A YEAR IN THE LIFE OF A HIGH TECH STANDARDS SETTING ORGANIZATION Section of Antitrust Law April 25, 2002 Washington, D.C. A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Overview Standards that facilitate interoperability are critical in high tech industries and increasingly raise antitrust issues, whether set through a standard setting organization, by ad hoc groups of competitors, or by a single dominant firm. A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization is sponsored by the following committees: Corporate Counseling, Intellectual Property, Sherman Act Section 1, and Trade Associations. This program, with its distinguished panel and comprehensive program materials, is designed to illuminate a part of this complicated area of the law. The focus of “A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization” is on the rights and obligations of a patent owner whose patent can preclude others from practicing a standard. A series of brief vignettes will be used to explore issues that can arise in the standards setting process. The brief vignettes will start with the formation of a standards setting organization, proceed through disputes over the nature and extent of any obligation to disclose patents and patent applications, followed by patent infringement litigation and counterclaims, and then conclude with an agency enforcement action. The perspectives of the different participants in the standards setting process will be presented to stimulate debate. In the process, practical advice will be provided by our panel of distinguished speakers. Since the Federal Trade Commission’s 1996 decision in Dell Computer Corp., 121 F.T.C. 616 (1996), there has been increasing controversy over the interface between antitrust and intellectual property in this area. Some commentators are urging the FTC and the DOJ to provide guidance and issue guidelines, but others are of the view that such steps are not necessary. The FTC and the DOJ are exploring these issues in their hearings on Competition and Intellectual Property Law and Policy in the Knowledge Based Economy. Specifically, hearings are scheduled on April 18, 2002 on Standard Setting Practices: Competition, Innovation and Consumer Welfare. Any material submitted in connection with that hearing should be available on the FTC’s website, http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/index.htm. 1 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Participants: (Detailed information on our panel is included at the end of the program materials.) Lisa C. Wood Lisa C. Wood will moderate the program. Ms. Wood is a senior partner at the Boston law firm of Nutter McClennen & Fish LLP and is Chair of Sherman Act Section 1 Committee. Richard B. Dagen Richard B. Dagen, Assistant Director of the Bureau of Competition for Anti-competitive Practices, Federal Trade Commission, will provide valuable insights, after noting that he is not speaking on behalf of the FTC. Mark A. Flagel Mark A. Flagel, a partner with the Los Angeles office of Latham & Watkins, represented Kingston Technology in its successful defense of patent infringement claims brought by Sun Microsystems. Joseph P. Lavelle Joseph P. Lavelle, a partner in the Washington D.C. office of Howrey Simon Arnold & White LLP, has represented Rambus Inc. and other clients in standard setting matters. Dorothy Gill Raymond Dorothy Gill Raymond is Senior Vice President and General Counsel, Cable Television Laboratories, Inc. Among Mrs. Raymond's accomplishments while at CableLabs are establishing royalty-free license pools for CableLabs' cable modem and PacketCable projects, and establishing a sub-licensing program for third party security software needed by cable modem manufacturers Richard S. Taffet Richard S. Taffet, a partner with the New York office of Thelen Reid & Priest LLP, has represented Accredited Standards Committee T1, sponsored by the Alliance of Telecommunications Industry Solutions (“ATIS”), since its formation in 1984. Mr. Taffet is also an original member of the American National Standards Institute’s Patent Committee. Program Materials Our program materials start with Richard S. Taffet’s "Patented Technology and Standard Setting: A Standards Development Organization View.” 2 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization This article provides a comprehensive review of patent disclosure policies adopted by various standards setting organizations and how those policies have changed over the past few years. The second article is “Standard Setting Activity - Offensive Claims,” by Joseph P. Lavelle and Melissa J. Gunthner. Although the focus of this article is on federal antitrust laws, the article also discusses federal RICO claims and state claims, including common law fraud claims. The third article is “Strategic Considerations When Asserting Defenses Against a Claim for Infringement of a Patent That Reads on an Industry Standard” by Mark A. Flagel and Michael J. Lawrence. This article is particularly helpful to antitrust lawyers unfamiliar with the intricacies of patent infringement litigation and the application of the affirmative defenses of estoppel, patent misuse, and implied license. The fourth article for the program is “Benefits and Risks of Patent Pooling for Standard Setting Organizations,” by Dorothy Gill Raymond. This article discusses the advantages and disadvantages of this alternate approach. To provide additional background, three case summaries that were prepared in anticipation of this program are also included. These articles were published in AT-IP Report, the electronic newsletter of the Intellectual Property Committee. "Rambus v. Infineon—The Latest Standard Setting Patent Disclosure Guidance," by Veronica Smith Lewis, AT-IP Report (September 24, 2001) provides an excellent discussion of a case which raises many of the issues presented in this program. “Intel Corporation v. VIA Technologies, Inc., 174 F. Supp2d 1038 (N.D. Cal. 2001),” by Richard S. Taffet and Sophia Fix, AT-IP Report (February 1, 2002), focuses on the scope of a license provided by single firm issuing a standard. “An Update on the Soundview Litigation”, by John S. Martin, AT-IP Report (December 7, 2001), discusses a series of patent and antitrust decisions relating to “V-Chip” technology. Finally, a detailed list of resources relevant to standard setting and 3 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization antitrust is included for your future reference. The current version of the list, with links to material available on the internet, is available on the Intellectual Property Committee's webpage under "Hot Topics," http://www.abanet.org/antitrust/committees/intell_property/hottopic.html. John Anthony Chavez Session Chair 4 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization A YEAR IN THE LIFE OF A HIGH TECH STANDARDS SETTING ORGANIZATION Section of Antitrust Law PATENTED TECHNOLOGY AND STANDARD SETTING: A STANDARDS DEVELOPMENT ORGANIZATION VIEW By Richard S. Taffet Thelen Reid & Priest LLP April 25, 2002 Washington, D.C. © 2002 Thelen Reid & Priest LLP 5 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization I. Introduction* This paper discusses how standards development organizations (“SDOs”) in the United States have addressed, and continue to address, issues relating to the use of proprietary – specifically patented – technology in the development of technical standards. Particular focus will be on standards development in technology and network industries. To provide context, an overview of different types of SDOs and the standard development process itself will be first set out. Next, a description of various patent policies, including the Patent Policy of American National Standards Institute (“ANSI”) and policies adopted by certain non-accredited SDOs, will be discussed. The rationales for and the consequences of these policies will be explained. It is hoped that this discussion will eliminate some of the confusion that exists concerning the scope and requirements of specific SDO patent policies. What this discussion is also intended to show is that, while clearly there have been some well-publicized instances of abuse of the standards setting process relating to patented technologies, in the context of overall standards development activity, such conduct is de minimis and has been effectively addressed by government enforcement agencies and in the courts under existing legal principles. In these circumstances those now pressing for uniform SDO patent policies that would impose specific mandatory obligations on patent holders and SDOs concerning disclosure requirements and the establishment of licensing terms should take care not to take such steps without being fully aware of the unintended consequences that may result. Even assuming specific mandatory requirements may be appropriate in particular situations – perhaps depending on the specific industry, the technology and the nature of patents involved – this should not suggest that a broad based, generalized, application of such obligations for all SDOs can be supported. Indeed, rather than avoiding abusive standards practices, the creation and imposition of new duties and obligations might * The author has represented Accredited Standards Committee T1, sponsored by the Alliance of Telecommunications Industry Solutions (“ATIS”), since its formation in 1984. Committee T1, as discussed below, is a leading telecommunications industry standards developer. Mr. Taffet is also an original member of the American National Standards Institute’s Patent Committee. 6 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization only upset the proper balance among the various stakeholder interests, and lead to increased litigation risks and less effective industry-wide standards development. II. Background A. Competitive Effects of Standards Development It is settled that procompetitive benefits may result from standard setting. As stated by the United States Supreme Court in Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. Indian Head, Inc.:1 When . . . private associations promulgate safety standards based on the merits of objective expert judgments and through procedures that prevent the standard setting process from being biased by members with economic interests in stifling product competition those private standards can have significant procompetitive advantages. Id. at 500. In particular, standard setting may result in procompetitive effects by: (i) serving as an efficient means for buyers and sellers to exchange information on complex product attributes; (ii) easing the introduction of new technologies; (iii) allowing innovative manufacturers to demonstrate advantages of new products; and (iv) reducing production and distribution costs by eliminating superfluous product variations. 2 These procompetitive advantages, it has been observed, may particularly arise in technology and network industries, including for telecommunications, computer hardware and software and Internet related products and services. Such products and services involve sophisticated and disparate technological attributes and depend upon the interconnectibility and interoperability of various competitive alternatives. 1 486 U.S. 492 (1988). 2 See, e.g., Clamp-All Corp. v. Cast Iron Soil Pipe Inst., 851 F.2d 478 (1st Cir. 1988), cert. denied, 488 U.S. 1007 (1989)(trade association’s promulgation of a standard lowers information costs and creates a better product – the very benefits the antitrust laws seek to promote); Consolidated Metal Prods., Inc. v. American Petroleum Inst., 846 F.2d 284, 296 (5th Cir. 1988)(“[e]ven if user reliance gives [the standard] influence over the market, that influence may enhance, not reduce, competition and consumer welfare”). 7 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Thus, for example, in Dell,3 the Federal Trade Commission observed that the record of the Commission’s hearings in the Fall of 1995 on Global and Innovation-Based Competition was “replete with discussion of the procompetitive role of standard-setting organizations,” and that one topic that was specifically considered at the hearings “was the important role of standard-setting in the technological innovation that will drive much of this nation’s competitive vigor in the 21st century.”4 Similarly, one frequent commentator has opined that standards play a “critical role” in connection with network-related products and services because they can lead to: (i) increased price competition resulting from consumers being more able to readily compare and contrast products and features; (ii) increased compatibility and interoperability so that new suppliers are better able to compete in producing products and services related to the underlying technology; and (iii) increased use of a particular technology allowing for the installed base of users to benefit from enhanced economic and functional values to the extent the technology is compatible with a large network of applications.5 It is equally settled, however, that standards development activity may cause anticompetitive harm, and may expose standards development organizations to potential antitrust liability.6 For example, as discussed by the Supreme Court in Allied Tube, standards setting may result in anticompetitive effects by excluding competing producers and facilitating 3 In re Dell Computer Corp., 121 F.T.C. 616, No. C-3658, 1996 FTC LEXIS 291 (May 20, 1996). 4 Id. at *20. Balto, David A., “Standard Setting in the 21 st Century Network Economy,” Computer and Internet Lawyer, June 2001. 5 E.g., American Soc’y of Mechanical Eng’rs, Inc. v. Hydrolevel Corp., 456 U.S. 556 (1982); Dell, supra at *21(“a standard-setting organization may provide a vehicle for a firm to undermine the standards-setting process in a way that harms competition and consumers”). Note, however, that “concerted action does not exist every time a trade association member speaks or acts. Instead, in assessing whether a trade association (or any other group of competitors) has taken concerted action, a court must examine all the facts and circumstances to determine whether the action taken was the result of some agreement, tacit or otherwise, among members of the association.” Alvord-Polk, Inc. v. F. Schumacher & Co., 37 F.3d 996, 1007,1009 (3d Cir. 1994), cert. denied, 514 U.S. 1063 (1995). See also Consolidated Metal Prods., 846 F.2d at 293-94 & n.30 (when analyzing activities of a trade association “the mere showing of relationships between alleged conspirators is insufficient to imply a conspiracy”); Wilk v. American Med. Ass’n, 895 F.2d 352 (7th Cir.), cert. denied, 496 U.S. 927 (1990)(same); Five Smiths, Inc. v. National Football League Players Ass’n, 788 F. Supp. 1042, 1049 n.5 (D. Minn. 1992)(same). 6 8 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization oligopolistic pricing by easing rivals’ ability to monitor each other’s prices. 7 Most recently, the potential for anticompetitive effects arising from the use of and reliance on intellectual property – particularly patented technology – in the development of standards has been the target of intensified scrutiny. For example, in announcing the current joint FTC/DOJ hearings on “Competition and Intellectual Property Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based Economy,” FTC Chairman Timothy Muris specifically commented that “[s]tandards that rely on intellectual property can raise difficult competition issues.”8 Chairman Muris also commented, however, that while such standards are now more common in the knowledge-based economy, some of the competition issues being raised in connection with them are not new.9 He is correct. B. Industry Consideration of Patented Technology in Standards Development Since at least the mid-1980s the implications of using patented technology in standards have been the subject of intense discussion and consideration by the standards community, including from the perspective of standards developers, owners of significant patented technology, and users of standards. Indeed, many, if not all, of the issues now being raised have been considered. Moreover, such consideration has been specifically undertaken in connection with standardization activities in technology and network markets. 7 486 U.S. at 500 n.5 (citing 7 Phillip E. Areeda, Antitrust Law, § 1503, at 373 (1986)). See also Remarks of FTC Commissioner Deborah K. Owen, Horizontal Restraints – Industry Standard Setting, delivered to the Compressed Gas Association Annual Meeting, March 4, 1994 (“classic example of raising rivals’ costs behavior is where a group of manufacturers manipulates industry product standards in order to prevent competing firms from introducing an innovative or lower-cost product”). Cf. Moore v. Boating Indus. Ass’ns, 819 F.2d 693 (7th Cir.), cert. denied, 484 U.S. 854 (1987) (determination of trade associations that they could not certify boat trailers which used lamps manufactured by plaintiff, in the face of an independent test report showing that the lamps manufactured by plaintiff did not comply with federal standards, did not violate federal antitrust laws absent evidence that challenged conduct had anticompetitive effect); In re Circuit Breaker Litig., 984 F. Supp. 1267 (C.D. Cal. 1997)(decision of standards development organization not to adopt a standard for rebuilt circuit breakers was reasonable, non-discriminatory, and based entirely on technical feasibility and did not cause any competitive injury). 8 Remarks of FTC Chairman Timothy J. Muris, Competition and Intellectual Property Policy: The Way Ahead, before the American Bar Association Antitrust Section Fall Forum, November 15, 2001. 9 Id. 9 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization At the heart of these discussions has always been the need to balance the interests of the various stakeholders in the standards development process, including owners of patented technology that may become essential for implementation of a standard, parties that want to gain access to patented technology to build or provide the standardized product or service, and SDOs themselves. The interests of SDOs may be particularly relevant since their focus should be specifically on the integrity of the standards process itself and its inherent procompetitive attributes, without regard to any particular vested interest that individual participants may have. Accordingly, over the years the position has been consistently asserted and reaffirmed, at least in connection with the development of standards by formal standards bodies such as those accredited by the American National Standards Institute (“ANSI”), that to achieve the proper balance between competing stakeholder interests, and to ensure to the greatest extent possible that standards setting will achieve desired procompetitive results, a patent policy should allow for use of patented technology and encourage the early disclosure of potentially relevant patents. To do this, the consensus has always been that a patent policy should not impose unduly burdensome obligations on patent owners concerning mandatory disclosure requirements or a duty to search patent portfolios. Nor should a policy, however, allow patent holders undue liberty in depriving the industry members access to required patented technology. Otherwise, the necessary balance for effective standards setting would be put out of line. Stated differently, the ANSI Policy strikes a balance between competing interests by recognizing in the first instance that the contribution of patented technology to standards development provides the opportunity for the “best” available technical alternative to be the focus of standards activity. As a result, firms that would not otherwise have the opportunity to commercialize such technology obtain the ability to actively compete in markets for the standardized products and services. Owners of patented technology, therefore, should not be dissuaded from foregoing at least certain of the exclusive rights afforded them by patent law (e.g., the right not to allow any commercialization of an invention), which could occur if they were made subject to mandatory requirements causing them to forego such rights. But, if access to patented technology for purposes of implementing a standard is not truly available, or if it is made available 10 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization only on terms or in a manner that causes anticompetitive harm or is otherwise inconsistent with legal principles, then there must be avenues of redress for such conduct. Recently, the balanced approach reflected by the ANSI Patent Policy has yet again been questioned. Once more some commentators and participants in standards development are asserting that more rigorous and expanded disclosure obligations should be imposed upon patent owners who wish to take part in standard setting, both as respects issued patents and unpublished patent applications. There are also some calls now for SDOs to take a greater role in assessing the validity of asserted patent rights and the appropriateness of license terms. These voices do not distinguish among different types of SDOs or the subject matter of the standardization effort, and, as in the past, they assert that such steps are necessary to address the possibility that the standards process will be abused by the improper assertion of patents that are required for implementation of standards. For many SDOs, however, the question is whether the proposed fix is worse than the any problem that actually exists. III. The Standards Development Process A. Types of SDOs The volume and pace of standards development in telecommunications, computer, Internet and other network industries has grown tremendously. One factor propelling such growth may be the increased number of firms offering competitive products and services in these markets, and the need to ensure that all such offerings can interconnect at and interoperate across common network interfaces. Standardization allows for such interconnection and interoperability. The types of organizations developing industry-wide standards in these areas has also expanded, both in number and type. But, while any number of informal consortia are regularly being formed, a primary source of many technical standards remains the formal SDOs accredited by the American National Standards Institute (“ANSI”). Some of the leading SDOs of this type are Committee T1, sponsored by the Alliance for Telecommunications Industry Solutions (“ATIS”); the Telecommunications Industry Association (“TIA”), which is part of the Electronic Industry Alliance (“EIA”); and the InterNational Committee for Information 11 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Technology Standards (“INCITS”), which is sponsored by the Information Technology Industry Council (“ITI”).10 These SDOs are subject to specific procedural requirements as a condition for ANSI accreditation. Private consortia, on the other hand, are not bound to the same procedural obligations. The rationale for establishing these “informal” bodies is often stated (whether accurately or not is subject to dispute) as the need to develop standards in a more timely manner than is possible in formal ANSI-type SDOs. Thus, concepts of due process, openness and consensus inherent in the ANSI process may be absent in the consortia context, and more lax procedural requirements may apply. As respects patent policies, however, some consortia adopt more stringent positions than required by ANSI for accreditation.11 B. Procedural Requirements The existence or lack of procedural safeguards in connection with standards setting will not, of course, in and of itself, be determinative of whether specific conduct is anticompetitive, including in connection with how patented technology is treated.12 Properly fashioned and implemented procedural guidelines, however, will be relevant for evaluating the competitive impact of specific standards related conduct. As the Supreme Court in Allied Tube stated: “[t]he hope of procompetitive benefits depends upon the existence of safeguards sufficient to prevent the standard-setting process from being biased by members with 10 From 1997 through 2001 INCITS was known as the National Committee for Information Technology Standards (“NCITS”), and from 1961 through 1996 NCITS was known as Committee X3, Information Technologies. ITI was formerly known as the Computer and Business Equipment Association (“CBEMA”). 11 For example, discussed below will be the patent policies of VESA, the SDO relevant to the Dell case, and JEDEC, the relevant SDO in the Rambus case and others. Neither of these SDOs is ANSI-accredited. JEDEC, however, is affiliated with EIA. The patent policy of another nonaccredited SDO, the ATM Forum, will also be discussed. Its policy is similar to the ANSI Policy. 12 E.g., Northwest Wholesale Stationers, Inc. v. Pacific Stationery and Printing Co., 472 U.S. 284, 293 (1985)(“the absence of procedural safeguards can in no sense determine the antitrust analysis. If the challenged concerted activity of [an association’s] members would amount to a per se violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act, no amount of procedural protection would save it. If the challenged action would not amount to a violation of § 1, no lack of procedural protections would convert it into a per se violation because the antitrust laws do not themselves impose on joint ventures a requirement of process”). 12 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization economic interests in restraining competition.”13 The ANSI process recognizes this principle. Specifically, the development of American National Standards in the United States is undertaken by independent SDOs accredited by ANSI. Accreditation by ANSI requires that SDOs comply with certain principles and procedures set out in ANSI’s “Procedures for the Development and Coordination of American National Standards” (the “Procedures” or “ANSI Procedures”). 14 The Procedures concern issues such as due process, openness, consensus and the avoidance of dominance by any particular industry segment. An opportunity for appeal must also be available. ANSI itself, however, it is important to note, does not develop standards.15 As stated in ANSI’s Procedures, ANSI’s role is “to verify that the principles of openness and due process have been followed in the approval procedure and that a consensus of those directly and materially affected by the standards has been achieved.” “Consensus” in this context is defined by the Procedures to mean “substantial agreement has been reached by directly and materially affected interests.” This signifies the concurrence of “much more than a simple majority, but not necessarily unanimity. Consensus requires that all views and objections be considered, and that a concerted effort has been made towards their resolution.” Thus, standards development in ANSI-accredited SDOs generally commences with the introduction of a technical contribution by subject matter experts. Such contributions are considered at escalating levels of the organization, starting in working groups, progressing to technical subcommittees and then evolving to the full SDO committee for 486 U.S. at 509. See also Pretz v. Holstein Friesian Ass’n of America, 698 F. Supp. 1531, 1540 (D. Kan. 1988)(“presence or absence of a fair hearing . . . certainly affects the factfinder’s determination of defendant’s motive or intent and reasonableness of defendant’s restraints under a rule of reason analysis”); Brant v. United States Polo Ass’n, 631 F. Supp. 71, 78 (S.D. Fla. 1986)(“[p]laintiff could argue . . . that the lack of procedural due process or fair play . . . somehow evidences an anticompetitive motive and intent”). 13 ANSI’s Procedures, and other information regarding the Institute, can be found at www.ansi.org. 14 The ANSI Operating Procedures of the Board of Standards Review explains, “ANSI does not develop standards. Standards are developed by many qualified technical societies, trade associations, and other groups which voluntarily submit them to ANSI for approval as American National Standards.” 15 13 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization approval as a draft proposed American National Standard. At each level the ANSI requirements of due process, openness and consensus apply. Accordingly, consideration and resolution of all conflicting views occurs, often times by refining, modifying or replacing the original technical contribution. As a result of this process, there is a dynamism inherent in the development of American National Standards that may lead to the evolution of the technical parameters of a standard as it is developed. Thus, the technical scope of an approved standard may be far different than that originally proposed in an initial industry contribution. Moreover, that parameter may evolve regularly over the standard’s development. These changes are driven by the requirements for openness and consensus, which allow for all views to be considered and require all opposing positions to be fully addressed. As a result, the goal is for a standard ultimately to reflect what the industry believes is the best technical solution for the matter at hand, taking into account any number of factors including technological attributes, time to market, and international precedent. Non-ANSI-accredited SDOs (i.e., the consortia), of course, are not required to adhere to these same procedural requirements. Participants in such groups are free to establish whatever guidelines and procedures they deem appropriate. Thus, limitations on membership, approval other than through consensus, and the absence of due process are all permissible. Many consortia though do adopt some procedural safeguards, no doubt at least in part because of the recognized antitrust advantages of properly implemented procedures. They do so also because the effective development of industry-wide standards can be eased and achieved more timely when input from all interested parties is encouraged and accommodated. 14 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization IV. Patent Policies16 A. The ANSI Patent Policy One factor considered for approval of an American National Standard developed by an ANSI accredited SDO is its compliance or noncompliance with the ANSI Patent Policy. 17 The ANSI Patent Policy has existed, with only limited modification, for at least 25 years. Starting in the mid-1980s, when technologically sophisticated standards development activity began to grow, the Policy has been continuously scrutinized regarding whether it continues to properly reflect a balance between and an appropriate accommodation of all stakeholder interests – patent owners, industry participants and SDOs.18 As an initial matter, the ANSI Patent Policy expressly provides that “[t]here is no objection in principle to drafting a proposed American National Standard in terms that include the use of a patented item, if it is considered that technical reasons justify this approach.”19 This statement is intended to make it clearly understood that a patented invention may be incorporated into an American National Standard when it represents, based upon industry consensus, the most advantageous technical solution for standardization purposes. This may be because of the specific technical attributes of the technology, the ability to develop a 16 For purposes of this discussion IPR policies relating to copyrights and other rights are not considered. Such policies raise distinct issues beyond the scope of this presentation. 17 The 2002 version of the ANSI Procedures contain the ANSI Patent Policy at Sections 1.2.121.2.12.4. ANSI has also published Guidelines for Implementation of the ANSI Patent Policy, which can be found at www.ansi.org/public/library/guides/ppguide.html (the “Guidelines”). As stated in Section I of the Guidelines, “[c]ompliance (or non-compliance) with the Patent Policy is one of the criteria to be considered by ANSI’s Board of Standards Review (“BSR”) in determining whether to approve (or withdraw approval of) an American National Standards. See ANSI Procedures Sections 1.3.1.1, 1.3.2.5.” 