Painting the SFI Landscape Observations from a Survey of State-Owned Financial Institutions By David Marston and Aditya Narain I. INTRODUCTION The state has a major presence in the financial sector of many countries around the world. This is particularly visible in banking, where despite several privatization initiatives over the last decade, public sector banks are still estimated to account for a significant portion of total banking sector assets.1 State intervention, however, is not confined to banking but also extends, albeit in a lesser degree, to insurance and contractual savings and collective investment schemes. Further, though state intervention is often more prominent in the developing world, it can also play an important role in the developed world, taking a variety of different forms from direct presence—banking in Germany to sponsorship—GSEs in the United States (Box 1). In the course of their country work, Fund staff regularly face issues of how the SFIs should be dealt with, given the overwhelming perception of SFIs as being inefficient and a fiscal drag. The resulting “wisdom” is that privatization is the route toward efficiency and more effective supervision. Notwithstanding, and even after the spate of privatizations in the 1970s, SFIs continue to thrive and have played significant roles in financial stability—from being a catalyst to crisis in Turkey, to being a stabilizing force in Russia. Over and above privatization, a quick survey of the headline issues over the past few months reveal the spectrum of issues that have confronted policy makers with regard to SFIs— recapitalization from the central bank reserves (China), concern of implicit guarantees of the housing GSEs and their supervisory framework (USA), buyback of equity of state banks and merger of development institutions with state banks (India), merger of development banks among themselves (Jamaica, Thailand, Taiwan, Indonesia, and Iran), and the furor over the threatened ratings downgrade of state banks (Germany). While information failures, externalities, economic disequilibrium, failure of competition, incomplete markets, institution building, and the need to redistribute resources according to the social agenda are often the rationale2 for intervention by the state, its detractors remain See, for example, data on the “percentage of bank assets government owned” for 107 countries tabulated in Barth (2001). 1 2 The U.S. budget documents contain an informative account of the rationale for state intervention in the financial sector. See, for instance, Chapter 8 of the 1998 budget document (Analytical Perspectives). For a discussion on the adverse effects of state ownership, see Chapter III of IMF (1998) and Carmichael (2002). 533581790 March 9, 2016 (12:42 AM) -2- Box 1. State Intervention in the Financial Sector in Advanced Economies—United States of America In the USA, the intervention of the state in the financial sector takes place in the form of both direct loans and guarantees as well as through the government-sponsored private enterprises. The range of intervention and the public perception of these programs is best summarized in this extract from the U.S. Budget Document for FY 2003: “Federal credit programs offer direct loans and loan guarantees for a wide range of activities, primarily housing, education, business and rural development, and exports. At the end of 2001, there were $242 billion in Federal direct loans outstanding and $1,084 billion in loan guarantees. Through its insurance programs, the Federal Government insures bank, thrift, and credit union deposits up to $100,000 guarantees private definedbenefit pensions, and insures against other risks such as natural disasters. The Federal Government also enhances credit availability for targeted sectors indirectly through Governmentsponsored enterprises (GSEs)—privately owned companies and cooperatives that operate under Federal charters. GSEs provide direct loans and increase liquidity by guaranteeing and securitizing loans. Some GSEs have become major players in the financial market. In 2001, the face value of GSE lending totaled $3.1 trillion. In return for serving social purposes, GSEs enjoy some privileges, which include eligibility of their securities to collateralize public deposits and be held in unlimited amounts by most banks and thrifts, exemption of their securities from SEC registration, exemption of their earnings from State and local income taxation, and ability to borrow from Treasury, at Treasury’s discretion, in amounts ranging up to $4 billion. These privileges leave many people with the impression that their securities are risk-free. GSEs, however, are not part of the Federal Government, and their securities are not federally guaranteed. By law, the GSEs’ securities carry a disclaimer of any U.S. obligation.” The reasons for intervention by the state are mentioned as information opaqueness (e.g. about certain groups of borrowers like start-up businesses and farmers); externalities (without state intervention, people may invest less than socially optimal amounts in activities that generate positive externalities, while over-investing in those that generate negative externalities), resource constraints (of the private sector, for example, in deposit insurance) and imperfect competition (because of barriers to entry, economies of scale, and foreign intervention). In the U.S. context, the main rationale for the Federal role is to “provide credit and insurance that private markets would not provide.” A host of government departments and GSEs are involved in the administration of these programs and their oversight—Department of Housing Affairs; Department of Veteran Affairs; the Department of Agriculture; Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Federal Home Loan Bank System (housing finance); Department of Education and Sallie Mae (education loans); Small Business Administrations, Farmer Mac, and the Farm Credit System (business and rural development credit); Departments of Agriculture, Defense, State, and Treasury and AID; OPIC and Export-Import Bank (international credit); FDIC (deposit insurance); Pension Benefit Guarantee Corporation (private pension plans); Federal Emergency Management Agency (flood insurance); and Risk Management Agency of USDA (subsidized crop insurance). The scope and content of these programs is substantial, so much so that the Budget Document of FY 1998 mentioned that “the Federal government continues to be the largest financial institution in the United States.” In recent times, concern is being expressed about the exponential growth