Growth and Decline in the Canadian Urban System: The Impact of Emerging Economic, Policy and Demographic Trends Pierre Filion Urban Planning University of Waterloo Keywords: Urban Systems, Urban Economics, Urban Polarization, Global Economy 1 2 Growth and Decline in the Canadian Urban System: The Impact of Emerging Economic, Policy and Demographic Trends Pierre Filion Abstract The Canadian urban system was first shaped by exogenous demand for staples and, subsequently, by the dichotomy between an industrial heartland and a resource based hinterland. Presently, transformations affecting the economy, policy-making and demography herald profound changes in the future configuration of the Canadian urban system. One possible scenario is a revival of the staples economy as economic globalization raises demand for commodities. Another scenario would entail a concentration of growth in large urban centres, by virtue of their attractiveness to specialized and high-order service occupations, two rapidly expanding economic sectors, and their strong pull on immigrants. In the case of either scenario, we can expect further polarization between growing and shrinking portions of the urban system (parts of the heartland in the first case and small urban areas in the second) in a neo-liberal policy context that is unfavourable to regional economic development interventions. The evolution of the Canadian urban system between 1971 and 2006 and present distributions of factors of growth and decline point to the second scenario, a growing large city-small city dichotomy. The article closes by discussing likely consequences of the resulting urban system configuration on labour market adjustments and public sector expenditure. Introduction In the last few decades, the Canadian urban system has been quite dynamic. Unlike many national systems of cities that have a rigid hierarchical structure, Canada’s has changed considerably in recent years. This dynamism is likely to continue in the coming decades, with new directions supplanting the most recent trends. Future trends are likely to be driven more by demographic and global economic trends than by explicit policy choices. As a result, while it is possible to outline potential configurations for the Canadian urban system, it is not certain which will prevail. The article analyzes the profound changes that will contribute to the continued transformation of the Canadian urban system: the clustering of growth in a few large urban centres and the decline of many smaller urban areas. How will modifications affecting the economy, policy and demography reshape the urban system over the next decades? This is an important topic, for trends affecting urban growth have far-reaching consequences. For example, economic and demographic growth translates into additional political influence at the national scale, which itself provides conditions for further development. Likewise, with decline come reduced political impact and a lesser capacity to secure conditions for improved economic fortunes. Moreover, a polarized urban system will inevitably pit expanding urban regions, confronted with the need for additional and improved infrastructures, against declining regions, unable to maintain infrastructure networks that exceed their needs and fiscal capacity. The more unbalanced the urban system becomes, the higher the public sector costs related to social and infrastructure expenditures, incurred as a result of having to deal simultaneously with growth and decline. Also, one cannot ignore the richer employment opportunities and superior life chances in rapidly expanding areas than in slow or negative growth regions. 3 To add historical perspective and help define the context influencing the configuration of the contemporary and future urban system, two historical phases that have moulded Canadian urban settlements are considered. The first, “staples” phase is responsible for pre-industrial settlement patterns, extending from the early European settlement to the late 19th century. A second, “heartland-hinterland,” phase accounts for subsequent uneven development between a generally rapidly growing industrialized core and the remainder of the nation, where development has been far more dispersed and cyclical. In the early years of the 21st century, rapidly advancing deindustrialization accompanied by robust world-wide demand for commodities point to a possible reversal of the heartland-hinterland disparities, whereby the resource-rich hinterland would grow faster than the manufacturing-oriented heartland. A second possible scenario is based on a different economic driver and leads to a quite different result. This alternate interpretation is based on a much enhanced role of the service sector, which accounts for an ever growing proportion of employment and consumer spending. It may be that the increasing service-sector orientation will foster a concentration of growth in large urban areas. Demographic trends are also expected to contribute to large-city growth. Immigrants, the main, and soon only, factor of population expansion, are attracted to large urban centres, which are known for their multiculturalism and where ethnic communities are wellestablished. In either circumstance, we can anticipate a widening gap between areas that are experiencing economic and demographic growth and those that are either stagnating or shrinking, given waning commitment to public sector compensatory measures, as neo-liberalism dislodges interventionism as the dominant political ideology. This article charts demographic and economic trends that have affected the Canadian urban system between 1971 and 2006. It then concentrates on more recent tendencies and 2006 variables that point to future trajectories. Historical Concepts Staples theory, as formulated by Harold Innis, provides an explanatory model for Canadian settlement patterns until industrialization emerged in the late 19th century. In this view, transportation systems, political institutions, demographic growth and the distribution and size of human settlements, were all driven by an exogenous demand for commodities. The development of Canada was propelled by the commodity needs of France and then Great Britain. The nature of the commodities in demand determined the form of transportation systems and the level of demographic growth. In the words of Innis (1995a [1931], 128): “The effects, on the economic development of the St Lawrence basin, of dependence on lumber as a staple product, were the opposite of the effects of dependence on fur. Whereas fur involved a heavy incoming cargo, lumber favoured a large return cargo and consequently provided a stimulus to immigration and settlement.” While the harvesting of fur and lumber and the extraction of minerals did not require a large population, the production of grain for export required a sizable rural population, provided mostly by immigration. In the same vein, as commodities became increasingly bulky and their flows ever larger, governments incurred debt to create required transportation systems – first canals, then railways. Successive institutional structures, culminating with Confederation, were 4 largely a response to the need to borrow and secure the resulting debt. Settlement patterns reflected the export-led staples economy (Innis 1995a [1931]; 1995b [1938]). Small population centres associated with the harvesting and extraction of commodities, along with the market and service centres catering to a rural population, and a small number of larger cities serving as points of transhipment and administrative centres for staples extraction and transportation enterprises constituted the early Canadian urban system (Sitwell and Seifried 1984). The heartland-hinterland model focuses on the division between an industrial heartland and a hinterland comprised of the remainder of the country (McCann and Gunn 1998). Protected by tariffs, and thus impelled largely by branch plants, Canadian industrialization mostly took place in the more densely populated rural basin, already the site of major cities, including Montréal and Toronto, the country’s two largest metropolitan regions. The heartland runs from Québec City to Windsor, an industrial corridor referred to as Canada’s main street (Blank 2008; Yeates 1975) (see Figure 1). The hinterland, in contrast, is more sparsely populated and continues to be mostly reliant on the extraction and harvesting of natural resources. It also includes vestiges of early Canadian industrialization in the Maritime Provinces. Still, the hinterland has spawned a number of sizable urban centres – Winnipeg, Calgary, Edmonton and Vancouver. From 1951 to 1971 demographic growth in the heartland exceeded that of the country as a whole, causing its share of the national population to reach 55 percent (Yeates 1998, 115). After this, rapid growth tended to concentrate in certain parts of the heartland: typically those areas associated with expanding sectors of the economy such as, until recently, the car industry. Meanwhile, the demographic expansion of the Québec portion of the heartland was challenged by the departure of some Anglophones reacting to the growing place given to the French language in this province, and a strong presence of sunset labour-intensive industries, such as textiles and garments. The 1988 Free Trade Agreement (FTA) between Canada and the US and the 1994 North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) involving Canada, the US and Mexico, caused major industrial realignments, as did the rapid industrialization of developing countries as global trade was liberalized (Barnes et al. 2000). Smaller branch plants were particularly