18 The initial in depth consideration of the ANSI Patent Policy occurred in approximately 1986 through 1988. At that time Committee T1 sought to evaluate the Policy in connection with the development of telecommunication interface and interoperability standards. Thereafter, in approximately 1991, ANSI established what was then an ad-hoc Patent Committee, and what is now a full ANSI Committee. The purpose was to revisit the same issues addressed by the T1 Committee, but with a broader representation of interests. The ANSI Patent Guidelines were developed by the ANSI Patent Committee. The ANSI Patent Committee continues to actively meet and address relevant issues. 19 ANSI Procedures, Section 1.2.12. 15 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization standardized solution in the most timely manner, or such other technical reasons as a consensus of an SDO deems relevant. This aspect of the ANSI Policy also avoids the potential for the type of anticompetitive conduct addressed by the FTC’s consent decree in American Society of Sanitary Engineers,20 which involved an ASSE policy that, among other things, prohibited the standardization of patented inventions. As alleged by the Commission, such a policy unreasonably restrained trade because (i) an innovative product was excluded from the market; (ii) buyers were misled to believe that the new product would not perform as well as approved products; and (iii) buyers were deprived of information about the performance of the product. The ANSI Patent Policy then addresses the situation where notice is given that a patent may be relevant to a proposed American National Standard. It does so without imposing any requirement that patent owners affirmatively disclose or search for potentially relevant patents. Rather, Section 1.2.12 states that “[i]f the Institute receives a notice that a proposed American National Standard may require the use of a patented invention, the procedures of Section 1.2.12.1 through 1.2.12.4 shall be followed.” These latter sections provide as follows: “Section 1.2.12.1 Statement from Patent Holder.21 Prior to approval of such a proposed American National Standard, the Institute shall receive from the identified party 22 or patent holder . . . 20 3 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 22,185 (1985). 21 In 1997 this Section was revised to delete a final paragraph that stated: The terms and conditions of any license shall be submitted to ANSI for review by its counsel, together with a statement of the number of independent licensees, if any, which have accepted or indicated their acceptance of terms and conditions of the license. This paragraphs was deleted upon the consensus recommendation of the ANSI Patent Committee because, as a matter of practice, it was not being followed. ANSI was not, appropriately, reviewing specific terms of license agreements and only on rare occasions were terms and conditions submitted by licensors to ANSI. The words “identified party” were added in 1997 to recognize that notice of a potentially relevant patent may be from a party other than a claimed patent owner. It is possible, therefore, that the party identified by the third party does not actually own a patent that may be required for implementation of the standard, and therefore may not be a “patent holder.” 22 16 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization either: assurance in the form of a general disclaimer to the effect that such party does not hold and does not anticipate holding any invention whose use would be required for compliance with the proposed American National Standard or assurance that: a. A license will be made available without compensation to applicants desiring to utilize the license for the purpose of implementing the standard; or b. A license will be made available to applicants under reasonable terms and conditions that are demonstrably free of any unfair discrimination. “Section 1.2.12.2 Record of Statement. A record of the patent holder’s statement shall be placed and retained in the files of the Institute. “Section 1.2.12.3 Notice. When the Institute receives from a patent holder the assurance set forth in 1.2.12.1(a) or 1.2.12.1(b), the standard shall include a note as follows: Note – The user’s attention is called to the possibility that compliance with this standard may require use of an invention covered by patent rights. By publication of this standard, no position is taken with respect to the validity of this claim or of any patent rights in connection therewith. The patent holder has, however, filed a statement of willingness to grant a license under these rights on reasonable and nondiscriminatory terms and conditions to applicants desiring to obtain such a license. Details may be obtained from the standards developer. 17 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization “Section 1.2.12.4 Responsibility for Identifying Patents. The Institute shall not be responsible for identifying all patents for which a license may be required by an American National Standard or for conducting inquiries into the legal validity or scope of those patents that are brought to its attention. These provisions reflect several important concepts. First, the Policy does not impose a duty on patent holders to search their portfolios to determine whether they own any patents that may be or are relevant to the proposed standard under development, or to disclose any such patents. While such disclosure is encouraged, it is not mandated, and experience in ANSI-accredited SDOs establishes that a mandatory rule is unnecessary. Specifically, it is recognized that patent owners have strong incentives to disclose the existence of potentially relevant patents during the development process. Such incentives include the enhanced ability to have one’s proprietary technology standardized on an industry-wide basis, and to enter into licensing arrangements at an early time. Thus, it is common for patent owners, particularly those with large portfolios, to provide general assurances of a willingness to license early in the development process.23 A strong consensus has also existed that imposition of mandatory search and disclosure duties could chill the incentive for patent owners to participate in the standards setting process, which would then cause industry to be deprived of potentially superior technology for standardization. Second, the Policy does not apply to pending patent applications. Discussion is presently underway in the ANSI Patent Committee regarding whether the Policy should be extended to published patent applications, but no decision in that regard has been made. Besides the confidential nature of unpublished patent applications, another rationale for not including them under the Policy is the dynamic nature of both standards development and of the patent approval process. Not only do the technical parameters of proposed standards evolve 23 Such assurances do not, typically, identify specific patents or proposed license terms, but they make it known that if any technology is standardized for which a license is needed, one will be forthcoming. ANSI’s Guidelines identify ways to encourage such disclosure. 18 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization continuously, the limitations of a patent’s claims may also as it is reviewed in the Patent and Trademark Office. Thus, any determination that an invention described in a yet-to-be-issued patent may be relevant or essential for use of a standard, which itself has not yet been defined, is a difficult task that could impose significant delay on the standards process. A patent applicant, however, is in no way precluded from disclosing the fact of and specifics concerning its pending application. Third, Section 1.2.12 intends to make clear that the assurances referenced in Section 1.2.12.1 are implicated only if ANSI receives a notice that a patent may be relevant to the standard under development.24 Again, no mandatory duty exists to give such a notice; rather, the incentives inherent in the process generally compel such a step. Further the use of the word “may” here is intentional, and is also consistent with the ANSI Policy’s goal to encourage disclosure of potentially relevant patents at as early a stage in the standards development process as possible. As stated in the ANSI Patent Guidelines, “[e]xperience has indicated that early disclosure of patents is likely to enhance the efficiency of the process used to finalize and approve standards.” Fourth, as noted above, the amendment to Section 1.2.12.1 to add the words “identified party” was intended to make clear that identification of a potentially relevant patent can be by a party other than the patent owner – e.g., a party with an interest in the standards development work which takes it upon itself to determine the existence of any potentially relevant issued patents. Again, this change was made to further encourage disclosure of relevant patent information. As with many things, however, in adopting this position the potential of unintended consequences needed to be considered. For example, a party seeking to slow the standards process, or avoid a particular technology from being standardized other than for legitimate technical reasons, could assert without basis that another party owns a relevant patent. To address such an assertion the claimed patent owner would be forced to undertake an expensive and time-consuming search of its patent portfolio and an analysis of potentially relevant patents. The ability to provide a general assurance to license without disclosure of information concerning specific patents helps avoid the possibility that the claimed patent owner in such circumstances would be unresponsive in providing any assurance. 24 In practice, SDOs also receive such notices and assurances, which are then passed along to ANSI as part of the approval process. 19 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Fifth, even if a patent that may be relevant is identified, the assurances contemplated by Section 1.2.12.1 only apply to patents that “would be required for compliance with the proposed American National Standard.” This is a very different criterion than a patent that “may” be relevant to the standard. The “required” language has been consistently understood to mean “essential” for implementation of the standard – i.e., absent a license, implementation of the standard would infringe the patent. Thus, if alternative methods exist to implement a standard, this aspect of the ANSI Policy would not apply. Similarly, if the patent concerns only informative (as distinct from normative) aspects of a standard, the Policy also would not apply. This is not to say, of course, that disclosure in such circumstances would not still be encouraged and made by the patent owner. Sixth, the notice contemplated by Section 1.2.12.3 is important to ensure that it is understood that neither ANSI nor an ANSI-accredited SDOs will become involved in ascertaining the applicability or validity of a particular patent in connection with a proposed standard. Likewise, Section 1.2.12.4 makes clear that neither ANSI nor ANSI-accredited SDOs will be responsible for identifying or conducting inquiries regarding the existence or validity of the identified relevant patents or additional patents.25 These sections, and the corresponding disclaimers used by Committee T1’s Procedure Manual thus provides for a notice to be given to committee members that “[d]isclosure made of such patents may not be exhaustive of all patents that may be essential for the use of standards under development, and that neither Committee T1, the [Technical Subcommittee] nor the [Technical Subcommittee] Chairman ensure the accuracy or completeness of any disclosure or whether any disclosure is of a patent that in fact may be essential for the use of standards under development.” A similar disclaimer is included in standards developed by Committee T1. 25 Similarly, Section 8.4 of the Policies and Guidelines of INCITS provides for notices both where a commitment to license has been made and where it has not. The following notice is used where notice and a commitment to license exist: “CAUTION: The developers of this standard have requested that holders of patents that may be required for the implementation of the standard disclose such patents to the publisher. However, neither the developers nor the publisher have undertaken a patent search in order to identify which, if any, patents may apply to this standard. As of the date of publication of this standard, following calls for the identification of patents that may be required for the implementation of the standard, notice of one or more such claims has been received. By publication of this standard, no position is taken with respect to the validity of this claim or of any rights in connection therewith. The known patent holder(s) has (have), however, filed a statement of willingness to grant a license under these rights on reasonable and non- discriminatory terms and conditions to applicants desiring to obtain such a 20 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization SDOs are intended to make clear that no expectation should arise that all potentially or actually relevant patents have been disclosed. As commented by the FTC in Dell, this set the ANSI Policy apart from the one considered there.26 Another important reason for ANSI and SDOs to limit their role in determining the existence or validity of any relevant patents is to avoid the risk of potential liability of the type that EIA now faces in the Sony Electronics, Inc. v. Soundview Technologies, Inc. case.27 The plaintiff there alleged that EIA, in connection with the development of a standard, induced its members to infringe plaintiff’s patent even though, plaintiff alleged, the patent was essential for implementation of the standard. The court specifically found the following allegations, if proven, sufficient to establish a EIA’s intent to induce infringement: “EIA identified the ‘most relevant’ patents for its members, circulated that information to them, posited various ways its members could avoid licensing obligations, and provided test tapes for its members to ascertain whether their allegedly infringing products met the regulatory requirements.”28 Accordingly, based at least in part on these allegations, the court denied EIA’s motion to dismiss plaintiff’s claim against it. Seventh, the ANSI Patent Policy does not contemplate ANSI or SDOs being involved in discussions or negotiation of license terms. Rather, such matters are left to the licensor and licensees.29 This position license. Details may be obtained from the publisher. No further patent search is conducted by the developer or publisher in respect to any standard it processes. No representation is made or implied that this is the only license that may be required to avoid infringement in the use of the standard. In the scenario where neither the developer nor the publisher has received notice, the following notice is provided: CAUTION: The developers of this standard have requested that holders of patents that may be required for implementation of the standard disclose such patents to the publisher. However, neither the developers nor the publisher have undertaken a patent search in order to identify which, if any, patents may apply to this standard. As of the date of publication of this standard and following calls for the identification of patents that may be required for the implementation of the standard, no such claims have been made. No further patent search is conducted by the developer or publisher in respect to any standard it processes. No representation is made or implied that licenses are not require to avoid infringement in the use of this standard. 26 See discussion infra at 23-24. 27 157 F. Supp.2d 190 (D. Conn. 2001). 28 Id. at 201. See also John S. Martin, An Update on the Soundview Litigation, AT-IP Report, December 7, 2001, www.abanet.org/antitrust/committees/intell_property/dec7report.html. Section III(B) of the Guidelines provides that “it should be reiterated, . . . , that the determination of specific license terms and conditions, and the evaluation of whether such license 29 21 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization has been followed because discussion of such issues in the development process could give rise to allegations of anticompetitive conspiracies, and thereby expose standards participants and SDOs to potential antitrust liability. This does not mean that a patent owner cannot announce what its terms will be, but involving an SDO as a vehicle for establishing licensing terms may more likely lead to allegations of collusion. In addition, participants in the standards development process are typically technical experts who generally would not be in a position or have the authority to address licensing terms on behalf of their companies. Further, reasonable and non-discriminatory (RAND) terms and conditions may, but need not, be identical for each licensee; they may vary depending upon a number of factors, including when in the development process a license is agreed upon, whether reciprocal licenses are involved, whether the licensed patent is bundled with other patents and other variables that might arise in specific circumstances. Thus, to allow appropriate licenses to be fashioned for each circumstance confidential negotiations between the parties outside the development arena are common. Again, the ANSI Policy does not require confidentiality, but accommodates it as part of the balancing of interests. Not only does this encourage patent owners to engage in licensing discussions without limiting the types of licensing arrangements they may make available, it provides standards participants knowledge of likely license terms and conditions even while a standard is still being developed. A mandatory requirement that such terms be publicly disclosed, however, could inhibit negotiations, or even cause patent owners to be unwilling to license at all. Notably, only in very few cases have there been any reports of objections to proposed license terms under the ANSI Policy, and in each instance the objections were resolved.30 terms and conditions are reasonable and demonstrably free of unfair discrimination, are not matters that are properly the subject of discussion or debate at a development meeting. Such matters should be determined only by the prospective parties to each license or, if necessary, by an appeal challenging whether compliance with the Patent Policy has been achieved.” One case, however, has addressed a patent owner’s proposed license terms under a patent policy similar to ANSI’s. In Townshend v. Rockwell Int’l. Corp., No. C-0400, 2000 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 5070, 2000-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 72,890 (N.D. Cal. March 28, 2000), the court dismissed defendant’s counterclaims under §§ 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act on the pleading. Defendant asserted its counterclaims in response to plaintiff’s claim of patent infringement, and based them on plaintiff’s alleged improper conduct that caused the International Telecommunications Union (“ITU”) to approve an industry standard that required use of plaintiff’s patented technology. In addition, plaintiff was alleged to have violated the ITU Patent Policy by denying access to its technology, “or conditioning the availability of the technology on reciprocal dealing, by extracting cross-licenses at fixed, artificially low rates and by attempting to double-charge [defendant] and its customers by requiring them each to pay a separate license fee . . .” 2000 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 5070 at *19-20. 30 22 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization These aspects of the ANSI Patent Policy have been maintained, and the principles underlying them affirmed, even in face of the possibility that the process may be abused as a result of a so-called “snake in the grass,” “hold up” or “patent ambush.” These refer to the situation where a patent owner does not disclose its patent rights during the standards development process, and only later asserts them after the standard has been widely implemented. Due to the serious impact that such conduct can have on the standards development process generally, careful consideration has repeatedly been given to such a possibility. The collective recollection of the ANSI Patent Committee, however, is that no such abuse has occurred in the development of American National Standards. In addition, the ANSI Patent Policy has withstood the test of time because it appears to be working. Not only have there been no recalled instances of a “snake in the grass” or “patent ambush,” the pace and volume of standards development has increased even as more patents have been identified and become relevant to standardized technology. Modifying the Policy to include more burdensome duties and obligations on patent owners, which could chill the incentive for patent owners to voluntarily disclose and agree to license their rights and also expose standards participants and SDOs to greater litigation risks, therefore, has been viewed as unnecessary and potentially detrimental to the balance of interests reflected by the current policy. The effectiveness of the ANSI Patent Policy is also reflected by its adoption by leading technology SDOs. These include Committee T1, which develops standards and technical reports related to functions and characteristics associated with interconnection and interoperability of In holding that defendant had not sufficiently alleged injury to competition, the court observed that the ITU Policy leaves negotiations of specific license terms to the parties, and that plaintiff had made its willingness to license known. Accordingly, because “a patent holder is permitted under the antitrust laws to completely exclude others from practicing his or her technology,” plaintiff’s submission of proposed licensing terms, whatever they were, would not state a violation of the antitrust laws. Id. at *23. Further, the court said, even if it were to consider the alleged unfair nature of the proposed terms, no injury to competition could be stated. The court reached this conclusion because: “a patent owner’s pursuit of optimum royalty income is not an act in restraint of trade”; “cross-licensing is considered a pro-competitive practice because it can facilitate the integration of complementary technologies”; and “because a patent owner has the legal right to refuse to license his or her patent on any terms, the existence of a predicate condition to a license agreement cannot state an antitrust violation.” Id. at *25-26. 23 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization telecommunications networks at interfaces with end user systems, carriers and information and enhanced service providers; INCITS, which develops standards in the field of information technology which encompasses storage, processing, transfer, display, management, organization and retrieval of information; TIA, which develops standards and specifications for telecommunications equipment and fiber optic products; and the Society of Cable Telecommunications Engineers (“SCTE”), which develops technical specifications relating to cable television products, procedures, materials and safety practices. Leading international technology standards organizations have adopted similar positions. The ITU, for example, as previously noted, has adopted a policy that is very similar in scope and application to the ANSI Patent Policy.31 Indeed, the ITU’s implementing guidelines for its Patent Policy point out that the underlying principle of its Policy is the same as underlies the ANSI Policy, and the policies of other standardization organizations including ISO, IEC and CEN/CENELEC.32 The Patent Policy of the European Telecommunications Standards Institute (“ETSI”) also seeks to encourage the early disclosure of relevant patent rights without imposing mandatory obligations on patent holders. Thus, the ETSI Policy states that it “seeks a balance between the needs of standardization for public use in the field of telecommunications and the rights of the owners of IPRs.” Members are, therefore, directed to use “reasonable endeavors” to inform ETSI of “essential” rights that the member becomes aware of, but any implication of an obligation to search is expressly disclaimed and no mandatory duty to disclose is imposed.33 2. Other Patent Policies (a) The ATM Forum 31 The ITU Policy can be found at www.itu.int/ITU-T/dbase/patent/Patent_Policy.html. 32 One difference between the ITU Policy and the ANSI Policy is that if a potentially relevant patent is disclosed in connection with the development of an ITU specification and the identified patent owner will not provide an assurance regarding licensing, the specification will not be approved. Under the ANSI Policy approval of the standard as an American National Standard may still occur if a consensus of the development organization is in favor. 33 The ETSI Policy can be accessed at www.etsi.org. 24 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Some non-accredited SDOs have also adopted ANSI-like patent policies. For example, the ATM Forum, an international group of providers of asynchronous transfer mode (ATM) technology and applications based upon international and national standards, has adopted a policy similar to the ANSI Policy in that it encourages disclosure of patent rights but does not mandate it. The ATM Forum’s policy also expressly does not obligate any member to disclose or identify any unpublished anticipated patent rights or to search for any potentially pertinent intellectual property or other rights.34 (b) VESA Other non-accredited SDOs, however, have adopted policies that vary from the ANSI-type policy in that they impose disclosure and other obligations upon patent holders, as well as expand the scope and source of disclosures that must be made. One such policy was adopted by the Video Electronics Standards Association (“VESA”), and was the subject of the FTC’s Dell proceeding. In contrast to the ANSI Policy, VESA imposed an affirmative disclosure requirement as a condition of membership by requiring members to certify whether they had any patents or other proprietary rights that conflicted with the standard at issue. This affirmative disclosure requirement, the Commission stated, “creates an expectation by [the VESA] members that each will act in good faith to identify and disclose conflicting intellectual property rights.” 35 The Commission further noted that other SDOs may have different procedures, and specifically that the ANSI Patent Policy does not create the same expectation because it “does not require that companies provide a certification as to conflicting intellectual property rights.”36 Accordingly, the Commission expressly cautioned that the relief in Dell “should not be read to impose a general duty to search.”37 The VESA Policy also differed from ANSI’s in another important way. It called for the representative of the member company attending the relevant meeting to make the disclosure regarding the existence of 34 See www.atmforum.com/pages/advantages/bylaws99.html at § 3.12.2. 35 Dell, supra at *18. 36 Id. and n.6. 37 Id. 25 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization patents and other intellectual property rights. The Commission found that the voting representative’s action bound Dell. Often times, however, as previously commented, a company’s representative participating in an SDO will have less than full knowledge concerning the scope of the company’s patent portfolio or of the specific limitations stated in claims of patents that may be relevant to the standard being developed. Thus, a policy that imputes the company’s knowledge to the representative, or vice versa, can create serious potential liability for patent owners, and thereby inhibit the standards process. (c) JEDEC Another non-accredited SDO whose patent policy differs from ANSI’s is the JEDEC Solid State Technology Association (“JEDEC”).38 The JEDEC Patent Policy is stated in various sections of its Manual of Organization and Procedure, and among other things “requires the early disclosure of known patents and patent applications that are or may be relevant to the work of the formulating committee. This duty extends to the patent owner and any other participant on the formulating committee with knowledge of the patent or patent application.”39 In addition, Section 7.3 of the JEDEC Manual provides “committees should avoid standardization that refers to a product on which there is a known patent unless all the relevant technical information covered by the patent is known to the formulating committee, subcommittee or task group.” Section 7.3 continues: If the committee member indicates that the standard requires the use of patent items, then the committee chairperson must receive a written assurance from the organization holding rights to such patents that a license will be made available to applicants desiring to implement the standard either without compensation or under reasonable terms and conditions that are demonstrably free of any unfair discrimination. 38 JEDEC is affiliated with EIA, as is TIA, both of which have adopted the ANSI Patent Policy. 39 The JEDEC Patent Policy is accessible at www.jedec.org. 26 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Section 7.3.1 imposes a further duty on the chairperson of any JEDEC committee to call to the attention of all present “the obligation of all participants to inform the meeting of any knowledge they may have of any patents, or pending patents that might be involved in the work they are undertaking.” Thus, like VESA’s, the JEDEC Policy imposes a mandatory disclosure obligation regarding patents and patent applications that may be relevant to the standard under consideration. Guidance is not provided, however, concerning the boundaries of relevance so that patent owners can have certainty in determining the extent of their disclosure obligation. Further, while this duty is sought to be limited to potentially relevant patents that are known by a JEDEC member or its participating representative, difficult issues will exist regarding what constitutes knowledge. For example, if a JEDEC member does not search its patent portfolio and thereby fails to uncover an essential patent, will it still be deemed to have the knowledge of that patent? Full and continuous searches may, therefore, be required, at least by implication. Likewise, if a company does search its portfolio, but innocently overlooks a potentially relevant patent, would that give rise to a claim that it violated JEDEC’s Policy and thereby should be stopped from asserting its patent? Further, what will be the consequence of a patent owner determining that its patent would not be relevant to a standard at an early formative stage, only to reach a different conclusion once the standard matures? As difficult as these issues are in connection with corporate members, they are likely be even more difficult when applied to the individual representatives of those members who actually attend committee meetings. The JEDEC Policy’s requirement that “all the relevant technical information covered by the patent” be disclosed also raises issues. This requirement seemingly would preclude the practice of a patent owner to simply provide a generalized assurance to license, and thereby avoid the burden and cost of continuously searching its patent portfolio to find potentially relevant patents, leading to delay in a standard’s development. This requirement could also lead to a “reverse snake in the grass” scenario where a third party, for improper purposes (e.g., to slow or avoid standardization), identifies a company as having a potentially relevant patent without identifying the patent. The claimed patent owner might not be able to identify a specific patent, or at least not in a timely manner, and as a result be unable to meet the requirement of disclosing all technical information covered by the asserted patent. Nor would the patent owner 27 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization likely be willing to disclaim rights that it may have, but which it does not know are actually implicated by the standard. As a result, the identifying party would succeed in blocking standardization. Disclosure obligations concerning unpublished patent applications also raise issues because standards participants may be compelled to disclose confidential proprietary technology not yet protected under patent law, before it is clear what the actual scope of a standard (or the patent) may be. As a result, inventors may be less willing to participate in standards development process because their ability to recoup their inventive investment could be eliminated. Thus, while patent policies such as those adopted by VESA and JEDEC may be deemed appropriate and necessary to address certain potentially abusive conduct in connection with specific standardization efforts, they can also raise serious issues, including potentially greater risks of litigation for standards participants and SDOs.40 As such, they may not be appropriate for other SDOs. Indeed, SDOs that follow the ANSI Policy have declined to adopt policies with the type of obligations and requirements reflected in the VESA and JEDEC Policies. III. Conclusion Standards development for information and technology industries is a complex process involving many competing interests. The complexities only become greater and the task of balancing all relevant interests only more challenging when patented technologies are involved. 