EO I. Introduction to Organization in Firms A. Introduction 1. 6 Basic Concepts: a. Risk v. control: As one ascends, the other descends, and vice-versa. The idea here is, with greater risk comes greater possibility of big success. But with EO, big success can only be had by ultimately relying on others. Hence the loss in control. On the other hand, too much control shuts out lots of options. b. Form over substance: There’s legal fiction, everywhere. c. Corporations are all about people. d. Money and markets matter (to whom is management responsible). e. Rules re: corporate law are passed by legislatures. With that in mind, ask yourself, “Who is supposed to benefit, and are the results of these laws optimal?” Another important question to ask is how do people set up enterprises given the rules under which they must operate? Rules really do matter. A final question to ask is when (and/or if) private arrangements should give in to public concerns. f. Last, but certainly not least: planning by lawyers is important. Figure out the rules, and draft wisely! You will avoid many potential pitfalls. 2. a. 1) 2) 3) Powers, Gain Why read it? It’s all about how people make companies. There are several instances of the risk/control interplay. It’s a good examination of the thoughts behind the corporate process. b. The three phases: 1) The Entrepreneur: Clare. a) Needs backers. The limitations of control. b) Hard to find investors. c) Could get a loan, but that’s really risky. d) What about shareholders? Note: When a company dissolves, all remaining assets are first used to pay off any debt. Whatever is left then goes to shareholders. Shareholders are therefore allocating some of the risk (but are also taking some of the control). Hmm, this looks like one situation where a higher risk for the entrepreneur may allow for greater control. 2) The Partnership: Clare’s sons and Innis. 1 a) Less control for the sons, since they allocate control to Innis. On the other hand, they have greater control of the market. b) At the same time, there is less risk, since the partnership controls the manufacturing, as well as the merchandising. On the other hand, with a bigger structure, there’s more room for trouble. 3) The Corporation: The End. a) Continuance - Corporations are the modern transmitter. b) Less risk #1 - protected by the government. c) Less risk #2 - Limited liability. d) Beware: Control problems can sneak back in here. Consider that the pursuit of profit is overshadowed by the pursuit of steady growth. Board of directors symbolizes this loss of freedom. e) Another problem exists in the alienation of control from the means of production and marketing. c. Two final points: 1) Corporate law is only a small part of the story. Fed securities law trumps corporate law. Don’t ignore it, just the same. 2) Freeze-outs. Common in smaller companies, this is where larger shareholders force smaller shareholders out. To avoid this, plan carefully. Most common and statutory law will also help, since we wish to protect investors (and investing). B. Agency Principles 1. Cases a. Humble Oil Refining Co. v. Martin Facts: Car roles away, hitting P. Gas attendant was negligent. P claims that D is liable, since attendant was an agent of D. D claims that attendant was really an independent contract, and that D therefore isn’t liable. Holding, Reasoning: The big question is whether D controlled the attendant. This court finds D did. Court bases its opinion on several factors: D provided the equipment D established the hours of operation D managed the operating costs The station only sold D’s products Other stuff b. Hoover v. Sun Oil Facts: Similar to Humble, but here negligent gas pumping caused a fire Holding, Reasoning: Court determines attendant is an independent contractor. The attendant: Controls hours Gets advice, not comands Rent (?) Controls compensation. The attendant has “the overall risk of profit and loss.” 2 No written reports between parties. Either party may terminate @ will. c. Question: Are these cases really that different? 1) These difference look substantial in form, only. For example, the “advice” given in Hoover could also conceal threats which would be just as coercive as the commands in Humble. It would seem the rule is just play the game, and make it look right. 2) Perhaps there is a policy rule here. Ask yourself, which party would best be able to control risk? This would still lead to gray areas, but provides a nice simple question in place of reliance on formalities. 