affected, as were industrial sectors unable to compete with cheaper imports. Yet, lately the heartland has enjoyed rapid development in knowledge-intensive sectors such as information technology in Ottawa, Toronto and Waterloo, pharmaceuticals in Montréal and Toronto, and aeronautics in Montréal. In the interventionist climate that prevailed from the 1950s to the early 1980s, the pursuit of territorial equity objectives led to public sector support for industrial development in the hinterland as well as less prosperous parts of the heartland. The federal government and the provinces devised a succession of programs encouraging the location of industrial investments in such areas (Coffey and Polèse 1987; Savoie 1992). In the end, these programs did little to alter predominant industrial location patterns. Public sector incentives proved to be no match to advantages such as production and supplier linkages, the availability of an abundant and diversified labour force and proximity to markets. For example, all efforts to spread car assembly beyond the Southern Ontario automobile production cluster, either elsewhere in the heartland or in the hinterland, ultimately failed. Some eccentric assembly plants were short lived: Renault operated from 1964 to 1972 south of Montréal, Bricklin from 1974 to 1976 in New Brunswick and Hyundai from 1989 to 1993 in the Québec Eastern Townships. Other facilities were longer lasting. This was the case of the Nova Scotia Volvo plant, in production from 1963 to 1998, and the GM plant north of Montréal, which operated from 1966 until 2002. However, with the 5 closure of the GM plant, once again, all car assembly activities were located in Southern Ontario. Some have maintained that, when considered in their totality, allocations of government expenditure with an economic development potential (infrastructure development, education, research and development...) ultimately favoured fast growing areas despite energetic regional development interventions, thus enshrining relations of dependency between under-developed and developed regions (e.g., Matthews 1983). In this view, rather than dispersing industrial activities, government actions furthered their concentration. Although this may overstate the case to some degree, it seems clear that industrial locations patterns are shaped more by market forces than by government economic development incentives. The interventionist decades also marked the launching of interprovincial equalization and transfer programs and constitute the period when these programs came closest to achieving their social equity objectives. They resulted in a redistribution of resources from the rich parts of the heartland, notably Southern Ontario, to less well performing portions of the heartland and much of the hinterland. But in an economy protected by tariffs, these financial flows did not necessarily represent a drain on prosperous regions within the heartland, as equalization and transfer payments helped to deepen markets for their industrial products. Changing Factors of Urban Growth and Decline Three factors were instrumental in shaping the Canadian urban system: the economy, public policy and demography (see Simmons and Bourne 2003). These factors can be seen as drivers of economic and population growth and decline, and thereby as largely responsible for the configuration of the urban system at any given time during the staples and heartland-hinterland periods, as well as in the present and future. The economy played the leading role in the development of the urban system. Over the staples era, population centres were linked to the harvesting, transportation and administration of commodities, adopting an east-west distribution reflecting the predominantly European origin of demand. Subsequently, manufacturing took advantage of existing concentrations of rural population and potential linkages. Once in place, manufacturing became a catalyst for further population expansion in the industrial heartland. Over the staples era, the impact of public policy on the urban system was manifest mostly in transportation and immigration policies. Later, tariffs played a central role in the industrialization of Canada; government interventions were for the most part favourable to a further economic development of the heartland. Finally, demography is an enabling but passive factor over both periods. The combination of high rates of natural growth and at times substantial arrivals of immigrants assured an ample supply of population supportive of economically and policy induced urban development trends. Economically expanding urban areas were able to rely on their own natural growth in addition to migratory flows from different parts of the country and their respective rural and small town basins, as well as from immigration. Together, these factors maintained the dichotomy between the heartland and hinterland, along with relative stability in the industrial specialization of regions within the heartland (Davies and Donoghue 1993; Polèse and Shearmur 2006a). Current and anticipated changes affecting these three factors explain present transformations within the urban system, which mark a departure from the heartland-hinterland 6 divide, and herald deeper modifications in the future. Beginning with economic trends, it is clear that globalization has had the same devastating effect on manufacturing employment in Canada as in other developed nations. There is also a Canadian specificity to globalization, which stems from the presence of an unusually large natural resources sector. With the quick industrialization of China and India comes a rising world-wide demand for commodities, with evident advantages for the Canadian natural resources sector. One possible outcome may, however, be a case of the “Dutch Disease”, whereby rising currency fuelled by strong demand for natural resources results in a loss of competitiveness within the manufacturing sector. With varying degrees of severity, Canada has faced such a situation from 2006 to 2008, and this trend is forecast to persist in the near future (Financial Forecast Center 2008). Alternatively, steep gyrations in the value of the Canadian dollar, responding to commodity demand cycles (a situation prevailing in late 2008), can be equally debilitating for manufacturing. Together, these trends suggest a partial return to a staples-dominated economy. While heartland manufacturing is hurt by difficulties in competing with developing nations, which are exacerbated by a strong Canadian currency, the hinterland benefits from a rising world demand for commodities. The economic balance would thus be tilting in favour of the hinterland. It is important, however, to realize that the extraction and harvesting of natural resources have less employment generation potential than manufacturing does. Beyond those that presently benefit the hinterland, there are other economic factors with urban system repercussions. This second category includes factors that can be seen as favourable to the expansion of large urban areas by contributing to, or taking advantage of, economies of agglomeration enjoyed within such urban centres. Different viewpoints on economies of agglomeration have been advanced, from the Marshallian perspective on industrial districts, to the more recent network approach of Michael Porter; work on learning and innovative regions and the creative class can also be interpreted as variations on the agglomeration economies theme (Boekema 2000; Doloreux 2004; Florida 2002a; Porter 1990). Economies of agglomeration have always disproportionately benefited large urban areas, but emerging circumstances appear to accentuate such advantages. In order to fill their requirement for an increasingly specialized labour force, large workplaces need to locate within access range of a substantial pool of workers. This is particularly the case for those establishments that require highly qualified employees. Concurrently, specialized workers are attracted to large centres because of a greater chance to find employment suited to their qualifications. The need for a large employment market is especially felt by households comprised of two professionals. In addition, presence in a rich labour market allows the pursuit of “horizontal” careers, a major advantage in times of frequent employment change (Shearmur and Doloreux 2008, 1062). Concentrations of urban amenities, such as culture, entertainment, sports and wide consumption choices, also draw highly qualified workers to large centres (Gertler et al. 2002; Ghent Mallett 2002; Simmons and Bourne 2003). And, when present in a city, knowledge workers stimulate economic growth by launching new enterprises and luring in firms dependent on their skills (Florida 2002a; 2002b). The vertical disintegration of production processes also encourages the presence of employment in large urban areas because of the resulting need for firms to maintain extensive linkage networks. In a similar vein, communication advancements have made it possible to spatially separate activities related to production or extraction processes. The location of administrative and product development stages of such processes can be dictated by the presence of the required workforce and the amenities it values, rather than proximity to production or 7 natural resources. For example, although the generator of boom towns such as Fort McMurray, much of the growth benefits of the Alberta tar sands industry are felt in Edmonton and Calgary, where service-type functions related to this industry are concentrated. In itself the rapid growth of the service sector also benefits the expansion of large urban