WHAT IS GOING ON WITH CONTEMPORARY PROTECTIONISM IN LATIN AMERICA? AN OVERVIEW* Alejandro D. Jacobo** and Ileana R. Jalile§ ABSTRACT This paper updates the stock of discriminatory policy instruments in Latin American countries and explores the determinants of tariff and non-tariff measures. Using pre and post-2008 crisis trade and protection data, the level of tariff barriers and the Anti Dumping (AD) initiations are explained by macro and micro variables. The study finds that Intra-industry trade (IIT) is an important source of revenue for governments. The results indicate that the crisis did not increase protectionism in countries where powerful exporters demand cheap imported inputs, but it did where this lobby is not powerfully enough to overcome the need to raise public revenues. It also finds that governments are enthusiastic to favor their exporters by reducing tariffs on inputs used by (upstream) home exporters in order to enhance their competitive position with foreign users. Concerning non-tariff barriers determinants, all the countries in the sample show a positive relationship between AD initiations and the tariff level. This could indicate that tariff and non-tariff instruments as protectionist measures are both complementary. Finally, an appreciation of the currency against the currency of their trading partners makes an AD initiation more likely to occur in some countries of the sample. However, the crisis has not reinforced the relationship between an appreciation/devaluation on the probability of an initiation of an AD procedure. JEL Classification: F13 Keywords: Trade policy, tariffs, non tariff barriers, protectionism, antidumping, intra industry trade 1. Introduction Different authors and studies have carefully documented new measures that discriminate against foreign products activated in world trade since the 2008 global financial crisis. The 7th Global Trade Alert Report (hereinafter GTA-7), for example, illustrate that Latin American * This paper is part of a larger effort made by Global Trade Alert (GTA) and the Latin American Trade Network (LATN) for the examination of contemporary protectionism. Financial support from the Center for Economic Policy Research is gratefully acknowledged by the authors. ** Universidad Nacional de Córdoba and Universidad Católica Argentina. § Universidad Nacional de Córdoba. governments did seek to use protectionist policy instruments to respond to the crisis and that unilateral discriminatory measures mushroomed after the outbreak of the recession.1 To cope with the global crisis, major economies implemented a trading scheme and subsidies, cheap access to credit and other tax deductions and exemptions for exporters helped the recovery in world trade (Evenett, 2010; Tussie, 2012). However, due to different reasons — mainly due to the lack of resources— others economies were unable to generate these stimulus packages and they use tariff and non-tariff measures as protectionist instruments. As to Latin America Countries (LAC), while some of them used tariff measures to protect one or more sectors affected by the global crisis, other economies started to assemble a trade policy pattern notably characterized by major movements in non-tariffs barriers as well (Dalle and Lavopa, 2010). The emergency tools used by LAC are such important in manner and magnitude that deserves a study monitoring what is going on with Latin America protectionism. The aim of this study is twofold. First, to provide a brief and updated description of the stock of discriminatory policy instruments in LAC. This will help us to identify the protectionist (tariff and non-tariff) measures imposed by the region on different trading partners. Second, to develop an empirical model that explores the determinants of these policy instruments. The use of pre and post crisis trade and protection data will allow us to search possible variations in the determinants of trade policy responses. The paper proceeds as follows. Section two provides an overview on recent trade barriers involving LAC. Section three develops a model in which the presence of discriminatory policies in a particular sector from a specific country depends on macro and microeconomic determinants. Section four presents the estimation and the results. Section five concludes. 2. Protectionist policy instruments in LAC: An overview 1 Managed Exports and the Recovery of World Trade: The 7th Global Trade Alert Report (2010). This section provides a regional perspective on trade barriers involving Latin American countries according to the World Integrate Trade Solution (WITS), Temporary Trade Barriers (TTB) and Global Trade Alert (GTA) databases.2 It reviews the policy instruments and identifies those countries using more as well as those suffering most protectionist policies. We update the last review of protectionist measures enacted for Latin America provided by the GTA-7.3 WITS database retrieves information on trade and tariffs compiled by international organizations: The United Nation Commodity Trade (UN-COMTRADE) database contains information on exports and imports by detailed commodity and partner country; the United Nations Trade Analysis Information System (UN-TRAINS) database shows information on imports, tariffs, para-tariffs and non-tariff measures; and the World Trade Organization’s (WTO) Integrated Data Base (IDB) and WTO’s Consolidated Tariff Schedule Data Base (CTS) which contains information on imports by commodity and partner country, Most Favored Nation (MFN) Applied Rate, Preferential Tariffs (when available), Bound Tariffs (BND) as well as other indicators. The Temporary Trade Barriers Database (TTBD) website hosts newly collected and freely available detailed data on more than thirty different national governments’ use of policies such as AD, global safeguards (SG), China-specific transitional safeguard (CSG) measures, and countervailing duties (CVD). GTA database includes trade barriers (e. gr. tariffs and AD measures) as well as others measures related to trade policy (e. gr. foreign investment related measures). GTA classifies these measures into three categories: (1) green measures (which involve liberalization on a nondiscriminatory basis or an increase in transparency), (2) amber measures (that involve discrimination against foreign commercial interests and include already applied measures and measures announced or under consideration which, if implemented, would discriminate those 2 These databases are available through the following links: http://wits.worldbank.org/wits/, http://econ.worldbank.org/ttbd/ and http://www.globaltradealert.org. 3 We partially follow Rozemberg and Gayá (2010) for comparison purposes. interests), and (3) red measures (that are already in force and certainly discriminate against foreign commercial interests). About trade barriers, we present information on protectionist measures imposed by 10 LAC using data available from GTA database. These countries are: Argentina (ARG), Bolivia (BOL), Brazil (BRA), Chile (CHL), Colombia (COL), Ecuador (ECU), Mexico (MEX), Paraguay (PRY), Peru (PER) and Venezuela (VEN). Although GTA database considers 27 Latin America economies, not all the countries have started to be monitored at the same time and/or have implemented measures, and therefore were not included in our analysis.4 Thus, to make a comparison with the last GTA-7 and to avoid distortions by introducing countries that previously were not considered, we finally analyze only 10 economies. The stock of trade restriction comprises barriers from November 2008 (when GTA database started its job and began to list measures) through 03/02/2012 (when the GTA database was downloaded for this study). Figure 1 distinguishes green, amber or red measures implemented by each country. As shown in the figure, Argentina leads the ranking with the application of red and amber measures (127 in total), followed by Brazil (63) and Mexico (13). Argentina also exhibits the highest ratio in the relationship between protectionist (red and amber) to green measures (12.7). According to the last GTA-7, in Argentina the use of red and amber measures increased by 84%. 