40 See, e.g., Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Technologies AG, No. 00CV524, 2001 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 11871 (E.D. Va. August 9, 2001) (Rambus’s violation of JEDEC Policy relevant to fraud verdict); Wang Laboratories, Inc. v. Mitsubishi Electronics America, Inc., 103 F.3d 1571, 1581-82 (Fed. Cir.), cert. denied, 522 U.S. 818 (1997) (plaintiff’s participation in and failure to comply with JEDEC policy basis for implied license defense); Veronica Smith Lewis, Rambus’ Limited Patent Disclosure To a Standard Setting Body Was Found To Be Fraudulent But Not An Antitrust Violation, AT-IP Report, June 6, 2001, www.abanet.org/antitrust/committees/intell_property /rambus.html.; Veronica Smith Lewis, Rambus v. Infineon-The Latest Standard Setting Patent Disclosure Guidance, AT-IP Report, September 24, 2001, www.abanet.org/antitrust/committees/intel_property/sep24report.html. See also Potter Instrument Co., Inc. v. Storage Technology Corp., 207 U.S.P.Q. 763, 766 (E.D. Va. 1980), aff’d, 641 F.2d 190 (4th Cir.), cert. denied, 454 U.S. 832 (1981) (estoppel defense considered in light of SDO policy providing that when any patent is to be included in a standard “the owner of such patent must bring to the attention of the Subcommittee the existence of such patents”). Cf. Stambler v. Diebold, Inc., 11 U.S.P.Q.2d 1709, 1714-15 (E.D.N.Y. 1988), aff’d, 878 F.2d 1445 (Fed. Cir. 1989) (plaintiff estopped from asserting claim of patent infringement where 10 years prior to suit it knew that allegedly infringing standard was being considered as an American National Standard). 28 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Experience shows, however, that these matters cannot be addressed in a “one size fits all” manner. Rather, in crafting patent policies SDOs must be allowed to give careful consideration to many different factors – the nature of the industry, the nature of the technology, and even the nature of patents involved – and care should be taken not to require changes to the standards development process when perhaps there is no compelling need or reason to do so. 29 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization A YEAR IN THE LIFE OF A HIGH TECH STANDARDS SETTING ORGANIZATION Section of Antitrust Law STANDARD SETTING ACTIVITY OFFENSIVE CLAIMS By Joseph P. Lavelle and Melissa J. Gunthner April 25, 2002 Washington, D.C. 30 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization INTRODUCTION Much has been written, debated, and dissected regarding the antitrust issues that arise when patent holders participate in voluntary standard setting activity. The debate is important. Intellectual property is a significant and generally procompetitive component of our modern economy. Likewise, voluntary standard setting activity generally is procompetitive. When the two combine to raise anticompetitive concerns, a careful review of the precise nature of the concerns and a discerning approach to a remedy is clearly in order. This article focuses on the largest risks attendant to standard setting activity—namely the affirmative damages and other claims that can be leveled against an IP holder that participates in standard setting activities. A companion article, by Mark Flagel and Michael Lawrence, discusses ways in which standard setting conduct may preclude enforcement of IP.1 We focus primarily on federal claims, which for the most part arise under the federal antitrust laws. However, the RICO statute has also been asserted against IP holders that have participated in standard setting activity. We also review state law claims. Most noteworthy among these is the claim for common law fraud successfully asserted at the trial court level in the district court decision in Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Technologies AG.2 For a general introduction to the claims that can arise out of  Mr. Lavelle is a partner at Howrey Simon Arnold & White, LLP. Ms. Gunthner is associated with the same firm. The views expressed here are those of the authors alone and do not necessarily represent the views of Howrey Simon Arnold & White or of any client of the firm. Mr. Lavelle has represented Rambus, Inc. and other clients in certain matters involving standard setting. Once again, the views expressed herein are Mr. Lavelle’s alone, not those of Rambus, Inc. or any other client of Mr. Lavelle. The authors thank Michael G. Cowie, Senior Litigation Counsel, Bureau of Competition, Federal Trade Commission. Mr. Cowie’s prior collaboration with the authors was of assistance in preparing this work. 1 Mark A. Flagel & Michael J. Lawrence, Strategic Considerations When Asserting Defenses Against a Claim for Infringement of a Patent that Reads on an Industry Standard (2002). 2 164 F. Supp. 2d 743 (E.D. Va. 2001). 31 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization standard setting activities, see the materials listed in the note.3 In this article, we focus on the developments that have occurred in recent case law relating to the offensive claims that can be asserted against a patentee who participates in standard setting. FEDERAL OFFENSIVE CLAIMS Misconduct in the standard setting process may lead to claims that the IP holder violated the federal antitrust laws—specifically, Section 1 of the Sherman Act, relating to agreements in restraint of trade, and Section 2 of the Sherman Act, relating to unlawful monopolization or the attempt or conspiracy to monopolize. In addition, IP holders have been subjected to claims and investigations by the Federal Trade Commission (“FTC”) under Section 5 of the FTC Act, in instances where the FTC Staff considered the IP holder’s conduct to amount to an unfair method of competition. Private litigants, the U.S. Department of Justice, the FTC, and state attorneys general may sue for violations of the Sherman Act. The FTC has exclusive power to bring an action under Section 5 of the FTC Act. Civil remedies for a violation of the federal antitrust laws may include treble damages to private litigants.4 Criminal liability may include a felony conviction and imprisonment and/or a fine up to $10 million for corporations and up to $350,000 if any other person.5 The Racketeer Influenced and Corrupt Organizations Act (“RICO”)6 provides for treble damage remedies and attorneys fees awards that have motivated private plaintiffs for decades to try to convert state law fraud claims into federal RICO claims. Despite numerous attempts by the courts to limit this tendency,7 lure continues to prove irresistible, and a challenge to standard setting conduct under RICO has been presented to at least one jury.8 3 Michael G. Cowie & Joseph P. Lavelle, Patents Covering Industry Standards: The Risks to Enforceability Due to Conduct Before Standard-Setting Organizations, AIPLA Q.J. (forthcoming 2002); 2 HERBERT HOVENKAMP ET AL., IP AND ANTITRUST § 35 (2002). 4 15 U.S.C. § 15 (2000). 5 15 U.S.C. §§ 1, 2 (2000). 6 18 U.S.C. §§ 1961 et seq. (2000). 7 H.J. Inc. v. Northwestern Bell Tel. Co., 492 U.S. 229 (1988); Sedima, S.P.R.L. v. Imrex Co., 473 U.S. 479 (1985). 8 Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Techs. AG, 164 F. Supp. 2d 743 (E.D. Va. 2001). 32 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization SHERMAN ACT Restraint of Trade – Section 1 Section 1 of the Sherman Act provides that “[e]very contract, combination . . . , or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal.” 9 Early on, the Supreme Court recognized that the statute could not literally mean what it says, and it is well established today that Section 1 prohibits only agreements that unreasonably restrain trade.10 The essence of a Section 1 claim resides in concert of action. Agreements that have on balance an anticompetitive effect on competition can violate Section 1.11 However, the existence of an agreement is essential to a claim. Concerted Action As illustrated by Hyundai Electronics Industries Co. v. Rambus Inc., failure to allege concerted action is fatal to a section 1 claim.12 Hyundai involved a challenge to a patentee’s failure to disclose pending patent applications to a standard setting body called JEDEC, which is active in the electronics and computer arts. Years after the patentee left the standards organization, it filed continuation applications and presented claims, some of which covered standards adopted by JEDEC. Hyundai claimed Section 1 was violated because Rambus’s conduct allegedly had an anticompetitive effect on a collaborative process—namely standard setting. The district court dismissed the Section 1 claim on the pleadings.13 The court held that a patent holder’s unilateral conduct can not result in a violation of Section 1. Applying well established principles, the found that while the unilateral conduct was 9 15 U.S.C. § 1. Chicago Bd. of Trade v. United States, 246 U.S. 231, 238 (1918); Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1, 58 (1911). For a detailed analysis of the case law under Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, the reader is urged to consult ABA Section of Antitrust Law, Antitrust Law Developments (4th ed. 1997). Antitrust Law Developments strives to present an accurate view of the current state of antitrust case law, with little or no editorializing or opining. 11 Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Serv. Corp., 465 U.S. 752, 768 (1984); Am. Tobacco Co. v. United States, 328 U.S. 781, 810 (1946). 12 No. C 00-20905 RMW (N.D. Cal. Jan. 19, 2001) (order granting in part and denying in part defendant’s motion to dismiss). 13 Id. at 4-5. 10 33 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization alleged to have an effect in a collaborative forum such as JEDEC, this fact alone is insufficient to support a section 1 claim.14 Where, on the other hand, concerted action is alleged, a section 1 claim based on misconduct in the standard setting process may survive a motion to dismiss. For example, in Sony Electronics, Inc. v. Soundview Technologies, Inc.,15 a district court denied a motion to dismiss a section 1 claim where concerted action between a standard setting organization and its members was alleged. Soundview Technologies, Inc. (“Soundview”) owned a patent that covered the Electronic Industries Alliance (“EIA”) standard for the V-chip, a device that allows parents to block undesirable television programming.16 EIA and its members (television manufacturers) allegedly rejected Soundview’s offer to license its patents on nondiscriminatory and reasonable terms and agreed upon a set price for a license under Soundview’s patent.17 Soundview claimed that EIA and its members participated in a group boycott and refusal to deal and engaged in price fixing in violation of section 1.18 The court determined that Soundview adequately plead a monopsony conspiracy. Anticompetitive effects, such as an artificial depression in price, an exodus of suppliers from the market, a reduction in innovation and development, and a restraint on individual television manufacturers’ ability to make independent economic decisions, could result.19 The court rejected the argument that the alleged conduct was protected by the Noerr-Pennington doctrine. As the court explained, “Soundview’s counterclaim contains substantially more than mere litigation or joint action to challenge a patent, in that it alleges a conspiracy to pay a maximum price and a group boycott not to accept a license from Soundview.”20 Antitrust Injury In addition to alleging concerted action, one must allege antitrust injury in order to state a claim under section 1. Antitrust injury is courtmade prudential doctrine that limits the type of damages that can be recovered in a claim under the federal antitrust laws. 14 Id. at 4. 157 F. Supp. 2d 180 (D. Conn. 2001). 16 Id. at 181. 17 Id. at 182. 18 Id. 19 Id. at 184-88. 20 Id. at 189. 15 34 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization The doctrine of antitrust injury requires that a plaintiff plead and prove two things: first, that the plaintiff was injured in fact; and second, that the injury is the type of injury the antitrust laws were intended to protect and flows from that which makes the defendant’s conduct unlawful under the antitrust laws.21 In Townshend v. Rockwell International Corp.,22 a district court dismissed a section 1 counterclaim without leave to amend for failure to allege antitrust injury. The accused infringer, Conexant, alleged that the patent holder, Townshend, and his licensee, 3Com, conspired to fraudulently procure an International Telecommunications Union (“ITU”) standard requiring the use of Townshend’s patent.23 As required by ITU’s patent policy, 3Com and Townshend stated their willingness to license the patent on non-discriminatory and reasonable terms.24 In addition, the parties announced the terms on which they were prepared to deal and posted them on a website. While Conexant argued that the terms were unfair and in violation of the ITU patent policy, the ITU was presumably satisfied that the patentee had complied with ITU rules by agreeing to grant non-discriminatory licenses. ITU subsequently adopted the standard, called V.90, and the standard remains in use today for dial-up modems.25 The court dismissed Conexant’s Section 1 claim for failure to allege antitrust injury.26 First, the court determined that the alleged unfair licensing terms, including “unfair royalty rates, double-charging of customers and manufacturers, mandatory cross-licenses, and reservation of the right to condition licenses on the resolution of litigation,” did not state an injury to competition.27 Relying on 35 U.S.C. § 271(d)(4), the court reasoned that it was not improper for a patentee to announce the terms on which it was willing to deal.28 Somewhat surprisingly, the court fails to distinguish between unilateral acts of a patentee, such as those covered in § 271(d)(4), and the allegations in this case, which relate to an alleged conspiracy to enforce the license terms. 21 E.g., Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Matic, Inc., 429 U.S. 477 (1977). No. C 99-0400 SBA, 2000 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 5070 (N.D. Cal. Mar. 28, 2000). 23 Id. at *5-6. 24 Id. at *20-21. 25 Id. at *21. 26 Id. at *28. 27 Id. at *22-23. 28 Id. 22 35 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Second, as the court stated, “Conexant’s allegations that Townshend initiated a patent infringement suit—without any additional allegation of anti-competitive aspects of this suit—does not state an antitrust injury, nor does it identify any antitrust injury caused by a conspiracy between 3Com and Townshend.”29 Again, the court does not consider whether litigation undertaken in furtherance of an alleged conspiracy should be treated different from the unilateral decision of a patentee to file suit. Finally, the court found that alleged injury to Conexant itself was insufficient to amount to an allegation of injury to competition.30 Monopolization – Section 2 Section 2 of the Sherman Act prohibits monopolization, or the attempt or conspiracy to monopolize, “any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations.”31 Section 2 of the Sherman Act is addressed primarily at unilateral conduct. Generally speaking, to prove the offense of monopolization, the plaintiff must prove that the defendant possessed monopoly power, and that the monopoly power was acquire or maintained through unlawful conduct.32 A threshold issue that is likely to recur relates to whether a claim that a patentee misused the standard setting process states a claim in light of the Federal Circuit’s overly broad dicta in In re Independent Service Organization Antitrust Litigation (“Xerox”).33 In Xerox, the Federal Circuit suggested that a patentee was free to enforce its patent without concern under the antitrust laws, unless the patentee was guilty of illegal tying, a Walker Process litigation, or the existence of sham litigation.34 Patentees accused of standards related antitrust claims will likely rely on Xerox as immunizing their conduct. In Hyundai Electronics Industries Co. v. Rambus, Inc., discussed supra, the district court rejected this argument in the context of a motion to dismiss. Hyundai asserted that Rambus violated Section 2 by attempting to monopolize the market for technology inputs to high-speed memory 29 Id. at *26-27. Id. at *27. 31 15 U.S.C. § 2 (2000). 32 E.g., United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir.), cert. denied, 122 S. Ct. 350 (2001); Elecs. Communications Corp. v. Toshiba Am. Consumer Prods., Inc., 129 F.3d 240, 246 (2d Cir. 1997). 33 203 F.3d 1322 (Fed. Cir. 2000). 34 Id. at 1326-27. 30 36 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization devices by violating certain disclosure rules before the JEDEC standards body. Rambus asserted that, as its alleged conduct was not a tie-in, Walker Process violation, or allegedly sham litigation, it was immune from antitrust scrutiny under the Xerox decision. Judge Whyte rejected this claim. Relying on the FTC’s consent decree in Dell Computer Corp.,35 the court reasoned that the allegations that the patentee failed to disclose its patent rights to a standards body called into question whether those patent rights were lawfully acquired. 36 In such circumstances, the court reasoned that “a defendant’s failure to disclose relevant patent rights to a standard-setting body and subsequent assertion of those rights against other members of the body may constitute an antitrust violation under section 2 of the Sherman Act.”37 Antitrust injury issues have arisen in private litigation under Section 2 as well. In ESS Technology, Inc. v. PC-Tel, Inc., the district court dismissed plaintiff’s section 2 claim for failure to allege antitrust injury. 38 PC-Tel, Inc. held patents essential for the ITU V.34 and V.90 modem standards. ESS Technology, Inc. alleged that the defendant held essential patents, that the plaintiff could not compete without licenses to those patents, and that the defendant refused to grant licenses to those patents under reasonable and non-discriminatory terms. Judge Whyte held that these allegations alone were insufficient to plead a violation of Section 2, in that the plaintiff had failed to plead injury to competition in a relevant market.39 The decision, of course, is clearly correct, in that the plaintiff had failed to plead that the alleged misconduct injured competition (as opposed to a single competitor) in a properly defined relevant market. Leave to amend was granted in this opinion. After the claims were amended, the defendant moved to dismiss the antitrust claims on the ground that the allegations that it was not offering fair licenses were not of the type of conduct outlined in Xerox as permitting an antitrust claim. Judge Whyte rejected this claim, finding that 35 121 FTC 616 (FTC 1996). Hyundai Elecs. Indus. Co. v. Rambus, Inc., No. C 00-20905 RMW, at 3-4 (N.D.Cal. Jan. 19, 2001). 37 Id. at 4. 38 No. C 99-20292 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 9, 1999). 39 Id. at 5. 36 37 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization the allegations of the complaint were sufficiently analogous to those in Xerox to permit the claim to go forward.40 In Townshend, discussed supra, the district court dismissed the accused infringer’s counterclaim for attempted monopolization.41 First, the court determined that the accused infringer’s allegations did not support an inference of a specific intent on the part of 3Com to control prices or destroy competition.42 The court reasoned that by stating terms on which they were willing to license and adhering to them, the patentee and its licensee could not be alleged to have formed a specific intent to monopolize a product and technology market related to the standard. The court also found no allegation of overt acts in furtherance of the claim of monopoly, relying primarily on the fact that there was no allegation that the standards body could have adopted technology that avoided the patentee’s patent.43 The court also found that there was an insufficient allegation of dangerous probability of monopoly, despite the fact that the complaint alleged that the patentee defendant held a patent covering the standard and that the licensee commanded 50% of the sales in the product market covered by the standard.44 In the product market, the court found the 50% market share inadequate in the absence of allegations that competitors were unable to expand output. In the technology market, the court reasoned that whatever exclusionary power the patentee held in technology input market for the standard, the market power was the result of the patent and hence was lawful. FTC ACT Under Section 5 of the FTC Act, the FTC has jurisdiction to investigate and prosecute unfair methods of competition in or affecting commerce.45 These methods of unfair competition include conduct that violates the antitrust laws. 40 No. C 99-20292 (N.D. Cal. July 11, 2000). Townshend v. Rockwell Int’l Corp., No. C 99-0400 SBA, 2000 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 5070, at *38 (N.D. Cal. Mar. 28, 2000). 42 Id. at *30-32. 43 Id. at *33. 44 Id. at *36-38. 45 15 U.S.C. § 45 (2000). 41 38 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization In American Society of Sanitary Engineering,46 the FTC accepted a consent decree in which a standard setting agency agreed to abandon a rule by which patented goods could not be considered for a standard. According to the Commission, the automatic exclusion of patented products from consideration for a standard was likely to deter the adoption of innovative technologies to the harm of consumers. Well known, of course, is the consent decree the FTC adopted in Dell Computer Corp.47 For those who have been stranded on a desert island, however, the facts of Dell involved standard on a video bus for a personal computer known as the VL-bus standard. According to the complaint, Dell held a patent on the connector used to connect the VL-bus to the motherboard of the computer. However, during the adoption and voting for the standard, Dell failed to disclose its patent. When voting in favor of the standard, a Dell employee certified that to the best of his knowledge, the proposal did not infringe any Dell patents. After the standard was adopted and successful, Dell wrote letters to computer manufacturers using the VL-bus. In these letters, Dell demanded that companies meet with Dell to determine how the accused infringers were going to respect Dell’s IP rights.48 The Commission’s complaint alleged that Dell’s conduct unreasonably restrained competition by hindering adoption of the standard, raising the costs of adopting the standard, and by exerting a chill on legitimate standards setting activity. 49 Dell agreed to a consent decree under which it agreed not to assert its patent against parties who adopted the VL-bus standard. Dell agreed to certain other relief as well.50 The Dell Computer consent decree catalyzed several distinct groups into action. Standards setting bodies vociferously opposed the use of Section 5 to create new rules regarding patent disclosure beyond the disclosure rules of the bodies themselves. Antitrust scholars questioned the use of Section 5 in a case where the allegations of anticompetitive intent were far from clear.51 At the same time, patent defendants rushed 46 106 FTC 324 (FTC 1985). 121 FTC 616 (FTC 1995). 48 Id. Complaint ¶¶ 7, 8. 49 Id. ¶ 9. 50 Id. Decision and Order ¶¶ II-VII. 51 See especially Commissioner Azcuenga’s Dissenting Statement in Dell Computer. 47 39 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization to assert estoppel and unenforceability defenses against any patent remotely related to the activity of a standards body. The FTC Staff continues to investigate allegations that Section 5 has been violated in connection with conduct by patent holders before standards bodies. Standard setting activities remain one focus of the joint DOJ/FTC hearing on IP and antitrust currently under way. RICO Standard setting participants may face civil liability under RICO. In Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Technologies AG,52 a claim that Rambus violated civil RICO was rejected by a jury. Infineon contended that a patentee’s conduct before a standards body constituted fraud and also constituted a “pattern of racketeering activity” within the meaning of the RICO statute.53 The jury was charged with a bare-bones, pattern RICO jury instruction. As the jury was instructed, Infineon had the burden to establish that Rambus, though its association with JEDEC, engaged in a pattern of racketeering activity by committing multiple acts of mail fraud and/or wire fraud in furtherance of a scheme to defraud JEDEC, causing injury to Infineon’s business or property. The jury found fraud and that verdict survived a post trial JMOL motion.54 However, the jury rejected the allegations under civil RICO. STATE OFFENSIVE CLAIMS While federal antitrust claims seem to be the vehicle of choice to challenge patentees conduct before standards setting bodies, several state law claims should be noted. First of all, in litigation in the federal courts in California, offensive claims routinely include allegations of a violation of Section 17200 of the California Business & Professions Code. In cases alleging the patentee failed to disclose IP to a standards body, it is common to include allegations of common law fraud in the offensive claim. When patentees have undertaken to grant reasonable and nondiscriminatory licenses before a standards body, a slightly different set of 52 164 F. Supp. 2d 743, 747 (E.D. Va. 2001). 18 USC § 1961 et seq. (2000). 54 Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Technologies AG, 164 F.Supp.2d 743 (E.D. Va. 2001). 53 40 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization issues arise. In this circumstance, the key issue often becomes just what constitutes a fair and reasonable royalty rate. In this context it is not uncommon for a defendant facing a claim of patent infringement to assert that the patentee’s promise to grant fair and reasonable licenses constitutes a contract, enforceable by either a direct or third party beneficiary of the promise. STATE UNFAIR COMPETITION LAWS Most states have a body of common law unfair competition law. Some states have codified their unfair competition provisions by statute. Other states have enacted state antitrust statutes and/or “little-FTC Acts” that prohibit unfair competition. The remedies available vary from state to state. All of these diverse state laws provide a potential vehicle for a claim against a patentee relating to conduct before a standards body. A number of cases pending in federal courts in California have asserted claims under Section 17200 of the California Business and Professions Code.55 Section 17200 prohibits certain acts of unfair competition. The statute does not contain a damages provision, but has been interpreted to allow for disgorgement of the defendant’s unjust enrichment and other equitable relief. As with many state laws, the outer limits of Section 17200 are often unclear. However, with respect to claims under § 17200, sounding in competition related claims, the California Supreme Court has held that § 17200 parallels antitrust law. In Cal-Tech Communications v. L.A. Cellular,56 the court held that in cases where the § 17200 claim relates to allegedly “unfair” acts directed at a competitor, that § 17200 mirrors the antitrust law. In such a case, the plaintiff must show that the challenged conduct “threatens an incipient violation of an antitrust law, or violates the policy or spirit of one of those laws because its effects are comparable to or the same as a violation of the law, or otherwise significantly threatens or harms competition.”57 Following the decision in Cell-Tech, motions to dismiss claims under § 17200 directed at conduct by patentees before standards bodies have tended to be resolved in the same way that the federal antitrust claim is resolved. If the federal antitrust claim survives then the § 17200 claim 55 Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 17200. 20 Cal.4th 163, 973 P.3d 527 (1999). 57 20 Cal.4th at 186-87. 56 41 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization survives a motion to dismiss.58 Likewise, if the motion to dismiss the federal claims is granted, dismissal of the § 17200 claim follows.59 FRAUD Common law fraud formed the basis for a jury verdict of Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Technologies, AG.60 The Rambus case involved standards relating to SDRAM and DDR SDRAM. These are memory technologies useful in personal computers and other devices. The standard setting activity was undertaken by a standards body called JEDEC, which has long promulgated standards for memories. Rambus attended JEDEC standards meetings from 1991 through the end of 1995. While a member of JEDEC, Rambus had on file in the PTO a patent application with a 1990 filing date that disclosed a number of fundamental advances in memory technology invented by Rambus. 61 There was evidence, which the jury credited, that while Rambus was at JEDEC it had the intent to secure patents covering the standard, that it worked with patent attorneys to write claims to cover the relevant standard, and that Rambus never disclosed its intent to secure such patents to the PTO. The jury found Rambus guilty of actual and constructive fraud and awarded the plaintiff $1 in actual damages as well as punitive damages. The punitive damages were later limited under Virginia law to $350,000.62 On JMOL, the trial judge reversed the finding of constructive fraud. He also reversed the finding of fraud as it related to the DDR SDRAM standard on the ground that Rambus had departed JEDEC before that standard was adopted and hence had no duty related to that standard. 63 As to the remaining finding of actual fraud as to the SDRAM standard setting, Rambus’s JMOL motion challenged every aspect of the fraud claim, including whether a duty existed to disclose pending patent applications, whether Rambus had any patent claims that were required to 58 E.g., Hyundai Elec. Indus. Co. v. Rambus, Inc., No. C 00-20905 RMW (N.D. Cal. Jan. 19, 2001); SanDisk Corp. v. Lexar Media, Inc., No. C 98-01115 (N.D. Cal. Oct. 17, 2000). 59 E.g., Townshend v. Rockwell Int’l Corp., No. C 99-0400 SBA, 2000 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 5070, at *38 (N.D. Cal. Mar. 28, 2000); ESS Technology, Inc. v. PC-Tel, Inc., No. C-99-20292 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 4, 1999). 60 164 F. Supp. 2d 743 (E.D. Va. 2001). 61 Id. at 747. 62 Id. 63 Id. at 765-67. 42 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization be disclosed and hence whether it breached any duty, whether it had intent to mislead, whether Infineon actually relied on Rambus’s silence, and whether Infineon suffered any compensable harm. In a lengthy opinion, the trial judge rejected all of these contentions.64 The court later entered a broad injunction and Rambus has appealed to the Federal Circuit. In a related case, Micron Technology, Inc. v. Rambus, Inc.,65 Judge McKelvie of the District of Delaware recently ruled that the finding of fraud against Rambus could not be automatically applied under collateral estoppel principles by other companies that adopted the JEDEC standards. The court found that the element of reliance in a fraud claim was personal to the plaintiff, rendering collateral estoppel inapplicable. 