areas. The range of services present in such urban areas is broader than in smaller cities, thanks to the predilection of high-order and specialized services for large centres (Coffey and Shearmur 1998; Shearmur and Doloreux 2008). Large urban areas are thus better positioned than smaller ones to export services. This is notably the case of health care, education, government, tourism, administrative functions and a wide range of business services. The growth of the service sector advantages large cities in another way. As services account for a rising share of consumption expenditures at the expense of goods, in part due to cheap imported products, monetary leakages out of a metropolitan region are reduced. More than goods, services tend to be produced within the region and thus provide larger multiplier effects. The larger a metropolitan region, the more extensive the range of available services, and the higher are the chances that service consumption will take place within the region. Ultimately, by this logic, in a highly developed service economy, even a narrow basic (export-driven) sector could be sufficient to sustain a vast metropolitan economy. The global city perspective portrays metropolitan regions that are highly service-dependent, characterized as they are by a service-oriented export sector and an extensive and highly diversified consumption sector. But as Sassan (1991) observed, such a configuration leads to a profound income and working condition gap between high- and low-order service sector occupations. It is important to stress that in their present “galactic” configuration, large urban areas have become complex assemblages of overlapping commuter sheds and retail catchment areas (Lewis 1983). As a growing proportion of commuter journeys focus on business parks located at the edge of the urbanized perimeter, large urban areas acquire an extended zone of influence (Coffey and Shearmur 2001). We can thus expect the growth of these urban areas to reverberate throughout a wide surrounding sector of 100 kilometres or more. At the same time, however, the propulsive effect of large urban centres on more distant manufacturing centres is on the wane, as production increasingly opts for low-wage developing countries. As regards policy-making, the last two decades have witnessed a sharp shift from interventionism to neo-liberalism (Graham and Marvin 2001; Hackworth 2007; Leys 2001). With most relevance to our object of study, this transition has resulted in trade liberalization and an erosion of regional economic development and redistributive programs. Nominally, welfare programs are still in place, but their impact is much reduced as a result of funding cutbacks and an overall inability to keep up with housing and food cost inflation. Meanwhile, little is left of the regional economic development instruments of the 1960s, 1970s and early 1980s (Brodie 1997). It deserves to be said, as well, that advancing de-industrialization has greatly reduced the pool of large workplaces sensitive to regional economic development incentives. A concerted conservative assault has triggered a shift from interventionist to neo-liberal policy-making. Critiques of interventionist policies were made all the more convincing by the lukewarm success of past interventionist efforts – limited decentralization of manufacturing employment, difficulties in breaking the welfare dependency cycle and, worst of all, a ballooning public sector debt attributed to profligate and ineffective state spending. One consequence of neo-conservative attacks has been the near elimination from the political narrative of concern over territorial justice, a popular theme thirty years ago. 8 Trade liberalization was a key factor in the demise of regional economic development programs as it is in present-day critiques of inter-provincial equalization payments. Once tariff protection was breached, it became even more difficult than in the past for governments to convince investors to locate in peripheral economic regions. Subsequently, to compete successfully for investments, governments had to put forward sites with the most advantages to investors. Once more, the car industry lends itself to an illustration of broad economic and policy trends. There has been a full turn away from efforts to decentralize the car industry. Government funding is now directed at Southern Ontario locations to support either the creation of new facilities or the modernization of existing ones. What is more, with the lifting of tariffs and the consequent opening of domestic markets to international competition, there has been less interest for generally prosperous Ontario to contribute to equalization payments, since a declining proportion of this money goes to the purchase of heartland industrial products. The drop in the economic performance of de-industrializing Ontario relative to the Canadian norm further contributes to this attitude. In fact, as of late 2008 Ontario qualifies as a beneficiary province regarding equalization payments. There is an additional facet of neo-liberalism with implications for the urban system. Deregulation of transportation and the privatization of the Canadian National Railway and Air Canada have ended cross-subsidization arrangements and resulted in deteriorated services in small markets, with adverse consequences for their growth potential. Turning to demography, we can expect that, increasingly, population trends will take an active role in shaping the urban system (Bourne and Rose 2001). The demographic scene is affected concurrently by low birth rates and growing reliance on immigration to sustain and expand the workforce and population. Canada has experienced below replacement birth rates since the early 1970s, which will soon translate into more retirements than entries in the job market and, from 2020 onwards, more deaths than births (Bélanger, Martel and Caron-Malenfant 2005, 17; Statistics Canada 2006). Not only will Canadian urban areas be confronted with negative natural growth, but in most cases they will no longer be able to tap surrounding rural areas and small towns to expand or even maintain their population. Already, this source of population has largely dried up. To be sure, some urban areas, especially retirement communities, will benefit from inter-provincial migration flows as population ages. But in virtually all cases, it is on immigration that urban areas will depend to maintain and expand their population. Areas that are unable to attract immigrants will experience demographic decline, with likely adverse economic consequences (Green and Green 2004). If present tendencies hold, reliance on immigration will concentrate growth in a few large urban centres, while most of the other urban areas will either stagnate or decline. At present, about 70 percent of all immigrants settle in the three largest metropolitan regions (McDonald 2004). Such a distribution pattern is partly explained by the presence of employment opportunities, but also by ethnic communities hospitable to new immigrants accounting for a rich multi-cultural environment. Over time, a gap may develop between demographic and economic trends within these large cities, as sensitivity to welcoming social environments eventually prevents immigrants from making location choices that are primarily economically driven. Such a gap may already be partly responsible for a lagging median household income growth, relative to other census metropolitan areas, in Toronto where approximately fifty percent of all immigrants to Canada settle (Toronto Dominion 2002; 2007). In the future, other important metropolitan regions beside the three largest will likely become more welcoming to immigrants as they host more and larger ethnic communities. But urban 9 areas with little appeal to immigrants will inevitably decline. This will especially be the case of small urban centres. Despite potential adjustment difficulties in the case of immigration and economic activity, factors of urban evolution are interconnected. For example, economic globalization is abetted by neo-liberalism while itself contributing to the adoption of neo-liberal policies. And in the long run, migration and immigration are responsive to economic prosperity, in other words, to the uneven capacity of urban areas to take advantage of, rather than being ravaged by, a globalized economy. The recent evolution of these factors suggests two potential, although not mutually exclusive, urban system trajectories. There is first the possibility of a resurgence of the hinterland, a consequence of rising demand for natural resources and an associated downfall in heartland manufacturing. The other scenario would entail a growing discrepancy between expanding large urban areas, benefitting from the ongoing rise of the service economy and the presence of an important majority of immigrants, and stagnating or declining smaller urban areas. Note that with the demise of redistributive policies in the wake of neo-liberalism, we can expect a deeper polarization between growing and declining areas under either scenario, than encountered over the interventionist decades. Methodology In this study of the urban system, census metropolitan areas as well as census agglomerations with a population floor of approximately 60,000 are considered.1 We set this minimum value to avoid the steep population gyrations that often characterize smaller places. This approach is, however, responsible for incomplete time series data for centres whose population reached this threshold after 1971.2 Census data are used to verify the extent to which anticipated trends have actually materialized. Time series data from 