4 This situation could generate a bias against those first monitored. For example, Uruguay applied measures before the GTA-7 was published. However, these measures were not considered in this report which means that Uruguay was not monitored. Figure 2 Number of Measures Implemented by LAC, according GTA classification 130 120 116 110 100 90 80 70 60 60 54 50 40 30 20 11 10 10 9 12 11 1 8 5 4 4 3 5 2 2 6 9 2 2 5 0 1 3 0 0 1 0 1 1 0 1 CRI CHL 0 ARG BRA MEX VEN PER Source: Authors' own estimation based on GTA database. COL ECU PRY BOL Red Amber Green Figure 2 shows the stock of red and amber measures implemented in LAC by type of measure. Trade defense measures (AD, countervailing duties (CVD) and safeguard) represent 30% of all red and amber measures, followed by non-tariff measures (28%) and tariff measures (15%). This situation exhibits some differences from the previous GTA-7: Non-tariff measures notably increased from 8.9 to 28% while tariff measures augmented from 12.9% to 15%.5 “Other Measures” includes, inter alia, the following ones: Consumption subsidy, Import subsidy, Competitive devaluation, Sanitary and Phytosantiary Measure, State-controlled company, Technical Barrier to Trade, Local content requirement, Trade finance and Export subsidy. 5 Figure 4 Red and Amber Measures Implemented in LAC, by Type of Measure Trade defence measure (AD, CVD, safeguard) 31% Other 14% Export taxes or restriction 4% Bail out / state aid measure 4% Investment measure 4% Non tariff barrier (not otherwise specified) 28% Tariff measure 15% Source: Authors' own estimation based on GTA database. Each measure individually imposed by one of the LAC generally affects various jurisdictions and sectors. Table 1 presents the ranking of jurisdictions affected by Red measures imposed by the LAC. China is more affected by these measures than the other countries (6.5% of total), followed by India, Korea and Indonesia (2.7% of total in each case). This situation shows some differences from the last GTA-7, since the United States, Germany, Brazil, France and Spain are not affected as before by red measures implemented by LAC.6 6 It is worth to mention that Table 1 assumes that when a measure referenced in GTA database contains more than a type of measure affecting different countries, then each of these measures will simultaneously affect these countries. Table 1 Red Measures Imposed by Latin America, by Affected Country Red Affected Jurisdictions Measures China 195 India 84 Indonesia 80 Republic of Korea 79 Thailand 78 Malaysia 77 USA 75 Singapore 72 Hong Kong 69 Viet Nam 69 Philippines 65 Germany 63 Pakistan 62 Brazil 57 Others 1863 Total 2988 Source: Authors' own estimates based on GTA database. All selected countries in the region imposed red measures to other LAC. In Table 2 we can observe the number of red measures implemented among the countries under analysis. Table 2 Number of Red Measures Imposed among Selected LAC ARG BOL 2 BRA 9 2 Implementing Jurisdiction CHL COL ECU MEX 1 1 1 2 Affected Jurisdiction ARG BOL 14 BRA 43 2 1 CHL 35 5 1 COL 30 1 ECU 27 1 1 MEX 21 2 8 1 PRY 30 4 PER 20 1 4 1 VEN 17 1 1 1 Source: Authors' own estimates based on GTA database. 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 PRY 4 4 5 2 2 PER 1 VEN 2 1 2 2 3 2 4 1 2 Thus, Latin America does not provide a better treatment to regional partners, but quite the opposite. Argentina is, by far, the most active user of measures that discriminate against commercial interest of other LAC. Those countries involved in economic integration processes are also affected by measures that restrict intra-zone trade (e. gr. MERCOSUR). With respect to jurisdictions that implement protectionist measures, the Russian Federation and Argentina leads the world ranking with 130 and 116 initiatives respectively, followed by the UK, Germany, China, India and Brazil, as shown in Table 3. Table 3 Red Measures Imposed, by jurisdiction Implementing Red Measures Jurisdictions Implemented Russian Federation 130 Argentina 116 UK 64 Germany 60 China 59 India 57 Brazil 54 France 54 Spain 50 Italy 49 Austria 47 Hungary 47 Greece 46 Ireland 45 Netherlands 45 Others 1206 Total 2129 Source: Authors' own estimates based on GTA database. Table 4 presents information on the evolution of tariff barriers in LAC in recent years. As shown, the countries have not passively used this kind of trade policy measure. In most of the countries we observe an upward tendency in the level of the Applied Tariff (t) after the global financial crisis. As we also observe, there is a great policy space for the countries to further increase their tariff and remain within the bounds of GATT-WTO commitments indicated by the Bound Tariff (tbnd).7 Table 4 Evolution of Tariff Barriers in LAC Countries Argentina Bolivia Brazil Chile Colombia Ecuador Mexico Paraguay Years Tariff Measures 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 Applied Tariff (t) 14.78 14.73 11.85 10.60 10.74 10.80 MFN Tariff (tMFN) 14.78 14.73 13.40 12.35 12.37 12.40 Bound Tariff (tBND) 31.64 31.72 31.86 31.95 31.93 31.96 7.76 7.19 6.48 9.27 8.63 2009 2010 9.83 9.76 11.41 11.48 11.59 13.43 31.97 31.96 31.85 6.20 6.18 7.49 9.58 8.53 8.46 8.46 10.23 11.78 Applied Tariff (t) 9.87 MFN Tariff (tMFN) 9.87 Bound Tariff (tBND) 39.97 39.97 39.98 39.98 39.98 39.98 39.97 39.97 Applied Tariff (t) 14.56 14.37 13.28 12.39 12.20 12.23 13.10 13.34 13.37 MFN Tariff (tMFN) 14.56 14.37 14.28 13.28 13.24 13.25 14.38 14.62 14.67 Bound Tariff (tBND) 30.67 30.75 30.71 30.80 30.87 30.90 30.96 30.94 30.94 4.89 4.86 2.23 1.96 1.39 5.97 4.86 6.00 6.00 5.99 5.99 5.99 5.99 5.99 25.06 25.05 25.05 25.06 25.06 25.06 25.06 11.44 11.87 11.33 10.81 10.73 10.71 11.20 12.40 12.82 12.77 12.81 12.79 12.73 12.75 38.15 n.a. Applied Tariff (t) 6.99 MFN Tariff (tMFN) 6.99 Bound Tariff (tBND) 25.04 Applied Tariff (t) 12.45 MFN Tariff (tMFN) 12.45 Bound Tariff (tBND) 38.57 38.29 38.14 38.05 38.06 38.06 38.15 Applied Tariff (t) 12.02 11.60 11.82 9.82 10.03 9.73 8.36 9.37 MFN Tariff (tMFN) 12.02 12.20 12.58 12.44 12.51 11.70 10.16 10.16 Bound Tariff (tBND) 21.84 21.98 22.65 22.49 22.57 22.17 21.64 21.64 Applied Tariff (t) 15.54 18.34 10.21 9.20 8.01 7.35 MFN Tariff (tMFN) 18.38 18.34 17.50 14.72 14.48 Bound Tariff (tBND) 34.98 34.98 34.97 34.94 34.95 Applied Tariff (t) 13.41 13.42 9.20 8.38 7.19 8.01 8.33 7.98 7.97 MFN Tariff (tMFN) 13.41 13.42 12.50 11.50 10.28 11.06 11.04 11.04 11.07 Bound Tariff (tBND) 32.67 32.69 32.45 32.67 32.70 32.75 32.63 32.61 32.61 9.65 9.19 8.57 8.54 3.86 3.73 4.78 10.18 9.58 9.60 9.64 4.96 4.74 5.17 30.08 30.07 30.06 30.07 30.08 30.08 30.06 n.a. n.a. n.a. Applied Tariff (t) Peru 2008 MFN Tariff (tMFN) n.a. n.a. Bound Tariff (tBND) Bound Tariff (tBND) Applied Tariff (t) MFN Tariff (tMFN) 13.54 8.26 34.98 34.98 34.99 9.86 9.64 9.52 9.50 9.61 9.59 12.53 12.33 12.32 12.35 12.32 12.32 31.25 31.29 31.52 31.52 31.54 31.58 31.58 31.58 13.54 12.22 12.69 12.22 12.17 11.84 12.07 13.02 13.04 13.44 14.25 14.31 14.36 14.55 14.48 Bound Tariff (tBND) 34.72 34.56 Source: Authors' own estimates based on data from WITS database. 