66 The court then stayed most of the balance of the case pending the result of the appeal in Rambus v. Infineon. A final case that is of interest on the fraud issue is SanDisk Corp. v. Lexar Media, Inc.67 In this case, SanDisk attended a formal standards setting related to flash memory as well as participated in certain industry initiatives related to standardizing flash memory, all without disclosing that it had a pending application that covered certain aspects of flash memory. When the patent issued and SanDisk sued for infringement, Lexar filed a counterclaim alleging that the failure to disclose the pending application amounted to fraud.68 SanDisk moved for summary judgment, contending that none of the standards bodies it participated in had any rule requiring that patent applications be disclosed and that it never misrepresented its patent position to anyone.69 While agreeing that there were no written regulations creating a duty to disclose patent applications, the court nonetheless denied SanDisk’s motion for summary judgment. The court concluded that Lexar offered sufficient evidence of an oral agreement among members of the standards association to survive summary judgment on the question of a duty. 64 Id. at 751-65. No. 00-792-RRM, 2002 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 3250 (D. Del. Feb. 27, 2002). 66 Id. at *33. 67 No. C 98-01115 (N.D. Cal. Oct. 17, 2000). 68 Id. at 1-3. 69 Id. at 3. 65 43 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization BREACH OF CONTRACT Finally, we turn to an offensive claim of a completely different sort. Here we consider a claim by a party who has adopted the standard in question that it is entitled to enforce the patent holder’s commitment to grant reasonable, non-discriminatory licenses through an action for breach of contract. Most standards bodies extract some sort of licensing commitment out of a patentee as a quid pro quo for having the IP included in the standard. Commonly, the commitment consists of an agreement either to not enforce the patent at all or else to agree to grant licenses on reasonable, non-discriminatory terms. In nearly all cases, the patentee chooses the latter course. With the IP issue “addressed,” the standards body then considers itself free to adopt the IP into the standard. The breach of contract theory being asserted here is that the patentee’s commitment to license on reasonable terms is a promise, made enforceable when the patentee’s technology is adopted into the standard. The defendant claims to be either the intended beneficiary or a third-party beneficiary of the promise. Hence, the defendant asserts that the patentee is bound by contract to grant a reasonable, non-discriminatory licenses (or whatever commitment it is that the patentee agreed to). Two cases are representative and instructive. In Rambus v. Infineon, and other Rambus-related litigation, the SDRAM manufacturing defendants alleged that Rambus incurred a contractual obligation to grant reasonable licenses. As Rambus never made any formal (or even informal) statements regarding its willingness to license, the defendants were apparently forced to argue that the contractual obligation arose simply because of Rambus’s presence at the standards meetings. In the Infineon case, this claim failed to survive a motion for directed verdict. The trial judge, in a common sense ruling, found that in the absence of any promise by Rambus, there could be no contract. On the other hand, in ESS Technology v. PC-Tel,70 a claim for enforcement of a contractual promise as a third party beneficiary was found to state a claim. In this case, the counterclaim alleged that the 70 No. C 99-20292 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 9, 1999). 44 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization licensing commitment was in fact made by the IP holder during the standards setting. One might reasonably ask what benefit accrues to the defendant from asserting this breach of contract claim? While the law is unsettled, it seems intuitively obvious that if the defendant is found to infringe, then the royalty awarded under 35 USC § 285 will be limited to the reasonable, non-discriminatory rate that the patentee promised to grant. What then does the breach of contract claim add to the rights the defendant already has? It has sometimes been suggested that a breach of contract claim would entitle the defendant to the equitable remedy of specific performance, and that the royalty rate would therefore be calculated by the judge, rather than the infringement jury. While this might be an advantage in some cases if true, it is unclear to us whether this outcome is actually possible given the respective roles of judge and jury explained by the Supreme Court in Becon Theaters, Inc. v. Westover.71 71 359 U.S. 500 (1959). 45 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization A YEAR IN THE LIFE OF A HIGH TECH STANDARDS SETTING ORGANIZATION Section of Antitrust Law STRATEGIC CONSIDERATIONS WHEN ASSERTING DEFENSES AGAINST A CLAIM FOR INFRINGEMENT OF A PATENT THAT READS ON AN INDUSTRY STANDARD by Mark A. Flagel and Michael J. Lawrence April 25, 2002 Washington, D.C. 46 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization I. INTRODUCTION Over the past decade, industry-wide standards have played an increasingly important role in the commercialization of new technologies. Courts have tried keep pace with this trend by balancing the principles of antitrust law and intellectual property rights. Today, it is well settled that a patent owner may be found guilty of some form of unfair competition or abuse of patent rights by enforcing its patent against a party practicing an industry standard where the owner, having encouraged the adoption of the standard, failed to notify the standard-setting body that it held a patent covering the standard prior to the standard’s adoption. For the accused infringer who practices the standard, that party can raise a number of affirmative defenses against a claim for patent infringement. Alternatively, the accused infringer may wish to adopt a more aggressive stance and plead counterclaims against the patentee. This article addresses the various legal options available to the accused infringer in the standardsetting context. II. A HYPOTHETICAL SCENARIO To illustrate the application of the legal options available to an accused infringer in the standard-setting context, it is useful to use a hypothetical case. Let’s assume that two of the leading telecommunications companies have independently developed a new generation of chipsets for their wireless telephones that are far more advanced than current technologies, and thus, render existing wireless phones obsolete. These telecommunications companies – Company A and Company B – are fierce competitors. Each company therefore offers its own competing wireless telephone based upon its own version of the new generation of chipsets. Although Company A and Company B use similar technologies in their chipsets, their telephones are unable to communicate with each other. In other words, a telephone from Company A is incompatible with a telephone from Company B. However, this incompatibility problem could be overcome if the companies adopted a uniform set of technical specifications concerning the operation of their chipsets.  The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily represent the views of Latham & Watkins. Mr. Flagel represented Kingston Technology in its successful defense of patent infringement claims brought by Sun Microsystems. 47 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Company A and Company B are both members of a telecommunications industry association. One of the missions of this association is to adopt uniform standards that ensure the interoperability of different telecommunications systems, such as the new chipsets developed by Company A and Company B. The association routinely hosts conferences in which members may offer proposals for the adoption of new standards. If association members reach a consensus about a new standard, the association will adopt and publish that standard. The association follows a voluntary “code of practice” regarding intellectual property rights that are the subject matter of proposed standards. In order to foster access to the standards, the code expressly provides that any member putting forward a proposal should, from the outset, advise all other members to any issued patents or pending patent applications that may conflict with the proposed standard. In addition, the member must announce whether or not it would be willing to negotiate licenses with other members on a non-discriminatory basis on fair and reasonable terms. If a member is unwilling to offer such a license, the code of practice dictates that the association will not adopt a standard that incorporates such proprietary technology. At an annual conference of the association, Company A and Company B each submitted its own competing written proposal for a standard of the new generation of wireless telephones. Both companies also made formal presentations to the members about the merits of their respective proposals, providing technical information and answering members’ questions. Following the presentations, the companies’ representatives privately lobbied individual members to adopt their respective proposals. At the conclusion of the conference, the association voted to adopt Company A’s proposed standard. The “Company A” standard was therefore published as the officially recognized standard of the association. At no time during the conference did any members identify or disclose that they had any patents or pending patent applications which would conflict with the standard. As it turned out, Company A had filed U.S. patent applications regarding the subject matter of Company A’s new generation of chipsets. However, Company A made no disclosures under the code of practice. At the same time, Company B modified all of its chipsets to practice the new standard. Company B sold these chipsets to the public 48 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization in large quantities, and received orders to manufacture and sell additional chipsets. Following the adoption of the standard, the U.S. Patent Office issued several patents to Company A. These patents cover or “read on” the standard. Once these patents issued, the legal department for Company A sent a letter to Company B stating that Company B’s products are infringing Company A’s patents. The letter demanded that Company B take a license on the following terms: it must (i) pay royalties of 5% per unit, and (ii) promise to stop selling any competing products in the separate market for wireless telephone accessories (which are not covered by Company A’s patents). Although Company B acknowledged that its chipsets practice the standard, and thus, infringe on Company A’s patents, it refused to take a license. Company A therefore filed a patent infringement suit against Company B. The suit seeks damages for past infringement and injunctive relief to prevent future infringing sales. Below, we shall discuss the application of these hypothetical facts to the strategic considerations and defenses available to an accused infringer in the standard-setting context. III.STRATEGIC CONSIDERATIONS AND DEFENSES When a patentee files an infringement suit based on a patent that reads on an industry standard, the accused infringer can assert a number of affirmative defenses if the patentee failed to disclose its patent rights to the standard-setting organization prior to the adoption of the standard. Potential defenses include (i) equitable estoppel, (ii) patent misuse, and (iii) implied license. These affirmative defenses are traditional patent lawbased defenses, but their logic applies to misconduct or deceptive practices relating to a standard-setting process, and the extension of patent rights beyond their lawful scope. A. Affirmative Defenses 1. Equitable Estoppel The doctrine of equitable estoppel is an affirmative defense to a claim of patent infringement. This affirmative defense holds that a patentee will be 49 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization estopped from enforcing a patent against an accused infringer where (1) the patentee – through misleading conduct or statements – represents to the accused infringer that no infringement suit will be filed, (2) the accused infringer relies on that representation, and (3) the accused infringer will be materially prejudiced if the patentee is allowed to proceed with its claim.1 This defense turns on whether the patentee makes deceptive statements that cause the accused infringer to reasonably believe that the patentee does not intend to enforce its patents.2 Generally, silence will not result in an estoppel unless there is a clear duty to speak, or the patentee’s continued silence reinforces the accused infringer’s belief that the patentee acquiesces in the accused infringer’s activities. The defense of equitable estoppel has been successfully invoked in a handful of cases where a patentee allegedly made misleading statements to a standard-setting body in connection with the formulation of an industry standard.3 For example, in Wang Laboratories Inc. v. Mitsubishi Electronics America, Inc., the court denied a patentee’s motion for partial summary judgment to dismiss the accused infringer’s defense of equitable estoppel. In that case, Wang sued Mitsubishi for infringement of two patents that covered an industry standard adopted by the Electronic Industries Association’s standardization group known as the Joint Electronic Device Engineering Council (JEDEC). JEDEC is composed of competing semiconductor manufacturers and sellers, including Wang and Mitsubishi. At a series of conferences, participants will vote on whether they should adopt industry standards for electronic components. Beginning in 1983, Wang urged JEDEC participants, including Mitsubishi, to adopt certain Single In-Line Memory Module (SIMM) technology as part of a proposed standard. Unbeknownst to the participants, Wang had two pending patent applications covering the SIMM technology that it was promoting. Under JEDEC’s internal policies, participants must disclose any pending applications to the body. However, Wang failed to do so. By 1 2 3 See, generally, A.C. Aukerman Co. v. R.L. Chaides Constr. Co., 960 F.2d 1020, 1041-44 (Fed. Cir. 1992) (explaining doctrine of equitable estoppel); Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Technologies AG, 155 F. Supp. 2d 668, 679 n.8 (E.D. Va. 2001) (explaining that affirmative defense of equitable estoppel is analogous to an offensive claim for fraud). See Aukerman at 1043. See, e.g., Potter Instrument Co., Inc. v. Storage Tech. Corp., 207 U.S.P.Q.2d 763, aff’d, 641 F.2d 190 (4th Cir. 1981) (affirming on other grounds); Stambler v. Diebold, Inc., 11 U.S.P.Q.2d 1709 (E.D.N.Y. 1998), aff’d, 878 F.2d 1445 (Fed. Cir. 1989); Wang Labs. Inc. v. Mitsubishi Elec. Am., Inc., 30 U.S.P.Q.2d 1241, 1247 (C.D. Cal. 1993), aff’d, 103 F.3d 1571 (Fed Cir. 1997) (affirming on other grounds). 50 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization 1986, JEDEC published a new standard incorporating the SIMM technology promoted by Wang. Thereafter, Wang’s applications were granted, and Wang filed an infringement suit against Mitsubishi. Based on these facts, the district court held that Mitsubishi showed that there were triable issues regarding the affirmative defense of equitable estoppel. The court found, among other things, that there were factual issues as to whether Wang’s failure to disclose the existence of its applications was misleading and deceptive, and whether Mitsubishi representatives in attendance at JEDEC conferences relied on Wang’s alleged misstatements when they approved a standard incorporating Wang’s SIMM technology. The court therefore denied Wang’s motion for partial summary judgment on the equitable estoppel defense. Using the hypothetical above, Company B (the accused infringer) could respond to the infringement suit filed by Company A (the patentee) by asserting a defense of equitable estoppel. Here, Company B could argue that Company A should be estopped from enforcing its patent rights covering the standard because Company A misled the association when it failed to disclose that it owned several patents. In relying on Company A’s deceptive silence, the association adopted a standard that incorporated Company A’s patents. Company B now will be materially prejudiced if Company A were allowed to proceed with its infringement claim. At this stage, Company B has no alternative to practicing the standard, which incorporates Company A’s patent technology. If Company A had complied with the association’s code of practice by disclosing its patents, the association might have implemented a different non-proprietary standard. Under these facts, Company B has a strong affirmative defense for equitable estoppel against Company A. 2. Patent Misuse Patent misuse is another affirmative defense to a claim of patent infringement. The purpose of this defense is to restrain business practices that improperly extend the “patent monopoly” beyond its lawful scope. 4 In 4 See, e.g., Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research, Inc., 395 U.S. 100, 136 (1969) (“there are established limits which the patentee must not exceed in employing the leverage of his patent to control or limit the operations of the licensee.”); B. Braun Med. Inc. v. Abbott Labs., 124 F.3d 1419, 1426 (Fed. Cir. 1997) (explaining that the key inquiry of the patent misuse doctrine is whether the patentee “impermissibly 51 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization other words, a patentee is not entitled to use a patent to obtain economic benefits beyond those which lawfully derive from the patent rights. 5 Patent misuse is an extension of the equitable doctrine of unclean hands, providing that a court of equity should not lend its support to enforcement of a patent that has been used to secure an unfair competitive advantage.6 In cases of patent misuse, the patent is rendered unenforceable and the patentee is not entitled to recover any infringement damages for the period of misuse. That is, courts withhold relief from the patentee until the patentee discontinues the abusive practice.7 Once the patentee purges its misuse, the patentee’s rights will be restored from that point forward. The defensive shield of patent misuse is analogous to the offensive sword of an antitrust claim. The defense seeks to restrain business practices that do not in themselves violate any law, but that draw anticompetitive strength from the patent right, and thus, are deemed to be contrary to public policy.8 In other words, patent misuse is a broader concept than an antitrust violation.9 Examples of patent misuse may include (1) “tying arrangements” or requiring the purchase of unpatented goods in order to obtain a license for patented goods,10 (2) “package licensing” or conditioning the purchase of a license upon acceptance of another license for an unrelated patent,11 (3) charging royalties based upon total sales, rather than the patented goods alone,12 (4) charging royalties after the 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 broadened the physical or temporal scope of the patent grant with anticompetitive effect.”). See Mallinckrodt, Inc. v. Medipart, Inc., 976 F.2d 700, 704 (Fed. Cir. 1992); Windsurfing Int’l, Inc. v. AMF Inc., 782 F.2d 995, 1001 (Fed. Cir. 1986). Carter Wallace, Inc. v. United States, 449 F.2d 1374, 1377 (Ct. Cl. 1971) (“Courts will not aid a patentee in infringement litigation if the patentee, in dealing with the patent by licenses or product sales, engages in conduct violative of the antitrust laws or the principles of equity.”). C.R. Bard, Inc. v. M3 Sys., Inc., 157 F.3d 1340, 1372-73 (Fed. Cir. 1998), reh’g denied & reh’g in banc declined, 161 F.3d 1380 (Fed. Cir. 1998) (“Patent misuse arises in equity, and a holding of misuse renders the patent unenforceable until the misuse is purged; it does not, of itself, invalidate the patent.”). Mallinckrodt, 976 F.2d at 704. Senza-Gel Corp. v. Seiffhart, 803 F.2d 661, 668 (Fed. Cir. 1986). Id. at 669. Western Elec. Co. v. Stewart-Warner Corp., 631 F.2d 333, 338 (4th Cir. 1980); McCullough Tool Co. v. Well Surveys, Inc., 343 F.2d 381, 408 (10th Cir. 1965); Apex Elec. Mfg. Co. v. Altorfer Bros. Co., 238 F.2d 867, 871 (7th Cir. 1956). Engel Indus., Inc. v. Lockformer Co., 96 F.3d 1398, 1408 (Fed. Cir. 1996). 52 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization expiration of a patent,13 (5) refusing to license a patent in circumstances where the patentee has a monopoly in the relevant market,14 (6) fixing the resale price of patented goods,15 and (7) prohibiting the making or selling competing goods as a condition to obtain a license for patented goods.16 Because patent misuse is a broader concept than an antitrust violation, patent misuse does not require proof of the same elements of an antitrust claim. First, patent misuse generally requires no evidence that the patentee wields “market power” in the relevant market.17 It is therefore unnecessary to show that the patentee has the capability to make a profit by either reducing output or charging a price higher than its marginal cost. Second, patent misuse requires no evidence of harm to the accused infringer.18 In other words, no allegation of specific injury is necessary to state this affirmative defense. Despite the lower threshold of proof required for patent misuse, this defense has not been successfully raised in any reported standard-setting case.19 For example, in Townshend, a district court held that a patentee could not be found liable for patent misuse by imposing supposedly unfair or discriminatory licensing terms on a patent which had been incorporated into an industry standard. In that case, an accused infringer alleged that a patentee had lobbied the International Telecommunications Union (ITU) to adopt a standard that embodied the patentee’s technology, but that the 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 Sunrise Med. HHG, Inc. v. AirSep Corp., 95 F. Supp. 2d 348, 414 (W.D. Pa. 2000); A.C. Aukerman Co. v. R.L. Chaides Constr. Co., 29 U.S.P.Q.2d 1054, 1058 (N.D. Cal. 1993). Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Serv., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 455 (1992). Mallinckrodt, 976 F.2d at 704; United States v. Studiengesellschaft Köhle, 670 F.2d 1122, 1131-32 (D.C. Cir. 1981). Keystone Retaining Wall Sys. Inc. v. Westrock Inc., 792 F. Supp. 1552, 1559 (D. Ore. 1991), aff’d, 997 F.2d 1444 (Fed. Cir. 1993); Nat’l Lockwasher Co. v. George K. Garrett Co., 137 F.2d 255, 256 (3d Cir. 1934). There are two exceptions to this basic rule. In cases (i) where a patentee refuses to license or use any rights to the patent or (ii) a patent is used as part of a tying arrangement, it must be shown that the patentee has market power in the relevant market. In 1988, Congress added subsections (d)(4) and (5) to 35 U.S.C. § 271(d) to make clear that these specific acts cannot constitute patent misuse in the absence of market power. See, generally, Virginia Panel Corp. v. MAC Panel Corp., 133 F.3d 860, 869 (Fed. Cir. 1997) (explaining that patent misuse requires proof of market power under section 271(d)). Hence, the 1988 amendment makes patent misuse considerably more difficult defense to prove as to certain types of conduct. Motorola, Inc. v. Kimball Int’l, Inc., 601 F. Supp. 62, 65 (N.D. Ill. 1984); Leesona Corp. v. Varta Batteries, Inc., 522 F. Supp. 1304, 1341 (S.D.N.Y. 1981). See, e.g., In re Indep. Serv. Orgs. Antitrust Litig., 85 F. Supp. 2d 1130 (D. Kan. 2000); Townshend v. Rockwell Int’l Corp., 55 U.S.P.Q.2d 1011 (N.D. Cal. 2000). 53 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization patentee’s proposed licensing terms violated the ITU’s internal policies by “conditioning the availability of the technology on reciprocal dealing, by extracting cross-licenses, at fixed, artificially low rates and by attempting to double-charge [the accused infringer] and its customers by requiring them each to pay a separate license fee for [the patentee’s] patents.” 20 The accused infringer sought relief from the federal courts because the ITU’s policies precluded the ITU itself from getting involved in intra-party disputes. The district court found that the accused infringer’s defense under 35 U.S.C. § 271(d) should fail: “Because a complete refusal to license does not constitute patent misuse . . . A statement of proposed licensing terms, which indicates a willingness to license in accordance with these terms, cannot constitute patent misuse.”21 Accordingly, the court dismissed the patent misuse defense. The Townshend decision has been criticized by leading commentators. The past chairman of the Federal Trade Commission, Robert Pitofsky, identified Townshend as an example of how federal courts have failed to properly balance competing principles of antitrust and intellectual property laws.22 He stated that undue emphasis has been placed on intellectual property rights, thereby allowing patentees to impermissibly extend their market power beyond the scope of their conferred rights.23 According to Pitofsky, this trend of granting broad exceptions to antitrust principles sacrifices more competition than is necessary to provide appropriate incentives to innovate.24 It remains to be seen whether federal courts will heed these comments. Using the hypothetical above, Company B (the accused infringer) could respond to the infringement suit filed by Company A (the patentee) by asserting a defense of patent misuse. Here, Company B could argue that Company A is not entitled to obtain economic benefits beyond those which lawfully derive from the patent rights: Company A seeks to leverage its patent rights under the standard by imposing licensing terms on Company B that impair competition. In order to obtain a license, Company B must promise to stop competing with Company A in the separate market for wireless telephone accessories. Hence, Company A seeks to coerce 20 21 22 23 24 Id. at 1017. Id. at 1024. See generally, R. Pitofsky, Antitrust and Intellectual Property: Unresolved Issues at the Heart of the New Economy, 16 Berkeley Tech. L.J. 535, 545-46 (2001). Id. at 546. Id. 54 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Company B to cease sales of products which are unrelated to Company A’s patents. Under these facts, Company B has a strong affirmative defense of patent misuse. 3. Implied License The doctrine of implied license is another affirmative defense to a claim of patent infringement. This defense is based upon a patentee’s waiver of its statutory right to exclude others from practicing the patented invention.25 Unlike an express license that arises by a written agreement between parties, an implied license arises by operation of law. In other words, an implied license may be inferred where the patentee’s words or conduct reasonably suggest an affirmative grant of consent or permission to its patent rights.26 For example, a patentee’s unrestricted sale of a device may indicate the grant of a license because the absence of any conditions connotes a license for all purposes.27 In the standard-setting context, the case of Wang Laboratories is instructive.28 In that case, the Federal Circuit held that a patentee gave an implied license by, among other things, failing to disclose to a standardsetting body that it held patents rights covering the standard.29 The Federal Circuit also observed that the patentee encouraged other manufacturers to produce such patented products so that it could buy their products, rather than making them for itself at a lower volume and higher cost.30 According to the court, the patentee therefore received exactly what it desired – a “design [that] is the industry standard, and the benefits of a large market and lower prices.”31 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 Spindelfabrik Suessen-Schurr Stahlecker & Grill GmbH v. Schubert & Salzer Maschinenfabrik Aktiengesellschaft, 829 F.2d 1075, 1081 (Fed. Cir. 1987). Wang Labs., 103 F.3d at 1581. Met-Coil Sys. Corp. v. Korners Unlimited, Inc., 803 F.2d 684, 687 (Fed. Cir. 1986). Wang Labs., 103 F.3d 1571. Id. at 1582. Id. at 1580. Id. at 1582. Cf. Winbond Elec. Corp. v. Int’l Trade Comm’n, 262 F.3d 1363 (Fed. Cir. 2001) (holding that patentee did not grant an implied license when it offered to make its patent available on a royalty-free basis if its patent was adopted into an industry standard because standard-setting body did not adopt patentee’s technology; patentee’s licensing condition was never satisfied, and thus, no license was intended). 55 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Using the hypothetical above, Company B (the accused infringer) could respond to the infringement suit filed by Company A (the patentee) by asserting a defense of implied license. Here, Company B could argue that an implied license should be inferred by Company A’s failure to disclose the existence of its pending patent applications under the code of practice. Given this code of practice, Company A’s silence led Company B to believe that Company A had nothing to disclose, and thus, it had no intention of demanding any royalties. The association, including Company B, chose a particular technology, which it believed, would be available to all without cost. Accordingly, Company A’s conduct arguably suggests an affirmative grant of permission to its patent rights. 4. Variations in the Hypothetical All of these defenses could be significantly affected depending upon the underlying facts. For example, if the code of practice of a standard-setting organization requires disclosure of issued patents, but does not expressly require disclosure of pending patent applications, these defenses can become more difficult.32 In addition, a party must determine whether the code of practice explicitly requires disclosure of all patents and patent applications of a company, or just those known by the company representatives to implicate the proposed standard.33 If there is a requirement to disclose all patents and applications, there will be a more difficult remedy issue: where a specific patent or application was not disclosed, but the nondisclosure was plainly unintentional, should the remedy be equitable estoppel, an implied license on a royalty-free basis, or a license on “fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory terms”? And, assuming the remedy should be a license on fair, reasonable and non32 33 Rambus Inc. v. Infineon Techs. AG, 164 F. Supp. 2d 743, 751-52 (E.D. Va. 2001) (upholding jury verdict that patentee breached duty to disclose pending patent applications to standard-setting organization even though organization’s rules made no explicit reference to pending patents). There has been extensive debate on this issue. See generally, In re Dell Computer Corp., 121 F.T.C. 616, 625-26 (1996) (there is no “general duty to search” for relevant patents, but codes of practice imposing an affirmative disclosure requirement would create an expectation that members “will act in good faith to identify and disclose conflicting intellectual property rights”). In reality, many companies have a portfolio of thousands of patents as well as pending patent applications, and the company representatives may have limited knowledge about those patents and applications that implicate a proposed standard. The question therefore may arise as to whether a code of practice of a standard-setting organization can ever require automatic licensing where company representatives innocently did not identify or disclose a patent. 