is most effective when it is directed toward elementary education. Raising the literacy rate is cheap relative to producing a university graduate, and the greatest gains in workforce productivity are provided by a literate workforce. 6. The probity of financial markets is important. Individuals are less likely to save if they lack faith in financial intermediaries. Somewhat surprisingly the Asian financial crisis of 1997– 1998 has not had a profound affect on personal saving. 7. Stock markets have not been an important element in the initial growth and development of Asian economies. Equity markets in early stages of development have tended to be shallow, rather volatile, and more significant in the redistribution of wealth than in the creation of it. Even in the most developed of the Asian economies, Japan, the stock market has been manipulated and has been a potential source of economic instability. 8. Foreign direct investment has not been a dominant factor in Asian growth. Japan’s success was financed to a very large degree out of domestic saving; in Korea loans from multilateral agencies were a substantial factor. In Indonesia and Singapore foreign investment has been more vital. In fact, the greater the reliance on foreign finance the more vulnerable was an economy to the panic and capital outflow of the crisi years. 9. Competitions—for example, those predicated on export performance—can be useful ways to augment the market, but only if they are well designed and disinterestedly administered. Recent problems in Korea concerning the dominance of few major groups calls into question how well Korean “competitions” helped the long-run growth of the economy. It is possible that the reliance on such competitions encouraged the over expansion, and subsequent collapse, of the dominant chaebol. 10. Well-paid and respected civil servants lower the probability of corruption. For a long time the image of incorruptible and very competent civil servants was a vaunted characteristic of the Asian model. American businesspeople, deeply mistrustful of government officials at home, attributed farseeing powers to those of Japan and Korea. However, more systematic studies of the Asian experience have revealed a much higher degree of corruption and a lower degree of competence, than once thought the case. The Lesson of the Crisis . . . despite its favorable attributes, such as effective mechanisms for technology transfer, outward orientation, and high savings, investment and human capital accumulation.there are downsides to the developmental state model, including a tendency to wasteful investment and the difficulties that it may pose for the transition to freer capital markets. These last are more attractive after the initial phase of development when coordination problems loom less large and diminishing returns are a bigger concern. Because the greatest successes of this managed development have come in the context of export-oriented manufacturing and industrialization, [I conclude] that an alternate model may be more appealing in the coming years of de-industrialization7. 7 Crafts, Nicholas, “East Asian Growth: Before and After the Crisis,” IMF, 1998, WP/98/137.