34.42 34.43 34.43 34.45 34.60 34.48 7 14.33 5.28 11.17 14.33 Venezuela 14.33 MFN Tariff (tMFN) 6.39 12.69 11.15 Uruguay Applied Tariff (t) n.a. n.a. n.a. Bound Tariffs (tbnd) are specific commitments made by individual WTO member governments and represent the maximum Most-Favored Nation tariff level that a country may levy for a commodity. The Most-Favored Nation tariffs (tmfn) are what countries promise to impose on imports from other members of the WTO, unless the country is part of a preferential trade agreement. WITS database uses the concept of Effectively Applied Tariff which is defined as the lowest available tariff and will be used as the Applied Tariff (t) if a preferential tariff exists. Otherwise, the MFN applied tariff will be used. According to GTA database, trade defense measures are the most used non-tariff trade policy instruments in LAC countries. Within these instruments, TTB database ranks AD at the top of the list. Table 5 presents information on 6-digit HS products with AD initiations per year for some LAC countries.8 Table 5 Antidumping Initiations in Selected LAC Years Argentina Brazil Colombia Mexico Peru 2002 57 12 n.a. 17 48 2003 1 4 n.a. 17 48 2004 30 8 2 6 46 2005 16 6 2 18 5 2006 15 15 66 7 7 2007 11 19 2 4 1 2008 42 53 9 1 7 2009 89 17 3 3 18 2010 41 46 4 3 n.a. Source: Authors' own estimates based on TTB database using iInformation on 6 Digits HS products. 3. On the political-economy variables of trade policy There is a vast theoretical and empirical literature analyzing the determinants of trade protection in the economy. In recent decades, however, this literature has moved towards the “endogenous” trade policy determination and constitutes the core of the literature on the political economy of trade policy (Gawande and Krishna, 2006).9 In line with this literature, the aim of this section is to analyze the determinants of trade policy in LAC and to verify if countries have changed their behaviour as a consequence of the crisis. 8 Due to availability of the data, the number of countries selected in Table 5 is reduced to five LAC. See Gawande and Krishna (2006) for a summary of the empirical literature on the determinants of trade protection. 9 Considering the evidence related to trade measures used by LAC we have already summarized in Section 2, we analyze two different policy instruments: Tariff Barriers and AD. We explore the determinants of both protectionist measures. For this purpose, we use 6-digit HS tariff, non-tariff and trade data provided by WITS and TTB databases to make inferences on the influence of micro and macroeconomic variables in determining the source of protectionism. The level of disaggregated data will allow us to take into account sectoral and partner countries differences that influence on trade protectionism. This strategy is not a novel one. Among other authors Olarreaga and Vaillant (2011), Gawande et al. (2011) and Bown and Tobar (2011) have already analyzed the determinants of trade policies using disaggregated data as we do. However, in comparison with the existing literature, we will focus specifically on Latin America Region and we will try to see if there is a change in the behaviour of LAC after the crisis with newly available data. Data and Methodology Our empirical approach have analyzed the following LAC: Argentina (ARG), Bolivia (BOL), Brazil (BRA), Chile (CHL), Ecuador (ECU), Mexico (MEX), Paraguay (PRY), Peru (PER), Venezuela (VEN) and Uruguay (URY) over the period: 2002-2010.10 As in Gawande et al. (2011), we explore the determinants of trade policy responses by estimating two equations. First, the Tariff Barrier Equation where the dependent variable is the effectively applied bilateral tariff. Second, the AD Equation where the dependent variable is AD initiation. In both equations we explain the presence and level of trade barriers in a 6-digit 10 The last available year on data on trade and tariff and not tariff barriers provided by the WITS and TTB databases is 2010. Since these databases provide information on Uruguay, this country is now formally introduced in the analysis. HS product imported from a particular country in a given year. This disaggregation is required because tariff and non-tariff barriers are determined at the product level. With regard to the Tariff Barrier Equation, the determinants of tariff barriers have been extensively discussed in the literature.11 As in Gawande et al. (2011) and Olarreaga and Vaillant (2011), we include in our analysis macro and microeconomic determinants of the level of tariff barriers. As we mentioned above, as dependent variable in this equation we will use the Effectively Applied Tariff, which is defined as the lowest available tariff. If a preferential tariff exists, it will be used as the effectively applied tariff. Otherwise, the MFN applied tariff will be used. Our proposed specification for this equation is as follows: t g,p,t= α1(tbndprfg,p,t)+ α2(iitg,p,t-1)+ α3(VSg) + α4(VS1g)+ +αg + αp+ αt + εg,p,t (1) where tg,p,t represents the level of the Effectively Applied Tariff on good g, imported from partner p at time t; tbndprg,p,t is a composite measure of tbnd and tprf (tbnd is the bound rate commitment at the WTO and tprf is the preferential tariff rate) and represents the value of this variable on good g, imported from partner p at time t; iitg,p,t-1 is a measure of intra-industry trade on good g, imported from partner p at time t-1; VSg and VS1g are measures of vertical specialization on product g; αg is an HS six-digit fixed effect; αp is a partner fixed effect and αt is a time fixed effect. The influence of Institutions is measured by the coefficient associated to the bound rate tbndprf (1). While applied rates are determined by each country, they are bounded above by their bound rate commitment at the WTO. The latter rates are determined in multilateral negotiations and they are exogenous in our model. Countries do not make commitments in terms of “applied protection” but instead in terms of the “ceiling” above which they commit not to raise their applied duty. However, if a country decide to sign a PTA the new effective bound on its tariff rate would be the preferential tariff rate (tprf ). Following Gawande et al. (2010), we define a composite measure where tbndprf = tprf whenever tprf is applicable, or tbndprf = tbnd 11 See Gawande and Krishna (2008) for a review of this literature. otherwise. The coefficient is expected to be positive and small if the structure of GATT/WTO incentives keep applied tariff in check. The coefficient 2 captures the impact of Intra-Industry Trade (ITT) on the tariff barrier level. The construction of an intra-industry trade index at product level would allow us to measure the trade in similar but differentiated products. Currently, an important share of trade is ITT. WITS database allow us to construct the following ITT measure at the 6-digit HS level: IIT = 1 − |Imports - Exports| / (Imports + Exports). Krugman (1981) demonstrate the gains from trade in the presence of product varieties. According to this we would expect that higher IIT would imply less protectionist pressures. However, more sophisticated models indicate that the presence of IIT does not necessarily imply a negative correlation between IIT and tariff. For example, in models featuring domestic and foreign duopolies, Brander and Spencer (1984) show that rents could be shifted from foreign to home firms through a strategic tariff policy. Then, even though the optimal action for both countries is to reduce tariffs, the unilateral incentive is for governments to use tariffs to play zero-sum games. If tariffs are strategic, then, a positive correlation between IIT and rents implies that tariffs should be positively associated with ITT. Another example could be Jørgensen and Schröder (2006) who show that an optimal tariff exists, below which welfare is reduced because there are too few domestic varieties and beyond which there are too many inefficiently-produced, costly domestic varieties. On the other hand, if tariffs in the countries are strategic as a source of government revenue one may expect a positive correlation between ITT and the dependent variable.12 The literature also points out that vertical specialization could have an impact on the tariff level. Vertical Specialization could be defined as production arrangements in which firms make final goods via multiple stages located in multiple countries, as an important aspect of overall input trade. We introduce two measures of vertical specialization: VS and VS1.13 VS is the share of imports in a sector that is used directly and indirectly in the country’s own exports (i.e. embedded as intermediate inputs). VS1 is the proportion of a sector’s exports used as 12 Gawande et al., 2011. Theories offer several explanations for vertical production networks, including cross-country and/or cross-industry differences in trade costs, factor prices, and the technological separability of production. While there is some evidence to support these theories, little work goes beyond documenting broad facts to provide a theoretically and micro-level empirical analysis of the importance of these explanations (Hanson et al., 2003). 