56 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization discriminatory terms, who gets to decide whether the proposed terms meet this definition? All of these answers will depend upon the particular disclosure rules of the standard-setting organization.34 An issue also may exist concerning the applicability of a patent to a standard. For example, if the code of practice requires the disclosure only of those patents that are “required” to practice the standard, a dispute can arise as to whether a particular patent is absolutely necessary, or merely one of several different ways to practice the standard.35 In short, the specific disclosure rules of the standard-setting organization will have to be carefully reviewed to determine the best defenses available to an accused infringer.36 B. Other Considerations and Counterclaims In addition to asserting affirmative defenses, the accused infringer can seize the offensive and plead counterclaims against the patentee in an infringement suit. Potential counterclaims may be based upon (i) a violation of antitrust laws, (ii) a violation of state unfair competition statutes, (iii) fraud on the standard-setting body, or (iv) breach of contract based upon the patentee’s failed promise to disclose the existence of patent rights. Furthermore, the accused infringer can refer alleged patent abuses to government agencies that are responsible for enforcing unfair competition laws. 34 35 36 For example, some codes require that all patents applicable to a standard be licensed on fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory terms. However, an accused infringer could still argue for equitable estoppel on the theory that, had the patent been disclosed during the standard-setting process, the standard would not have been adopted, or it would have deliberately excluded the patent at issue. See generally, Intel Corp. v. VIA Techs., Inc., 174 F. Supp. 2d 1038 (N.D. Cal. 2001) (interpreting the scope of a license granted by the patentee under an industry standard after the patentee sued a licensee for practicing a separate patent that was allegedly not “required” to be practiced under the standard). See generally, R.S. Taffet, Patented Technology and Standard Setting: A Standards Development Organization View (forthcoming 2002) (discussing how standard-setting organizations approach the use of proprietary technologies). 57 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization 1. Antitrust One offensive claim is an antitrust counterclaim based upon the patentee’s misconduct in the standard-setting process. The patentee who participates in standardization but fails to disclose that it owns any patent rights that cover the standard may become a bottleneck in the market. For example, once a standard has been adopted, the patentee might refuse to license its technology to others, and thus, can exert monopolistic control over supply and prices. In this regard, the patentee’s refusal to deal could result in an antitrust violation. Ordinarily, a refusal to license a patent does not constitute an antitrust violation since mere ownership of a patent does not normally confer market power on the patentee.37 However, this general rule applies where the patented technology is merely one of a number of substitutable technologies that are available in the market.38 With the adoption of a standard, there are few, if any choices, to the patented technology – i.e., the patented technology becomes an essential facility to entering the market. Indeed, a standard is usually intended to preclude other competing technologies from being commercialized.39 As a consequence, 37 38 39 Continental Paper Bag Co. v. Eastern Paper Bag Co., 210 U.S. 405, 429 (1908); Intergraph Corp. v. Intel Corp., 195 F.3d 1346, 1362 (Fed. Cir. 1999); Genentech, Inc. v. Eli Lilly & Co., 998 F.2d 931, 949 (Fed. Cir. 1993); Genentech Labs. v. Brennan, 952 F.2d 1346, 1354-55 (Fed. Cir. 1991). See also 1995 Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Antitrust Guidelines For the Licensing of Intellectual Property, § 2.2, reprinted in ABA Section of Antitrust Law, Antitrust Law Developments (4th ed. 1997) at 1486 (“Although the intellectual property right confers the power to exclude with respect to the specific product, process, or work in question, there will often be sufficient actual or potential close substitutes for such product, process, or work to prevent the exercise of market power.”). See Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2, 16 (1984) (explaining that “it is fair to presume that the inability to buy the product elsewhere gives the seller market power” where the seller has a patent or similar “monopoly over a product”). See, e.g., In re Pabst Licensing, GmbH Patent Litig., 2000 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 12076 *21 (E.D. La. Aug. 11, 2000) (denying motion to dismiss antitrust claim even though there is no presumption that patent ownership creates market power since lack of presumption “does not exclude the possibility that a patent owner does have market power”); Dell, 121 F.T.C. at 624 n.2 (explaining that wide acceptance of an industry standard “effectively confer[s] market power upon [the patentee]” where the standardsetting body could have adopted an alternate standard based upon equally effective, non-proprietary technologies). But see Townshend, 55 U.S.P.Q.2d at 1021] (holding that the accused infringer “has not alleged facts to show that competitors are unable 58 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization the patentee obtains the power to control prices or restrict competition because there are no substitutes for the patented technology. Using the hypothetical above, Company B (the accused infringer) could respond to the infringement suit filed by Company A (the patentee) by asserting a counterclaim for an antitrust violation under Section 2 of the Sherman Act.40 Here, Company B could argue that Company A possesses monopoly power in the market for the new generation of wireless telephones by virtue of the fact that the standard incorporates Company A’s patents (and thus, the patented technology is an essential facility), and that it willfully acquired that power through its deception of the standard-setting body by failing to disclose its patent rights. In addition, Company A also sought to willfully acquire monopoly power in another market – the telephone accessories market – when it imposed licensing terms that require licensees to stop selling competing telephone accessories. However, Company A could respond to these accusations by pointing out that Company B has merely assumed the existence of monopoly power, and that there is no evidence that Company A actually obtained such power as a result of the adoption of the standard. These facts present a complex case in which the outcome is uncertain. 2. Unfair Competition Another offensive claim is a counterclaim for unfair competition under a state statute. It is difficult to generalize about the nature of such a claim because unfair competition statutes vary from state to state. Generally, however, the scope of state unfair competition laws are broader than federal antitrust laws.41 In this regard, unfair competition laws may enable an accused infringer to plead an offensive claim that falls short of constituting an antitrust violation. 40 41 to expand output, and as such, has not alleged that [the accused monopolist] has a dangerous probability of monopolization of the product market.”). See 15 U.S.C. § 2. This section prohibits a party that possesses “monopoly power” in a relevant market from willfully acquiring or maintaining that power through restrictive or exclusionary conduct. Monopoly power, also referred to as “market power,” is “the power to control prices or exclude competition.” United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 391 (1956). See, e.g., Cel-Tech Communications, Inc. v. L.A. Cellular Tel. Co., 20 Cal. 4th 163, 187 (1999) (explaining that California’s unfair competition statute (Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 17200) requires “conduct that threatens an incipient violation of an antitrust law, or violates the policy or spirit of one of those laws . . . ”) (emphasis added). 59 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization 3. Fraud Another offensive claim is a counterclaim for fraud based upon the patentee’s misconduct in the standard-setting process. The case of Rambus42 is instructive. In Rambus, the court upheld a jury verdict that a patentee deceived a standard-setting body by failing to disclose to the body that it had pending patent applications regarding the subject matter of the standard. In that case, the accused infringer asserted a fraud counterclaim in response to the patentee’s infringement suit. The Rambus court held that there was sufficient evidence to support the jury’s finding that the accused infringer, which was a member of the standard-setting body, reasonably relied upon the patentee’s non-disclosures, and that it was later harmed when it incurred attorneys’ fees in defending itself against the patentee’s suit. Using the hypothetical above, Company B (the accused infringer) could respond to the infringement suit filed by Company A (the patentee) by asserting a counterclaim for fraud on the standard-setting body. Here, Company B could argue that Company A’s failure to disclose the existence of its pending patent applications constituted misleading and deceptive conduct. Under the code of practice, Company A had an affirmative duty to disclose to the association whether it had any patent rights regarding the subject matter of the standard. Given this code of practice, Company B should have identified its pending patent applications. Under the circumstances, Company B reasonably relied upon Company A’s non-disclosures, and inferred that Company A had no such patent rights. Accordingly, Company A’s subsequent efforts to enforce its patent rights arguably constituted a fraud. 42 164 F. Supp. 2d 743. See also, V. Smith Lewis, Rambus v. Infineon – The Latest Standard Setting Patent Disclosure Guidance, <http://www.abanet.org/antitrust/committees/intell_property/sep24report.html> (analyzing Rambus decision). 60 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization 4. Breach of Contract Another offensive claim is a counterclaim for breach of contract based upon the patentee’s misconduct in the standard-setting process. This cause of action is somewhat novel and relatively untested.43 The grounds for this claim is that the accused infringer is a beneficiary of the patentee’s legal promise to the standard-setting body that the patentee will disclose the existence of any patent rights under the body’s code of practice. Hence, the patentee’s failure to abide by its promise gives rises to a claim for breach of contract by the accused infringer. The accused infringer arguably suffers damages when it is required to defend itself in a patent infringement suit filed by the patentee. Using the hypothetical above, Company B (the accused infringer) could respond to the infringement suit filed by Company A (the patentee) by asserting a counterclaim for breach of contract. Here, Company B – as a member of the association – could argue that it is a third-party beneficiary to Company A’s contractual duty under the code of practice. The purpose of this code is to foster access to standards by requiring members to disclose any patent rights and to license those patent rights on fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory terms. By failing to disclose its patent rights to the association and by failing to offer a license on reasonable terms, Company A breached its contract with the association. In its capacity as a third-party beneficiary, Company B may therefore seek to recover damages for this breach. 5. Referring the Case to Law Enforcement Agencies In addition to affirmative defenses or counterclaims where the accused infringer turns to the judicial system for relief, an entirely different option is to report any suspected patent abuses to federal or state agencies that are responsible for enforcing unfair competition statutes. In recent years, for example, the FTC has taken an interest in enforcing unfair competition laws against patentees who allegedly deceived standard-setting organizations. In the matter of Dell,44 the FTC investigated a personal computer manufacturer for alleged manipulation of a standard adopted by the Video 43 44 See EES Tech., Inc. v. PC-Tel, Inc., No. C 99-20292 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 2, 1999) (order denying defendant’s motion to dismiss claim for specific performance where plaintiff alleged that it was third-party beneficiary to defendant’s agreement with standard-setting body and where defendant agreed to license its patent to all on fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory terms). 121 F.T.C. 616. 61 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Electronics Standards Association (VESA). In 1992, VESA launched a series of meetings to evaluate a proposed standard for a “VL-bus” – the mechanism that transfers electronic information between a computer’s central processing unit and peripherals. During these meetings, Dell actively lobbied other VESA members to approve the proposed standard. At the same time, VESA members were asked to certify whether they owned any patents that conflicted with the proposed standard. Although Dell had been granted a patent that covered elements of the proposed standard, it certified that it had no such patents. Thereafter, VESA adopted the proposed VL-bus standard, which became a commercial success. Only then did Dell break its silence about its patent. Dell notified various companies that were practicing the VL-bus standard that it was entitled to receive royalties for patent infringement. The FTC conducted an investigation of Dell’s activities, concluding that Dell engaged in anticompetitive business practices. According to the FTC, Dell sought to capitalize on the VL-bus standard when, if Dell had disclosed the existence of its patent, VESA could have adopted a different standard that did not “read” on Dell’s patent: “In this case – where there is evidence that the association would have implemented a different nonproprietary design had it been informed of the patent conflict during the certification process, and where Dell failed to act in good faith to identify and disclose patent conflicts – enforcement action is appropriate to prevent harm to competition and consumers.” As a remedy, the FTC ordered Dell not to enforce its patent rights against any party that practices the VESA standard. Of course, there can be no guarantee that a government agency will conduct an investigation just because it receives a referral from an aggrieved party. Moreover, there can be no guarantee that any investigation will lead to a favorable result. This option therefore should not be chosen as an alternative to asserting an affirmative defense or pleading a counterclaim, but as an additional means to obtain full relief for the aggrieved party. Furthermore, counsel should be careful not to threaten criminal charges to obtain an advantage in civil litigation. 45 45 In a number of states, it is unethical for an attorney to threaten criminal prosecution in the context of a civil case. See, e.g., Cal. Rule of Prof. Conduct 7-104 (“A member of the State Bar shall not threaten to present criminal, administrative or disciplinary charges to obtain an advantage in a civil action . . . ”). Cf. ABA Formal Ethics Op. 92-363 (July 6, 1992) (stating that, under certain circumstances, it is ethical for an attorney to threaten criminal prosecution to obtain an advantage in the context of a civil case – namely, where the criminal matter is related to the client’s civil claim, the attorney has a well-founded belief that both the civil claim 62 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Instead, the aggrieved party should understand that this option merely seeks to improve the prospects that applicable laws will be enforced. III.CONCLUSION Where a patentee files an infringement suit based on a patent that reads on an industry standard and where the patentee failed to disclose its rights to the standard-setting organization, the accused infringer has a number of options about how to respond to the infringement claim. The accused infringer can assert affirmative defenses, including (i) equitable estoppel, (ii) patent misuse, and (iii) implied license. Or, if the accused infringer wishes to seize the offensive, it can plead counterclaims based upon (i) a violation of antitrust laws, (ii) a violation of state unfair competition statutes, (iii) fraud on the standard-setting body, or (iv) breach of contract based upon the patentee’s failed promise to disclose the existence of patent rights. The accused infringer can even refer alleged patent abuses to government agencies that are responsible for enforcing unfair competition laws. The specific course of action will vary depending upon the facts of the particular case. and the criminal charges are warranted by the law and the facts, and the attorney does not attempt to exert or suggest improper influence over the criminal process). 63 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization A YEAR IN THE LIFE OF A HIGH TECH STANDARDS SETTING ORGANIZATION Section of Antitrust Law BENEFITS AND RISKS OF PATENT POOLING FOR STANDARDS SETTING ORGANIZATIONS by Dorothy Gill Raymond Senior Vice President and General Counsel Cable Television Laboratories, Inc. April 25, 2002 Washington, D.C. © 2002 Cable Television Laboratories, Inc. 64 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization BENEFITS AND RISKS ORGANIZATIONS OF PATENT POOLING FOR STANDARDS SETTING TABLE OF CONTENTS I. Introduction II. Historical View III. Current View A. Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property IV. B. MPEG-LA business review letter C. The DVD letters A Framework for Analysis A. How are essential patents defined and determined? B. Who can join the pool? C. Does the pool promote innovation? D. Does the pool allow members access to information they would not have outside the pool? V. VI. Other Considerations For a Standards Body A. Should access to IPR in the pool be free? B. How is the royalty fee set? C. How important is compliance to the standard? Conclusion 65 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization BENEFITS AND RISKS OF PATENT POOLING FOR STANDARDS SETTING ORGANIZATIONS I. INTRODUCTION A patent pool can be a way for a standards body to effectuate its policy of requiring contributors to make essential intellectual property rights (IPR) within a standard available on fair, reasonable and nondiscriminatory terms. This paper explores the historical and current views of patent pools, proposes a framework for analysis to be used by a standards body in determining whether to proceed with a patent pooling arrangement, and concludes with some practical considerations.1 A patent pool is an agreement by multiple owners of IPR (which can include copyrights as well as patents) to interchange licenses or to grant licenses to third parties.2 Patent pools can enable the spread of technology, lower consumer prices, and foster competition but they can also limit innovation, restrict output and raise prices. II. HISTORICAL VIEW The original judicial view of patent pools was consistent with the view that a patent grants a legal monopoly, thus courts gave “broad deference to the licensing practices of patentees.”3 Patentees pooled patents and attached conditions to the licenses that effectively restrained 1 The author is General Counsel for Cable Television Laboratories, Inc. CableLabs is a private industry consortium that helps the cable television industry implement new technologies, such as digital television and high speed cable modems. CableLabs’ efforts include developing voluntary open interface specifications which are available for any interested manufacturer and which allow compliant equipment manufactured by any vendor to interoperate on cable television systems. CableLabs participated in the development of the MPEG standard and was instrumental in forming the IPR Working Group. Since the formation of the MPEG licensing pool, CableLabs has created royalty-free pools for three of its voluntary industry interface standards, including the highlysuccessful interface standard for high-speed cable modems. 2 See U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission, Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property, (1995) (the “Licensing Guidelines”). Although patent pools and cross-license arrangements are similar, the principal distinction between a cross-license and a patent pool is that licenses from a patent pool are usually made available even to companies that lack any IPR to contribute to the pool. 3 See Steven C. Carlson, Note, Patent Pools and the Antitrust Dilemma, 16 YALE J. ON REG. 359, 373 (1999). 66 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization trade. In E. Bement & Sons v. National Harrow Co.,4 the Supreme Court found nothing wrong with a patent pool that fixed prices: “The fact that the conditions in the contracts keep up the monopoly or fix prices does not render them illegal…[the Sherman Act] clearly does not refer to that kind of a restraint of interstate commerce which may arise from reasonable and legal conditions imposed upon the assignee or licensee of a patent by the owner thereof, restricting the terms upon which the article may be used and the price to be demanded therefor.”5 But, as happens many times in other areas of antitrust law, the pendulum swung in the other direction and the view of what is acceptable changed, perhaps as a result of the excesses catalogued in Bement. Courts began viewing patent pools as a mechanism for cartels to engage in collective price setting or output restrictions. “Rights conferred by patents are indeed very definite and extensive, but they do not give any more than other rights a universal license against positive prohibitions. The Sherman law is a limitation of rights, -rights which may be pushed to evil consequences, and therefore restrained.”6 The pooling of blocking airplane patents during World War I was done at the behest of the government7 and appears to be not so much anomalous as indicative of the heavy burden necessary to show when patent pooling could be permissible. The government needed more airplanes, but the two rival manufacturers with blocking patents were demanding large royalties. Faced with high costs that also resulted in limited production, the government decided the solution was a patent pool of all US-issued airplane patents with licenses being made available to all aircraft manufacturers. In the early seventies, the view that a patent conferred monopoly power that could be used to harm competition culminated in the Department of Justice identifying suspect practices that came to be called 4 E. Bement & Sons v. National Harrow Co., 186 U.S. 70 (1902). Id. at 91-92. 6 Standard Sanitary Manufacturing Co. v. United States 226 U.S. 20, 49 (1912). See also HartfordEmpire Co. v. United States, 323 U.S. 386 (1945); Carlson, supra note 2, at 373-374, and Robert P. Merges, Institutions For Intellectual Property Transactions: The Case for Patent Pools (August 1999) at www.law.berkeley.edu/institutes/bclt/pubs/merges. 7 See “Cross Licensing and Antitrust Law”, address by Joel I. Klein, Acting Assistant Attorney General, Antitrust Division, U.S. Department of Justice (May 2, 1997), reprinted at www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches. 5 67 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization the “Nine No-No's.”8 The suspect practices included grantbacks of improvements and royalties unrelated to sales volume,9 and did not require any inquiry into whether there were substitutes for the licensed patent. While patent pooling was not one of the Nine No-No’s, the Nine No-No’s did not create an atmosphere that was conducive to pooling of patents, even though there might have been good reason to do so. III. CURRENT VIEW A. Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual 10 Property. The Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission issued the Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property (the “Licensing Guidelines”) in 1995, firmly swinging the pendulum back in contrast to the Nine No-No’s. The Licensing Guidelines explicitly recognize that patent pooling is generally procompetitive and should be analyzed using the rule of reason. The Licensing Guidelines contain considerations for analyzing patent pooling. One must consider whether the pool creates efficiencies that are more significant than the harm to non-participants in the pool. The Licensing Guidelines make it clear that a pooling arrangement does not need to be open to any interested party unless participation is necessary in order to compete in the relevant market or if the participants have market power. One must also consider whether the pool reduces incentives to innovate. Requiring grantbacks or licensing of IPR at very low rates may stifle innovation. Conversely, the pool may make a new technology more widely available or clear blocking patents, so that innovation can take place at a different, more efficient level, such as what happens when underlying technology is standardized. 8 See Sheila F. Anthony, Antitrust and Intellectual Property Law: From Adversaries to Partners, 28 AIPA Q.J. 1, 3 (2000) reprinted at www.ftc.gov/ftc/news.htm. 9 See Willard K. Tom and Joshua A. Newburg; Antitrust and Intellectual Property: From Separate Spheres to Unified Field, 66 Antitrust L.J. 167, 178-184 (1997) for a thorough discussion of the history and evolution of these practices. The other no-no’s included tying of unpatented products, tie-outs (or restrictions on a licensee’s ability to deal in products or services not within the scope of the patent), restrictions on licensee’s sale of products using the patented process, specifying minimum sales prices for licensed products, granting the licensee veto power over future licenses, and mandatory package licenses. 10 See Licensing Guidelines, supra. 68 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization B. The MPEG Business Review Letter.11 The Department of Justice was given the opportunity to make its position on patent pools more definitive when the participants in the MPEG-2 compressed digital video standard, after forming an IP Working Group, decided to pool essential patents. In the MPEG review letter, the Department of Justice articulated considerations for when pooling patents may be pro-competitive, and applied them to the very specific facts of the MPEG pool. The Department of Justice considered four main factors: (1) the patents licensed by the pool are all essential to comply with the MPEG-2 standard and are thus complementary, not competitive; (2) the license offered by the pool is the same for any and all licensees including “maverick competitors and upstart industries;” (3) the structure of the pool prohibits exchange of competitively sensitive information among participants and (4) the license agreement does not restrain development of rival products or technology. Looking in-depth at each factor gives a clear roadmap of how to make a standards-based pool procompetitive. 1. Only essential patents are licensed. The MPEG standard is extremely complex and, as the work product of many companies sitting in many meetings, contains intellectual property contributed by many different participants. Without the licensing mechanism supplied by the MPEG pool, fewer companies would have implemented the standard, and the products manufactured to the standard would be more expensive. The Department of Justice stated that “a combination of complementary intellectual property rights, especially ones that block the application for which they are jointly licensed, can be an efficient and procompetitive method of disseminating those rights to would-be users.”12 The MPEG IP working group retained an independent expert (at the cost of much time and money) to review all 800 submitted patents to determine which patents were truly essential to implement the MPEG standard.13 Thus, the patents in the MPEG pool are not substitutes for See Letter from Joel I. Klein, Ass’t Attorney General, Department of Justice, Antitrust Division, to Gerrard R. Beeney, Esq. (June 26, 1997) www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/busreview/1170.htm (the “MPEG review letter”). The author was General Counsel for CableLabs at this time. 12 MPEG review letter, supra, page 9. 13 Twenty-seven essential patents had been identified when the business review letter was requested. See MPEG review letter, supra, page 3. 11 69 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization one another (i.e., they are not competitive); rather, they are all required in order to implement MPEG. The pool arrangements provide that the independent expert will continue to review additional patents submitted to it for inclusion into the pool. 2. Non-discriminatory license terms. The MPEG license is a very straightforward technology license. The same terms are available to any one who wants a license, enforced with a most-favored nations clause. And, if a potential licensee does not like the terms of the MPEG license, it is free to make its own individual license arrangements for the MPEG-2 patents, because the license into the pool is non-exclusive. 3. Limited chance for collusion. The MPEG-LA agreements are set up to minimize the possibility of pool members exchanging competitively sensitive information. Information flowing into the pool is accessible only by the MPEG Licensing Authority (MPEG-LA), which is independent from the licensors. And information flowing from MPEG-LA is governed by confidentiality provisions. In addition, the Department of Justice recognized that the royalty rate is so minimal that there is no reduction in downstream price uncertainty. 4. Incentive to innovate. The MPEG license does not discourage innovation. The royalty rate is based on the number of units manufactured, described as “actual use” by the Department of Justice, instead of a flat fee or a fee based on the size of the licensee. Thus, if and when something better comes along, the license agreement does not impose extra or sunk costs for switching to the new technology. Nor does the license prohibit a licensee from manufacturing non-MPEG-2 compliant products. The MPEG license has two provisions that at first blush might seem problematic, but were recognized by the Department of Justice as being pro-competitive. If a licensee has an MPEG-2 essential patent, the licensee must license it to any of the MPEG IPR licensors or licensees on fair and reasonable terms and conditions. The grant-back is limited to essential patents--and since the MPEG-2 standard was completed at the formation of the pool, the Department of Justice correctly judged that there would be little, if any, innovation within the standard itself. The grant-back is also fair. It prevents a licensee with essential IPR from taking advantage of everyone else’s low cost IPR under the MPEG license, while extracting high rates for its own essential IPR. 70 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization The other interesting provision is a partial termination right given to licensors, who may request that MPEG-LA terminate the license of that licensor’s IPR to a particular licensee, if that licensee has sued the licensor for infringement of an MPEG-2 essential or “related” patent, or refused to license a related patent on fair and reasonable terms. The Department of Justice pointed out that the termination of license for that licensor’s essential IPR puts the licensee in the same position it would be in if there were no pool at all--it is free to negotiate directly with the terminating licensor, who remains bound by the MPEG standard setting organization’s requirement for licensing on fair and non-discriminatory terms. C. The DVD letters. After the definitive MPEG review letter, two other pools were formed (both relating to DVD technology) after getting favorable business review letters from the Department of Justice. 