in the contingent liabilities of some of the GSEs, especially in the housing finance and the pension segments, and calls for capping these have been reported in the press. At the same time, there is also discussion on the strengthening of the supervisory arrangements for some of these agencies, following an accounting scandal in one of the largest GSEs. -3- unconvinced. They see state ownership as creating market distortions, thwarting competitive forces, limiting supervisory effectiveness, clouding the budgetary process, leading to frequent recapitalization, and increasing the scope for patronage and corruption. In any case, as is argued, the state can always intervene directly through the budget process to instead of seeking to ‘own’ for instance, banks. Many reasons have been offered as to why the state chooses to ‘own’ a financial institution3—for instance, the private sector institutions may not have developed in the sector, or it may want to directly control the outcomes, i.e., to make a political statement. While many institutions have been created specifically for the purpose of lending to priority regions or activities or offering subsidized insurance to vulnerable target groups, there have also been waves of nationalization of the private sector institutions, particularly in the decolonization phases, where the attempt may have been, in part, to reduce the economic concentration of power. While there has been a gradual return of ownership to the private sector, particularly in Europe and Latin America, the state will continue to be a dominant player in the financial sector for times to come. II. IMF SURVEY In this background, IMF conducted a survey4 of countries in October 2003 of the structures, relationships, and incentives that affect the performance, supervision, and governance of SFIs. It seeks to provide an insight into some of the following questions: do SFIs have a competitive advantage over the private sector in terms of funding? Are they subject to less effective supervision? Are their governance policies intrinsically weak? The survey aimed at initiating an agenda of research that abstracted from issues of ownership but rather recognized SFIs as a fact of the financial landscape. Staff experience has been that oversight arrangements vary markedly, and absent explicit guidance from the standard setters, the research agenda would aim at developing good practice guidance on oversight that would better inform the work of the Fund. The survey sought responses from a large group of member countries on all ‘state-owned’ financial institutions whether commercial and specialized/development banks and nonbanks, insurance companies, or collective/other investment schemes such as mutual, investment, provident, and pension funds. Keeping in mind that the influence of ownership could be exercised by the state, even in the absence of a majority stake, ‘state owned’ was defined as “any shareholding arrangement by which the state (central, state, local, or other elected body) or any entity of the state has a controlling ownership interest or a minority that allows the 3 See Hemming and Fouad in this volume for a discussion on the rationale of state ownership of banks in this volume. 4 See Appendix for the format of the survey. -4- state to exercise management control.” Information was sought from national authorities on the following broad areas: types of institutions and activities; ownership structures; policy goals; funding arrangements; supervision and oversight; and governance arrangements. At the time of this conference, the survey still represented work in progress. Of the 25 countries which responded, 2 countries reported ‘nil’ state-owned institutions, while 1 country reported that it had only 1 insurance company in this category, which had been set up to in the aftermath of a particular event, and that it would be wound up by the end of the year. The remaining 22 countries reported 680 SFIs in all three broad segments—banking, insurance, and securities/investments, though commercial banking was by far the most significant. In the following sections, some of the results of the survey are presented. However, there are some very important caveats to be kept in mind while interpreting these results. First, the sample is actually by default based on those countries that responded to the survey in time and, hence, these results should not be taken to be representative of the universe. For instance, of the entire 680 reported institutions, 1 developed country reported 520 banking institutions owned by the local and state governments which would tend to give a very skewed picture of SFIs in the developed world! As data for these were presented on an aggregate basis, these institutions have not been taken into account while presenting many of the responses. Second, in some cases the responses are incomplete, i.e., the authorities contacted have reported only on the institutions that are supervised by them or are under their regulatory influence. As our contact agencies were the central banks and the bank supervisor in most cases, hence, the number of SFIs, especially the nonbanks, may have been underreported. In addition, there are several other factors which have likely inhibited the authorities in their responses or have delayed them. The first is the apprehensions that the survey results may be used to underscore or promote the privatization agenda of the international institutions since this has often been an important component of Fund/Bank advice. A second reason is that simply no single agency has this information. As a result, it would require a coordinated effort among many agencies to obtain this information in several countries, because the SFIs could be under the administrative charge of a host of ministries and spread across federal, regional, and local governments. III. THE SFI LANDSCAPE SFIs are prevalent in many areas of financial activity. Countries were asked to report on each SFI, indicating what type of institution did it operate as (commercial bank, development bank, etc.) From the institutions in the state sector reported in the survey (Table 1), it may be seen that SFIs are prevalent in many areas of financial activity although commercial banking is dominant (and the most discussed). Further, they are a feature in both the developed and developing countries in the sample, although in the former, their presence is only in the banking and insurance sectors. Among banking institutions, some were reported as banks, -5- others as development banks, and in 5 countries, as institutions which engaged in both