13 intermediates by exporters in other countries.14 These two variables have been constructed in Daudin et al. (2010) using trade and input-output data from the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) database. To construct the variables VS and VS1, Daudin et al. (2010) computes valueadded trade for 66 regions and 55 sectors in 1997, 2001 and 2004.15 The construction of VS and VS1 for different years depends on the input-output matrices for each reporting country. Since LAC do not systematically update input- output data, VS and VS1 were generated using the last available input-output matrices. It implies that VS and VS1 at each 6-digit HS code will be constant along the period. Input-output tables indicate that the same sector is the larger user of imports by that sector. While a positive coefficient in VS may indicate that the exporters are not powerful enough to overcome the need to raise revenues, a negative coefficient on VS1 can be interpreted as a global supply chain against protectionism. Among other macroeconomic determinants of policy trade responses that may vary across years are the level of activity, unemployment and institutional variables. These determinants have been taken into account in Olarrega and Vaillant (2011) using year fixed effects. We follow the same strategy. Besides, any particular determinant of protection towards a partner that is timeinvariant (as for example distance, institutional similarity, or similarities in the comparative advantage) is controlled using partner fixed effects. The literature has also points out other microeconomic determinants of trade policy instruments such as the concentration of the sectors, output or the extent to which workers are unionised. Unfortunately, we do not have data about these variables at the disaggregated 6-digit HS, so we assume that these variables remain constant during the period and we control them using product fixed effects. 14 VS1 measures the intensity of two sources of anti-protectionist pressure. High tariffs on imports in a sector undermine the competitiveness of the sector’s exports that intensively use those imports. Inputoutput tables indicate that the same sector is the larger user of imports by that sector. As consequence, the first source of anti-protectionism is exporters of that sector who will lobby against tariffs that raise their input costs and make them uncompetitive. The second source of anti-protectionism is foreign lobbying by exporters in other countries who depended on the source country for supplying them with intermediate inputs. Low or zero tariffs in the source country are desirable for keeping their input costs down (Gawande et al., 2011). 15 We thank Guillaume Daudin for generously providing us the data. We use concordance tables for matching 55 sectors from the GTAP to the 6-digit HS codification used in our empirical approach. With regard to the AD Equation, we should note that the determinants of Non-Tariff Barriers have also been extensively studied in the literature.16 Our proposed equation specification is as follows: ADg,p,t=α1(uvg,p,t-1)+α2(mg,p,t-1)+α3(tg,p,t)+α4(VSg)+α5(VS1g)+α6(RBERp,t)+αg+αp+αt+εg,,p,t (2) where ADg,p,t is a dummy variable indicating the presence of an AD on good g, imported from partner p at time t; uvg,p,t is the unit value of good g, imported from partner p at time t; mg,p,t is the value of imports of good g, imported from partner p at time t; tg,p,t is the Effectively Applied Tariff on good g at time t; VSg and VS1g are measures of vertical specialization on product g; RBERp,t is the real exchange rate with respect to partner’s p currency at time t; αg is an HS sixdigit fixed effect; αp is a partner fixed effect, and αt is a time fixed effect. Among the most important macroeconomic determinants that vary among partners, we include Real Bilateral Exchange Rates (RBER) and MFN (or effectively applied tariff) rates. The first measures the impact of bilateral competitiveness of each country vis-à-vis each of its trading partners. On the other hand, the coefficient associated to tariff rate indicates the extent to which AD and tariff rates act as complementary or substitute trade policy. We have special interest in the RBER coefficient. Following Olarreaga and Vaillant (2011) the sign of this coefficient is ambiguous. Feinberg (1989) suggests that it should be positive as the depreciation of the local currency increase the probability of finding dumping, while Knetter and Prusa (2003) suggest that the coefficient should be negative because a depreciation of the local currency difficults injury on the economy. As microeconomic determinants that affect trade policy responses we consider the Price and the Value of Imports which vary across partners, years and sectors. The coefficient associated to these variables would indicate the casual effect from the price and size of imports on the determination of the presence of an AD. To sum up, we postulate that the propensity to initiate 16 Se Aggarwal (2004) for brief review of the literature. See also Knetter and Prusa (2003), Prusa and Skeath (2002), and Sabry (2000). an AD procedure would increase with larger imports (2 >0), and that higher unit prices are less likely to lead to finding dumping or injury from subsidies (1 < 0). We have also included in our econometric specification the vertical specialization (VS and VS1) measures. As we previously mentioned, we expect that an increase in vertical specialization reduce the protectionism in the reporting country whether local governments favour global supply chains. This means that AD initiations should be inversely related with vertical specialization measures. On the other hand, a positive coefficient on VS could be associated with the fact that exporters in the reporting countries are not powerful enough for fight against protectionism, while a positive coefficient on VS1 could indicate that exporters of partner countries are not lobbying against protectionism on local governments. We follow the same approach presented in the tariff equation and we use year fixed effects to control for domestic macroeconomic determinants of policy trade responses that vary across years (such as the level of activity, unemployment and institutional variables). Any particular determinant of protection towards a partner that is time-invariant (as for example distance, institutional similarity, or similarities in the comparative advantage) is controlled using partner fixed effects. Again, in order to control for microeconomic determinants of trade policy instruments (such as the concentration of the sector, output or the extent to which workers are unionised), we assume these variables keep constant in the period and consequently we control for them using product fixed effects. 