1971 to 2006 depict the evolving balance between heartland and hinterland, and between large and small urban centres. They provide historical background for the interpretation of current tendencies and attempts at forecasting the future of the urban system. Change in employment structure between 1996 and 2006 is explored, with particular attention to categories with strong growth potential. And, in an effort to anticipate differences in the future evolution of urban areas under consideration, their 2006 employment sector distribution, age structure and presence of immigrants and inter-provincial migrants are assessed. The large urban area category includes the five census metropolitan areas with a 2006 population exceeding the million: Toronto, Montréal, Vancouver, Ottawa-Gatineau,3 Calgary and Statistics Canada defines census metropolitan areas and census agglomerations as follows: “A census metropolitan area (CMA) or a census agglomeration (CA) is formed by one or more adjacent municipalities centred on a large urban area (known as the urban core). The census population count of the urban core is at least 10,000 to form a census agglomeration and at least 100,000 to form a census metropolitan area. To be included in the CMA or CA, other adjacent municipalities must have a high degree of integration with the central urban area, as measured by commuting flows derived from census place of work data.” (Statistics Canada n.d.) 2 Over time, Statistics Canada adjust the boundaries of CMAs and CAs to reflect changes in commuting patterns; such changes generally have limited effect on population totals. 3 Known as Ottawa-Hull in earlier censuses. 1 10 Edmonton. This category also incorporates census metropolitan areas immediately adjacent to the top five CMAs. Oshawa and Hamilton, both bordering Toronto, are included from 1971 onwards, and St-Jean-sur-Richelieu and Abbotsford, adjacent respectively to Montréal and Vancouver, are added to the large city category from 1996, when they were first constituted as census metropolitan areas. All other centres are referred to as small urban areas. Canadian Urban System Trajectories Between 1971 and 1986, the hinterland experiences a faster population, employment and income growth than the heartland, partly a reflection of high energy prices and a robust demand for other commodities over this period (Tables 1, 2 and 3 and Figures 2, 3 and 4). Another contributing factor may have been the impact of the especially slow demographic and economic growth over this period of Montréal, Canada’s largest metropolitan region until 1976. Along with a departure of Anglophones, Montréal adjusted to a shrinking of its long-established Canada-wide zone of economic influence (shared with Toronto) to one that is limited to the Province of Québec (Higgins 1986; Polèse and Shearmur 2004). The urban system situation changes as the demographic growth rates of the hinterland and heartland converge over the 1986-1996 and 1996-2006 periods (Table 1 and Figure 2). However, between 1986 and 1996, the hinterland maintains its advantage over the heartland in terms of employment growth, but registers a similar rate of job creation as the heartland over the subsequent period (Table 2 and Figure 3). Finally, income follows the same convergent trajectory as population, recording a near absence of growth in both the hinterland and heartland over the largely recessionary 1986-1996 period, only to recover afterwards at about the same rate in both regions (Table 3 and Figure 4). The three tables and figures point to a period of hinterland catching up, followed by equivalent growth rates in the two regions. Note, however, that the tables indicate a variety of evolutionary patterns among hinterland and heartland urban areas. In both cases, as some urban areas experience rapid growth, others either stagnate or, indeed, decline. In the heartland such a situation is accounted for by the divergent performance of different industrial sectors, particularly the contrast between sunrise and sunset industries, whereas in the hinterland, varying growth levels are driven by the absence of synchrony in demand cycles for different natural resources – the lack of coincidence in demand peaks and valleys for oil and lumber, for example. Another factor of hinterland-heartland convergence may be the strong growth of large urban areas, irrespective of their regional location. The trend revealed by the comparison of large and small urban areas is sharper than the one that emerges from our observation of heartland-hinterland distinctions. Large cities experience more rapid growth on all three variables over all periods, with the sole exception of income over the economically troubled 1986-1996 period (Figures 2, 3 and 4). Population growth discrepancy between large and small urban areas increases after 1986, partly due to a post-1986 Montréal rebound. But differences in the growth rate of the two other variables remain largely constant over the entire 1971-2006 period. The methodology may in fact underestimate the large city category growth advantage, for a number of fast growing urban areas classified within the small urban area category – Peterborough, Guelph, Kitchener and Brantford – are in the orbit of the Toronto metropolitan region and thus benefit from its propulsive effect (Coffey and Polèse 1988; Polèse and Shearmur 2006a; Phelps, Fallon and Williams 2001; Portnov 2006; Shearmur and Polèse 2005). 11 Table 4 and Figure 5, which monitor the evolution of employment categories between 1996 and 2006, paint a similar picture to that of previous tables and figures.4 For one, while disproportionately affected by manufacturing employment losses, the hinterland experienced faster growth than the heartland in two employment categories with an important knowledge content and economic growth potential: management occupations and natural and applied sciences and related occupations. For another, these two employment categories along with occupations in arts, culture, recreation and sport (a sector of employment that contributes to the appeal of an urban area for knowledge workers), grew much more rapidly in large than in small urban areas. To help forecast future trends, the next three tables and the next figure concentrate on 2006 variables that point to future economic and demographic trajectories. Table 5 and Figure 6 show little difference between heartland and hinterland urban areas in the concentration of management occupations, natural and applied sciences and related occupations, and of occupations in arts, culture, recreation and sport. Yet, as expected, Table 5 and Figure 6 do present important variations in primary and manufacturing sector employment between these two regions. Concentration of manufacturing employment is much higher in the heartland than in the hinterland, and the opposite holds for primary sector employment. But even in the hinterland, primary sector employment as a proportion of all employment is low; manufacturing employment is declining everywhere. Evolutionary trends identified in Table 4 and Figure 5 are reflected in an overrepresentation of management occupations, natural and applied sciences and related occupations, and of arts, culture, recreation and sport occupations in large relative to small cities. All large urban areas score near or above the national average for these three occupation categories, with the exception of arts, culture, recreation and sport occupations in Calgary and Edmonton. Table 5 also indicates that, with the exception of Ottawa, heartland large metropolitan regions record a presence of manufacturing employment that exceeds the national average, while posting a below average presence of primary industry jobs. The three large hinterland urban areas, all located in Western Canada, register primary employment levels above the national norm and manufacturing employment below this level. Alongside the concentration of propulsive employment sectors, demographic features allow us to forecast future growth in the listed urban areas. Table 6 shows that the age profiles of large metropolitan regions are, as expected, less extreme than those of small urban areas. Large urban areas tend to approximate the national distribution, with somewhat of an older profile in Montréal and a younger one in Calgary and Edmonton. The most striking observation to emerge from Table 6 concerns the aging profile of the population of many small urban areas (see Statistics Canada 2007). These fall into three categories: 1) Economically struggling hinterland urban areas, which have lost much of their working age population and thus people in the child-rearing age (Chicoutimi-Jonquière, Sault Ste Marie, Thunder Bay and Nanaimo); 2) Urban areas in the heartland, which are facing similar demographic circumstances because of deindustrialization (Trois-Rivières, Kingston, Peterborough and Sarnia); 3) Retirement communities (Kelowna and Kamloops). Québec City is in a category of its own because it is the largest metropolitan region with such an aging population. The aging pattern of Québec City cannot be attributed primarily to a poor performance of national resource industries or the loss of manufacturing activity, but rather more likely to the combined effect of a low birth rate, the depletion of the regional basin from 4 It is for reasons of consistency in Statistics Canada employment categories that we focus on a ten year period in Table 4 and Figure 5. 