commercial and development banking. Table 1. State-Owned Financial Institutions in Responding Countries Commercial banks (1) (2) Development banks Commercial cum development banks Postal banks Nonbank finance companies Development financial institutions Leasing companies Mutual guarantee companies Insurance companies (3) Asset management companies/funds Mutual funds Pension/provident funds Investment companies/funds Health insurance fund Total (4) Advanced Economies Institutions Countries 19 5 Other Emerging and Developing Economies Institutions Countries 56 11 Total (institutions) 75 Total (countries) 16 4 1 4 1 9 9 5 3 13 10 9 4 1 0 1 0 2 2 2 2 3 2 3 3 1 1 6 2 7 3 0 21 0 1 2 0 1 0 2 21 1 1 3 2 2 2 5 3 0 0 10 3 10 3 0 0 0 0 2 3 1 2 2 3 1 2 0 0 4 1 4 1 0 50 0 1 1 108 1 158 1 Notes: (1) Under commercial banks, advanced economies, institutions, includes 1 bank providing both banking and insurance services, and another bank providing banking, insurance, and asset management services. (2) Under commercial banks, other emerging and developing economies, institutions, includes four banks providing banking and asset management services, and one bank providing banking, insurance, and securities services. (3) Under insurance companies, other emerging and developing economies, institutions, re-insurance company. (4) Under total, advanced economies, institutions, excludes 520 savings banks owned by the state and local governments reported by one country for which aggregated data was reported. -6- The size of the SFI sector can be significant (Table 2). In the sample, the size of the assets of the state-owned institutions varied from insignificant to 159 percent of GDP. Among the different types of institutions, banks tended be the most significant in size, with the largest single bank having assets equal to 47 percent of GDP, development bank 13 percent, insurance company 2.9 percent, DFI 2.3 percent and a pension fund 18 percent. The size of the assets under management of AMCs was not given. Table 2. Size of the SFI Sector Other Size to GDP Advanced Emerging/ (in percent) Economies Developing 0-1 3 2 1-10 1 4 10-50 2 6 50-100 1 1 100+ 1 1 Total 8 14 Note: Under the size to GDP column, 100+ includes 520 banks excluded from Table 1, which together account for 48. percent of GDP in the country. Minority shareholding by the state was uncommon. Of the institutions for which data was provided, about half were fully owned by the state (40 percent by the central government and less than 10 percent by state or local government). Another 20 percent were majority central government owned (with the stake ranging from 50 percent to 99 percent) and 20 percent majority owned by the state government. In the remaining 10 percent, the government held a minority stake but held control over management, thus leading to their classification as a SFI. Nationalization or takeover of private institutions was rare. Only nine institutions in three countries were reported to have been nationalized, erstwhile private sector institutions. All others were set up in the public sector with specific objectives. In the case of banks, these objectives ranged from benefit of a particular region, trade, or activity (SME, artisan, and tradesmen) to agriculture, trade, encouragement of thrift, housing, and even collection of judicial deposits. In the case of development banks it ranged from general economic development to development of infrastructure, middle and low income housing, and international trade. The development financial institutions (DFIs) had been set up for the support of specific sectors such as industry, agriculture, housing, and tourism. The insurance companies included general insurance, reinsurance, and export credit insurance. The mutual guarantee companies specialized in providing financial guaranties to their participant partners (SME) focused on specific regions or sectors of activity and the government reinsures the majority of transactions under public policy programs. Investment funds were mainly linked to social safety nets such as health insurance and retirement, while the nature of business the asset management funds/companies was not specified. -7- In Table 3, we include a sampling of the objectives of the institutions, as laid out in the authorizing or acquiring law, to provide an insight into the diverse flavor of public policy expectations from these institutions and also reproduce in Box II, the multitude of objectives assigned to just one SFI. Table 3. Policy Objectives of SFIs Type of Institution Commercial Banks Postal Banks Development Banks Development Financial Institutions Insurance Companies Export Credit Agency Health Fund AMC Stated Policy Objectives in Authorizing/Acquiring Law of SFIs to support the economic development of the country; to take money from juridical and natural persons and to allocate them; to establish conditions for the implementation of the regional economic and social programs; to direct lending to the priority industries and the population; to order the financial and economic relations between enterprises, establishments, organizations, financial institutions, state bodies, financial flows and the region’s budget; (to ensure) timely receipts of tax payments; to undertake mortgage lending and issue of mortgage bonds; to participate in realization of national investment policy in priority sectors of economy; to earn profits; to receive and grant loans on behalf and by order of the government; to create a system of financing and lending to producers of agro industrial sector; to liven up the work of the administration on capital markets; to make operations with budget accounts of the district and local authorities; to develop progressive forms of the external economic links to widen the export potential; to ensure the equilibrium of the balance of payments and increase the efficiency of public production; to support artisans, tradesman, and SME’s economically; to stimulate public savings; and to collect and manage deposits imposed by the law or by the courts. to grant loans to public sector; to encourage the savings of households nationwide; to protect small depositors; and to support the government housing policies by granting subsidized housing loans. to promote the state’s economy ensuring credit to all economic sectors; to promote productive activities in the region; to specialize in medium- to long-term operations; to provide fixed and working capital; to offer guarantees and direct technical assistance for the preparation and capacitation of personnel specialized in the execution of projects aiming at the social-economic