4. Estimation and Results Estimates from a baseline partner and year fixed effects model of applied bilateral tariffs that represents the influence of the variables considered are presented in Table 6 (see Appendix). In the model, the year fixed effect controls for any domestic macroeconomic change such as the level of economic activity or unemployment in the reporter countries. The partner fixed effect controls for any particular determinant of protection towards that partner that is time-invariant, as for example distance, institutional similarity, or similarities in the comparative advantage. The model performs well. The coefficient of 0.25 on tbndprf for Argentina indicates that if bound rate (adjusted for PTA agreements) increases 1 point, Argentina’s bilateral applied tariff increases 0.25 points. Peru exhibits lowest coefficient (0.14) while Ecuador shows the highest (0.61). Despite the availability of tariff policy space, one reason for the small coefficients in Argentina is that since the majority of trade is carried on with MERCOSUR partners the competition with others is not probably an issue. Another reason is that the agreement has accelerated the decline of inefficient industries in Argentina, so the country does not face protectionist demands from those sectors. However, the small coefficients in the line of the table are the rule and they do not necessarily reveals the feature of belonging to a PTA or the existence of completely efficient industries in all the cases. Rather, the low coefficients may indicate that WTO incentives kept applied tariffs in check.17 The coefficient of 1.64 on IIT for Argentina indicates that a higher intra-industry trade is associated with an increase in Argentinean tariffs. This is quite the opposite of the prediction from intra trade models that emphasize the additional welfare gains from expanding the varieties.18 Besides, the positive sign on IIT could indicate the dependence of Argentina on tariffs as a source of revenue. Since much of the Argentinean trade is with PTA’s partners more revenues means higher tariffs on non PTA partners, even if trade with them is two-way trade in similar goods. The selected countries have positive coefficients revealing revenues requirements. For Mexico, however, IIT has a negative coefficient that may indicate the additional welfare from expanding the variety in differentiated products. In this case, the gains from trade appear to overwhelm the need to use tariffs for revenues motives.19 While measures of VS does not dissuade the use of tariff in Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Paraguay and Peru, it does deter their use in Ecuador, Mexico, Venezuela and Uruguay. Recall that the VS measure of vertical specialization is the share of imports in a sector 17 Gawande et al. (2011). The results presented in Jørgensen and Schröder (2006) and Brander and Spencer (1984) could also explain the positive correlation we have found. 19 As in Gawande et al. (2011), we are unable to discriminate among different theories. 18 that is used directly and indirectly in the country’s own exports (i.e. embedded as intermediate inputs). So, while the exporters of countries included in the first club of nations are not powerful enough to overcome the need to raise revenues, the importance of exporters in the other club of countries results obvious. The second vertical specialization measure (VS1) shows a negative coefficient across the table (with the exception of Uruguay). This could be interpreted as a global supply chain against protectionism. Recall that this measure is the proportion of a sector’s exports used as intermediates by exporters in other countries. Thus, the coefficients suggest that the governments are enthusiastic to advance their exporters’ interests by reducing tariffs on the inputs used by (upstream) home exporters in order to enhance their competitive position with foreign users. The negative coefficients may also be taken as evidence for the idea that exporters in foreign countries may (politically) influence home tariffs since their competiveness depends on the supply of cheap inputs from home producers. Following Gawande et al. (2011), each variable is interacted with a post-crisis dummy to find out whether the relationships observed in Table 6 remained unaltered through the crisis or were fundamentally changed by it. The results are presented in Table 7 (see Appendix). Consider the coefficient on the interaction term tbndprfxI2009. The positive and statistically significant coefficient in most of the cases (with the exception of Mexico, Peru, Venezuela y Uruguay) indicate that the majority of the countries did not lower their tariffs and feel the pressure in the post-crisis period to raise them. In the case of Argentina, for example, the coefficient on tbndprf increased by 0.026 in 2009 over a pre-crisis coefficient of 0.24, signaling a readiness to increase tariffs up to the bound levels. For other countries, the change on coefficients is still small, considering the magnitude of the crisis. The coefficient on IITxI2009 for Argentina is negative. However, taken into account the overall impact of IIT post- crisis on the level of the tariff (1.8771-1.2729), we may conclude that its public finances depend on tariff revenues. The same conclusion may be applied for Brazil, Colombia, Paraguay, Peru and Uruguay. In the case of Bolivia, Chile, Ecuador and Venezuela the positive impact of IIT on the tariff level has been reinforced after the crisis. This situation probably means that the need of revenue from foreign trade is even higher after the 2008 economic downturn. Finally, we observe that the overall impact of IIT on Mexico has changed after the crisis. In fact, while before the crisis the theory emphasizing the additional welfare gains from expanding the varieties was verified, after the crisis the theory of tariff revenue dependency could be applied. Consider the vertical specialization measures: VSxI2009 and VS1xI2009. The latter term shows large negative coefficient for Ecuador, Mexico, Brazil and Bolivia (-17.82, -12.47, -15.87 and 13.82 in each case). In the post-crisis period, the export sectors in Ecuador, Mexico, Bolivia and Brazil’s partner countries seem to have a strong influence on lowering their tariffs, specifically on products that the partners import from those countries for intermediate use.20 This source of anti-protectionism is also evident in Peru, Paraguay, Venezuela, Colombia and, to a lesser extent in Argentina. In the case of Chile and Uruguay, VS is the main source of antiprotectionism after the crisis where domestic exporters are the prime movers in demanding lower protection on imported goods they intensively use. Both sources of anti-protectionism are used in Ecuador, Mexico and Venezuela. Other studies include in the analysis other regressors in their empirical estimation that are not introduced in our analysis. For example, some of them include variables that measure the influence of intermediate use as well as other political economy variables that intent to determine the propensity of protectionism. However, if we assume that these variables are surely time invariant across products during the period analyzed, we can control for their effect on the level of the tariff using product fixed effects. The good fixed effect would also controls for any other time invariant 6-digit HS determinant of protection, as the political strength of producers. When we control for these fixed effect some of the variables that we have considered in our econometric estimation are dropped because they were constructed using data that remain constant across the period (e. gr. VS and VS1). 