12 which it traditionally drew its population and, we will see in Table 7, a low presence of immigrants and inter-provincial migrants. After decades of below-replacement birth rates, only migration and immigration can maintain or increase the population of urban areas. Thus, those areas capable of attracting migrants and immigrants will see their population grow or remain stable, while the ones that are unable for a variety of reasons to lure new residents will inevitably experience a downward trend at some point over the next twenty years. Table 1 has offered a foretaste of things to come by listing seven urban areas in decline between 1996 and 2006, whereas only one area faced similar circumstances over either the 1971-1986 or 1986-1996 periods. Table 7 indicates very low interprovincial migration with Province of Québec urban areas as a destination, a consequence of linguistic differences with the rest of Canada. Even Montréal, which pulls in large numbers of immigrants, registers an exceptionally low presence of inter-provincial migrants. Windsor and Sault Ste Marie also benefit little from inter-provincial migration. Immigration is more vital than inter-provincial migration because it provides a larger influx of population. Table 7 reveals important discrepancies in levels of immigration. It shows that immigration contributed little to the population of urban areas east of Montréal, to small centres in Southern Ontario (Belleville and Peterborough), to Northern Ontario communities (North Bay and Sudbury), to small Prairies urban areas and to Prince George in Northern British Columbia. The tendency is for large urban areas to post the highest proportion of immigrants (this is especially the case for Toronto and Vancouver) and for the small ones to register a lower presence of immigrants, although with important regional differences. Unless they experience a sharp change in their level of immigration, all urban areas with a low score will be in a perilous demographic situation over the coming decades. This will particularly be the case for the numerous urban areas that combine low inter-provincial migration and especially immigration, with an older age profile: Moncton, St John, Chicoutimi-Jonquière, Québec City, Sherbrooke, Trois-Rivières, Belleville, Peterborough, North Bay, Sudbury, Sault Ste Marie and Thunder Bay. The Coming Polarization of the Canadian Urban System Findings question past conceptualizations of growth dynamics within the Canadian urban system. The heartland-hinterland distinction seems to be on the wane, with the hinterland in a catching up phase between 1971 and 1986 but then experiencing a general stabilization of its growth level at the same rate as that of the heartland. Of course, demand cycles for different natural resources have played a role, but present and anticipated long-term, structural factors point to an ongoing robust demand for natural resources. As the heartland-hinterland divide dissipates, the large city-small city discrepancy widens. We anticipate that differences between these two groups of cities will be the major force shaping the future Canadian urban system. There is, to be sure, a persistent difference in the respective presence of primary and manufacturing sector employment in large heartland and hinterland urban areas, but it is largely the extensive service sector (both in terms of size and specialization) they share, that accounts for their rapid growth. In this light, the future of Canada will take the form of a clustering of population in a few large centres, at the expense of the remainder of the urban system. Polarization is the dominant theme to emerge from this study. As large centres will enjoy rapid growth, many small ones will decline. These contrasting trajectories will be propelled by multiple causation mechanisms responsible for durable ascending and descending trends (Myrdal 13 1963). In large urban areas, growing labour and consumer markets will attract investment, which in turn will further stimulate these markets. Also, with economic and demographic expansion comes additional political influence, which secures government interventions favourable to further growth. An opposite sequence of events will maintain a descending course in many small urban areas. If growth abets growth, decline abets decline. Conditions are thus present for a bifurcated demographic and economic evolution of the Canadian urban system. The coming age will be one of extremes, especially given reduced government capacity and determination to counteract territorial decline in a neo-liberal policy environment. The Canadian urban system of tomorrow will be polarized, confronted at once with steep urban growth and decline (Polèse and Stren 2000). In this perspective, the future will advantage Toronto, Montréal, Vancouver, Ottawa-Gatineau, Calgary and Edmonton. Urban areas within the orbit of these regions will also enjoy rapid growth. There will be other expanding settlements, but they will account for a minute share of national urban growth. This will be the case of resource-based centres benefitting from international demand cycles and retirement communities such as Kelowna and Victoria. Having seen how the economy, policy and demography have driven the evolution of the Canadian urban system, we now look at how these three aspects of society will be affected by the future configuration of this system. Such a polarized urban system will introduce economic rigidities hindering labour force adjustments to changing economic trends. On the one hand, economic victims of small urban area decline will find it difficult to move to large centres, where cost of living and especially that of housing far exceed those of small centres. At the same time, large urban areas themselves may at times face a labour force oversupply due to their strong attractive power on immigrants. In these circumstances, their ability to draw immigrants, associated with their advanced cosmopolitanism, would exceed their job creation capacity. From a policy perspective, governments will be confronted simultaneously with demands for interventions that are supportive of growth and measures to either reverse decline or attenuate its consequences. Large urban centres will call for extended infrastructure networks to accommodate growth along with expanded services to cater to their swelling population. Large city lobbies will use their rising political clout to pressure senior governments for additional financial support. A coalition of large city mayors is pressing for additional senior government physical and social infrastructure investments in order to maintain a healthy social climate and a well-performing economy (Globe and Mail June 2, 2006; Toronto Star May 5, 2007). It stresses the central role these centres play in the Canadian economy, and thus the need to take necessary measures to maintain their economic vitality (see also Conference Board of Canada 2006; 2007). Significantly, large city mayors underscore distinctions between requirements of their cities and those of smaller urban areas, and thus the need for a special treatment for large cities on the part of senior governments (Toronto Star September 17, 2004). The concentration of population in large urban centres will represent a source of tensions within provincial structures of government, as the political weight of large urban centres within provinces will increase at the expense of small centres and rural areas. Provincial governments will be loathe (as they presently are) to create powerful metropolitan-wide administrations, for fear that they could become a source of political competition. The situation is different in small urban areas, many of which will clamour for interventions to address their decline. In doing so, they will be confronted with obstacles. First, there is little evidence of government capacity to arrest economic decline. We have seen that in the past regional economic development programs met with lukewarm success. What is more, 14 there is no effective planning model to deal with declining economic activity and population (Andersen 2005; Polèse and Shearmur 2006b; Rieniets 2005). What is an urban area to do in the face of a downward demographic and economic trend and resulting shrinking financial resources? Selectively close down neighbourhoods to consolidate the remaining population or lower infrastructure and service standards (more or less) evenly throughout its territory? It is also important to recall the prevalence of a neo-liberal ideological climate suspicious of ambitious government interventions. In sum, even if senior governments were willing to intervene, their capacity to deal effectively with decline would be uncertain. In any event, given the depleted political clout that comes with a falling population and economic activity, it is unlikely that small urban areas experiencing decline will be capable of convincing senior governments to expend large amounts of resources to redress their demographic and economic conditions or, even minimally, to assuage these conditions. Finally, anticipated demographic trajectories will result in deepening social and cultural contrast between large urban areas with their rising presence of immigrants, and the remainder of the country, where the proportion of people born in Canada will remain very high. The distinction between large diversified cities and small culturally homogenous urban areas in decline will be particularly sharp. There is danger that such a polarized social environment will eventually translate in cultural and political clashes. Conclusion Findings challenge the enduring effectiveness of the heartland-hinterland perspective as an explanation of uneven development in the Canadian urban system. Evidence of heartland growth advantages over the hinterland dissipates from 1971 onwards. The interpretation of past trends and present statistics