development of the state; furtherance of financing according to state commission; to make loans and other financing to public sector; to support the country’s development policies by extending loans to the joint-stock companies; to channelize savings in the country and abroad toward development-oriented investments; to contribute to the improvement of the capital markets; to support infrastructure investments and other investments of the municipalities both financially and technically; to favor the development of the national economic activities; to serve as the financial arm of the development policy of the state; to provide exclusive management of consignations; support of government’s housing policies by granting residence loans to government employees; asset management services to other public entities; and to provide second floor operations to private financial entities development of SMEs countrywide; provision of Agricultural Credit to Farmers; to investigate and finance tourism; to provide loans and grants of public moneys for the construction of dwellings; and granting of loans for housing purposes with priority given to persons of middle or low income to act as an insurer in respect of the assets and prospective liabilities of the (state) and statutory corporations; to transact workers compensation insurance; to administer a motor accident compensation scheme; to carry out functions in relation to the management and control of moneys and other assets of the (states) and statutory corporations; and to create a local reinsurance capacity the improvement of exports, diversification of exported goods and services, causing exportation to enter into new markets; providing exporters and overseas contractors with support for increasing the competitiveness and security in international markets; and supporting and encouraging overseas investments and production and sale of export-oriented capital goods to support the development of an efficient and equitable health care system by providing affordable, accessible health insurance to mobilize investment and to make operations on the securities market; -8- Box 2. Financial Superheroes—Public Policy Expectations from SFIs When SFIs are seen as instruments to implement the economic and development policies of the state, they can be entrusted with a variety of wide-ranging and diverse objectives. Such public policy expectations from SFIs can be challenging for the management of the institution. As an example, the objectives of a leading state-owned financial institution in one major emerging economy extracted from one response to the survey question on “ policy objectives in authorizing/ acquiring law’ is listed below: ...help the Federal Government in carrying its credit policy and aims (i) taking deposits, of any kind, (ii) offer banking services, (iii) manage exclusively the Federal Lotteries, (iv) act exclusively as a pawnbroker, (v) offer services on behalf of the Federal Government, provided those services are of the nature of a financial institution, or provide other services under agreements with other entities or companies, (vi operate in the financial and capital markets, (vii operate as an underwriter, broker, or dealer in the stock market, securities market, or any other capital market, (viii operate as an issuer and manager of credit cards, (ix operate in the foreign exchange market (x) operates as an insurance dealer, stocks dealer, and operate in the leasing market, (xi) offer services related to the incentive of culture and tourism, (xii) manage Federal Government’s housing and sanitation programs, (xiii) manager of the Government Severance Indemnity Fund for Employees, (xiv) manage the funds of programs on behalf of the Federal Government, (xv) grant loans and financing of social nature, (xvi) operate in the financial and capital markets on behalf of the Federal Government, (xvii) operate as a custody agent, and (xviii)offer services of consultancy and management of economic activities, public policies, welfare, and other subjects related to its activities. The spectrum of objectives incorporates, other than the traditional banking, insurance, and securities, more exotic areas such as pawn broking, lottery management, sanitation, culture, and tourism. Considering that SFIs can also suffer from ‘mission creep’ in that more objectives can be added on to their mandate to meet specific situations, they may often face situations where they are actually being guided by conflicting objectives. In this context, devising better methods to measure their performance to more accurately reflect their effects can be a task as challenging as supervising their multi-faceted operations. IV. ISSUES IN COMPETITION AND FINANCIAL RELATIONS WITH THE GOVERNMENT Among the many reasons why SFIs are seen to thwart competition is that they are perceived to have a funding advantage over the private sector on account of their access to the deep pockets of their owner, often through concealed subsidies and transfers that can bail them out of trouble. This often implicit and sometimes explicit guarantee allows them to access funding at cheaper rates. Governments recognize this contingent liability but this is not often reflected in their budgetary estimates. Besides, particularly in the case of banks, they are often the preferred bankers for the state, receiving both deposits and government business. -9- Though the survey did not address these issues primarily, the responses provide an insight into some of these issues and are discussed in this section. SFIs may have access to a more extensive funding base. While commercial banks, as well as commercial cum development banks, relied mainly on retail deposits as their main funding sources, 90 percent of the development banks had no retail deposits. There were, however, two development banks which reported around 40 percent exposure to retail deposits. This clouds the distinction between development banks and commercial banks and presents a situation where the rationale for the regulation for both could be the same. In addition, one reinsurance company, one investment company and three DFIs also reported high (more than 70 percent) retail deposits. The development banks relied more on wholesale deposits and long-term borrowings from the treasury and central bank as their major funding source. In addition, direct government grants were reported as funding sources for commercial banks (two countries), commercial and development banks (two countries) and for the guarantee companies in one country, and two for other institutions. Far more important and