20 A lower cost makes partners more competitive and, in turn, this situation increase the purchases from Ecuatorian, Mexican, Bolivian and Brazilian suppliers and expand their exports. Table 8 (in the Appendix) presents the result of the estimation including good fixed effects. As we can observe, the coefficients associated with the institutional variable tbndprf do not generally present considerable changes compared with the previous specification. On the other hand, we can observe some changes on the overall impact of intra industry trade on protectionism after the crisis. While a positive impact of ITT in the level of the tariff was the rule in the previous specification (indicating that weak tax system in these countries relies almost at all on revenue tariff), when considering product fixed effect this relation has changed for some countries. On this new specification there is evidence that in Argentina, Colombia, Paraguay and Uruguay the gains from trade in similar but differentiated products appear to overwhelm the need to use tariff for revenues motives. We look at the incidence of AD initiations using conditional logit models with partner, product and year fixed effects. Previous studies of trade defense measures have restricted their samples only to sectors in which these kind of measures have taken place. In our study, we compare 6digit HS commodities on which AD investigations occurred with the overwhelming number of cases in which these investigations do not exist. Due to the lack of data, we only have results for Argentina, Brazil, Mexico, Colombia and Peru. Table 9 (in the Appendix) presents the results of estimating the AD equation. We observed that all the countries in our sample show a positive relationship between AD initiations and the tariff level. This could indicate that, as a protectionist measures, tariff and non-tariff measures are both complementary. This relationship is reinforced after the crisis only in Argentina. This situation may indicate that this country may have stepped up AD investigations after the crisis as a complement to tariff barriers. The coefficient on BRER is negative and statistically significant for Argentina, Brazil and Colombia. This indicates that an appreciation of their currency against the currency of their trading partners makes a AD initiation more likely to occur. When this variable is evaluated in the post crisis period, we find that the coefficient has reduced in Argentina and Colombia and remains the same in Brazil. Consequently, the crisis has not reinforced the relationship between an appreciation/devaluation on the probability of an initiation of an AD procedure. The coefficients on VS are positive for all countries except for Peru. This exception indicates that only in Peru the exporters are powerful enough to lobby against the initiation of an AD on imports of goods used directly and indirectly by Peruvian exporters. For the post crisis years, Argentina is the only country where we can observe a change in the relationship between VS and AD. Specifically, it could indicate that Argentinean exporters are now more powerful in fighting against AD initiations over their imports. The coefficient on VS1 is negative in the case Colombia, but positive for Peru, México and Brazil. A negative sign on this variable indicates that government favors global supply chains (Colombia) while a positive one could indicate that foreign exporters do not have political influence on the local economic policy (Brazil, Mexico and Peru). Besides, we can observe that the negative impact of VS1 in the propensity of initiating an AD is not reinforced after 2008 in Colombia. While in Table 9 we observe that the propensity to initiate an AD is positively related with the level of the tariff effectively applied on a particular product, it is important to take into account that some problems of endogeneity may emerge.21 Our strategy in this paper is to control for 6digit HS product fixed effect. We suppose that the endogeneity problem could arise due to a non-observed variable that determines both AD initiations and the level of the tariff. Such nonobserved variable could be the political strength of domestic producers of each 6-digit HS product. Therefore, controlling for product, year and partner fixed effects is our last estimation and we present the results of this specification in Table 10 (in the Appendix). For Argentina we observe that the most important determinant of the probability of an AD initiations is the RBER. It means that the propensity to initiate a trade defense measure in Argentina strongly depends on the level of appreciation of its currency against its partner’s countries and that for years after 2008 this relationship has been reinforced. While prior to 2008 the relationship between the level of the tariff and the probability of initiate an AD procedure was not statistically different for zero, after crisis we can observe a complementarity between both measures of protectionism. With regard to Brazil, the Table 10 indicates that the propensity 21 Aggarwal (2004) introduces a lagged tariff as independent variable, while others, such as Trefler (1993) uses a simultaneous equation model. to initiate an AD depends on the level of the tariff and the RBER. It indicates that tariff and non tariff barriers are complementary and that the propensity to initiate an AD in Brazil depends on the level of appreciation of its currency against its partner’s countries. Besides, the impact of these variables on the probability of initiating an AD remains the same after the crisis. In Mexico AD initiations and tariff appear to be complementary and the lower prices for product imported from partners are more likely to lead to AD initiation. Both effects are not reinforced after the breakdown of the crisis. For Colombia, the variables included in our analysis do not explain the presence of an AD. After the crisis, however, the level of the tariff and unit values of imports could explain the initiation of this non tariff barrier. According to our results, the negative coefficient related to the tariff indicates that sectors with high tariffs are less likely to get protected through AD initiations. Surprisingly, the coefficient associated with unit values is positive and statistically significant. This could be explained by the fact that products subject to AD tend to be timer invariant and that AD are more likely to be applied on goods for which domestic demand is growing and this implies higher prices from these partners.22 Finally, in the case of Peru, the unit value of imports is the only variable that could explain the presence of an AD. According to our estimation, the lower prices for product imported from partners are more likely to lead to AD being imposed on those imports. This effect is not reinforced after the crisis. 5. Concluding comments The paper provides a brief and updated description of the stock of discriminatory policy instruments in LAC and it also explores the determinants of the protectionist measures imposed by these countries. There is an increase in the use of discriminatory measures by LAC and two of them (Argentina and Brazil) lead the ranking of countries implementing discriminatory measures worldwide. 