3) Note the trade-off: greater control may be economically sound, but it may increase liability (although it may also decrease negligent behavior). Consider which of these two costs more: bonding costs, or insurance premiums. d. Gay Jenson Farms Co. v. Cargill, Inc. Facts: Warren gets line of credit from Cargill to sell grains. Hill sells grain to Cargill, which pays off line of credit. Warren goes out of business. Holding, Reasoning: The big question is, was there a special relationship between Cargill and Warren that would make the former responsible for the latter’s problems? The court decides that there is. Note: Professor West notes two factors that should make us suspicious are the increasing line of credit and the “strong paternal guidance.” In considering the first factor, a good question to ask is would an independent interest really behave in this manner. It’s a comparative question, but even with little empirical data, it would seem Cargill’s behavior indicated too great a concern with Warren’s well-being to indicate an arm’s length relationship. On the other hand, perhaps Cargill just has a stupid loan officer. Even though the loan officer is definitely an agent of Cargill’s, would that connect the two companies? As for the latter, this court list several sub-factors in determining Cargill’s relationship. We’ll indicate the factors Professor West deems truly important. The court rules that Cargill assumed control of Warren’s business, using the Restatement (Second) of Agency and a practical laundry list to draw this conclusion. Note: The Restatement is really more about the actions of the two parties, and less about the contract between them. The laundry list: 1) Cargill’s constant recommendations to Warren by telephone. Too ambiguous to be really important. 2) Cargill’s right of first refusal on grain. Not important, either. Why not? 3) Warren’s inability to enter into mortgages, to purchase stock or to pay dividends without Cargill’s approval. Hey, isn’t this a traditional lender requirement? That it is, but the court recognizes this, considering such a factor only “in light of all the circumstances surrounding Cargill’s aggressive financing of Warren.” Are there any other factors that stand on their own? 3 4) Cargill’s right of entry onto Warren’s premises to carry on periodic checks and audits. Same as #3. 5) Cargill’s correspondences and criticism regarding Warren’s finances, officers salaries and inventory. Same as #3. 6) Cargill’s determination that Warren needed “strong paternal guidance”. This is an observation; whether it was acted upon is another matter. 7) Provision of drafts and forms to Warren upon which Cargill’s name was imprinted. That’s something, but not enough on its own. 8) Financing of all Warren’s purchases of grain and operating expenses. Same as #3. 9) Cargill’s power to discontinue the financing of Warren’s operations. Same as #3. All of these factors seem pretty weak, or at least they don’t indicate how an agency relationship is any different from a lending relationship. Certainly we don’t want to lump them all together; that would seriously deter lending. Here are some other factors which indicate an agency relationship: 1) Cargill contacted Warren’s customers and notified them that Warren’s checks were good. What gives them that authority? 2) Cargill’s supervision of the elevator. 3) This was a jury trial. Was their finding of an agency relationship clearly erroneous? Probably not. There’s enough reason to believe the jury’s finding. 2. The Five Types of Agency a. Actual express agency. P (the principal) authorizes A (the agent) to negotiate with third party (T). A acts accordingly. b. Actual implied agency. P can’t think of everything A has to do. So, P will tell A “do what you need to get the job done.” A is therefore acting for P, even if P wasn’t completely specific on all A must do. However, A is limited by standards of reasonableness (like industry standards, for instance) and legality. Is that circular? If the behavior was illegal, then P isn’t responsible, but the only proof is the assumption that P would never implicitly require illegal behavior of A. I guess the way out of this is asking whether P’s request really was implicit. c. Apparent authority. P notifies T of A’s right to deal. Even if A doesn’t know of authority, T thinks A has it. Unlike express and implied agency, the communication goes from principal to 3rd party. Communication has to come directly from the principal. Manifestation of agency can come through agent to 3rd party. Could be actual, if P and A had actually communicated. Can also be non-actual: P notifies T. P also notifies A, but with provision to call P first. A contacts T without calling P. A has apparent authority even though A breached an agent relationship with P. What this means: Draft your authorizations carefully, or don’t tell T that you’re bound by A. 4 Note: Both P and T can enforce any apparent authority arrangements. d. Ratification. By enforcing contract, P ratifies it. This is true even where A arranged an unauthorized contract. e. Inherent Agency Power P tells A to do x. Mistakenly, A does y. Respondeat superior - P should pay for A’s torts. While unauthorized, A’s