1. The letter to Philips, Sony and Pioneer.14 In the second formal review of an IPR pool, the Department of Justice addressed a few different twists from what MPEG LA had proposed. The definition of essential patent was broader -- “necessary (as a practical matter)”, compared to MPEG LA’s more rigorous definition of “technical necessity.” The parties to the letter successfully argued that “necessary as a practical matter” would be interpreted by the expert as “no economically viable substitute,” which would limit the pool to complementary patents, as did “technical necessity.”15 The Department of Justice was also concerned about the true independence of the expert. Unlike MPEG where CableLabs, which was not a licensor, funded the expert, the expert here was funded by the licensors. However, the expert was contractually obligated to act independently and the licensors gave written assurances that the expert’s “compensation and future retention will not be affected by his determinations as to essentiality.” The Department of Justice gave the companies the benefit of the doubt, but indicated that if the pool ended up See Letter from Joel I. Klein, Ass’t Attorney General, Department of Justice, Antitrust Division, to Gerrard R. Beeney, Esq. (December 16, 1998), www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/busreview/2121.htm, (the “first DVD letter”) 15 See id. at 5. 14 71 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization including non-essential patents, its “enforcement intentions” might change. 16 2. The letter to Hitachi, Matsushita, Mitsubishi, Time Warner, Toshiba and JVC.17 The third review of an IPR pool also addressed the definition of “essential” and the independence of the expert. In the third pool, “essential” was defined to include patents for which there is no “realistic” alternative. The parties reassured the Department of Justice that “realistic” meant economically feasible, and the Department was again satisfied that only complementary patents would be included.18 The expert in this pool was also retained by the licensors. Unlike the previous DVD pool, the contractual agreement with the expert contained explicit, objective criteria for the expert to consider in determining whether a patent is essential, the expert could not be dismissed by the licensors except for malfeasance or nonfeasance, the expert was paid by time and not by number of essential patents determined, and, finally, the formula for dividing royalties was based in part on patent count, which gave the licensors an incentive to make sure the expert did not included non-essential patents.19 It is also worth noting in passing that while one of the licensors would be managing the pool (in contrast to the independent management of MPEG LA), that licensor agreed to internal firewall provisions to protect competitively sensitive information.20 IV. FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS Patent pools are very popular in the video, communications and data areas, which not coincidentally rely heavily on compatibility standards. Of course, there are other ways of achieving interoperability besides a patent pool. However, if the standard is based on contributions 16 See id. at 6. See Letter from Joel I. Klein, Ass’t Attorney General, Department of Justice, Antitrust Division, to Carey R. Ramos, Esq. (June 10, 1999) www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/busreview/2485.htm, (the “second DVD letter”). 18 See id. at 7. 19 See id. at 9. 20 See id. at 5 and 8. 17 72 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization from many different companies, and it enables a product that is expected to be popular in the market place, a patent pool has become the norm.21 CableLabs’ motive in fostering the MPEG pool was to ensure that companies desiring to build consumer electronics products (particularly cable television set-top boxes) incorporating the standard had access to the IPR necessary to build products to the standard.22 Outside of the standards area, IPR pools are recognized as promoting access to IPR.23 Even if the standards body imposes an explicit obligation on the companies contributing IPR to make that IPR available on fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory terms, a patent pool can be a critical necessity for the successful commercial adoption of the standard. The absence of a patent pool (with a sufficient critical mass of patents) creates an uncertain level of risk and exposure to patent lawsuits, thus manufacturers are reluctant to enter the marketplace. The Licensing Guidelines and the three business review letters leave the state of the law clearly in a rule of reason context. However, it would be a mistake to construe the business review letters as carte blanche for any patent pool. The competitive landscape has to be carefully analyzed, and the effect of each provision in the licensing arrangements and pool creation must be considered.24 The framework proposed here is designed to aid such analysis and consideration. A. How are essential patents defined and determined? The starting point of any analysis of a proposed patent pool is whether the patents being pooled are complementary or competitive,25 and how the determination will be made. From the discussion above, it is evident that while the Department of Justice prefers a strict definition of “essential,” i.e., that it be technically required, a definition of “essential” that includes the concept of “no economically feasible alternative” does not appear to create a significant 21 See Merges, supra at 33. The author was General Counsel of CableLabs during this period. 23 See, for example, Jeanne Clark, Joe Piccolo, Brian Stanton and Karin Tyson, Patent Pools: A Solution to the Problem of Access in Biotechnology Patents, U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (December 5, 2000), at www.uspto.gov/web/offices/pac/dapp/opla/patentpool.pdf. 24 See Carlson, supra, for a discussion of the “enormous” anticompetitive potential of the MPEG LA patent pool, premised mostly on the concern that the patents in the pool may not be truly complementary. 25 See id. at 49 for the suggestion that “open membership” and nonexclusive licensing are more essential for patent pools than is “strict complementarity.” 22 73 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization risk of disapproval. Pools of patents that are merely related or useful to the practice of the specification would likely be problematic. Because by definition these patents are not “essential” they can represent substitutes to each other. If all substitutes are included in the pool, the Department of Justice warns of the risk of price fixing. If only some of the substitute patents are included, the pool could “unreasonably foreclose the competing patents from use by manufacturers.”26 This risk is exemplified by the FTC’s actions in the Summit Technology and VISX matter.27 The FTC forced those two companies to terminate their pooling arrangement of two competitive patents for PRK eye surgery, claiming the requirement for each company to pay $250 into the pool for each use took away any incentives for price competition between the two companies. The pool also required that any license to a third party had to be approved by the other company, which in effect meant no other companies were licensed. The companies’ defense was that the pool eliminated the risk of costly and uncertain patent infringement litigation between the two companies. The FTC was not persuaded. From a standards body viewpoint, narrowly crafting the definition of “essential” patents can make marketing of the patent pool to prospective participants easier as well. Prospective participants are generally reticent to provide a patent license to a potentially large group of licensees (often including competitors of the participant). Making the definition of essential patents very narrow and well defined may persuade prospective participants to joint the patent pool. In addition to the definition of essential patent, the method for determining what is essential is important. Needless to say, interpreting a patent against a written standard for unspecified products requires great expertise, which does not come cheap. The Department of Justice prefers an independent third party to make the determination, as in MPEG. For the two DVD pools, the experts were funded by the licensors establishing the pool. In the first DVD letter, the Department of Justice reluctantly approved a contractual obligation on the part of the expert to be independent, when coupled with letters of assurances from the licensors. 26 See the first DVD letter at 5 and the second DVD letter at 5-6. See the FTC’s analysis of the antitrust issues at www.ftc.gov/os/1998/9808/d09286ana.htm, for the complete docket listing, see www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/d9286.htm. 27 74 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization In the second DVD letter, the licensors added more safeguards for independence, providing for objective criteria to be followed by the expert in making its determination. Why did the licensors in these two pools fund the expert? In MPEG, it was CableLabs that engaged the third party expert, at great expense.28 In the DVD instances, there did not appear to be anyone other than the licensors that was willing to fund the search. Generally, it has been the author’s experience that standards bodies do not have the financial wherewithal to fund such a review. One possibility, adopted by the Digital Video Broadcasting Project,29 is to ask each IPR holder submitting a possible “essential patent” to pay an up-front fee to cover the review. This could either be a barrier to competition, in that a company struggling for funding (or an individual inventor) may not be able to pay the fee, or it could be procompetitive in that only companies who are relatively certain their patent is essential will be willing to pay the fee. At the time of this writing, it is too early to tell what the actual effect will be of this structure on the number of patents that are submitted. B. Who can join the pool? The patent pool in the Summit/VISX patent pool was not created in a standard setting context, but it does illustrate how pooling patents can hurt rivals. Requiring the approval of pool members before another company joins should have a legitimate justification; otherwise it just looks like limiting competition. Looking at the many patent pools for the promotion of new technologies that have been created by groups of companies (usually called “founders” or “promoters”), these pools have avoided antitrust problems by making the license available to any interested party, and by making the royalties, if any, minimal.30 Also, the pro-competitive effects of these pools are obvious and explicit. 28 Legal and expert fees paid by CableLabs exceeded $1,000,000. While most of these fees were ultimately reimbursed by the licensors out of the license fees collected, it took several years for CableLabs to be completely reimbursed. It was, in effect, an interest free loan by CableLabs to the pool. 29 The Digital Video Broadcasting Project (DVB) is an industry-led consortium of over 300 broadcasters, manufacturers, network operators, software developers, regulatory bodies that primarily operates in Europe. The standard in this particular case is the Multimedia Home Platform (MHP) standard for digital receivers. The fee proposed by DVB is $3500 per submission. 30 These pools are most prevalent in the computer industries. For example there are pools for the Universal Serial Bus Interface (see www.usb.org/), the Bluetooth short-range wireless networking “standard” (see www.bluetooth.org/), and the Universal Plug and Play forum (see www.upnp.org/). 75 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Another pro-competitive factor is making the license granted to the pool by the essential IPR holder non-exclusive. This creates an alternative to the pool, which is always good in the eyes of the antitrust regulators. And if the license coming from the pool is attractive, it is an alternative that does no harm to the pool. Similarly, any barriers for a company to obtain a license from the pool will likely create competitive concerns. Rather, the patent pool license should be made available to all comers on a “non-discriminatory” basis. While none of the pooling business review letters addressed the scope or the field of use granted by the license, the Licensing Guidelines indicate that such restrictions may be pro-competitive.31 If the pool grants licenses for essential patents in a standard computer interface that must interoperate with other products also compliant to the same standard, a field of use limitation that restricts the grant of a license to only products which comply with the standard is probably reasonable. Conversely, a restriction that prevents the licensee from making products that comply with rival standards is probably unreasonable. C. Does the pool promote innovation? All three business review letters addressed grant back clauses and concluded that the ones proposed by the three pools were pro-competitive, and did not reduce incentives to innovate. The grant-backs were limited to essential patents, and prevent a licensee from taking “advantage of the benefits of the pool while exploiting its own market power” over other licensees.32 Another interesting area for discussion in setting up a pool is what rights a licensee should have to use the IPR licensed from the pool to make improvements outside of the standard. It is probably reasonable to grant the right to use the essential IPR to make improvements that do not adversely affect the product’s compliance with the standard.33 Most standards bodies have procedures for changing their 31 See Licensing Guidelines, supra at 5. See the first DVD letter, supra at 7. 33 See Multivideo Labs, Inc. v. Intel Corp., 99 Civ. 3908 (DLC), 2000 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 110 (S.D. N.Y. Jan 7, 2000) for a discussion about the importance of compatibility with respect to the USB standard. While not a pooling case, it does provide an excellent discussion on the benefits of a uniform interface standard compared to the benefits of innovation. 32 76 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization standards, or introducing new ones. Creators of a patent pool for a particular standard may want to consider how to explicitly address changes in the standard. If the standard changes, should a company be forced to license its IPR on the same terms (e.g. without the right to renegotiate the licenses arrangements in the pool) if it is also essential to the revised standard? Another potential chill for innovators happens when the royalty fee charged by the pool is a flat fee that is not based on actual usage. In the MPEG review letter, the Department of Justice explicitly contrasted license fees based on actual usage compared to a per-processor fee, for example.34 D. Does the pool allow members access to information they would not have outside the pool? The patent pool should prevent information sharing among competitors. If the licensors to the pool are also licensees from the pool, the administration of the pool should make sure that the reporting of license fees due from each licensee is not shared with the licensors except in an aggregate manner. The MPEG review letter and the second DVD letter both make this clear.35 And, as made clear in the Summit/VISX matter,36 the license fee should not represent a major portion of the cost of the product. As a practical matter, if the license fee from the pool is too high, it will be counter productive for wide acceptance of the standard it is expected to support. 34 See the MPEG review letter, supra at 12. See id. at 11 and the second DVD letter, supra at 8. 36 See supra note 20. 35 77 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization V. OTHER CONSIDERATIONS FOR A STANDARDS BODY In addition to considering how the proposed pool will address the issues highlighted above, a standards body will face other issues with antitrust components as the pool is being established. A. Should access to IPR in the pool be free? Patents in any Internet specification promulgated by the Internet Engineering Task Force must be dedicated to the public. There are other examples of royalty-free pools where the licensors retain ownership of their IPR, but make it available royalty-free for those companies who wish to build products which comply with the standard.37 The author’s experience in setting up the royalty-free pools has been that companies are willing to license their IPR royalty-free only if there is the economic expectation of opening up new markets, and the companies understand that is the intent of the organization from the beginning. If the IPR in the pool is made available on a royalty-free basis (or, equivalently, a mutual covenant not to sue), the need for answering the question of what is essential IPR probably does not need to be answered. Nevertheless, the problem of hold-outs must be still be addressed in a royalty-free pool. The author’s approach to this is a simple one--if a company wants to receive a license from the pool (to implement the standard), that company must also grant a license to the pool. Of course, if the non-participant in the pool does not wish for a license (perhaps because it is not a manufacturer), this approach will not bring them into the pool. However, the author has also observed that in other markets, such as the video markets noted above, royalty-bearing pools appear to be the norm. In addition to a desire to collect royalties, some companies believe the possibility of royalties can be used persuasively to get IPR holders to join the pool. On the other hand, even in the MPEG pool, which is royaltybearing, at least one essential IPR holder chose not to join.38 B. How is the royalty fee set? If a patent pool is being formed, a discussion of the royalty fee is inevitable. If the pool contains 37 For example, while not reported in the antitrust literature, CableLabs has successfully established royalty-free pools for three of its interface specifications. See supra note 1. 38 Lucent Technologies Inc. was one of the parties requesting the MPEG review letter, but did not enter into a licensing arrangement with the pool. 78 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization only complementary, essential IPR, then one can argue that there is no price fixing. This position is tacitly acknowledged by the Department of Justice in the DVD letters.39 On the other hand, some standards organizations are “wary of sanctioning any specific agreement regarding the magnitude of licensing terms for fear of … ‘price fixing.’” 40 In fact, the Soundview litigation included the allegation that the standards body fixed prices as part of setting up the pool.41 A related issue is how the royalties are divided up among the licensors. It can be per-patent, as in the MPEG pool,42 or by formula, as in the second DVD letter.43 One could argue that the fact that all the parties contributing essential IPR to the pool have agreed on a method probably means that it is fair; however, if the division of royalties is on some noneconomic basis so that incentives to innovate would be skewed, problems may arise. C. How important is compliance to the standard? Compliance is another issue that deserves attention. Where the field of use for the license is restricted to products that are compliant with the standard, what is the mechanism for determining compliant products, and who makes the determination? Although it did not arise in the licensing context, the Multivideo Labs case44 illustrates some of the risks present if the determination of compliance is not based on objective criteria, consistently applied. VI. CONCLUSION Patent pools are a way for standards bodies to make essential IPR available to interested parties. If the standard is an enabling one, such as a communications interface, access to the IPR required to implement the standard on fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory terms is crucial for wide adoption of the standard. 39 See DVD-1, supra at 5 and DVD-2, supra at 6. See Carl Shapiro, Navigating the Patent Thicket: Cross Licenses, Patent Pools and StandardSetting (March 2001), page 10, available at www.haas.berkeley.edu/~shapiro/thicket.pdf. 41 See Sony Electronics, Inc. v. Soundview Technologies Inc., 157 F.Supp. 2d 180 (D. Conn. 2001). 42 See MPEG Review Letter at 7. 43 See the second DVD letter at 2. The formula was not disclosed. 44 See Multivideo Labs, supra note 28. 40 79 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Thanks to the efforts of MPEG LA and the companies that requested the DVD letters, more clarity has been offered around establishing patent pools, and thus patent pools are becoming more common. With this in hand a standards body (and the companies participating in it) should not shrink from the complexity of an IPR pool. The familiar consensus process that a standards body follows in creating a standard is similar to the consensus process of negotiating a patent pooling arrangement among many rights holders. As instructed by the Licensing Guidelines, the Department of Justice in the MPEG review letter and the DVD letters applied the rule of reason to analyze the patent pools. This should give standards bodies comfort that if there is a good reason to make the IPR available by way of a patent pool, antitrust law will not be a barrier. If (1) the patent pool is comprised of essential patents only, as determined by an independent expert, (2) access to the license offered by the patent pool is open to any interested party, (3) the patent pool does not facilitate the sharing of competitively sensitive information among competitors, and (4) the patent pool does not contain disincentives for innovation, such an arrangement among companies that are competitors can easily have pro-competitive results. 80 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Rambus v. Infineon—The Latest Standard Setting Patent Disclosure Guidance By Veronica Smith Lewis Vinson & Elkins, l.l.p. Dallas, Texas The recent rulings in Rambus v. Infineon[1] provide the most comprehensive guidance thus far regarding the existence and scope of the patent disclosure obligations that arise as a result of participation in a standard setting body. Rambus sued Infineon in the Eastern District of Virginia for infringement of four (4) patents covering technology related to semiconductory memory devices. Rambus maintained that certain forms of Infineon’s Dynamic Random Access Memory ("DRAM"), including Infineon’s Synchronous Dynamic Random Access Memory ("SDRAM") devices and double data rate ("DDR") SDRAM devices, infringed Rambus patents issued in 1999 and 2000.[2] DRAM chips are the dominant form of memory employed in the semiconductor industry today. Rambus believes its patents cover the technology incorporated in the SDRAM and DDR SDRAM industry standards, and as a result, virtually all manufacturers of such devices are obligated to obtain licenses under its patents. Rambus has thus taken a very aggressive stance on licensing. It has publicly asserted: "[t]hose companies that decide to litigate" rather than voluntarily enter into licensing agreements "will pay higher royalty rates."[3] This is a significant threat given the fact that industry heavyweights such as Samsung, NEC, and Toshiba have apparently entered into Rambus licensing agreements with royalty rates as high as 3.5‑ percent.[4] A company forced to pay an even higher rate would be at a significant competitive disadvantage. Moreover, Rambus has made the stakes even higher by explaining that it "may not license those companies that litigate and lose."[5] Thus, if Rambus is right about the scope of its patents, a company may be foreclosed from production of SDRAM and DDR SDRAM devices altogether if it does not voluntarily enter into a licensing agreement with Rambus. The pressure on Infineon to acquiesce to Rambus’ licensing demands was thus immense. Infineon, nevertheless, chose to counter Rambus’ infringement claims using two, seemingly, inconsistent theories. 81 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Defensively, Infineon maintained that its industry standard SDRAM and DDR SDRAM devices do not infringe Rambus’ patents.[6] Infineon also simultaneously raised offensive counterclaims premised on the notion that Rambus had, while participating in the industry group that established the SDRAM and DDR SDRAM standards, surreptitiously obtained patents that covered products that comply with these standards.[7] Infineon’s offensive claims raised a number of important questions about the patent disclosure obligations that arise when a company participates in a standards setting body. Infineon claimed that Rambus was a long time member of the body that established the SDRAM and DDR SDRAM industry standards, Committee Number 42.3 of the Joint Electronics Devices Engineering Infineon Council ("JEDEC"). Infineon alleged that JEDEC policy requires members of such committees to disclose all known patents and pending patent applications that relate to technology under consideration for adoption as part of an industry standard and to state whether they are willing to license any such patented technology for free or on reasonable, non-discriminatory terms.[8] According to Infineon, this policy serves a number of important purposes: First, it operates to prevent any single company from secretly capturing the industry standard by remaining silent while JEDEC adopts a standard that, unbeknownst to the other JEDEC members, is encompassed by a member’s patent or pending patent application. In other words, the policy operates to provide the industry an opportunity to develop open standards free from potential blocking patents. Second, the policy operates to prevent an unscrupulous member from manipulating the standards setting process to its advantage by filing patent applications on technology learned about through participation in JEDEC. Finally, the policy ensures that licenses to patent rights that are implicated by a JEDEC standard are offered to members of JEDEC for free or for a reasonable and nondiscriminatory royalty. This disclosure obligation also allows JEDEC and its members to design around such potential or actual patent rights if JEDEC members are unable to obtain a license under satisfactory terms.[9] Infineon asserted that Rambus had failed to disclose relevant patent applications it had pending while it was a member of JEDEC Committee 42.3, made disclosures that led other members of that Committee to believe Rambus was in fact properly disclosing all relevant patents and applications, and used information obtained as a result of its participation 82 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization in JEDEC Committee 42.3 to draft patent claims that covered the SDRAM and DDR SDRAM standards. Infineon maintained that Rambus was guilty of monopolization and attempted monopolization under 15 U.S.C. § 2, fraud, breach of contract, and violations of the Racketeer Influenced and Corrupt Organizations Act ("RICO") as a result of this conduct.[10] Infineon has, thus far, been successful on both its defensive and offensive fronts. After both parties concluded presentation of evidence in support of their case, the Court ruled that Infineon’s SDRAM and DDR SDRAM products do not infringe Rambus’ patents as a matter of law.[11] In fact, the Court has now ruled that Rambus’ patent infringement claims were so baseless that Infineon should be awarded $7,123,989.52 in attorneys’ fees and costs.[12] Rambus’ infringement allegations were clearly believed to have no merit whatsoever. The Court explained: the clear and convincing evidence shows that Rambus knew, or should have known, that its patent infringement suit was baseless, unjustified, and frivolous—one in which reasonably ‘intelligent people should have known would have no chance of success’ . . . . Rambus’ construction of the disputed claim terms and its theory of infringement were directly at odds with the intrinsic evidence contained in specifications and prosecution histories of the patents-in-suit . . . . Rambus’ view of the patents was completely untethered to the language of the patent claims or the written description, and in many cases, flatly contradicted the written description.[13] Nevertheless, the Court allowed Infineon’s fraud and RICO theories to go to the jury.[14] The jury concluded that Rambus was liable for actual and constructive fraud as a result of its improper SDRAM and DDR SDRAM related patent disclosure and awarded Infineon $1 in nominal damages and punitive damages of $3.5 million.[15] The Court has now reduced the punitive damages award to $350,000,[16] granted Rambus judgment as a matter of law on the constructive fraud claim,[17] and granted Rambus judgment as a matter of law on the actual fraud claim to the extent that it was based upon failures to disclose to the JEDEC DDR SDRAM standard committee.[18] However, the Court has upheld the actual fraud verdict premised on Rambus’ improper patent disclosure to the JEDEC SDRAM standards committee.[19] Rambus has thus been found to be guilty of fraud for failing to disclose information related to its SDRAM patents to a JEDEC Committee 83 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization notwithstanding the fact that the Court has ruled that Rambus’ SDRAM patents do not cover the JEDEC SDRAM standard as a matter of law. This anomalous result raises a host of questions about the patent disclosure obligations of an industry standard setting participant. The latest answers from Rambus v. Infineon are outlined below. What Needs to Be Disclosed—Issued Patents, Patent Applications, Predecessor Applications? Rambus claimed it could not be found to have failed to comply with JEDEC’s disclosure requirements because: (1) the JEDEC Manual of Organization and Procedure did not explicitly require it to disclose patent applications until it was amended in 1993; (2) it disclosed the only issued patent that it obtained while a member of JEDEC Committee 42.3; and (3) it did not file the applications which resulted in the SDRAM and DDR SDRAM patents it asserted against Infineon until after it had ended its membership in JEDEC Committee 42.3. [20] Rambus asserted it surely was not required to disclose what did not exist while it participated in the standards setting process. Infineon found these arguments "disingenuous"[21], and the Court ultimately agreed. The Court found that although "the JEDEC manual did not explicitly provide, until 1993, that pending patents were to be disclosed, Infineon presented clear and convincing evidence at trial, through JEDEC members and representatives, that, at all times at issue before 1993, the duty to disclose applied to pending applications."[22] Significantly, the Court found that "Infineon demonstrated that Rambus officials themselves understood that it was JEDEC’s practice to require disclosure of pending patent applications."[23] The Court found that Rambus’ disclosure of its single issued ‘703 patent "actually misrepresented the scope of Rambus’ pending patents because the ‘703 patent admittedly did not relate to the SDRAM work" of Committee 42.3.[24] Moreover, the Court rejected Rambus’ contentions regarding the timing of the applications for and issuance of the patents asserted against Infineon noting that "Infineon did not circumscribe its fraud claim only to the four patents-in-suit; instead, it alleged that Rambus committed fraud upon Infineon (as a member of the JEDEC committee), by failing to disclose any pending patents related to the SDRAM work", and "the four patents-in-suit are divisional or continuation applications of other Rambus patents which were pending during the time that Rambus was a member of the JEDEC and at a time when Rambus had a duty to disclose its 84 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization pending patents."[25] Which Patents or Applications Must be Disclosed? Rambus was found to be guilty of fraud because it failed to disclose pending patent applications "relating to JEDEC’s SDRAM work".[26] The JEDEC disclosure standard was quite broad and vague. JEDEC participants were "to inform the meeting of any knowledge they may have of any patents, or pending patents, that might be involved in the work they are undertaking."