22 Olarreaga and Vaillant (2011). Moreover, some of these measures mutually affect LAC. Trade defense measures (AD, CVD and safeguard) represent 30% of all red and amber measures, followed by non-tariff measures (28%) and tariff measures (15%). With regard to the determinants of the measures imposed by LAC, we have found that WTO and PTA (Preferential Trade Agreements) incentives appear to have kept applied tariff in control. In spite of all LAC has plenty of space to raise tariff, they did not strongly use this policy space for greater protectionism. On the other hand, following the 2008 financial crisis most of the countries feel the pressure to raise their tariff up to the bound levels (with the exception of Mexico, Peru, Venezuela and Uruguay). The study also finds that ITT is associated with an increase in tariffs in most of LAC (with the exception of Chile and Mexico). This is quite the opposite of the prediction from IIT models that highlight the additional welfare gains from expanding the varieties. It could indicate that these countries strongly depend on tariff as a source of government revenue. After the crisis the overall impact of IIT on tariff level is positive and reinforces the dependence on tariff revenues in almost all LAC. We have found a positive coefficient for the VS measure for Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Paraguay and Peru, indicating that exporters of these countries are not powerful enough to overcome the need to raise revenues. Our regressions show that the crisis did not change the relationship between the level of VS and the tariff (except for the case of Chile). Thus, we observe some heterogeneity across LAC since exporters in Ecuador, Mexico, Venezuela and Uruguay (and Chile after 2008) did were successful in demanding protectionism. The negative coefficient associated with the VS1 measure of vertical specialization (the proportion of a sector’s exports used as intermediates by exporters in other countries) for almost all countries analyzed, in general, suggest that governments are enthusiastic to favor their exporters by reducing tariffs on the inputs used by (upstream) home exporters in order to enhance their competitive position with foreign users. The negative coefficient could also support the idea that foreign exporters have influence in determining liberalizing trade policy in LAC. As to AD determinants, tariff and non-tariff protectionist measures are complementary. The evidence for Argentina indicates that this country may have further increased AD investigations after the crisis as a complement to tariff. The coefficient on BRER is negative and significant for Argentina, Brazil and Colombia. This indicates that an appreciation of their currency against the currency of their trading partners makes an AD initiation more likely to occur. When this variable is evaluated in the post-crisis period, we find that the coefficient has been reduced in Argentina and Colombia and it remains the same in Brazil. Consequently, the crisis has not reinforced the relationship between an appreciation/devaluation on the probability of an initiation of an AD procedure. The coefficients on VS1 are negative in the case Colombia, but positive for Peru, Mexico and Brazil. A negative sign on this variable indicates that government favors global supply chains (Colombia) while a positive one could indicate that foreign exporters do not have political influence on the local economic policy. Besides, we can observe that the negative impact of VS1 in the propensity of initiating an AD was not reinforced after 2008 in Colombia. References Aggarwal, A. (2004). “Macro Economic Determinants of Antidumping: A Comparative Analysis of Developed and Developing Countries, World Development, vol. 32 (6): 1043- 1057. Baldwin, R. and S. Evenett (2009). The Collapse of Global Trade, Murky Protectionism, and the Crisis: Recommendations for the G20, A VoxEU.org Publication, Center for Economic Policy Research, London. Bchir, M. and S. Jean and D. Laborde (2005). “Binding Overhang and Tariff-Cutting Formulas”, CEPII Working Paper 18, October. Bown, C. P. (2011). ‘Introduction’, in C.P. Bown (Ed.) The Great Recession and Import Protection: The Role of Temporary Trade Barriers, London, CEPR and the World Bank. Bown, C. P. (2010a). “Taking Stock of Antidumping, Safeguards, and Countervailing Duties, 1990-2009”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 5436. Bown, C. P. (2010b). “Temporary Trade Barriers Database”, http://econ.worldbank.org/ttbd/. Brander, J. and B. Spencer (1984). Tariff protection and imperfect competition. In Monopolistic Competition and International Trade, H. Kierzkowski (Ed.), Oxford: Oxford University Press. Daudin, G., C. Rifflart and D. Schweisguth (2011). “Who Produces for Whom in the World Economy”, Canadian Journal of Economics, 44 (4): 1403-1437. Eichengreen, B. and K. O’Rourke (2009). “A Tale of Two Depressions”, http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/3421. Eichengreen, B. and D. Irwin (2009). “The Slide to Protectionism in The Great Depression: Who Succumbed and Why?”, NBER Working Paper No. 15142. Evenett, S. and M. Wermelinger (2010). “A Snapshot of contemporary protectionism: How important are the murkier forms of trade discrimination?”, Asia-Pacific Research and Training Network on Trade Working Paper Series, No. 83, September. Evenet, S. (2009). “What can be learned from crisis era protectionism? An initial assessment”, CEPR Discussion Paper Series No. 7494. Feinberg, R. (1989). “Exchange Rates and ‘Unfair Trade”, Review of Economics and Statistics, 71 (4): 704-707. Gawande, K., B. Hoekman and Y. Cui (2011). “Determinants of Trade Policy Responses to the 2008 Financial Crisis”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper number 5862. Gawande, K. and P. Krishna (2008). “The Political Economy of Trade Policy: Empirical Approaches”, in E. Choi and J. Harrigan Handbook of International Trade, Basil Blackwell: 213-250. Grossman, G., and E. Helpman (1994). “Protection for Sale”, American Economic Review, 84(4): 833-850. Jacobo, A. and I. Jalile (2012). “On the Macro and Micro Determinants of Protectionist Policy Instruments in Latin America: An Exploratory Note”, GTA-CEPR-LATN Joint Conference on Analyses of Contemporary Protectionism: Implications for Latin America, Lima, Perú, manuscript. Jørgensen, J. and P. Schröder (2006). “Tariffs and Firm-Level Heterogeneous Fixed Export Costs,” Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy 5(1): Article 18. Kee, H., I. Neagu, and A. Nicita (2010). “Is Protectionism on the Rise? Assessing National Trade Policies During the Crisis of 2008”, World Bank Working Paper No. 5274. Kee, H., A. Nicita, and M. Olarreaga (2008). “Import Demand Elasticities and Trade Distortions”, Review of Economics and Statistics, 90 (4): 666‐682. Knetter, M. and Prusa T. (2003). ‘Macroeconomic Factors and Antidumping Filings: Evidence from Four Countries’, Journal of International Economics, 61 (1): 1-17. Krugman, P. (1981). “Intra-industry Specialization and the Gains from Trade”, Journal of Political Economy, 89 (5): 959- 973. Hanson, G., R. Mataloni and M. Slaughter (2003). “Vertical Production Networks in Multinational Firms”, NBER Working Paper No. 9723. Hummels, D., J. Ishii, and K. Yi (2001). “The Nature and Growth of Vertical Specialization”, Journal of International Economics, 54 (1): 75-96. Olarreaga, M. and M. Vaillant (2011). “Micro and Macro Determinants of Trade Temporary Barriers: The Brazilian Case Over the Last Two Decades”, Departamento de Economía, Universidad de la República, Documento number 07/11. Prusa, T. and S. Skeath (2002). “The Economic and Strategic motives for Antidumping Filings”, Weltwirstchaliftches Archives, 138 (3): 389- 413. Rozemberg, R. and R. Gayá (2010). “Global Crisis and Trade Barriers in Latin America”, in S. Evenett (Editor) Managed Exports and the Recovery of World Trade: The 7th GTA Report. A Focus on Latin America, Center for Economic Policy Research. Sabry, F. (2000). “An Analysis of the Decision to File, the Dumping Estimates, and the Outcome of Antidumping Petition”, International Trade Journal, 14 (2): 109-145. Takacs, W. (1981). ‘Pressures