widespread was the reliance on government deposits, which were reported by banks and development banks in nine countries, but were more significant in development banks (up to 65 percent of the total) than in commercial banks (up to 3 percent of the total). In a few cases, the state provides explicit guarantees for the liabilities of the SFIs. While one country offered full coverage for all deposits of the state banks, another country covered retail deposits in full for 4 of the 19 state banks it reported and for the MTNs, marketable bonds and CPs issued by two other banks; while two countries offered this coverage for the deposits held prior to the takeover of acquired banks. In the case of development banks, two countries explicitly guaranteed the retail and wholesale deposits, as well as bond and other borrowings of the development banks, while one country each covered the retail deposits of its postal bank, commercial cum development bank and development financial institution. Policy lending was an important feature, though bank supervisors were at times used for monitoring policy targets. Sixty-one institutions (including 13 institutions stated to be operating as commercial banks) reported receiving annual or periodic policy targets from the government. These targets were monitored regularly, with period varying from one week to one year and by different bodies—the concerned ministry (ministry of property, development, industry, foreign trade, foreign affairs, science and technology, and any other ministry that allocated the resources for the SFI; the Board, the SEC, the audit court, and in several cases, (18 institutions in 5 countries), the bank supervisors or central bank. Again, in many cases, the performance was monitored jointly by more than one agency. Transfers to the SFIs from the state are often off the budget and non-transparent. Nine institutions reported receiving annual or periodic funds from the government which were all itemized in the government budget. Another 41 institutions (in 11 countries) reported receiving government funds only under ‘infrequent special conditions’ and of these, 13 (in 5 countries) reported that the funds were not itemized in the government budget. SFIs were also used for raising financial resources for government. Of the 34 institutions that reported government bonds as an area of activity, 20 had an exposure less that - 10 - 10 percent of assets, 9 between 10 percent to 50 percent and 5 had an exposure greater than 50 percent. These were three banks and two postal banks. In addition, of the 36 SFIs, that reported data on the average percentage of net profits transferred to the government, in nearly half the cases, these were more than one third of the net profits. Profitability and performance was not without concerns. Though the majority of the institutions were intended to be run on a ‘for profit’ basis with the rest to be run on a ‘zerocost’ basis, nearly one third of all institutions for which individual data was available reported a loss in at least one of the three previous years. Capital injections were fairly widespread ( see Table 4) and not infrequent and took many forms such as subscriptions of shares, reinvestment of dividends receivable/issue of shares in lieu of dividend, fiscal appropriation, issues of special government bonds, transfers from the concerned ministry, grants, assumption of debts (banks), and assumption of losses (insurance). As many as 63 institutions reported capital injections since inception (32 banks, 9 development banks, 8 commercial cum development banks, 1 postal bank, 4 DFIs, 3 insurance/guarantee companies, 3 AMCs, and 1 ECA. In 42 cases, the most recent injection had taken place in the period 2000–03, while in 37 cases, there had been more than one capital injection in the past, including in 19 banks, 1 postal bank, 5 development banks, 8 commercial cum development banks, 2 AMCs, 2 DFIs, and 2 insurance companies. Table 4. Capital Injections in SFIs For Profit Zero Cost 71 11 18 6 (25 percent) (55 percent) Capital injections in previous periods 41 10 (58 percent) (90 percent) (1) excludes 21 guarantee companies run on zero cost basis which reported financials on an aggregated basis. Number of institutions (1) Losses in one or more of past three years If profit maximization is not the stated goal of the SFI, then financial data needs to be looked at in conjunction with the desired outcomes vis-à-vis the policy goals to make an assessment of the performance of the SFI. Does moral hazard affect the risk behavior of SFIs? It could be argued that because the state has a history of bailing out SFIs in times of distress and, because many SFIs are used to affect policy lending or investment, the managers of the SFIs are encouraged to engage in riskier lending/investing behavior. This, in turn, could be reflected in a higher level of NPLs. At the same time, when combined with the desire of the state to minimze the reported “cost” of operating the SFIs to meet its own budgetary needs, this could also result in lower provisioning for the NPLs. - 11 - Table 5. NPLs and Provisioning Coverage of SFIs Provisions NPL Number to NPLs Number (in percent) of SFIs (in percent) of SFIs 0–5 27 0–5 7 5–10 21 5–10 12 10–20 12 10–20 8 20–50 8 20–50 9 >50 3 >50 39 Note: (1) Under >50, under Provisions to NPLs, under Number of SFI, includes 10 which report full or more provisioning No solid conclusions should be drawn from the data presented in Table 5, (except that managing credit risk remains challenging for SFIs) in the absence of comparator private sector data and given that there may be a difference in the classification, provisioning, and taxation regimes. However, one third of the SFIs reported NPLs higher than 10 percent while a similar proportion also showed that their provisioning covered less than half the reported NPLs. V. ISSUES IN SUPERVISION & GOVERNANCE The survey sought information on a variety of supervisory aspects: Most institutions are subject to some form of minimum prudential standards. The exception to this were 2 postal banks, 3 development banks, the 2 mutual funds, the 2 pension funds, and the 4 investment companies. While the standards were prescribed under the relevant banking laws for the state-owned banks, for one postal bank, it was the State Corporations Act; and for the development banks, it varied from the law incorporating the institution, legislative decrees, the Companies Act, special resolutions/regulations of the central bank, the central bank act, the banking law or its amendments; for the insurance companies, it was mainly the insurance