actions resemble what P has authorized A to do. 3. Hypo: Paula, Amy and Tom P tells A to hire a camera person – express authority to hire, implied authority to take care of contract details T wants a job as a camera person, asks P. P hates T, says, “I’d love to work with you, but A is doing hiring.” P tells A, under no circumstances hire T. A talks with T, T convinces A to hire him. A hires T. P fires A, but loses in court when she refuses to honor the K because A had apparent authority. Twist 1: Manifestation that A is doing hiring comes through agent of P. A still has apparent authority. Manifestation can come through an agent (here, secretary). Twist 2: A tells T that she has authority to hire. T did not hear this from P. Might have case for apparent authority. Difficulty: A leaves out that she does not have authority to hire T. Twist 3: P has a good reputation for making family films. Decides to do a racier film. Asks sleazy director Alice to do everything as if she’s the sole producer, but not to let anyone know that it was her behind it. Only other stipulation: don’t hire T. A hires T. P fires A. T sues P. P is liable, should be careful in choosing agents. Twist 4: A hires T, tells P. P says, “I told you not to hire him.” A apologizes. P says, “fine, I’ll go along with it.” K ratified by P. 4. More Cases a. Lind v. Schenley Industries, Inc. (p. 30) [Seinfeld-esque?] Facts: Herrfeldt (VP of Park) tells Lind that Kaufman would inform him of the details of his compensation. Kaufman told L he would get 1% of the gross sales of the men under him. Kaufman had no authority to set salaries – only the president did – and the president did not authorize the compensation Kaufman offered L. Holding, Reasoning: Park was liable under a theory of apparent authority. Restatement defines apparent authority as “[T]he power to affect the legal relations of another person by transactions with third persons, professedly as agent for the other, arising from and in accordance with the other’s manifestations to such third persons.” Court goes on to consider the manifestations: 5 K’s power to set salaries. Kaufman only has authority to offer commission if it’s close to salary company would normally offer. Apparent authority depends on 3rd person believing it would be reasonable. The commission would have quadrupled L’s salary. This isn’t really reasonable. If L was really concerned, why didn’t L hold off for years before saying something. K was “the boss.” Reasonableness is the big issue. The longer the contract, the greater the responsibility of employee to determine its reasonableness. Note: How could this have been avoided? By L? L could have asked for the K in writing, gone to H to approve it. By Park (the company)? Park could have had an employee manual, rule about approving commissions or new salaries that increase your compensation by more than a particular percent. These do not avoid inherent agency, agency manifested by A. P’s safeguards against A really only work if A is an honest A, or if A couldn’t claim ambiguity in P’s communication. b. Watteau v. Fenwick (p. 43) Facts: Humble’s (A) beerhouse was bought out by a firm of brewers (Watteau, et al. - P). A remains as manager, his name is over the door. P tells A to buy all his needs (except bottled ales and mineral water) from P. A buys cigars, bovril and other articles and didn’t pay up. Issue: Does P owe anything to T? What sort of agency are we considering? No manifestation by P (principal) to T no apparent agency. No express authority by P to A no actual (or implied) authority. Holding, Reasoning: Inherent agency power applies here since the 3rd party could perceive the sale as being within the scope of H’s duties. Doesn’t matter that principal is undisclosed. Why should principal be responsible for agent’s acts? Principal is the best equipped to know the agent hired and to guard against poor business practice by agent. c. Bacroft-Whitney v. Glen (p. 58) Facts: Glen’s “sins”: personally recruited B-W employees assisted recruitment (by supplying picture) and strategizing misled LCP as to whether he would help thwart a raid (see fn.7, p. 61) gives MB salary information Holding, Reasoning: (p. 65) – Guth v. Loft: “Corporate officers and directors are not permitted to use their positions of trust and confidence to further their private interests. While technically not trustees, they stand in a fiduciary relation to the corporation and its stockholders.” 