for Protectionism: An Empirical Analysis’, Economic Inquiry, 19 (4): pp. 687-93. WTO (2009). Overview of Developments in the International Trading Environment, WT/TPR/OV/12. Appendix 0.3577 R2 *** *** *** 0.4537 225305 0.0944 -0.5107 *** 0.1855 4.5029 0.0891 *** 0.4189 520806 Yes Yes 0.1001 -23.5130 0.1689 17.6481 0.0353 1.2547 0.0011 BRA 0.2867 *** *** *** *** 0.963 391623 Yes Yes 0.0095 -0.0266 0.0113 0.1203 0.0062 0.0174 0.0001 *** *** *** CHL 0.2270 *** 0.3294 370479 Yes Yes 0.1308 -19.4677 0.1634 0.7665 0.0629 2.8131 0.0007 *** *** *** COL 0.1190 *** 0.5234 289586 Yes Yes 0.1905 -8.7163 0.0916 -5.5615 0.0891 1.5468 0.0014 0.0008 MEX 0.3006 *** 0.5614 631402 Yes Yes 0.1363 *** -42.9247 *** 0.0753 *** -13.7267 *** 0.0483 *** -0.3437 *** ECU 0.6062 *** *** *** 0.4527 147476 Yes Yes 0.2249 -21.3775 *** 0.2684 11.0866 0.1634 1.5567 0.0017 PRY 0.1838 *** 0.3448 270131 Yes Yes 0.1412 -20.6054 0.2945 15.1719 0.0675 2.5795 0.0016 *** *** *** PER 0.1411 *** Notes: (1) Dependent variable is applied tariff; (2) tBNDPRF is the bound rate augmented by preferential rate when applicable; (3) Standard errors in italics; (2) *** p<0.01; (3) Data pooled across 2002-2010. 405806 Yes Yes 0.1182 -10.4062 0.1151 10.7300 0.0519 1.3201 0.0010 *** 0.0013 1.6420 BOL 0.1820 *** ARG 0.2502 *** N Partner FE Year FE VS1 VS ITT tBNDPRF Table 6 0.3659 192941 Yes Yes 0.2216 -18.6735 0.1658 -15.3033 0.1756 1.1945 0.0018 *** *** *** VEN 0.2384 *** 0.4767 192591 Yes Yes 0.1792 1.0467 0.1344 -12.3440 0.1110 0.5585 0.0017 *** *** *** URY 0.2019 *** 405806 Yes Yes 0.3586 225305 Yes Yes 0.4764 0.2109 *** *** *** *** *** *** -13.8269 *** 0.4219 8.8649 0.2542 6.6616 0.0011 0.0544 0.1064 2.9715 0.2086 2.4029 0.2865 *** *** *** *** *** 0.0936 *** 2.4124 0.2933 -1.7366 0.1294 -1.2729 0.0021 0.0255 0.1309 -10.9265 0.1273 11.0759 0.0573 0.5260 0.0010 *** 0.0014 1.8771 BOL 0.1656 *** ARG 0.2436 *** 520806 Yes Yes 0.4270 0.2316 -15.8650 0.4024 23.2473 0.0840 -0.4936 0.0018 0.0655 0.1121 -20.0695 0.1890 12.5779 0.0392 1.3880 0.0011 BRA 0.2707 *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** 391623 Yes Yes 0.9631 0.0225 0.0142 0.0270 -0.2902 0.0143 0.0458 0.0003 0.0059 0.0108 -0.0309 0.0128 0.1829 0.0071 0.0067 0.0001 *** *** *** *** *** CHL 0.2262 *** 370479 Yes Yes 0.3302 0.2938 1.5520 0.3714 0.6947 0.1378 -1.0562 0.0012 0.0222 0.1503 -19.8583 0.1878 0.5570 0.0717 3.0861 0.0008 *** *** *** *** *** *** *** COL 0.1132 *** 289586 Yes Yes 0.5307 0.4636 -17.8188 0.2205 -4.8493 0.2165 2.9222 0.0030 0.0859 0.2109 -5.2596 0.1022 -4.6159 0.0983 0.9891 0.0015 -12.4735 MEX 0.3307 *** 0.1032 0.5272 *** 631402 Yes Yes 0.5677 0.2992 *** -12.4735 *** 0.1680 *** -6.6868 *** *** 0.0014 *** -0.1147 *** 0.1570 *** -39.6396 *** 0.0868 *** -11.9952 *** 0.0556 *** -0.4970 *** ECU 0.5923 *** *** *** 147476 Yes Yes 0.4530 0.5015 -1.0052 0.6060 4.6313 0.3619 -1.7024 0.0022 0.0030 0.2629 *** *** *** -21.1225 *** 0.3115 9.8869 0.1923 2.0249 0.0018 PRY 0.1829 *** 270131 Yes Yes 0.3550 0.3200 -0.7927 0.6754 1.2924 0.1460 -0.6157 0.0026 -0.1665 0.1603 -20.2187 0.3362 14.7202 0.0781 2.6949 0.0017 *** *** *** *** *** *** *** PER 0.1794 *** Notes: (1) Dependent variable is applied tariff; (2) tBNDPRF is the bound rate augmented by preferential rate when applicable; (3) Standard errors in italics; (2) *** p<0.01; (3) Data pooled across 2002-2010. N Partner FE Year FE R-squared VS1xI2009 VSxI2009 ITTxI2009 tBNDPRFxI2009 VS1 VS ITT tBNDPRF Table 7 192941 Yes Yes 0.3661 0.4520 -1.6839 0.3374 -2.5947 0.3578 0.6435 0.0022 -0.0008 0.2808 -18.0240 0.2108 -14.3017 0.2227 0.9515 0.0020 *** *** ** *** *** *** VEN 0.2385 *** 192591 Yes Yes 0.4769 0.4645 0.7554 0.3408 -2.4302 0.3072 -1.0154 0.0026 -0.0040 0.1969 0.9201 0.1473 -11.9119 0.1202 0.7137 0.0017 ** *** *** * *** *** *** URY 0.2027 *** *** 403587 Yes Yes Yes 0.3115 0.0548 225304 Yes Yes Yes 0.4330 0.1906 5.1084 *** 0.0815 -0.4264 -1.3989 *** 0.0275 0.0009 *** -0.0366 0.0009 0.0687 0.0009 *** 0.0008 0.0399 BOL 0.1940 *** ARG 0.3738 *** 520806 Yes Yes Yes 0.3337 0.0381 -0.0038 0.0196 0.0068 0.0008 0.0758 0.0009 BRA 0.3587 *** *** 391613 Yes Yes Yes 0.9629 0.0114 0.0295 0.0063 -0.0294 0.0002 0.0042 0.0001 *** *** *** CHL 0.2338 *** 370481 Yes Yes Yes 0.2576 0.0579 -0.0937 0.0315 -0.2291 0.0005 0.0202 0.0005 ** *** *** COL 0.1609 *** 289585 Yes Yes Yes 0.4788 0.1261 4.2240 0.0606 -0.8652 0.0017 0.2056 0.0013 0.0006 MEX 0.3939 *** *** 631358 Yes Yes Yes 0.4693 0.0651 0.6951 *** 0.0365 *** -0.3247 *** 0.0009 *** -0.1093 *** ECU 0.4568 *** 147469 Yes Yes Yes 0.3959 0.1882 -0.8320 0.1046 -0.5004 0.0012 0.0155 0.0012 *** *** *** PRY 0.3013 *** 270131 Yes Yes Yes 0.2334 0.0591 0.5684 0.0342 -0.1066 0.0010 -0.0323 0.0007 *** *** *** PER 0.2088 *** Notes: (1) Dependent variable is applied tariff; (2) tBNDPRF is the bound rate augmented by preferential rate when applicable; (3) Standard errors in italics; (2) *** p<0.01; (3) Data pooled across 2002-2010. N Partner FE Year FE Product R-squared ITTxI2009 ITT tBNDPRFxI2009 tBNDPRF Table 8 192932 Yes Yes Yes 0.2828 0.1639 0.7110 0.1228 0.1800 0.0011 -0.0098 0.0012 *** * *** VEN 0.2956 *** 192592 Yes Yes Yes 0.4215 0.1065 0.0697 0.0604 -0.3888 0.0009 0.0058 0.0012 *** *** URY 0.3601 *** Tabla 9 t ARG 0.0444 *** 0.0186 VS VS1 BRER 3.5078 BRA 0.1059 0.0178 *** 6.6032 1.1251 2.8009 -0.1454 3.5772 1.2038 1.6331 -1.5047 *** *** -2.2312 MEX 0.0229 *** 0.0042 *** 3.7400 *** 1.0817 *** 4.3331 COL 0.1379 *** PER 0.3377 0.0197 0.0441 12.3015 *** -5.6619 1.5355 2.2921 0.0231 -0.0048 0.0658 0.0030 *** 0.0000 0.0000 *** -64.5921 *** *** 2.4430 -13.7930 *** 7.8290 * -0.3534 *** 0.0000 *** -33.5240 Imports 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 Unit Values -0.0134 -14.0099 0.0240 7.2951 21.4922 46.7286 15.9726 -0.0089 -0.0033 -0.1069 0.0899 79.4899 0.0462 0.0894 0.1309 0.8666 -5.8989 -13.2480 0.5898 txI2009 0.0523 *** 0.0238 0.2891 0.0000 -178.3344 0.0000 VSxI2009 -5.4049 1.8031 17274.2700 4.7066 16.1521 VS1xI2009 0.2014 -1.5298 -4.7378 23.1958 1.9595 10344.7600 6.5183 6.0903 5.2855 ImportsxI2009 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0070 0.0000 0.0000 UnitValuesxI2009 -0.0146 -13.9624 -45.8221 143.9287 49282.1500 102.7704 60.4284 TCRBxI2009 1.2404 -0.1363 -0.5507 0.0025 0.4894 3340.1530 0.5213 0.0016 8014.6860 N Partner FE Year FE 148284 Yes Yes 125851 Yes Yes 159138 Yes Yes 53763 Yes Yes 80329 Yes Yes *** 0.0559 *** *** 2.0494 0.8672 *** *** 6.8371 0.5875 0.0000 *** *** 20.2175 *** 5.5488 0.0000 *** -57.3029 * -128.1398 81.2093 Notes: (1) Dependent variable is a binary variable indicating the presence of an AD initiations in a particualr HS 6 digit sector; (2) Standard errors in italics; (3) *** p<0.01. Tabla 10 BRA 0.1708 *** t ARG -0.0008 BRER -1.5824 0.5957 0.9227 Imports 0.0000 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 Unit Values -0.0052 -1.8700 0.0067 4.4753 *** -2.6676 PER 0.0525 COL 0.1780 0.0392 0.3083 0.1765 *** 0.0207 -0.0053 -0.3007 0.0783 0.0163 0.3135 *** 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0456 0.0303 MEX 0.1604 *** 0.0002 0.0001 -187.3616 -60.5449 25.4968 119.8994 32.2589 0.0000 -42.1161 *** ** 0.0358 -0.0409 -0.0397 -0.3475 0.0274 63.9757 0.0508 0.1889 0.1165 ImportsxI2009 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0001 0.0001 0.0000 0.0127 0.0000 UnitValuesxI2009 -0.0025 1.7309 -27.9655 TCRBxI2009 1.3088 N Partner FE Year FE Product FE txI2009 0.0563 *** 0.0002 195.9998 ** 0.0001 -74.6243 11457.6900 85.7151 116.4329 133.4613 0.2594 -0.5714 0.0024 -137.7459 0.5224 2865.8620 0.5071 0.0239 12943.3900 11831 Yes Yes Yes 5644 Yes Yes Yes 6911 Yes Yes Yes 5604 Yes Yes Yes 1487 Yes Yes Yes 0.0349 *** *** Notes: (1) Dependent variable is a binary variable indicating the presence of an AD initiations in a particualr HS 6 digit sector; (2) Standard errors in italics; (3) *** p<0.01.