[27] Infineon presented no expert testimony regarding the scope of the patent applications Rambus was alleged to have improperly failed to disclose or their relationship to the SDRAM standards.[28] Instead, the Court found that evidence which demonstrated that Rambus intentionally set out to draft patent claims that were designed to cover the technology under consideration by JEDEC was sufficient to establish a relationship between the patent applications and the JEDEC standard.[29] How Much Disclosure is Required? Rambus maintained that it met its disclosure obligations because its application for an international patent through the World Intellectual Property Organization ("WIPO") became public information in October 1991. Rambus’ WIPO application had a written description that was identical to the one in all Rambus’ U.S. patents, including the SDRAM and DDR SDRAM patents asserted against Infineon. Rambus’ WIPO application was discussed during JEDEC meetings, and Rambus claimed that, as a result, all its inventions were disclosed, and such disclosure put all relevant observers on notice that it was seeking patent protection in technological areas related to the SDRAM and DDR SDRAM industry standards under consideration.[30] The Court rejected this contention. While the written description in the WIPO patent application was the same as that in the undisclosed SDRAM patents, "Rambus presented no evidence at trial indicating that the description, on its face, relates to SDRAMS."[31] Moreover, the WIPO patent claims, at the relevant time, related only to a predecessor RDRAM technology.[32] 85 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization At What Point in The Standard Setting Process Must Disclosure be Made? The Court’s judgment as a matter of law ruling with respect to the DDR SDRAM actual fraud claim turned on a resolution of this issue. Rambus maintained that it had no duty of disclosure with respect to DDR SDRAM standard setting because it was no longer a member of JEDEC when one of its Committees began to work on that standard.[33] Infineon claimed Rambus did have a DDR SDRAM duty of disclosure because "certain ‘concepts’ which ultimately made their way into the DDR SDRAM standard, were discussed while Rambus was a member of JEDEC."[34] The JEDEC witnesses who testified gave conflicting evidence on this point.[35] The Court concluded that Infineon "failed to prove, by clear and convincing evidence, that, before the DDR SDRAM standard-setting process actually began, Rambus had a duty to disclose."[36] Because there was no clear DDR SDRAM duty to disclose, Rambus’ failure to do so could not be a basis for a fraud finding, and accordingly, the Court granted Rambus judgment as a matter of law on this claim.[37] Can Improper Standard Setting Patent Disclosure be The Basis For an Antitrust Violation? Infineon’s claim that Rambus’ improper disclosures were predatory acts taken as part of a scheme to monopolize the "DRAM technology market"[38] never reached the jury. After the Court ruled that Infineon’s industry standard SDRAM and DDR SDRAM products indeed do not infringe Rambus’ patents, Infineon withdrew its monopolization claims,[39] and the Court granted Rambus’ motion for judgment as a matter of law on Infineon’s attempted monopolization claim, concluding that Infineon had failed to submit evidence establishing the scope of a relevant geographic market.[40] Infineon had pled a relevant United States market and argued that such a geographic market was necessarily "implicit" given that Rambus relied upon United States patents as the basis for its alleged predatory conduct.[41] Infineon maintains that the "U.S. patent laws compel the definition of the relevant geographic market as the United States in a monopolization case based on U.S. patent enforcement"[42] and relies upon a decision from the Northern District of Texas, Buehler A.G. v. Ocrim 86 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization S.p.A., in support of its position. [43] Fourth Circuit precedent consistently requires a party asserting a Section 2 antitrust claim to offer proof of a geographic market.[44] An appeal of the court’s ruling on Infineon’s attempted monopolization claim thus may provide interesting precedent regarding the type of geographic market proof an antitrust plaintiff must submit to establish antitrust claims based on alleged misuse of United States patent rights. Interestingly, it would be the Federal Circuit, which would hear an appeal that would establish this precedent.[45] However, it appears unlikely that any precedent addressing antitrust liability based on alleged improper patent disclosure before a standards setting body is likely to arise from appeal of Rambus v. Infineon. Thus, ultimate resolution of Rambus v. Infineon is not likely to provide guidance to those attempting to assess the antitrust implications of patent disclosure issues arising as a result of participation in an industry standard settings body. The In re Dell Computer Corp. consent decree makes it clear that the Federal Trade Commission ("FTC") believes it is a violation of antitrust law for a company to make the false affirmative certification that it has no relevant issued patents to a standard setting body that requires disclosure of such patents.[46] Notably, the FTC proceeded under Section 5 of the Clayton Act which makes unfair methods of competition and unfair or deceptive acts or practices unlawful. The FTC was not required to and did not allege any relevant geographic or product market. or the existence of market power in any such markets.[47] While the standard setting patent disclosure arena thus remains an antitrust minefield, Rambus v. Infineon makes one thing clear. Limited or improper patent disclosure to a standards setting body can have serious adverse consequences. Endnotes [1] Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Technologies AG, No. Civ. A. 3:00CV524, 2001 WL 913972 (E.D. Va. Aug. 9, 2001). [2] See id. at *1; First Amended Complaint for Patent Infringement, Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Technologies AG, E.D. Va. (No. Civ. A. 3:00CV524). [3] Substituted First Amended Answer and Counterclaims to Rambus’ First Amended Complaint at pp. 35-36, Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Technologies, AG, E.D. Va. (No. Civ. A. 3:00CV524) [hereinafter "Infineon Answer and Counterclaims"]. [4] Tony Smith, Rambus’ "very high" DDR royalty revealed; The Register, May 25, 2001, available at http://www.theregister.co.uk/content/3/18706.html. [5] Infineon Answer and Counterclaims at pp. 35-36. [6] See id. at p. 17. [7] See id. [8] See id at pp. 33-57. [9] See id. at pp. 39-40. 87 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization [10] See id. at pp. 30-77. [11] May 4, 2001 Transcript of Trial Proceedings at p. 28, Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Technologies AG, E.D. Va. (No. Civ. A. 3:00CV524). [12] Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Technologies AG, No. Civ. A. 3:00CV524, 2001 WL 913973 (E.D. Va. Aug. 9, 2001), [13] Id. [14] Infineon withdrew its monopolization claim, and the Court granted Rambus judgment as a matter of law on Infineon’s breach of contract and attempted monopolization claims. Rambus, 2001 WL 913972, at *1. [15] Id. at *2. The jury rejected Infineon’s RICO claim. Id. [16] The Court reduced the punitive damages award in accordance with Va. Code § 8.01-38.1. Id. [17] See id. at *5-*6 ("constructive fraud cannot, as a matter of Virginia law, be premised on an fraudulent omission or concealment of a material fact"). [18] See id. at *18-*20. [19] See id. at *6-*18. [20] See Plaintiff Rambus Inc.’s Brief in Support of its Motion to Dismiss, Motion to Strike and Motion for a More Definite Statement at pp. 2-3, 6-10, Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Technologies AG, E.D. Va. (No. Civ. A. 3:00CV524) (hereinafter "Rambus Motion to Dismiss"). Rambus attended Committee 42.3 meetings from December 1991 until December 1995. It formerly withdrew from the Committee by letter dated June 17, 1996. Rambus disclosed U.S. Patent No. 5,243,703, which issued on September 7, 1993, to the Committee. The applications for the Rambus patents asserted against Infineon were submitted between 1997 and 1999 and issued in 1999 and 2000, long after Rambus left Committee 42.3. See Rambus, 2001 WL 913972, at *4, *18. [21] See Defendants’ Opposition to Rambus’ Motion to Dismiss and Motion to Strike at p. 3, Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Technologies AG, E.D. Va. (No. Civ. A. 3:00CV524). [22] Rambus, 2001 WL 913972, at *3. [23] Id. at *6-*7. [24] Id. at *10. [25] Id. at *4, *9 (emphasis in original). [26] Id. at *7-*8. [27] Id. at *3 (emphasis added). This was the standard set forth in the 1993 amended JEDEC Manual of Organization. The Court accepted Infineon’s witnesses’ testimony that this requirement was practiced prior to 1993. See id. at *8. [28] See id. [29] See id. at *7-*8. [30] See id. at *9; Rambus Motion to Dismiss at pp. 2-3, 7-8, 13-15. [31] Rambus, 2001 WL 913972, at *9. [32] Id. [33] Id. at *18. JEDEC Committee 42.3 did not begin working on the DDR SDRAM standard until December 1996. Rambus attended its last JEDEC meeting in December 1995 and formally withdrew from JEDEC by letter dated June 17, 1996. Id. [34] Id. at *19. [35] The Chairman of Committee 42.3 testified that the duty to disclose was triggered during the balloting of a proposed standard. However, a JEDEC consultant testified that Rambus had a duty to disclose when several presentations related to technology ultimately incorporated in the DDR SDRAM standard were made. See id. at *19-*20. [36] Id. at *20. [37] Id. [38] See Infineon Answer and Counterclaims at pp. 32-33, 70-75. [39] May 4, 2001 Transcript of Trial Proceedings at p. 100, Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Technologies AG, E.D. Va. (No. Civ. A. 3:00CV524). [40] See id. at pp. 158-59. [41] See id. at pp.138-43; Infineon Answer and Counterclaims at p. 32. [42] Infineon’s Motion for Reconsideration of the Court’s May 4, 2000 Ruling Granting Judgment as a Matter of Law on Infineon’s Attempted Monopolization Claim at p. 1, Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon 88 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Technologies A.G., E.D. Va. (No. Civ. A. 3:00CV524). [43] 836 F. Supp. 1305 (N.D. Tex. 1993). There, the court explained: "The geographic market in this patent case is limited to the United States . . . . The limitation reflects the view that the United States is the only geographic market where a U.S. patent can be ‘misused’ in a manner leading to antitrust violations . . . ." Id. at 1325. [44] See, e.g., Consul Limited v. Transco Energy Co., 805 F.2d 490, 493 (4th Cir. 1986), cert. denied, 481 U.S. 1050 (1987); Satellite Television & Associates Res., Inc. v. Continental Cablevision of Va., Inc., 714 F.2d 351, 355 (4th Cir. 1983), cert. denied, 465 U.S. 1027 (1984). [45] The Federal Circuit has exclusive jurisdiction over any appeal from a final decision of a United States District Court when the jurisdiction of the District Court was based, in whole or in part, on the presence of a claim arising under the patent laws. See 28 U.S.C. §§ 1295(a)(1), 1338(a). [46] Consent Decree No. C3658, 121 F.T.C. 616, 1996 WL 350997 (May 20, 1996). [47] See id. ***************************************************************************************************************** *************************************************************************************************** Ms. Veronica Lewis is a partner with Vinson & Elkins and is located at the firm's Dallas office. Ms. Lewis specializes in complex commercial litigation, including intellectual property and antitrust matters. She may be contacted at 214.220.7757, vlewis@velaw.com. ***************************************************************************************************************** ******************************************************************************* 89 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization An Update on the Soundview Litigation By John S. Martin Background. In 1996, Congress mandated that all television sets sold after January 2000 contain "V-Chip" technology that would permit the blocking of violent and pornographic programming. This mandate gave rise to a series of patent and antitrust decisions last summer from the District of Connecticut which may be of interest. Upon passage of the V-Chip mandate, an industry association of television manufacturers -- known as Electronic Industries Alliance or EIA -- began to study patents covering the technology they would have to incorporate. During these meetings, the parties discussed possible terms under which they would license the patents. One of the more important patents belonged to Soundview Technologies, Inc., which was a member of the association but did not overtly participate in the relevant meetings. Soundview subsequently offered patent licenses to EIA and its members. Instead of purchasing the licenses, however, the EIA and its members filed a declaratory judgment action against Soundview, and Soundview counterclaimed for patent infringement and antitrust violations. EIA and the manufacturers moved for summary judgment and to dismiss the counterclaims, and in June and July 2001 the district court denied each of these motions in three separate opinions. The court held that 1) Soundview had sufficiently pleaded a monopsonistic conspiracy to fix licensing fees, 2) the manufacturers did not receive an implied patent license from the government mandate, and 3) Soundview had sufficiently pleaded inducement by EIA. Monopsonistic Conspiracy. After holding that there was no higher pleading standard for antitrust cases, and construing an affidavit from earlier litigation that it held to be part of the pleadings, the Court held that Soundview had alleged a conspiracy by the manufacturers to fix license prices at artificially low levels. Sony Electronics, Inc. v. Soundview Technologies, Inc., 157 F. Supp. 2d 180, 184 and 188 (D. Conn. 2001). The court then discussed the 90 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization economic theory of a monopsonistic conspiracy by purchasers to drive input prices down, noting that, while it could reduce consumer prices, it could nevertheless harm the competitive marketplace by causing suppliers to exit. Id. at 185. The Court recited caselaw holding that "monopsonistic schemes" involving conspiracy between horizontal competitors "may violate the antitrust laws," id. at 187, and held that "a motion to dismiss is not the appropriate procedural vehicle to decide these complex questions," id. at 185. Noerr Pennington The Court also held that dismissal at this stage of the proceedings could not be based on the a Noerr Pennington doctrine, holding that an alleged "conspiracy to pay a maximum price" and "group boycott" went well beyond "mere litigation or joint action to challenge a patent."Id. at 189. Implied License. The government had been granted a non-exclusive, royalty-free license to use the relevant patent "with the power to grant licenses for all governmental purposes." Sony Electronics, Inc. v. Soundview Technologies Inc, 157 F.Supp. 2d 172, 176 (D. Conn. 2001). In their motion to dismiss, the manufacturers argued that the decision to require V-Chips in all television sets was a "governmental purpose" and that passage of the V- Chip mandate conferred upon them an implied license. The court first noted that "’judicially implied licenses are rare,’" id. at 175 (quoting Wang Laboratories, Inc. v. Mitsubishi Electronics America, Inc., 103 F.3d 1571, 1581 (Fed. Cir. 1997). The court then rejected this argument on the ground that the V-chip legislation did not mandate use of the specific patented technology at issue; to the contrary, the standards had been set by the industry itself. Id at 176. The court also rejected the manufacturers’ argument that Soundview’s statements before the FCC indicated it would not enforce its patents and therefore estopped it to enforce them now. The Court found neither sufficiently explicit statements by Soundview nor reliance by the manufacturers. Id. at 178-79. Inducement Soundview also counterclaimed against EIA for inducing its members to 91 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization infringe the patent. The court rejected EIA’s motion to dismiss, applying liberal notice pleading standards and holding that Soundview had alleged "acts of inducement" in EIA’s patent search, patent analysis, proposal for strategies to avoid royalty demands and other conduct, as well as EIA’s knowledge of the patent at the time it took these actions. Sony Electronics, Inc. v. Soundview Technologies Inc, 157 F.Supp. 2d 190, 196 and 197-98 (D. Conn. 2001). ************************************************************************************ ************************************************************************************ *********** Mr. Martin is a partner in the Richmond Virginia Hunton & Williams. He may be reached at (804) 788-8774, jsmartin@hunton.com ************************************************************************************ ************************************************************************************ *********** 92 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Intel Corporation v. VIA Technologies, Inc. 174 F. Supp.2d 1038 (N.D. Cal. 2001) By: Richard S. Taffet and Sophia Fix Introduction On November 20, 2001, the United States District Court for the Northern District of California issued an interlocutory order granting defendant VIA Technologies, Inc.’s ("VIA") motion for summary judgment on Intel’s claims of patent infringement. The Court based its decision on the ground that VIA was licensed to practice certain Intel patents required to implement an industry-wide standard promoting Intel’s "Fast Write" signal protocol.1 The patent at issue was United States Patent No. 6,006,291, entitled "High-Throughput Interface Between A System Memory Controller and a Peripheral Device" (the "‘291 Patent"). VIA conceded that some of its products practiced the "Fast Write" protocol, and thereby were within the limitations of certain claims of the ‘291 Patent. It argued, however, that it did not infringe because it had agreed to Intel’s industry-wide license in connection with the standardization of a specification that included "Fast Write." Intel argued that "Fast Write" was outside the scope of its industrywide license because the license only granted rights to protocols "required" to comply with the standard, and "Fast Write" was an optional protocol. The Court’s holding in favor of VIA resulted solely from its interpretation of Intel’s license agreements under general principles of contract law. It did not, therefore, address the type of issues that have been the subject of recent and significant attention arising in the context of patented technology being used in the development of standards by Standards Development Organizations ("SDOs") and other industry groups. As discussed below, however, the case may still provide some useful insights for participants in SDOs. Background In July 1996 Intel released version 1.0 of its Accelerated Graphics Port ("AGP") Specification. The AGP Specification was developed entirely by Intel as an industry standard, without involvement from any SDO or other industry group. The Specification established a new protocol for data 93 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization transfers between the graphics chip and the chipset included in a computer’s motherboard. AGP was promoted by Intel as an "open specification" and was made available to the industry by a license that could be downloaded from Intel’s web site. VIA signed the AGP 1.0 license agreement in December 1996 and commenced producing chipsets compatible with graphics chips using AGP. Intel proceeded to develop improvements to the 1.0 Specification, including the "Fast Write" protocol." AGP 1.0 allowed graphic chips to initiate data transfers, while "Fast Write" allowed the chipset itself to instigate high-speed data transfers to the graphics chip. In December 1997, Intel filed a patent application for "Fast Write," and in May 1998 it released the AGP 2.0 Specification that disclosed, among other things, "Fast Write." Upon release of the 2.0 Specification, Intel posted an AGP 2.0 form license agreement. VIA entered the AGP 2.0 license on March 8, 2000. In July 2000, Intel asserted claims against VIA under four different patents, including the ‘291 Patent. The issue addressed by the Court on VIA’s motion for summary judgment was whether Intel’s AGP licenses granted VIA the right to practice the "Fast Write" invention. Discussion The License First, the Court discussed the relevant provisions of the Intel license agreements. As noted by the Court, what was licensed by Intel were "Interface Claims," which were defined to be a patent claim that "must be infringed in order to comply with the AGP Interfaces." In turn, "AGP Interfaces" were defined as "the electrical interfaces and bus control protocols disclosed in, and required by the Accelerated Graphics Port Interface Specification." (Emphasis added.) Finally, the "Accelerated Graphics Port Interface Specification" was defined as "the specifications described in the documents entitled Accelerated Graphics Port Interface Specification, Revisions 1.0 and 2.0 published by Intel." According to Intel, the licenses granted only a right to the required "baseline" features of the AGP Specifications. Protocols and electrical 94 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization interfaces not required to perform the baseline functions, including "Fast Write," it argued, were not "required," and were instead "optional," and therefore not licensed. 174 F. Supp.2d at 1048. VIA, needless to say, offered a contrary interpretation. It argued that "all technology necessary for any specification in the AGP 2.0 Specification regardless of whether it is an optional feature (rather than an essential feature)" was licensed. (Emphasis in original.) Thus, since it was necessary to implement "Fast Write" in the exact way specified in the standard, or the chips would not be compatible with the chips of other manufacturers using the standard, it was "required" and a licensed feature. Id. The Court’s Interpretation The first interpretive step taken by the Court was to ascertain the meaning of the term "Accelerated Graphics Port Interface Specifications." This was significant because the license extended to "the electrical interfaces and bus control protocols disclosed in, and required by" the "Accelerated Graphics Port Interface." Intel’s interpretation, that it simply referred to the generic AGP 1.0 and 2.0 Specifications as a whole, but not to any specific contents within the Specifications, was rejected by the Court as unreasonable. Instead, the Court adopted VIA’s position that the term incorporated the detailed directions of how to implement various features, including "Fast Write." Id. at 1048. Next, the Court considered whether "Fast Write" was "required" by the Accelerated Graphics Port Interface Specification, even though it was not part of the baseline Specifications. Here, too, VIA’s interpretation, that all features specified in the Specifications, whether optional or not, were "required," was held reasonable. Specifically, the Court relied upon the fact that the AGP 2.0 Specification "makes clear that even ‘optional’ features, such as Fast Write still have a ‘required’ implementation of exceeding exactitude." Intel witnesses agreed that "optional" features had to be implemented as required by the AGP 2.0 Specification. Id. at 1049. Accordingly, the Court concluded, "Fast Write" and the other "optional" features were included in the license since they "must be implemented in the ‘required’ way or not at all." Id. Intel’s arguments to the contrary were deemed unavailing. For example, the Court rejected Intel’s attempted distinction between 95 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization "optional" and "required" features, noting that "[t]he license does not explicitly exclude ‘optional’ features. It does not even use the words ‘optional’ or ‘baseline’ at all. On the other hand, the license explicitly extends to interfaces ‘required by’ the specifications. Fast Write . . . is a specification." Id. at 1049. The Court also found the interpretation put forth by Intel to be self-contradictory in that numerous features in the Specifications were labeled "optional" while Intel contended they were licensed. Further, under Intel’s interpretation, the Court observed graphics chipmakers would not be afforded any license. Finally, the Court rejected Intel’s argument that its interpretation was consistent with the policies underlying the purpose of the license as reflected by industry practice. While plausible, the Court stated, the argument did not make Intel’s interpretation of the actual words used reasonable. While the foregoing was held by the Court to be dispositive, it stated another independent ground for its decision. Because the license agreements were drafted by Intel, and made available to the industry on a take-it-or-leave-it basis, to the extent any ambiguity existed regarding the meaning of particular words, including "required," applicable law compelled that such ambiguities be resolved against Intel. Id. at 1050. Further, the Court did not find meaningful other models of cross-licensing agreements, or testimony by Intel representatives offering their interpretations of the license terms. Conclusion While this case does not address issues arising in the context of an industry standards body pursuant to a patent policy, the Court’s analysis provides some useful insights regarding licenses that may be made available pursuant to such policies. Specifically, just like Intel’s license, such licenses will likely be interpreted under established principles of contract law, and will bind licensors to the terms set forth, irrespective of an SDOs policy. Accordingly, patent owners granting rights to technology that is included in a standard should take care to make sure the terms of their licenses are sufficiently clear so that only those rights intended to be made available are in fact granted. Conversely, licensees, to reduce the risk of expensive and time-consuming infringement litigation, should make sure the grant of rights to them is as clear as possible. Endnotes 1. The "Fast Write" signal protocol allows communication through chipsets 96 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization embedded in computer motherboards. As explained by the Court: "[T]he components of a computer system include separate chips mounted on a circuit board known as the motherboard. The system memory, microprocessor, chipset, and various input/output devices, such as modems, are all distinct components. In order to communicate with each other, each component chip must send its signals through the chipset, which acts as a translator between components." 174 F. Supp.2d at 1040. ************************************************************************************ ************************************************************************************ ******************************** Mr. Taffet is a partner in the New York office and Ms. Fix an associate in the San Francisco office of Thelen Reid & Priest LLP. Mr. Taffet may be reached at (212) 603-8925, rtaffet@thelenreid.com. Ms. Fix may reached at (415) 369-7616, sfix@thelenreid.com. ************************************************************************************ *************************************************************************** 97 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Resources Relating to Antitrust and Standards Setting In May 2001, in connection with the initial planning for this program, the Intellectual Property Committee started preparing a list of resources relevant to antitrust and standard setting. The effort started when Suzanne T. Michel identified some key articles. Over the past few months, the list expanded with helpful comments from a number of people, including: James Atwood, David A. Balto, Michael Cowie, Brian Grube, Sean P. Gates, Joseph Kattan, Chris Kelly, Joseph P. Lavelle, Mark Lemly, Michael Lindsay, Suzanne T. Michel, Bruce McDonald, Michael McNeely, M. Howard Morse, James Murray, Patrick O'Connor, Daniel Prywes, Bilal Sayyed, David R. Steinman, Carl W. Schwarz, Richard H. Stern, and Lisa Wood. The list was reworked by Michael McNeely and Patrick O'Connor, and then by Bruce McDonald for a September 24, 2001 standards setting program in Houston, Texas. Howard Morse, Chair of the Intellectual Property Committee, supplemented the list of resources for the Section's Fall program. Finally, Ed Biester, John Martin, and Joe Lavelle have provided explanatory notes on a number of the cases. The list, of course, could also include more general boycott cases, certification mark cases and a number of related cases, but we have tried to keep the list fairly narrowly focused on standard setting and IP subject matter. The current version of the list, with links to material available on the internet, is available on the Intellectual Property Committee's webpage under "Hot Topics," http://www.abanet.org/antitrust/committees/intell_property/hottopic.html. Cases Addamax Corp. v. Open Software Foundation, 888 F. Supp. 274 (D. Mass. 1995), later proceeding, 964 F. Supp. 549 (D. Mass. 1997), aff'd, 152 F.3d 48 (1st Cir. 1998) Software company whose bid for technology sales was denied challenged actions of group of computer sellers who set standards for operating system technology. On summary judgment the court (1) found antitrust injury because of the computer sellers’ power in the downstream market for PC’s, and (2) rejected the concept that 98 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization standard setting body as a joint venture acted unilaterally or was insulated from section 1 liability simply because it was a valid joint venture. The court rejected per se treatment, and applied the rule of reason. The court found triable issues as to market power and anticompetitive effect because of the group’s ability to affect industry standards and factual issues with respect to anticompetitive intent based on certain documents. Ultimately, defendants prevailed at trial. Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. Indian Head, Inc., 486 U.S. 492 (1988) Efforts to affect product standard setting process of private association were not protected by Noerr-Pennington even though the code for the design and installation of electrical wiring systems was widely proffered for adoption and adopted into local laws. No damages were imposed for the incorporation of that Code by any government. Where an economically interested party exercises decision-making authority in formulating a product standard for a private association that comprises market participants, that party enjoys no Noerr immunity from any antitrust liability flowing from the effect the standard has of its own force in the marketplace. American Society of Mechanical Engineers, Inc. v. Hydrolevel Corp., 456 U.S. 556 (1982) Standard setting organization responsible for acts of agents acting with apparent authority that violate antitrust law despite substantial agency law defenses which, the court holds, are inconsistent with the policy of vigorous enforcement. Antitrust laws apply to nonprofit professional standard setting organizations. American Society of Sanitary Engineering, 106 F.T.C. 324, 1985 FTC Lexis 20 (1985) (Brought by T.J. Muris as Bureau Director). FTC Complaint alleged that American Society of Sanitary Engineering ("ASSE") violated section 5 of the FTC Act by refusing to consider certification that alternative, patented, toilet tank flush valves which offered improvements to existing devices specified by its standard, were also compliant with ASSE standards, which were adopted into many local codes and compliance with which was alleged to be "essential for manufacturers of plumbing products to do business in many markets." ASSE entered into a consent order prohibiting ASSE from excluding from standards a product which is 99 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization patented or produced only by one manufacturer or a limited number of manufacturers, where ASSE has issued standards for competing products, the applicant has reasonably established that the product adequately meets the implicit or explicit performance goals required by the existing standard covering competing products, and ASSE does not rely upon a justification meeting reasonable standard setting criteria, i.e., "criteria which are consistently applied in the development or modification of a standard and which promote the legitimate self-regulatory goals of ASSE, such as assuring a reasonable and adequate level of safe and effective performance for a product." See discussion in Timothy J. Muris, "Competition and Intellectual Property Policy: The Way Ahead", Prepared Remarks Before Antitrust Section Fall Forum (November 15, 2001) Bond Crown & Cork Co. v. FTC, 176 F.2d 974 (4th Cir. 1949) Brant v. United States Polo Association, 631 F. Supp. 71 (S.D. Fla. 1986) Polo player in the process of starting rival league is suspended from long-standing league for arguing with umpires. Applying NCAA v. Board of Regents of the University of Oklahoma, 468 U.S. 85, 1984, court rejects plaintiff’s per se group boycott analysis. Under rule of reason, court denies preliminary injunction because conduct based suspension is not anticompetitive. Brookins v. International Motor Contest Association, 219 F.3d 849 (2000) Race sanctioning body set standard for transmissions that excluded plaintiff. Summary judgement granted because no market power and no concerted action. Clamp-All Corp. v. Cast Iron Soil Pipe Institute, 851 F.2d 478 (1st Cir. 1988), cert. denied, 488 U.S. 1007 (1989) Consolidated Metal Products, Inc. v. American Petroleum Institute, 846 F.2d 284 (5th Cir. 1988) On summary judgment, court refuses to treat as a per se unlawful group boycott a trade association decision which has no 100 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization compulsory effect on others. Applying rule of reason, court finds no unlawful conduct because evidence shows that decision was a good faith attempt to apply appropriate standards with no anticompetitive intent. Dell Computer Corp., 121 F.T.C. 616, 1996 FTC Lexis 291, 1996 WL 350997 (1996). Dell had certified that it did not have intellectual property rights interfering with a "VL-bus" standard, for the bus between a computer’s CPU and peripheral devices, and the Video Electronics Standards Association (VESA) adopted the standard. After the standard was adopted and implemented, Dell sought to assert a patent interfering with the standard. Where VESA arguably would not have adopted the standard if it had been aware of the Dell patent, the FTC asserted that Dell’s conduct violated section 5 of the FTC Act, and Dell entered into a Consent Judgment precluding its assertion of the patent against use in compliance with the standard. DM Research, Inc. v. College of American Pathologists, 170 F.3d 53 (1st Cir.1999) Affirms dismissal of Complaint alleging that effect of trade association guidelines harmed plaintiff’s business and caused owners to sell at a loss. Court rejects "implausible conclusory allegation" of conspiracy to "adopt faulty standard where main effect would be to raise costs" for certain competitors in the industry. ECOS Electronics Corp. v. Underwriters Laboratories, Inc., 743 F.2d 498 (7th Cir. 1994), cert. denied, 469 U.S. 1210 (1985) Eliason Corp. v. National Sanitation Foundation, 614 F.2d 126 (6th Cir.), cert. denied, 449 U.S. 826 (1980) ESS Technology, Inc. v. PC-Tel, Inc., No. C-99-20292 (N.D. Cal. 1999) ESS Tech., Inc. v. PC-Tel, Inc., No. C-99-20292 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 2, 1999) (order granting in part and denying in part defendant’s motion to dismiss) Plaintiff alleged it cannot produce modems that comply with ITU 101 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization standards without infringing defendant’s patents and that defendant refuses to license its patents on fair and reasonable terms. The court dismissed the plaintiff’s Sherman Act §2 claim and related state unfair competition claim for failure to allege antitrust injury. Plaintiff also asserted a claim for specific performance, arguing that it was a third-party beneficiary to defendant’s agreement with ITU to license on fair and reasonable terms. The court rejected defendant’s argument that its agreement with the standard-setting organization was too vague to support a claim for specific performance. ESS Tech., Inc. v. PC-Tel, Inc., No. C-99-20292 (N.D. Cal. July 3, 2000) (order denying defendant’s motion to dismiss). Plaintiff alleged that defendant refused to license its patents on fair and reasonable terms after representing to a standard-setting organization that it would do so. Defendant argued that a patent holder may unilaterally refuse to license its patents without being subject to antitrust liability. The court denied defendant’s motion to dismiss plaintiff’s antitrust, patent misuse, and state unfair competition claims, stating that defendant’s "alleged acts amount to more than just legitimately exercising a right to refuse to license patented technology." Fashion Originators’ Guild of America, Inc. v. FTC, 312 U.S. 457 (1941) Foundation for Interior Design Education Research v. Savannah College of Art & Design, 2001-1 Trade Cas. ¶ 73,212 Analyze refusal to accredit under rule of reason, no antitrust injury. Hyundai Electronics Indus. Co. v. Rambus, Inc., No. C-0020905RMW (N.D. Cal. 2001) Hyundai Elecs. Indus. Co. v. Rambus Inc., No. C 00-20905 (N.D. Cal. Jan. 19, 2001) (order granting in part and denying in part defendant’s motion to dismiss). The court dismissed plaintiff’s claim under section 1 of the Sherman Act, holding that it is insufficient to allege unilateral conduct in a collaborative standard-setting process. The court concluded that the plaintiff stated a claim under section 2 of the Sherman Act and section 17200 of the California Business and Professions Code. 102 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization In Re Independent Service Organization Antitrust Litigation: CSU, L.L.C. v. Xerox Corp., 203 F.3d 1322 (Fed. Cir. 2000), cert. denied, 121 S.Ct. 1077 (2001) Grants summary judgment in favor of defendant Xerox which refused to sell patented and copyrighted materials to independent servicers of its products, holding that assertion of intellectual property rights to exclude was valid business justification for refusal to deal. In controversially broad language, the Court states: "In the absence of any indication of illegal tying, fraud in the Patent and Trademark Office, or sham litigation, the patent holder may enforce the statutory right to exclude others from making, using, or selling the claimed invention free from liability under the antitrust laws." Intel Corp. v. Via Technologies, Inc., Intel Corp. v. Via Technologies, Inc., 2001 WL 777085, *6 (N.D. Cal. 2001) Denies motion to dismiss antitrust counterclaim in patent infringement action. Holds that allegation of sham patent litigation is properly pleaded where a license was allegedly given to practice some of patents in suit and fraud on PTO alleged for another. Declines to decide whether Noerr-Pennington applies where good faith claims are mixed with sham claims in a single suit. Intel Corp. v. Via Technologies, Inc., 174 F. Supp.2d 1038 (N.D. Cal. 2001) See Richard S. Taffet and Sophia Fix, Intel Corporation v. VIA Technologies, Inc., AT-IP Report (February 1, 2002); Massachusetts School of Law at Andover v. American Bar Ass’n, 937 F. Supp. 435 (E.D. Pa. 1996), aff’d, 107 F.3d 1026 (3d Cir. 1997), cert. denied, 522 U.S. 907 (1997) Granting defendant motion for summary judgment on NoerrPennington/state action defense on grounds that alleged damages were caused by state laws rather than directly by allegedly anticompetitive standard setting activity in the accreditation of law schools. Milk and Ice Cream Can Institute v. F.T.C., 152 F.2d 478 (7th Cir. 1946) Affirms FTC cease and desist order which had found that standard setting organization engaged in price fixing. 103 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Moore v. Boating Industry Ass’ns, 754 F.2d 698 (7th Cir. 1985), vacated, 474 U.S. 895 (1985), later proceeding, 819 F.2d 693 (7th Cir. 1987), cert. denied, 484 U.S. 854 (1987) Motorola, Inc. v. Rockwell Int’l Corp., No. 95-575 (D.Del. 1995) Multivideo Labs, Inc. v. Intel Corp., 99 Civ. 3908 (DLC), 2000-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 72,777, 2000 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 110 (S.D. N.Y. Jan. 7, 2000) After Intel made statements that plaintiff’s personal computer peripheral device did not comply with standards it had promoted, plaintiff sued for monopolization and attempted monopolization. Court granted summary judgment for Intel because, regardless of market power in CPU’s, Intel did not compete with the plaintiff in the market for the products at issue. Holds that claim of "monopoly leveraging requires a threshold showing a threat of higher price or reduced output in the secondary market." National Association of Review Appraisers & Mortgage Underwriters v. Appraisal Foundation, 64 F.3d 1130 (8th Cir. 1995), cert. denied, 517 U.S. 1189 (1996) National Macaroni Manufacturers Ass'n v. FTC, 345 F.2d 421 (7th Cir. 1965) Affirms FTC order finding that standards set by Macaroni/Spaghetti Trade Association calling for blended, rather than pure, form of durum wheat had effect of depressing price of that input to below market levels. Nat'l Camp Ass'n Inc. v. American Camping Ass'n Inc., SDNY No. 99 Civ. 11853 (DLC) (12/15/00) Applying rule of reason to refusal to accredit claim, no market power, no evidence of concerted action. NDC Health/IMS Health, Case COMP D3/38.044, European Commission’s Decision of July 3 2001, (Interim measures), suspended by August 10, 2001 Order of the President of the Court of First Instance, Case T-184/01 R, Decision of October 29, 2001 by the Court of First Instance 104 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Potter Instrument Co. v. Storage Technology Corp., 1980 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 1438, 207 U.S.P.Q. (BNA) 763 (E.D. Va. 1980), aff’d, 641 F.2d 190 (4th Cir. 1981), cert. denied, 454 U.S. 832 (1981) Radiant Burners, Inc. v. Peoples Gas Light & Coke Co., 364 U.S. 656 (1961) Complaint states a claim where it alleges arbitrary and capricious standards for approval of gas burners together with conspiracy between utilities and standard setting organization not to provide gas for use in unapproved burners. Rambus, Inc. v. Infineon Technologies AG, (No. 3:00CV524), 2001 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 11871 (E.D. Va. Aug. 9, 2001) (SDRAM), see also 155 F. Supp. 2d 668 (E.D. Va. 2001) (attorney fee award) In patent infringement action, defendant counterclaimed alleging that plaintiff had defrauded it by failing to disclose patent applications in meeting of standard setting body of which both were members and where standards using the patented technology were developed. Jury verdict finding fraud affirmed by court. See Veronica Lewis, "Rambus v. Infineon-The Latest Standard Setting Patent Disclosure Guidance" AT-IP Report (September 24, 2001) SanDisk Corp. v. Lexar Media, Inc., No. C-98-01115 (N.D. Cal. 2000) Sandisk Corp. v. Lexar Media, Inc., No. C 98-01115 (N.D. Cal. Oct. 17, 2000) (order granting in part and denying in part plaintiff’s motion to dismiss and for summary judgment). The court denied plaintiff’s motion for summary judgment on defendant’s fraud claims, finding that there was a genuine dispute as to whether plaintiff had a duty to disclose a pending patent application arising from unwritten agreements among members of standard-setting organizations. The court also denied plaintiff’s motion for summary judgment with respect to the unfair competition claim under California law, which proscribes conduct that is "unlawful," "unfair," or "fraudulent." Sessions Tank Liners, Inc. v. Joor Manufacturing, Inc., 1992 Trade Cas. ¶ 69,688 (C.D.Ca.1991), aff'd in part, 827 F.2d 458 (9th Cir), cert. granted and vacated, 487 U.S. 1213; judgment entered in favor of the plaintiff on remand, 786 F. Supp. 1518 (C.D. Ca. 1991), 105 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization rev'd, 17 F.3d 295 (9th Cir. 1994), cert. denied, 513 U.S. 813 (1994). In first appeal, 9th Circuit held that Noerr-Pennington immunity applies to lobbying of private model code association, but there is an exception for "sham" conduct. Sham claims pleaded where standards were passed due to false representation made to standard setting body. On remand, deliberate misrepresentation is proved, but in subsequent appeal 9th Circuit holds that NoerrPennington applies because harm results entirely from government conduct in enforcing model code and no harm is alleged in jurisdictions where the model code was not enforced by the government body. Schachar v. American Academy of Ophthalmology, 870 F.2d 397 (7th Cir. 1989) In an appeal from jury instructions at trial, where verdict was for defendant, Judge Posner rejects out of hand plaintiff’s contention that labeling of certain opthalmological treatment as experimental was an antitrust violation. Remarks that antitrust is about competition and not a code of medical ethics. Silver v. New York Stock Exchange, 373 U.S. 341 (1963) New York Stock Exchange requires disconnection of wire lines between member firms and nonmember firms. The court holds that this conduct presented a clear case of a per se unlawful group boycott and held that this conclusion was not altered by the duty of self-regulation imposed on such firms by the Securities Exchange Act. Sony Electronics, Inc. v. Soundview Technologies, Inc., 157 F. Supp. 2d 172-190 (D. Conn. 2001) See John S. Martin, "An Update on the Soundview Litigation." AT-IP Report (December 7, 2001). Stambler v. Diebold, Inc., No. 85 CV 3014, 11 U.S.P.Q.2d (BNA) 1709, 1988 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 10132 (E.D.N.Y.) aff'd 878 F.2d 1445 (Fed. Cir. 1988) Patent case involving defense of laches and estoppel; eleven year delay in bringing suit held unreasonable and summary judgment granted for defendant. Standard Sanitary Mfg. Co. v. United States, 226 U.S. 20 (1912) 106 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Court affirms an injunction baring agreement between a group of defendants comprising 85% of the manufacturers of enameled iron ware from entering into agreements purportedly designed to permit widespread use of patented technology but which also included fixing of prices through a pricing committee. Sun Microsystems, Inc. v. Kingston Technology Co., No. C-9903610, (N.D. Cal.) Sun Microsystems, Inc. v. Kingston Tech. Co., No. C99-03610 (N.D. Cal. Feb. 7, 2000) (Kingston’s Answer, Affirmative Defenses, and Counterclaims to First Amended Complaint for Patent Infringement). The defendant argued that the patent holder’s infringement claims were barred by the doctrines of misuse and estoppel based on the patent holder’s conduct in JEDEC standard-setting proceedings. Townshend v. Rockwell International Corp., 2000-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 72,890, 55 U.S.P.Q.2d 1011 (N.D.Cal. 2000) In patent infringement suit, defendant argues that plaintiff patent holder and company to whom he licensed technology unlawfully caused a trade association to adopt an industry standard which embodied the technology without disclosing trade secret litigation and prospective patent litigation. The court dismisses Section 1 claim for failure to plead sufficient injury to competition because conduct is a lawful incident of the patent monopoly and because patent holder offered licenses on reasonable terms. Regarding Section 2 claim, finds that patent holder’s conduct before Trade Association was not anticompetitive. Wang Laboratories, Inc., v. Mitsubishi Electronics America, Inc., 103 F.3d 1571 (Fed. Cir.), cert. denied, 522 U.S. 818 (1997) Rejects patent claim based on estoppel and implied license; others permitted to go forward. Windbond Electronics Corp. v. International Trade Commission, 262 F.3d 1363 (Fed Cir. 2001) General discussion of inequitable conduct and implied license issues relating to inventorship issues Zaveletta v. American Bar Ass’n, 721 F. Supp. 96 (E.D. Va. 1989) 107 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Articles, Speeches, Treatises and Testimony James J. Anton and Dennis A. Yao, "Standard-Setting Consortia, Antitrust, and High Technology Industries," 64 Antitrust L.J. 247 (1995) Mary L. Azcuenaga, The Intersection of Antitrust and Intellectual Property: Adaptations, Aphorisms and Advancing the Debate, before the American Law Institute-American Bar Association, Antitrust/Intellectual Property Claims in High Technology Markets, San Francisco, California (January 25,1996) David A. Bagwell, "Keeping Antitrust Simple:'Your Momma's Rules' For Attending Meetings," 48th Annual Spring Meeting, Section of Antitrust Law, Joint Committee Program of the Trade Association Committee and the Corporate Counseling Committee (April 7, 2000) David A. Balto and Robert Pitofsky, "Antitrust and High-Tech Industries: The New Challenge," 43 Antitrust Bulletin 503 (FallWinter 1998) David A. Balto, "Standard Setting in the 21st Century Network Economy," 18 Computer & Internet Lawyer 5 .(June 2001) David A. Balto, "Standard Setting in a Network Economy," then Assistant Director Office of Policy and Evaluation, Bureau of Competition, Federal Trade Commission, before Cutting Edge Antitrust Law Seminars International, New York, New York (February 17, 2000) Jack E. Brown, "Technology Joint Ventures to Set Standards or Define Interfaces," 61 Antitrust L.J. 921 (1993) Dennis W. Carlton and J. Mark Klamer, "The Need for Coordination Among Firms, with Special References to Network Industries," 50 U. Chi. L. Rev. 446 (1983) Michael G. Cowie and Joseph P. Lavelle, "Patents Covering Industry Standards: The Risks to Enforceability Due to Conduct Before Standard-Setting Organizations," AIPLA L.Q. (forthcoming) Susan A. Creighton, "The Antitrust Counterclaim: Recent 108 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Developments under Noerr-Pennington," Antitrust and Intellectual Property 13 (Newsletter of the Intellectual Property Committee of the Antitrust Section of the ABA) (Fall 2000) John Croll & Brain Martin, "The Role of Antitrust Enforcement in Standardization in High-Technology Industries," ALI-ABA 111 (1998) Paul David and Shane Greenstein, "The Economics of Compatibility Standards: An Introduction to the Recent Research," Economics of Innovation and New Tech. 3 (1990) Joseph Farrell, "Standardization and Intellectual Property," 30 Jurimetrics J. 35 (1989) FTC Staff Report, Anticipating the 21st Century: Competition Policy in the New High-Tech, Global Marketplace (1996) Sean P. Gates, "Standards, Innovation, and Antitrust: Integrating Innovation Concerns into the Analysis of Collaborative Standard Setting," 47 Emory L.J. 583 (1998) Harry S. Gerla, "Federal Antitrust Law and Trade and Professional Association Standards and Certification," 19 U. Dayton L. Rev. 471 (1994) Richard Gilbert, "Symposium on Compatibility: Incentives and Market Structure," 40 J. Ind. Econ. 1 (1992) Jennifer L. Gray, "Antitrust Guidelines for Participating in Standard Setting Activities," Corporate Counseling Report (Newsletter of the Corporate Counseling Committee of the Antitrust Section of the ABA) (Spring 2001) Carole E. Handler and Julian Brew, "The Application of Antitrust Rules to Standards in the Information Industries - Anomaly or Necessity" 14 The Computer Lawyer 1 (1997) Herb Hovenkamp, et al., Intellectual Property and Antitrust Law (1 st ed. 2001) Chapter on Standard Setting 109 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Michael Katz & Carl Shapiro, "Systems Competition and Network Effects," 8 J. Econ. Perspectives. 93 (1994) James B. Koback, Jr. "The Mutable Interface: Standard Setting, Antitrust and Intellectual Property," The Media Law Report, Vol. 2, No, 10 (August 1996) Daniel E. Lazaroff, "Sports Equipment Standardization: An Antitrust Analysis," 34 Ga. L. Rev. 137 (1999) Douglas D. Leeds, "Raising the Standard: Antitrust Scrutiny of Standard-Setting Consortia in High Technology Industries, 7 Fordham Intellectual Property Media & Entertainment L.J. 641 (1997) Mark A. Lemley, "Antitrust, Intellectual Property, and StandardSetting Organizations," (forthcoming) Mark A. Lemley, Standardizing Government Standard-Setting Policy for Electronic Commerce, 14 Berkeley Tech. L.J. 745 (1999) Mark A. Lemley, "Antitrust and the Internet Standardization Problem," 28 Conn. L. Rev. 1041 (1996) Mark A. Lemley and David McGowan, "Legal Implications of Network Economic Effects," 86 Calif. L. Rev. 479 (1998) Mark A. Lemley & David McGowan, "Could Java Change Everything? The Competitive Propriety of a Proprietary Standard," 43 Antitrust Bull. 715 (1998) Veronica Lewis, "Rambus v. Infineon-The Latest Standard Setting Patent Disclosure Guidance" AT-IP Report (September 24, 2001) Veronica Lewis, "Rambus’ Limited Patent Disclosure To A Standard Setting Body Was Found To Be Fraudulent But Not An Antitrust Violation," AT-IP Report (June 6, 2001) Amy A. Marasco, Vice President and General Counsel, American National Standards Institute, Testimony before the Federal Trade Commission (December 1, 1995). 110 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization John S. Martin, "An Update on the Soundview Litigation." AT-IP Report (December 7, 2001). Samuel R. Miller, "Standard-Setting in the Computer Industry - the Antitrust Risks," 13 The Computer Lawyer 1 (1996) J. Mueller, "Patenting Industry Standards, " 34 J. Marshall L. Rev. 897 (Summer 2001) Timothy J. Muris, "Standards-Setting Process Important But Must Not Be Used to Restrict Innovation" before American National Standards Institute's 1984 Public Conference on Standards and the Law, (March 27, 1984). FTC Press Release Timothy J. Muris, "Competition and Intellectual Property Policy: The Way Ahead", Prepared Remarks Before Antitrust Section Fall Forum (November 15, 2001) Robert Pitofsky, "Antitrust and Intellectual Property: Unresolved Issues at the Heart of the New Economy," before The Antitrust, Technology and Intellectual Property Conference (March 2, 2001), Robert Pitofsky, " Antitrust, Technology and Intellectual Property, " 16 Berkeley Tech. L.J. 535 (2001) Robert Pitofsky, "Self Regulation and Antitrust," before the D.C. Bar Ass'n (February 18, 1998). Daniel I. Prywes, "Patent Ambushes and Licensing in Computer Standard-Setting Groups," Antitrust Report (March 2001) Michael J. Schallop, "Leveraging Intellectual Property Rights to Encourage Interoperability in the Network Computing Age, 28 AIPLA Q.J. 195 (2000) D. Schneck, "Setting The Standard: Problems Presented to Patent Holders Participating in the Creation of Industry Uniformity Standards," 20 Hastings Comm/Ent. L.J. 641 (1998) Carl W. Shapiro & Hal R. Varian, "Information Rules: A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy" (1999) Carl W. Shapiro, "Antitrust in Network Industries," before the 111 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization American Law Institute and American Bar Association (Jan. 25, 1996) Carl W. Shapiro, "Navigating the Patent Thicket: Cross Licenses, Patent Pools, and Standard-Setting (March 2001), forthcoming in Innovation Policy and the Economy, Adam Jaffe, Joshua Lerner, and Scott Stern, eds. (MIT Press, 2001) Robert A. Skitol, Antitrust Issues Confronting Collective Standard Setting in High-Technology Industries, before the ABA Antitrust Section (February 25, 1999) David R. Steinman and Daniellle S. Fitzpatrick, "Antitrust Counterclaims in Patent Infringement Cases: A guide to Walker Process and Sham Litigation," Corporate Counseling Report (Newsletter of the Corporate Counseling Committee of the Antitrust Section of the ABA) (Fall 2001) Richard H. Stern, "Another Update Skullduggery," IEEE Micro, Sept.-Oct., 2001 on Standardization Richard H. Stern, "More Standardization Skullduggery," IEEE Micro, July-Aug., 2001 Richard H. Stern, "Preventing Abuse of IEEE Standards Policy," IEEE Micro, May-June, 2001 Richard H. Stern, "When Compliance with a Standard Gets Too Expensive," IEEE Micro, Nov.-Dec., 1999 Richard H. Stern, "Licensing IP Embodied in Standards, Part 2," IEEE Micro, Sept.-Oct., 1999 Richard H. Stern, "Licensing IP Embodied in Standards," IEEE Micro, July-Aug., 1999 Richard H. Stern, "Inviting Participants in Standard Setting," IEEE Micro, May-June, 1998 Richard S. Taffet, "Standards and Certifications: Risks and Benefits," Paper presented at the ABA Antitrust Section Program 112 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization on Trade Associations and Antitrust: A Practical Guide (1996) Alan J. Weinschel, The Antitrust–Intellectual Property Handbook, Chapter 4 "Antitrust and Standard Setting, Formal and De Facto" (2000) 113 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Session Chair John Anthony Chavez Anthony is Counsel with ExxonMobil Chemical Company, in the company's intellectual property licensing group. In previous assignments he has coordinated antitrust compliance programs, handled regulatory filings in the United States, the European Union, and a number of other jurisdictions, directed complex antitrust cases, and responded to government investigations. Mr. Chavez has written and lectured on legal topics relating primarily to: antitrust analysis of joint ventures; antitrust/intellectual property interface; corporate compliance programs; trade secrets and misappropriation; and white collar crime. He is a member of the American Bar Association and the Houston Bar Association. He currently serves as a Vice Chair of the Intellectual Property Committee of the ABA Antitrust Section (2000-present). Previously, he served as a Vice Chair of the Corporate Counseling Committee of the ABA Antitrust Section (1998-2000). He designed and established web sites for the Corporate Counseling Committee and the Intellectual Property Committee. In addition, for the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Section of the Houston Bar Association, he served as Chair (1997-1998); Vice Chair (1996-1997); Secretary/Treasurer (1995-1996); and Council Member (1993-1995). He earned his J.D. in 1981 from Stanford University and his B.A. in 1977 from the University of California at Santa Barbara. He is admitted to practice before the bars of the States of California (1981), New York (1986), and Texas (1982), the United States Supreme Court (1986), and the United States District Courts for the Central (1983), Northern (1982), and Southern (1982) Districts of California; the Southern (1982), Western (1983), and Northern (1991) Districts of Texas; and the Eastern and Southern Districts of New York (both 1986). Moderator Lisa C. Wood Lisa C. Wood is a senior partner at the Boston law firm, Nutter McClennen & Fish LLP, where she co-chairs the financial litigation and antitrust practice groups. She has substantial experience representing corporations, accounting firms, and corporate officers and directors in 114 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization antitrust, professional liability, corporate and federal securities litigation and in counseling corporate clients on antitrust and securities compliance. Active in the American and Boston bar associations, Ms. Wood is chair of the “section one” committee of the ABA’s antitrust section, a member of the BBA’s council, past chair of the BBAs litigation section and vice-chair of the corporate counsel committee of the ABA s section of litigation. She has written and lectured extensively on antitrust and federal securities matters. Ms. Wood is also active in community affairs, currently serving as chairman of the volunteer lawyers’ project, a trustee of the Boston bar foundation, and a member of the board of directors of the national conference for community and justice. Participants Mark A. Flagel Mark A. Flagel is a litigation partner in Latham & Watkins' Los Angeles office and is the head of the Intellectual Property and Technology Practice Group in Los Angeles. He is also Co-Chair of the firm's national Intellectual Property and Technology Practice Group. Mr. Flagel received his BA from UCLA in 1980, and his JD from U.C. Berkeley (Boalt Hall) in 1983. Mr. Flagel has been involved in many high visibility cases. For example, Mr. Flagel was one of the trial attorneys for Stac Electronics in its successful prosecution of a patent infringement suit against Microsoft, resulting in a jury verdict for $120 million. More recently, Mr. Flagel represented Kingston Technology in its successful defense of patent infringement claims brought by Sun Microsystems. That case involved a number of the standard-setting issues that will be addressed in this Program. Mr. Flagel has also been involved in various pro bono matters. He serves on the Board of Directors of Kayne-ERAS Center, a non-profit organization that serves at-risk children and young adults by providing a school, a camp, two group homes, vocational training and numerous other services. 115 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization Joseph P. Lavelle Joseph P. Lavelle is a partner at Howrey Simon Arnold & White, LLP. He is the head of Intellectual Property litigation in the D.C. office of Howrey. Mr. Lavelle has also taught a course on intellectual property and antitrust law at Georgetown University Law Center for a number of years. Mr. Lavelle graduated from Univ. Pittsburgh School of Law, summa cum laude, in 1982. Mr. Lavelle has been involved in a large number of antitrust/IP cases, including many matters involving standards setting issues in the computer memory, modems, DSL, and other industries. Mr. Lavelle represents Rambus, Inc. in several matters involving standards setting. Dorothy Gill Raymond Dorothy Gill Raymond is senior vice president and general counsel for Cable Television Laboratories, Inc. (CableLabs). In that role, Mrs. Raymond is responsible for all legal matters involving CableLabs, including antitrust compliance, intellectual property rights issues for CableLabs' specification efforts, protection of intellectual property, and other general corporate and contractual matters. In addition, Mrs. Raymond is a member of the senior staff of CableLabs, providing input on policy and strategic issues, including CableLabs’ efforts to develop and certify interoperable high speed data modems and advanced digital settop boxes. Among Mrs. Raymond's accomplishments while at CableLabs are establishing royalty-free license pools for CableLabs' cable modem and PacketCable projects, and establishing a sub-licensing program for third party security software needed by cable modem manufacturers. Mrs. Raymond is also responsible for monitoring the procedures of CableLabs' various specification compliance review boards. Mrs. Raymond has spoken on a wide variety of topics relating to antitrust and cable television legal matters. Publications include “The Role Of InHouse Counsel” in Judy Whalley, ed., Merger Review Process, (American Bar Association, 1995). Before joining CableLabs, Mrs. Raymond was a staff attorney for TeleCommunicatons, Inc. (TCI) responsible for mergers and acquisitions, and 116 A Year in the Life of a High Tech Standards Setting Organization then Vice President and General Counsel for WestMarc (a TCI subsidiary) with legal responsibilities including TCI's alternative access business and its satellite-delivered programming business. She holds a law degree from the University of Colorado and an undergraduate degree (summa cum laude) from the University of Denver. CableLabs is a research and development consortium of cable television system operators representing the continents of North America and South America. CableLabs plans and funds research and development projects that will help cable companies take advantage of future opportunities and meet future challenges in the cable television industry. It also transfers relevant technologies to member companies and to the industry. In addition, CableLabs acts as a clearinghouse to provide information on current and prospective technological developments that are of interest to the cable industry. CableLabs maintains web sites at www.cablelabs.com; www.cablemodem.com; www.cablenet.org; www.opencable.com; and www.packetcable.com. 117