act; for the guarantee companies, it was a special act; for the DFIs, it was state corporations act; and for the NBC, it was the central bank law combined with federal law. Loose convergence of supervisory approaches—The responses suggest that in many countries the approaches to supervision/regulation applicable to commercial banks are being carried over to the development banks and the DFIs, and in most cases, the supervision of these entities had been entrusted to the banking supervisor. Most development banks were subject to risk-weighted capital requirements like their commercial banking counterparts. However, the practices were not as uniform in other aspects—for instance, while most development banks were subject to some form of single/group borrower exposure limit, it - 12 - was not always linked to the entities equity. In some cases, it was an absolute amount; in some cases, it was determined by the budgetary laws or by internal resolutions or estimates. The mutual guarantees companies were subject to regulation identical to banks and were also supervised by the bank supervisor, as were 3 of the DFIs. The plethora of oversight agencies could lead to conflicting interests and coordination issues. For banks, compliance with regulations was most often supervised by the banking supervisor. In addition, in many cases, the performance targets were also monitored by the supervisor which could be seen to create a conflict of interest. In one of the two countries reporting the biggest size of the sector, the authorities for monitoring compliance with the standards were, in addition to the bank supervisory agency, the ministry of finance, the national auditors, and foreign exchange administration. In the case of the second, compliance was monitored by both the supervisory agency and the state government for the banks and the ministry of finance with the ministries of economy and labor for the development bank. In another case, it was mentioned that the compliance with the standards was done by the banking supervisor at the request of the ministry of finance, although the final responsibility lay with the ministry. For the one postal bank, which was reported to be supervised, the relevant agency was the ministry of finance and the office of the president. For some nonbanks, compliance with regulations was monitored by the administrative ministry (ministry of finance or economy or the concerned ministry for the DFI (tourism, agriculture, etc.)). For the insurance companies, the supervisor was the insurance supervisory agency, except in two cases, where it was the treasury in one case and a combination of a private auditor, economy ministry, and a parliamentary tribunal in another. Regulatory forbearance is more likely to be implicit rather than explicit. Exemption from banking law was specifically provided only in a few cases involving development banks and postal banks. Further, supervisory standards could differ between state-owned enterprises and their private sector counterparts. Although, in most cases where institutions were subject to prudential standards, they were reported to be subject to the same standards as their counterparts in the private sector; some countries did report that different standards were applied for SFIs. This ranged from banks including development banks (1 country); postal savings banks (1 country), commercial cum development banks (1 country), funds under public sector management (2 countries), insurance agency (1 country), and DFIs (1 country). In addition, some other responses were nuanced with a country with major SFI presence indicating that “while the supervisory principles were the same, the standards may differ among different types of institutions.” Corrective action by the supervisor was limited in certain institutions. Even in cases where the development banks were subject to supervision by the supervisory agency, one supervisor stated that the supervisors could “only draw the attention of the bank to the developments concerned and try and find a solution in consultation with the MoF, which could take corrective action,” while another stated that they would “take minor action while leaving stronger action to the Ministry of Finance.” Of course, in the case of postal banks and those development banks and DFIs which were not subject to supervision, no corrective action was available to the supervisors. On the issue of whether the supervisor had to - 13 - necessarily consult with the government before taking corrective action, one country stated that this was so in case of severe punishment measures; two others reported that this was necessary for their banks; another for the supervised postal bank; and in one case, for a commercial cum development bank. Inspection and audits were a regular feature although external auditors reports were not always disclosed. On-site inspections were a regular feature at the banks and insurance companies and only 1 bank reported that no on-site supervision was carried out because the supervisors relied on off-site surveillance for all banks in that country. In addition, one development bank which was otherwise supervised reported that it was not inspected on-site although all other development banks and DFIs were inspected regularly by the supervisors. While regular audits by external auditors were required in all cases, in several nonbank institutions, this was performed by an arm of the state, most often the Comptroller & Auditor General (1 postal bank, 1 commercial cum development bank, 5 DFIs, 2 insurance companies and all the funds). In addition, the fiscal authorities audited the AMCs in one country while the audit office of the banking association audited the numerous state-owned savings banks in another. The practice of choosing the external auditors varied across countries and institutions, with the appointing authorities being the AGM of the shareholders, by open competition/public bidding, by the audit committee of the supervisory board from a list approved by the central bank/bank supervisor, or by the owner. In the case of the AMCs, the results were not being disclosed although the authorities agreed that the results should be disclosed in principal at the right time. The report of the independent auditors was not disclosed in many cases although some clarified that the opinion on the annual accounts was disclosed without the report being disclosed. Governance practices leave scope for improvement. The survey sought information on some components of the governance structure and incentive systems in the SFIs—Does the board include nongovernmental