suggests a much transformed Canadian urban system in the future. The article explored the possibility of a hinterland revival that would take it back to a staples oriented model of development. While robust world-wide demand for commodities would appear to support such a development pattern, statistics on the evolution of the Canadian urban system do not point to hinterland revival as the main trend affecting the evolution of the urban system. Absence of strong growth across the entire hinterland is due to jarring demand cycles for commodities and the low employment creation potential of resource harvesting and extraction, relative to the manufacturing and service sectors. It rather appears that changes affecting the economy, policy-making and demography will result in a highly polarized pattern consisting of a few large urban areas experiencing high rates of growth and numerous smaller centres caught in a cycle of decline. The transition is driven by a rise of the service sector within the economy, which advantages large metropolitan regions, and a preference of immigrants for these regions. Diminished redistribution policies will prevent any significant growth deflection away from these centres, which could attenuate progressing polarization. References Andersen, L. L. (2005). Shrinking cities and the need for a reinvented understanding of the city. Paper given at the 2005 AESOP Conference, Vienna. Retrieved October 2008 from http://aesop2005.scix.net/cgi-bin/papers/Show?_id=320 15 Barnes, T. J., Britton, J. N. H., Coffey, W. J., Edgington, D. W., Gertler, M. S., & Norcliffe, G. (2000). Canadian economic geography at the millennium. The Canadian Geographer 44, 4-24. Bélanger, A., Martel, L., & Caron-Malenfant, É. (2005). Population projections for Canada, provinces and territories 2005-2031. Ottawa: Minister of Industry (Statistics Canada, Catalogue 91-520-XIE). Blank, S. (2008). Trade corridors and North American competitiveness. American Review of Canadian Studies 38, 231-237. Boekema, F. (2000). Knowledge, innovation, and economic growth: The theory and practice of learning regions. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. Bourne, L. S., & Rose, D. (2001). The changing face of Canada: The uneven geographies of population and social change. The Canadian Geographer 45, 105-119. Brodie, J. (1997). The new political economy of regions. In W. Clement (Ed.), Understanding Canada: Building on the new Canadian political economy (pp. 240-266). Montréal and Kingston: McGill-Queen’s University Press. Coffey, W. J., & Polèse, M. (Eds). (1987). Still living together: Recent trends and future directions in Canadian regional development. Montréal: Institute for Research on Public Policy. Coffey, W. J., & Polèse, M. (1988). Locational shifts in Canadian employment, 1971-1981: decentralization v. Decongestion. The Canadian Geographer 32, 248-256. Coffey, W. J., & Shearmur, R. G. (1998). Employment growth and structural change in urban Canada, 1971-1991. Review of Urban and Regional Development Studies 10, 60-88. Coffey, W. J., & Shearmur, R. G. (2001). Intrametropolitan employment distribution in Montréal, 1981-1996. Urban Geography 22, 106-129. Conference Board of Canada (2006). Canada’s hub cities: A driving force for the national economy. Ottawa: Conference Board of Canada. Conference Board of Canada (2007). Mission possible: Successful Canadian cities. Ottawa: Conference Board of Canada. Davies, W. K. D., & Donoghue, D. P. (1993). Economic diversification and group stability in an urban system: The case of Canada, 1951-1986. Urban Studies 30, 1165-1186. Doloreux, D. (2004). Regional innovation systems in Canada: A comparative study. Regional Studies 38, 481-494. Financial Forecast Center (2008). <http//www.forcasts.org/cdollar.htm> Florida, R. (2002a). The rise of the creative class. New York: Basic Books. Florida, R. (2002b). The economic geography of talent. Annals of the Association of American Geography 92, 743-755. Gertler, M., Florida, R., Gates, G., & Vinodrai, T. (2002). Competing on creativity: Placing Ontario’s cities in North American context. Toronto: Ontario Ministry of Enterprise, Opportunity and Innovation, and Institute for Competitiveness and Prosperity. Ghent Mallett, J. (2002). Silicon Valley North: The formation of the Ottawa innovation cluster. Ottawa: Information Technology Alliance of Canada. Globe and Mail (June 2, 2006). Big-city mayors want larger share of taxes. A6, Murray Campbell. Graham, S., & Marvin, S. (2001). Splintering urbanism: Networked infrastructures, technological mobilities and the urban condition. London: Routledge. 16 Green, A. G., & Green, D. (2004). The goals of Canada’s immigration policy: A historical perspective. Canadian Journal of Urban Research 13, 102-139. Hackworth, J. R. (2007). The neoliberal city: Governance, ideology, and development in American urbanism. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Higgins, B. (1986). The rise and fall of Montréal? Moncton, NB: Canadian Institute for Research on Regional Development. Innis, H. A. (1995a [1931]). Transportation as a factor in Canadian economic history. In D. Drache (Ed.). Staples, markets and cultural change: Selected essays, Harold A. Innis (pp. 123-138). Montréal and Kingston: McGill-Queen’s University Press. Innis, H. A. (1995b [1938]). The penetrative process of the price system on new world states. In D. Drache (Ed.). Staples, markets and cultural change: Selected essays, Harold A. Innis (pp. 66-87). Montréal and Kingston: McGill-Queen’s University Press. Lewis, P. (1983). The galactic metropolis. In R. Platt and G. Macinko (Eds). Beyond the urban fringe: Land use issues of nonmetropolitan America (pp. 23-49). Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press. Leys, C. (2001). Market-driven politics: Neoliberal democracy and the public interest. London: Verso. Matthews, R. (1983). The creation of regional dependency. Toronto: University of Toronto Press. McCann, L., & Gunn, A. (1998). Heartland-hinterland: A regional geography of Canada. Toronto: Prentice Hall (3rd edition). McDonald, J. T. (2004). Toronto and Vancouver bound: The location choice of new Canadian immigrants. Canadian Journal of Urban Research 13, 85-101. Myrdal, G. (1963). Economic theory and under-developed regions. London: Methuen. Phelps, N., Fallon, R., & William, C. (2001). Small firms, borrowed size and the urban-rural shift. Regional Studies 53, 613-624. Polèse, M., & Shearmur, R. (2004). Culture, language, and the location of high-order service functions: The case of Montréal and Toronto. Economic Geography 80, 329-350. Polèse, M., & Shearmur, R. (2006a). Growth and location of economic activity: The spatial dynamics of industries in Canada 1971-2001. Growth and Change 37, 362-395. Polèse, M., & Shearmur, R. (2006b). Why some regions will decline: A Canadian case study with thoughts on local development strategies. Papers in Regional Science 85, 23-46. Polèse, M., & Stren, R. (Eds). (2000). The social sustainability of cities: Diversity and the management of change. Toronto: University of Toronto Press. Porter, M. E. (1990). The Comparative Advantage of Nations. New York: Free Press. Portnov, B. A. (2006). Urban clustering, development similarity, and local growth: A case study of Canada. European Planning Studies 14, 1287-1314. Rieniets, T. (2005). Shrinking cities: Growing domain for urban planning? Retrieved October 2008 from http://aarch.dk/fileadmin/grupper/institut_ii/PDF/paper_presentation_EURA2005.pdf Sassen, S. (1991). The global city: New York, London, Tokyo. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Savoie, D. J. (1992). Regional economic development: Canada’s search for solutions (2nd edition). Toronto: University of Toronto Press. 17 Shearmur, R., & Doloreux, D. (2008). Urban hierarchy or local buzz? High-order producer service and (or) knowledge-intensive business service location in Canada, 1991-2001. Professional Geographer 60, 333-355. Shearmur, R., & Polèse, M. (2005). Diversity and employment growth in Canada, 1971-2001: Can diversification policies succeed? The Canadian Geographer 49, 272-290. Simmons, J., & Bourne, L. S. (2003). New fault lines? Recent trends in the Canadian urban system and implications for public policy. Canadian Journal of Urban Research 12, 2247. Sitwell, O. F. G., & Seifried, N. R. M. (1984). The regional structure of the Canadian economy. Toronto: Methuen. Statistics Canada (2006). How will Canada’s population grow in the coming decade? Ottawa: Statistics Canada. Statistics Canada (2007). Portrait of the Canadian population in 2006 by age and sex: Subprovincial population dynamics. Ottawa: Statistics Canada. Retrieved October 2008 from http://www12.statcan.ca.proxy.lib.uwaterloo.ca/english/census06/analysis/agesex/Subpro v2.cfm Statistics Canada (n.d.). Geographical units: Census Metropolitan Area (CMA) and Census Agglomeration (CA). Retrieved October 2008 from http://www12.statcan.ca`English`census01`products`reference`dict`geo009.htm Toronto Dominion Bank (2002). The Greater Toronto Area economy: Canada’s primary economic locomotive in need of repair. Toronto: Toronto Dominion Bank. Toronto Dominion Bank (2007). An update to TD Economics’ 2002 Report on the Greater Toronto Area (GTA) economy. Toronto: Toronto Dominion Bank. Toronto Star (September 17, 2004). Miller shows he can be tough. B 01, Royson James. Toronto Star (May 5, 2007). Big cities back a penny. F 06. Yeates, M. (1975). Main Street: Windsor to Québec City. Toronto: Macmillan. Yeates, M. (1998). The industrial heartland: Its changing role and internal structure. In L. McCann and A. Gunn (Eds). Heartland-Hinterland: A Regional Geography of Canada (pp. 109145). Toronto: Prentice-Hall (3rd edition). 