representatives? How is the institution’s chief executive appointed? Under what conditions can the chief executive be removed? Are employees compensated as regular government employees? How are managers compensated? Several state-owned institutions (27 including 13 banks, 4 development banks and 3 commercial/development banks) did not have any form of nongovernment representation on their boards. With a few exceptions, most of these were fully owned by the state. However, there were also several (21) fully owned institutions which did have nongovernmental representation on the board. A wide variety of responses were received for the appointing authority for senior management—the general assembly of the shareholders, the board of directors/supervisory board/advisory board; the office of the president or prime minister or the governor of the shareholder states; the ministry of finance or the concerned ministry; or by royal decree. While in the case of commercial banks, the supervisor was almost always consulted prior to the appointment of proposed senior managers, this was not often the case for development banks (11 including 6 commercial cum development banks), for the general insurance company, or the guarantee companies. Again, the appointment of chief executives was not - 14 - often for a fixed term (11 banks, 7 development banks, 1 development/commercial bank, 2 DFIs, 3 insurance companies, and 3 of the funds). A few other SFIs reported that their chief executive was appointed on a one year renewable term, while another stated that the chief executive was by rotation from the board of directors for a one year term. In the case of one postal bank, the chief executive was the ex-officio finance secretary. In most cases, employees are not compensated like government employees. In the discussion on the incentive systems that thwart the professionalization of public institutions, and, hence, their performance, is the issue of how the employees and management of these institutions are treated—like civil servants for their pay and terms of employment or like their better paid, but less secure, private sector counterparts? The responses indicated that while the employees of banks had their own (board determined; contracted, as private sector workers; through collective wage agreement for entire banking sector; own wage agreement authorized by government) compensation arrangements; in many (12) cases, the employees of development and postal banks were compensated like government employees. However, in some of these cases, the management was compensated more competitively (like private company; performance criteria; advise by private consultants on the basis of market conditions; fixed remuneration, etc,). VI. CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS The purpose of this presentation has been to paint the landscape with regard to the diversity in the SFI sector and to look at some explicit or covert structures which highlight the issues surrounding state intervention in the financial sector. While no conclusive observations are being drawn from the limited and idiosyncratic sample, the variety of institutions and practices do suggest that there are several issues in the supervision and governance of these institutions which need to be specifically addressed. Should there, for instance, be a subset of supervisory standards that apply to banks and other institutions in the public sector? Ideally, one would expect the standards applicable to the industry be applied to all participants, but it is well recognized that there are certain features arising out of state ownership that need to be kept in mind. In the case of commercial banks, the Basel Core Principles, which are the standards for bank supervision, obliquely refer to the application of the principles to these institutions in an Appendix, suggesting that “In principle, all banks should be subject to the same operational and supervisory standards regardless of their ownership; however, the unique nature of government-owned commercial banks should be recognized”; then, it goes on to emphasize that they should be required to “operate to the same high level of professional skill and discipline as required of privately owned commercial banks,” and supervisors should “apply their methods in the same manner to (these) institutions as they do to al other commercial banks.” Yet, the issues faced by supervisors in such an environment would be the extent to which they take into account the support of the government, which can keep technically insolvent institutions open, so that the corrective action regime and the exit policy/resolution regimes - 15 - for these institution would be different, as well as would the issue of implementing fit and proper and licensing conditions. The issues are more marked and varied for development banks and financial institutions; the supervision of which may derive more from a fiscal imperative rather than a depositor protection viewpoint. This picture becomes a bit clouded as we find development banks, which have substantial retail deposits, commercial banks with very little retail deposits, and nonbanks with high retail deposits. In addition, when an institution operates both as a development bank and a commercial bank, managing the risks may be more challenging. Developing a regulatory paradigm for both (a) deposit taking nonbanks and (b) non-deposit taking development banks, development financial institutions and other nonbank credit institutions would the be the next step in the process. At the same time, this paradigm should also provide for the treatment of such of these institution, which are second tier institutions, and provide refinance rather than direct finance. A similar approach would have to be crafted for the insurance companies, which are subject to either different standards or where compliance is with the treasury or administrative ministry, and the mutual and other funds which are outside the supervisory scope of the usual supervisors. As long as supervision of these various nonbank entities is with the different ministries, their supervisors will suffer from both resource and independence issues. One approach would be to bring them under an umbrella supervisor for SFIs; another would be to integrate their supervision back with the supervisor for the sector to which they correspond but with a subset or expanded set of standards applicable to them. Irrespective of the approach taken for their supervision, improvement in the governance structures of these institutions would have to be addressed as an environment in which the state is