18 Table 1: Population Change 1971-2006 St John’s1, 2 Halifax1, 2 Moncton1, 2 St John1, 2 ChicoutimiJonquière1, 2 Québec2, 3 Sherbrooke2, 3 Trois-Rivières2, 3 St-Jean-surRichelieu3, 4 Montréal3, 4 Ottawa-Hull3, 4 Kingston2, 3 Belleville2, 3 Peterborough2, 3 Oshawa3, 4 Toronto3, 4 Hamilton3, 4 St Catharines2, 3 Kitchener2, 3 Brantford2, 3 Guelph2, 3 London2, 3 Windsor2, 3 Sarnia2, 3 Barrie3, 4 North Bay1, 2 Sudbury1, 2 Sault Ste Marie1, 2 Thunder Bay1, 2 Winnipeg1, 2 Regina1, 2 Saskatoon1, 2 Lethbridge1, 2 Calgary1, 4 Red Deer1, 2 Edmonton1, 4 Kelowna1, 2 Kamloops1, 2 Abbotsford1, 4 Vancouver1, 4 Victoria1, 2 Nanaimo1, 2 Prince George1, 2 Population 1971 Population 1986 Population 1996 Population 2006 131805 222650 161901 295990 102084 121265 158468 174051 332518 113491 125705 160454 181113 372858 126424 122389 151643 480500 84570 97925 603267 129960 128888 671889 147384 139956 76461 715515 186952 141529 87492 2743175 602520 85880 2921357 819263 122350 63540 120325 2627980 498520 303425 226840 80280 62665 285990 258650 78430 87083 203543 3427168 557029 343258 311195 90521 85962 342302 253988 85700 3326510 1010498 143416 93442 100193 268773 4263757 624360 372406 382940 100238 105420 398616 278685 86480 118695 64785 160488 83619 125562 667209 193652 219056 63053 821628 60075 862597 136541 84914 136480 1831665 304287 85585 75150 3635571 1130761 152358 91518 116570 330594 5113149 692911 390317 451235 124607 127009 457720 323342 88793 177061 63424 158258 80098 122907 694668 194971 233923 95196 1079310 82772 1034945 162276 92882 159020 2116581 330088 92361 83225 106760 155415 81270 112090 540245 140720 126455 403300 57422 148877 84617 122217 625304 186521 200665 58841 671326 495700 785465 89730 61773 1082280 195795 1380729 255547 67621 % change 19711986 22.83 32.94 % change 19861996 7.5 12.34 11.17 3.66 1.25 % change 19962006 4.06 12.13 11.4 -2.64 -5.49 % change 19712006 37.41 67.46 25.55 53.67 31.62 11.38 13.41 8.59 6.49 26.85 1.12 14.43 48.91 121.06 44.53 6.5 35.97 42.47 13.87 23.34 17.22 32.53 87.67 77.41 37.05 69.16 30.41 11.74 13.13 37.19 12.76 37.18 19.69 -1.8 9.27 15.05 32.05 24.41 12.09 8.49 23.05 10.73 22.64 16.45 9.72 0.91 9.29 11.9 6.24 -2.06 16.35 23 19.92 10.98 4.81 17.83 24.31 20.48 14.83 16.02 2.67 49.17 -2.1 -1.39 -4.21 -2.11 4.12 0.68 6.79 50.98 31.36 37.78 19.98 18.85 9.38 16.52 15.56 8.48 7.92 10.75 13.59 -4.21 4.12 9.03 15.74 32.55 58.68 66.46 12.82 7.8 -1.18 2.74 6.7 3.82 9.17 7.16 22.39 58.46 9.82 52.17 37.46 27.58 30.52 32.66 19.07 11.13 19 14.64 83.46 174.75 94.57 38.99 28.64 98.92 55.22 102.68 60.05 25.01 13.21 1.83 -1.44 9.65 28.58 38.55 84.99 167.62 108.78 95.57 68.59 1 Hinterland 2 Small urban area (2006 population less than 1 million) 3 Heartland 4 Large urban area (census metropolitan area with 2006 population of more than 1 million or adjacent census metropolitan areas) 20 Table 2: Employment Change 1971-2006 St John’s1, 2 Halifax1, 2 Moncton1, 2 St John1, 2 ChicoutimiJonquière1, 2 Québec2, 3 Sherbrooke2, 3 Trois-Rivières2, 3 St-Jean-surRichelieu3, 4 Montréal3, 4 Ottawa-Hull3, 4 Kingston2, 3 Belleville2, 3 Peterborough2, 3 Oshawa3, 4 Toronto3, 4 Hamilton3, 4 St Catharines2, 3 Kitchener2, 3 Brantford2, 3 Guelph2, 3 London2, 3 Windsor2, 3 Sarnia2, 3 Barrie3, 4 North Bay1, 2 Sudbury1, 2 Sault Ste Marie1, 2 Thunder Bay1, 2 Winnipeg1, 2 Regina1, 2 Saskatoon1, 2 Lethbridge1, 2 Calgary1, 4 Red Deer1, 2 Edmonton1, 4 Kelowna1, 2 Kamloops1, 2 Abbotsford1, 4 Vancouver1, 4 Victoria1, 2 Nanaimo1, 2 Prince George1, 2 Employment 1971 Employment 1986 Employment 1996 Employment 2006 45260 90410 66835 148215 44300 49540 58705 74930 163035 54095 53390 63905 88130 199555 66565 59035 69175 168690 30100 31610 270505 57770 51060 315045 66645 58670 34340 383465 91665 65715 45265 1007385 248600 35270 1348190 426765 60330 25305 46580 1177535 200470 117870 100795 33150 26515 122915 97945 30465 40600 102180 1870765 274260 158555 162050 41425 44660 174885 116695 40310 1502380 502070 66850 41050 43135 126865 2061615 294225 165230 192055 45380 54690 190405 130770 38165 56895 28385 70170 34860 57765 324745 96400 107150 31190 441575 30130 434020 62480 40475 60645 908320 148890 38285 37490 1835840 601540 74930 44475 56665 170020 2627350 347490 192400 243340 63475 69700 235430 152990 43050 93410 29835 75340 36720 59250 366430 106425 125530 50425 632020 48770 583215 82005 47910 79665 1104760 175055 44260 44490 40155 59490 30605 43605 229635 58220 49745 167425 25435 62630 35950 57555 310860 92960 96390 27765 352435 206055 392950 35635 26945 440220 75865 670805 114255 30020 21 % change 19711986 47.67 63.94 % change 19861996 12.11 10.00 22.11 7.77 8.86 % change 19962006 17.62 22.4 23.05 10.57 8.25 % change 19712006 94.72 120.72 60.36 91.93 61.53 16.47 15.36 14.9 21.72 37.54 12.01 31.81 127.32 204.53 107.89 33.83 71.67 71.05 11.44 17.65 10.81 82.24 141.97 112.45 60.44 119.36 58.87 36.81 34.52 60.77 24.96 68.43 42.28 19.14 32.32 6.24 24.16 10.20 7.28 4.21 18.52 9.55 22.46 8.87 12.06 -5.32 22.2 19.81 12.09 8.34 31.37 34.02 27.44 18.1 16.44 26.7 39.87 27.45 23.65 16.99 12.8 64.18 5.11 7.37 5.34 2.57 12.84 10.4 17.15 61.67 43.13 61.87 34.38 31.25 18.37 31.36 21.63 17.57 15.61 18.67 23.37 5.28 17.46 31.99 35.37 59.67 93.77 110.50 11.6 12.04 -3.03 0.36 4.47 3.7 11.16 12.34 25.29 90.70 10.45 75.33 50.21 52.38 50.60 35.41 30.31 24.88 47.02 123.93 265.01 123.12 73.34 63.23 141.42 91.48 162.87 91.54 56.2 41.31 26.64 19.98 35.88 59.57 82.8 152.35 277.49 183.04 150.96 130.75 See notes at the bottom of Table 1. 22 Table 3: Average Household Income Change 1976-2006 (in 2005 dollars) St John’s1, 2 Halifax1, 2 Moncton1, 2 St John1, 2 ChicoutimiJonquière1, 2 Québec2, 3 Sherbrooke2, 3 Trois-Rivières2, 3 St-Jean-surRichelieu3, 4 Montréal3, 4 Ottawa-Hull3, 4 Kingston2, 3 Belleville2, 3 Peterborough2, 3 Oshawa3, 4 Toronto3, 4 Hamilton3, 4 St Catharines2, 3 Kitchener2, 3 Brantford2, 3 Guelph2, 3 London2, 3 Windsor2, 3 Sarnia2, 3 Barrie3, 4 North Bay1, 2 Sudbury1, 2 Sault Ste Marie1, 2 Thunder Bay1, 2 Winnipeg1, 2 Regina1, 2 Saskatoon1, 2 Lethbridge1, 2 Calgary1, 4 Red Deer1, 2 Edmonton1, 4 Kelowna1, 2 Kamloops1, 2 Abbotsford1, 4 Vancouver1, 4 Victoria1, 2 Nanaimo1, 2 Prince George1, 2 Income 1976 Income 1986 Income 1996 Income 2006 47437 53974 60860 62094 55347 51672 54446 58727 58578 55289 53648 49915 65852 66325 59995 61234 55552 52398 47186 46324 55884 49059 48744 53359 47180 47768 48795 60884 53301 51683 57928 52580 62351 54406 56183 69596 59335 53167 54695 63128 56213 51178 55125 49730 54527 54899 58110 58477 55842 68910 73143 62387 57054 60807 53715 61263 59395 61515 64726 54403 69247 60394 56604 56246 70944 73334 65464 57428 65260 57212 65970 61338 65926 63713 63796 56154 60280 56758 61965 55763 59354 54885 55564 69331 57743 60888 56318 60960 60455 65947 61366 54938 68110 63038 80838 69185 60372 65316 82205 87820 76787 65053 78223 67694 77920 70345 72796 72448 76128 61159 68071 62487 64470 64533 68280 66059 64257 98253 77761 79163 64515 63797 66041 73258 67838 57819 69859 46072 63368 56717 51684 50700 48661 46674 56699 55087 59042 58004 61907 56911 62144 57241 55726 69345 55400 63262 50101 56234 53830 48251 61346 53851 61855 23 % change 19711986 28.3 15.04 % change 19861996 -3.5 -5.66 -0.1 3.83 -8.32 % change 19962006 12.13 13.22 8.51 14.14 11.29 % change 19712006 38.82 22.88 6.65 3.97 5.23 -4.52 -3.83 -2 14.1 12.97 8.2 18.72 16.2 12.96 11.57 6.85 11.62 9.06 -3.17 -0.5 1.78 19.89 29.65 27.16 5.03 25.99 15.86 10.98 11.48 10.31 8.01 12.35 8.19 5.86 10.69 0.72 2.95 0.26 4.93 0.66 7.32 6.51 7.68 3.27 7.17 -1.56 15.87 16.74 14.56 6.66 16.13 15.87 19.75 17.3 13.28 19.86 18.32 18.11 14.68 10.42 13.71 19.33 8.91 12.92 10.09 4.04 15.73 15.04 20.36 15.65 41.72 34.67 30.01 14.56 4.65 9.24 11.09 10.55 5.24 2.57 12.15 -11.56 2.27 19.78 12.25 27.71 22.64 22.3 1.94 7.56 -2.15 0.09 -2.02 -4.49 -4.11 -0.29 -0.02 14.19 -3.75 12.41 8.4 13.96 11.61 7.5 13.96 10.11 32.91 22.85 50.3 39.11 36.6 27.11 41.9 36.12 42.9 28.13 25.27 23.89 7.42 10.17 24.74 27.28 40.32 41.53 73.29 42.89 36.09 40.59 See notes at the bottom of Table 1. 24 Table 4: Percent Change in the Number of Workers in Different Employment Sectors 1996-2006* St John’s1, 2 Halifax1, 2 Moncton1, 2 St John1, 2 ChicoutimiJonquière1, 2 Québec2, 3 Sherbrooke2, 3 Trois-Rivières2, 3 St-Jean-surRichelieu3, 4 Montréal3, 4 Ottawa-Hull3, 4 Kingston2, 3 Belleville2, 3 Peterborough2, 3 Oshawa3, 4 Toronto3, 4 Hamilton3, 4 St Catharines2, 3 Kitchener2, 3 Brantford2, 3 Guelph2, 3 London2, 3 Windsor2, 3 Sarnia2, 3 Barrie3, 4 North Bay1, 2 Sudbury1, 2 Sault Ste Marie1, 2 Thunder Bay1, 2 Winnipeg1, 2 Regina1, 2 Saskatoon1, 2 Lethbridge1, 2 Calgary1, 4 Red Deer1, 2 Edmonton1, 4 Kelowna1, 2 Kamloops1, 2 Abbotsford1, 4 Vancouver1, 4 Victoria1, 2 Nanaimo1, 2 Prince George1, 2 Total Total Employment Management Business etc. Health 10.25 13.10 26.40 17.12 -5.47 Natural science etc 54.90 59.33 80.97 88.89 33.11 17.62 22.40 23.05 10.57 8.25 19.12 28.10 30.10 12.94 -0.56 21.72 37.54 12.01 31.81 22.20 19.81 12.09 8.34 31.37 34.02 27.44 18.10 16.44 26.70 39.87 27.45 23.65 16.99 12.80 64.18 5.11 7.37 5.34 2.57 12.84 10.40 17.15 61.67 43.13 61.87 34.38 31.25 18.37 31.36 21.63 17.57 15.61 18.67 24.22 Arts etc Sales and service Trades etc Primary Manufacturing and utilities 21.39 34.85 34.28 21.01 25.06 Social Science etc 26.72 60.23 28.81 20.33 22.00 24.55 33.74 13.83 -9.77 -14.47 3.90 5.86 10.31 1.06 2.98 14.42 19.18 7.71 -7.66 19.20 34.34 31.86 12.36 -21.90 6.87 -5.06 0.80 -12.32 -33.97 -28.75 6.06 48.31 4.23 3.55 6.21 26.43 -2.46 21.14 44.52 47.75 8.92 68.47 27.60 29.19 14.55 49.75 50.10 50.96 32.46 77.85 27.85 48.27 37.30 16.67 9.09 27.78 12.43 15.80 26.58 62.40 9.88 57.63 10.55 55.13 29.41 -16.79 -2.65 4.82 -10.83 0.84 26.91 8.88 2.77 -4.07 40.21 61.58 35.12 33.61 26.05 32.61 41.15 50.21 17.67 25.23 12.71 80.50 7.39 6.85 10.42 6.26 25.22 21.77 33.11 62.95 64.24 70.02 48.69 53.22 21.60 44.48 26.49 19.09 24.18 35.11 29.91 9.75 8.43 16.23 9.41 16.68 25.54 14.42 5.99 7.65 19.58 37.07 25.61 11.53 5.05 7.98 45.47 -6.48 8.01 0.40 -4.26 5.16 2.73 8.10 39.09 27.28 51.41 21.02 22.65 19.59 13.19 6.50 5.67 6.74 8.98 12.40 45.65 46.04 46.76 91.40 65.08 59.58 76.33 44.90 32.01 83.90 76.74 55.59 72.14 87.31 22.00 106.29 16.80 34.74 50.96 18.20 47.37 38.43 46.89 77.82 91.25 104.31 70.01 63.27 75.91 80.77 64.82 46.85 17.33 27.20 60.70 25.69 24.31 23.82 9.07 38.67 43.95 37.74 31.63 29.49 53.92 59.63 30.36 33.54 32.47 21.21 96.61 24.71 22.77 27.51 21.95 29.01 19.71 35.76 102.81 68.86 60.95 57.19 47.09 24.43 37.69 36.84 24.27 48.41 69.93 34.84 60.11 59.07 29.89 17.15 55.96 73.81 53.83 43.16 28.41 45.24 70.24 52.83 45.47 47.32 24.95 84.11 21.03 36.87 17.52 20.16 42.53 38.59 48.06 65.75 66.42 43.20 55.24 46.59 31.47 56.68 49.02 30.06 28.14 49.62 51.14 30.92 25.67 24.94 23.81 32.37 79.18 35.41 33.33 24.59 22.54 22.05 43.97 17.54 33.41 6.37 75.20 -0.84 39.76 0.00 10.51 20.20 15.10 6.96 41.61 56.97 28.48 25.86 52.55 31.64 16.35 41.74 40.88 44.21 6.62 32.67 15.06 6.67 -1.76 -7.62 21.02 26.96 13.89 9.51 20.82 14.81 24.36 8.57 8.12 15.96 5.42 48.68 -5.92 -5.42 -0.98 -0.49 -1.99 -4.04 -0.78 31.06 15.61 25.16 8.91 11.31 -0.11 12.55 9.76 4.87 7.08 -1.61 11.10 26.52 16.78 14.63 20.37 38.43 39.70 33.79 30.71 17.50 41.14 66.74 41.43 36.08 14.67 16.76 82.62 13.73 4.28 -3.65 -8.14 11.14 17.09 26.71 82.85 58.82 95.96 63.67 42.57 18.83 40.61 18.03 21.74 13.39 27.10 30.10 12.95 7.64 -6.82 -19.93 32.13 20.45 26.46 28.81 5.55 9.74 112.16 7.09 13.62 20.22 20.28 17.87 22.11 -15.19 6.40 17.11 -0.82 -17.15 -0.68 196.46 23.93 88.72 14.68 9.96 4.50 28.18 6.20 2.93 -18.73 5.76 15.16 -21.41 -10.21 -25.19 1.32 3.49 -11.22 7.52 -20.30 -31.32 -2.60 -0.40 10.00 13.81 -4.24 -15.59 41.85 -27.10 -37.79 -40.63 -40.98 -10.64 -21.12 -4.60 71.12 -1.54 63.00 -18.78 -13.64 -12.30 8.78 -1.67 -15.32 -18.21 -12.46 -6.21 *The full definition of the employment categories are: a) management occupations; b) business, finance and administrative occupations; c) natural and applied sciences and related occupations; d) health occupations; e) occupations in social science, education, government service and religion; f) occupations in art, culture, recreation and sport; g) sales and service occupations; h) trades, transport and equipment operators and related occupations; i) occupations unique to primary industry; j) occupations unique to processing, manufacturing and utilities. 25 See notes at the bottom of Table 1. 26 Table 5: Percent of Workers in Selected Employment Categories 2006* Management St John’s1, 2 Halifax1, 2 Moncton1, 2 St John1, 2 ChicoutimiJonquière1, 2 Québec2, 3 Sherbrooke2, 3 Trois-Rivières2, 3 St-Jean-surRichelieu3, 4 Montréal3, 4 Ottawa-Hull3, 4 Kingston2, 3 Belleville2, 3 Peterborough2, 3 Oshawa3, 4 Toronto3, 4 Hamilton3, 4 St Catharines2, 3 Kitchener2, 3 Brantford2, 3 Guelph2, 3 London2, 3 Windsor2, 3 Sarnia2, 3 Barrie3, 4 North Bay1, 2 Sudbury1, 2 Sault Ste Marie1, 2 Thunder Bay1, 2 Winnipeg1, 2 Regina1, 2 Saskatoon1, 2 Lethbridge1, 2 Calgary1, 4 Red Deer1, 2 Edmonton1, 4 Kelowna1, 2 Kamloops1, 2 Abbotsford1, 4 Vancouver1, 4 Victoria1, 2 Nanaimo1, 2 Prince George1, 2 10.60 11.43 10.07 8.94 7.67 Natural science etc 8.69 7.38 6.14 7.63 7.21 Art etc Primary 3.17 3.80 2.66 1.96 1.97 2.02 1.49 1.50 1.81 2.25 Manufacturing and utilities 2.24 2.21 3.21 3.23 5.46 8.69 8.64 8.24 8.38 8.85 5.91 5.58 5.84 3.49 2.80 2.55 2.01 1.09 1.98 2.18 1.20 3.40 8.31 7.77 9.25 10.81 11.62 9.65 8.75 9.23 10.65 12.20 11.05 9.32 9.84 8.86 10.04 9.18 8.48 7.83 10.85 10.22 8.39 7.94 8.46 9.68 9.96 9.43 8.98 11.41 8.84 10.06 11.88 9.23 9.19 11.80 11.09 10.27 8.82 7.91 12.18 6.35 6.00 5.51 6.29 8.54 6.16 4.33 7.81 4.19 7.39 5.97 6.13 7.67 5.09 4.89 5.30 7.50 5.54 6.35 6.80 6.30 4.69 11.54 5.34 7.39 4.69 6.02 3.83 7.70 7.78 5.35 5.52 4.30 4.47 3.21 2.05 2.81 2.71 4.09 2.77 2.58 2.40 1.87 2.91 2.53 2.02 1.94 2.34 1.98 2.36 2.23 2.40 2.99 3.22 2.69 2.26 3.03 2.08 2.65 2.92 2.43 1.92 4.31 4.19 3.10 1.63 0.82 1.26 1.92 2.48 2.90 1.71 1.00 2.34 3.85 1.57 3.71 1.95 2.66 1.79 2.96 1.84 1.94 5.00 1.81 3.00 1.48 2.29 4.04 6.64 2.00 7.55 2.90 4.58 4.36 9.11 1.86 2.41 3.33 4.74 5.79 1.60 2.58 10.39 6.28 8.42 7.43 6.83 6.54 12.17 11.86 13.41 8.49 13.94 6.23 7.46 3.20 2.28 4.62 3.67 5.79 2.12 4.13 4.70 3.14 4.56 3.19 3.98 3.50 6.77 4.15 1.67 3.20 5.77 Total 10.84 7.90 3.56 1.77 5.64 *See Table 4 note for a full definition of the employment categories and notes at the bottom of Table 1. 27 Table 6: Percent of Population in Different Age Groups 2006 St John’s1, 2 Halifax1, 2 Moncton1, 2 St John1, 2 ChicoutimiJonquière1, 2 Québec2, 3 Sherbrooke2, 3 Trois-Rivières2, 3 St-Jean-surRichelieu3, 4 Montréal3, 4 Ottawa-Hull3, 4 Kingston2, 3 Belleville2, 3 Peterborough2, 3 Oshawa3, 4 Toronto3, 4 Hamilton3, 4 St Catharines2, 3 Kitchener2, 3 Brantford2, 3 Guelph2, 3 London2, 3 Windsor2, 3 Sarnia2, 3 Barrie3, 4 North Bay1, 2 Sudbury1, 2 Sault Ste Marie1, 2 Thunder Bay1, 2 Winnipeg1, 2 Regina1, 2 Saskatoon1, 2 Lethbridge1, 2 Calgary1, 4 Red Deer1, 2 Edmonton1, 4 Kelowna1, 2 Kamloops1, 2 Abbotsford1, 4 Vancouver1, 4 Victoria1, 2 Nanaimo1, 2 Prince George1, 2 Total 0-9 10.43 10.16 10.26 10.71 9.25 10-19 12.45 12.53 11.92 13.63 12.75 20-29 14.98 14.52 14.35 11.97 12.19 30-39 14.62 14.29 14.35 12.90 10.65 40-49 16.56 17.25 16.08 16.68 17.43 50-59 14.41 14.30 14.32 14.90 16.49 60-69 8.64 8.44 8.69 9.18 10.53 70-79 4.92 5.26 5.75 5.94 7.09 80+ 3.01 3.26 4.27 4.08 3.61 9.37 10.48 8.73 10.60 11.58 12.84 12.14 13.54 14.09 14.49 12.57 12.76 12.46 11.95 10.74 12.79 16.41 15.49 16.61 16.71 15.64 14.54 15.86 14.54 10.22 9.78 11.19 9.36 6.38 6.32 7.72 6.03 3.84 4.12 4.45 3.67 10.72 11.24 9.95 10.58 9.41 12.61 11.94 11.26 10.18 12.29 11.77 12.09 11.01 12.21 9.93 12.86 10.04 10.37 9.26 9.98 11.17 11.27 11.77 11.93 12.07 11.85 11.57 9.57 9.95 12.82 10.28 8.77 9.45 12.06 11.11 12.55 13.49 12.88 13.79 13.53 15.30 13.29 13.43 13.13 13.85 13.98 13.15 13.72 13.61 13.71 15.28 13.65 13.23 13.17 13.21 13.53 14.11 14.33 14.03 13.16 13.77 13.70 12.79 13.53 14.78 12.54 11.34 12.88 14.77 13.12 13.60 13.46 13.77 11.70 12.61 11.85 13.52 12.30 11.55 14.51 12.13 14.82 14.02 13.14 11.58 12.22 12.83 12.35 11.47 11.94 13.82 15.26 16.46 16.24 15.49 19.23 15.80 11.30 12.53 13.41 13.79 13.02 11.72 13.22 13.71 14.16 14.22 12.41 11.67 10.62 14.16 15.35 13.21 11.92 14.70 12.61 14.59 13.14 14.40 10.82 14.79 11.65 12.46 10.69 12.22 13.13 12.57 12.65 11.88 16.07 14.12 14.03 11.34 11.88 13.48 14.74 12.27 11.31 13.86 14.13 16.63 17.35 16.07 16.40 15.17 17.94 16.94 16.35 15.72 16.26 15.96 16.36 16.11 16.02 15.70 17.79 16.72 16.80 16.36 16.55 16.10 16.04 15.73 14.59 17.21 15.90 16.40 15.84 16.25 15.41 17.03 15.56 15.53 16.97 16.66 13.60 13.90 14.21 13.85 14.77 12.73 12.83 13.45 14.19 12.58 14.08 12.45 13.46 12.99 15.54 11.57 14.31 14.57 15.36 14.98 13.83 13.38 12.78 12.67 12.92 11.91 13.25 14.43 15.50 12.39 14.16 15.70 15.75 14.89 13.60 9.00 8.02 9.59 9.83 10.27 7.38 7.70 8.90 10.19 7.43 8.78 7.33 8.49 8.29 10.16 7.26 9.89 9.66 10.64 9.28 8.12 7.61 7.08 8.06 6.43 6.05 7.39 10.90 10.12 8.00 8.26 9.63 10.74 8.04 8.34 6.22 5.13 6.86 7.47 8.02 5.14 5.36 6.81 7.97 5.15 6.39 5.64 6.05 5.85 7.87 5.16 7.15 6.95 8.38 7.10 5.97 5.71 5.38 6.40 4.25 4.37 4.99 8.58 6.71 5.80 5.61 7.34 7.62 4.34 5.79 3.53 3.19 4.26 4.70 5.58 2.90 3.08 4.28 5.14 3.23 4.30 3.57 4.00 3.47 4.68 3.07 3.78 3.61 4.68 4.71 4.34 4.06 3.82 4.23 2.40 2.82 2.87 5.24 3.53 3.91 3.60 6.38 5.02 1.86 3.52 See notes at the bottom of Table 1. 28 Table 7: Percent of Population Born Outside the Province and Outside Canada 2006 St John’s1, 2 Halifax1, 2 Moncton1, 2 St John1, 2 ChicoutimiJonquière1, 2 Québec2, 3 Sherbrooke2, 3 Trois-Rivières2, 3 St-Jean-surRichelieu3, 4 Montréal3, 4 Ottawa-Hull3, 4 Kingston2, 3 Belleville2, 3 Peterborough2, 3 Oshawa3, 4 Toronto3, 4 Hamilton3, 4 St Catharines2, 3 Kitchener2, 3 Brantford2, 3 Guelph2, 3 London2, 3 Windsor2, 3 Sarnia2, 3 Barrie3, 4 North Bay1, 2 Sudbury1, 2 Sault Ste Marie1, 2 Thunder Bay1, 2 Winnipeg1, 2 Regina1, 2 Saskatoon1, 2 Lethbridge1, 2 Calgary1, 4 Red Deer1, 2 Edmonton1, 4 Kelowna1, 2 Kamloops1, 2 Abbotsford1, 4 Vancouver1, 4 Victoria1, 2 Nanaimo1, 2 Prince George1, 2 Total Born in Canada But Outside Province 7.15 24.28 20.29 14.36 1.64 Born Outside of Canada 2.26 2.13 1.42 2.64 3.66 5.54 2.17 2.93 3.56 20.92 14.29 14.02 7.11 9.53 6.46 7.92 8.02 9.10 7.32 9.20 7.75 4.67 8.01 9.80 10.35 8.92 5.52 10.30 13.38 12.89 14.98 24.17 30.91 33.39 24.01 39.12 28.61 21.49 17.42 31.98 29.60 26.22 11.80 20.36 17.93 12.15 8.61 9.26 16.31 45.38 24.05 18.02 22.84 12.79 20.29 19.10 23.12 12.61 12.72 5.68 6.60 10.27 10.25 17.46 7.55 7.61 11.54 23.42 9.25 18.34 14.62 10.41 23.31 39.27 18.78 15.08 9.35 25.28 2.90 7.35 3.36 4.11 1.16 29 See notes at the bottom of Table 1. 30 31 Figure 2: Percent Population Change 1971-2006: Heartland and Hinterland, Large Urban Areas and Small Urban Areas 32 Figure 3: Percent Employment Change 1971-2006: Heartland and Hinterland, Large Urban Areas and Small Urban Areas 33 Figure 4: Percent Average Household Income Change 1971-2006 (in 2005 dollars): Heartland and Hinterland, Large Urban Areas and Small Urban Areas 34 Figure 5: Percent Change in Employment Categories* 1996-2006: Heartland and Hinterland, Large Urban Areas and Small Urban Areas *For a full description of the employment categories see note at the bottom of Table 4. 35 Figure 6: Percent of Workers in Selected Employment Categories*, 2006: Heartland and Hinterland, Large Urban Areas and Small Urban Areas *For a full description of the employment categories see note at the bottom of Table 4. 36