the main stakeholder —as the owner, lender, borrower, shareholder, and sometimes depositor; and where the supervisor and the auditor are also controlled by the state. In this context, many of the recommendations regarding public sector governance, which were made in the 4th conference in this series held in 2001 (Financial Sector Governance—The Roles of the Public and Private Sectors), still remain center stage. As was stated in one of the presentations, “The ultimate challenge, therefore, is to define a set of manageable public sector governance practices that constrain the role of the public sector to its legitimate roles, and that do so in such a way that mitigates the inefficiencies and conflicts that might still arise, while minimizing the temptation for corruption.” (Carmichael 2002). - 16 - References Richard Hemming and Manal Fouad “Fiscal Transparency and Public Banks” in this volume Barth, James R., Gerald Caprio, and Ross Levine, 2001, “The Regulation and Supervision of Banks Around the World—A New Database” (World Bank: Washington, D.C.) Carmaichael, Jeffery, 2002. “Public Sector Governance and the Finance Sector” in Financial Sector Governance—The Roles of the Public and Private Sectors (Brookings Institution Press: 2002) International Monetary Fund “Toward a Framework for Financial Stability” 1998. United States Government, Office of Management and Budget, “Analytical Perspectives, Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal Year 2003” http://www.whitehouse.gov/ omb/budget/fy2003/ - 17 - APPENDIX I IMF Survey of State-Owned Financial Institutions 1. General Information 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.5(a) 1.5(b) 1.5(c) 1.5(d) 1.5(e) 1.5(f) 1.5(g) 1.5(h) Name Central government shareholding (as % of total) State & local governments total shareholdings (as % of total) Ratio of assets to GDP Does this institution operate as a: commercial bank postal savings bank development bank international trade bank mutual fund insurance company asset management/reconstruction company fund other financial institution 2. Sources of funding as a percent of total assets 2.1 Retail deposits 2.2 Are these deposits explicitly guaranteed by the government? 2.3 Wholesale deposits including syndicated loans 2.4 Are these wholesale deposits or loans explicitly guaranteed by the government? 2.5 Domestic marketable bonds, MTNs, or commercial paper 2.6 International bonds, MTNs or commercial paper 2.7 Are marketable bonds, MTNs or CP issues explicitly guaranteed by the government? 2.8 Insurance or guarantee fees 2.9 Direct government grants 2.10 Long-term borrowing from the Treasury or Central Bank 2.11 Government deposits 2.12 Other 3. Recent performance and operating statistics 3.1 Return on assets prior year 3.2 Average return on assets over the prior 3 years 3.3 Profit or loss history over prior 3 years 3.3(a) 2002 3.3(b) 2001 3.3(c) 2000 3.4 Ratio of nonperforming assets to total assets 3.5 Ratio of provisions for non-performing assets to nonperforming assets 3.6 Average percent of net profits transferred to government 4. Business/policy objectives 4.1 4.2 4.3 4.4 4.5 4.6 Originally established as public sector enterprise? Originally private, subsequently acquired by government? Law or decree authorizing institution State institutional policy objective in authorizing/acquiring law Is the institution intended to be run at a profit, at zero cost to the government enterprise, or on a subsidized basis? Percent of institution’s assets or activities devoted to: - 18 - 4.6(a) 4.6(b) 4.6(c) 4.6(d) 4.6(e) 4.6(f) 4.6(g) 4.6(h) 4.6(i) APPENDIX I agriculture housing industrial projects SME specialized lending micro finance institutions import/export other specialized finance commercial lending to corporates government bonds 5. Relationship with government 5.1 Legal minimum state ownership required by law 5.2 Receives annual/periodic government funds? 5.3 Receives annual/periodic policy target goals? 5.4 Is performance regularly monitored relative to policy targets? 5.5 By what agencies, ministries or organizations? 5.6 Are funds itemized in government budgets? 5.7 By what process are funds allocated? 5.8 Receives government funds only under infrequent special conditions? 5.8(a) How are capital injections accomplished? 5.8(b) Most recent capital injection date and amount 5.8(c) Other prior capital injection dates and amounts 6. Supervision prudential standards 6.1 Is the institution subject to minimum prudential standards? 6.2 Minimum capital standard (discuss regulatory basis and level) 6.3 Maximum loan-to-value forms 6.4 Maximum indebtedness measure 6.5 Foreign exchange exposure limits 6.6 Market risk limits 6.7 Maximum total lending limits 6.8 Singe/group/related borrower limits with any exceptions 6.9 Limits on the use of derivatives 6.10 Maximum internal risk management guidelines 6.11 Rules for recognition of non-performing assets 6.12 Rules for minimum provisions required for non-performing assets 7. Authorizing legislation and prudential oversight 7.1 What laws or decrees authorize prudential standards? 7.2 Are privately owned institutions of similar character subject to the same standards? 7.3 What supervisors or ministries monitor compliance with these standards? 7.4 How is the supervisory agency funded? 7.5 How is the head of the supervisory agency appointed and for what term? 7.6 In what circumstances can he/she be removed and by whom? 7.7 What is the range of corrective actions available to the supervisor? 7.8 Is the supervisor required to consult with the government before initiating corrective action? 7.9 Is any exemption in compliance available to these institutions? 7.10 Is the supervisor consulted on the fitness and propriety of proposed senior managers? - 19 - 7.11 7.12 APPENDIX I What powers does the supervisor have to require changes in investment or operating policies? Does the supervisor have the power to recommend changes in investments or operating policies? 8. Auditing and examination policies 8.1 Are regular inspections/examinations conducted by the supervisor? 8.2 Are regular audits required? 8.3 Who performs the audits? 8.4 How are the auditors selected? 8.5 Are the audit results publicly disclosed? 8.6 If so, how? 9. Governance policies 9.1 9.2 9.3 9.4 9.5 9.6 Does the board include non-governmental representatives How is the institution’s chief executive appointed? Does the executive serve for a fixed term? Under what conditions can the chief executive be removed? Are employees compensated as regular government employees? How are managers compensated? 10. Other factors that merit consideration