6 Hypo: AFoster invited by competitor law firm to open new branch office and bring some good people with her. What can she do? Fellow associates? Real world answer: practice of recruiting others is very common (more so peers than subordinates?) What about recruiting clients? Not allowed, but this actually happens even more commonly than recruiting associates. Can’t recruit clients before leaving. Underhanded stuff happens. Explicit recruiting would be a breach of fiduciary responsibility. Watch out for confidentiality and conflict of interest situations. The Restatement allows for liability for breaking contract, but an attorney isn’t on contract. Safe harbor approach – announce you’re leaving first, drop hints later e. Town & Country House & Home Service, Inc. v. Newberry (p. 71) Facts: T&C cleaned houses, s are their former employees. s left to open their own home-cleaning business, enticed away clients of T&C. Holding, Reasoning: This court treats the case as a client list which is a trade secret. Prof. W: Case is really about implicit application of the duty of loyalty. Just because your employment has ended doesn’t mean your duty of loyalty is over. Different from law firm situation. Lawyers often call up old clients after leaving one firm for another. Generally, this is not seen as breaching a duty of loyalty. Why? Courts make distinction between legal services and cleaning services. Should they? Both involve a degree of trust between client and service-provider. C. Partnership 1. The Framework. a. Distinguishing factors (Note: Form over Substance re: distinctions from corporations). taxes partnership doesn’t pay taxes partners report gain/loss on individual returns liability unlimited transferability of non-transferable interest life limited life corporation pays taxes twice – (1) by corporation and (2) by shareholders on dividends Special tax rules: corporation can elect to be taxed as an SCorporation. Need less than 35 shareholders with one state of residence; shareholders then pay tax on individual returns Corporations can get special expenses – lunch, travel, etc. – treated specially. State taxes too – incl. franchise taxes (just to be registered as a corporation in the state) limited shares may be transferred unlimited life 7 flexibility more flexible centralized management could provide for a centralized management structure expenses less flexible, standardized, have by-laws, etc. But, can structure agreements/corporate docs to be more flexible has board of directors, CEO, power structure added costs: tax returns (accountants charge more), incorporation fees b. Limited partnership – one partner or more is a limited partner, enjoys same status as shareholder; other partners are general partners Don’t need to register with any government authority in order to become a partnership. Just start acting like one – *share profits, *share control. Can become partners whether you want to or not. Don’t need a formal agreement. However, to become a corporation, need to register/apply with the Secretary of State. c. Hypo: 1) Scenario: Clinton and Yeltsin resign and decide to go into business together, open a Stucky’s in the South. Both are wealthy and want to protect their assets. The firm is small, don’t want to spend their own money, go for loans. But bank will probably ask them to vouch for their loans with their personal funds. 2) Liability? Partnership - If there are 5 investors and one wants to run the business while the others sit back. Bank might be satisfied with only the active people securing the loans. May be able to get insurance to cover liability. Limited Partnership - Protects assets, and limited partners are very limited in liability. 3) Transferability - Want transferability of interest corporation Stock of closed (smaller) corporations are easily transferable. Can use stock repurchase agreement to restrict movement of shares. Partnership – new partners admitted only on vote of existing partners. Partners can decide that the vote need not be unanimous. 4) Duration - Theoretically, a corporation has an unlimited life while a partnership does not. In theory, whenever a partner dies, the partnership dies as well and other partners have to reconvene and vote to re-enter the partnership. Starting 50 years ago, courts allowed partnerships to make rules that the death of a partner doesn’t end the partnership. 5) Flexibility - Generally less with corporations (by-laws and such). 6) Overall - you can manipulate surrounding to achieve results either way. 8 d. Another alternative - Limited liability corporation (LLC). Tax treatment as partnership, everything else is like a corporation. 2. What Makes a Partnership a. Excerpts from the Uniform Partnership Act Section 6 - Partnership is an association of two or more persons to carry on as co-owners a business for profit. Must conform with rest of act. Section 7 - Sharing of property does not of itself establish a partnership. Neither does sharing of gross revenue. Profit sharing is primie facie evidence of a partnership, unless such profits are received in payment: as a debt as wages or rent as an annuity as interest of on a loan as the consideration for the sale of a good-will of a business. Section 9 - Carrying on business as if the business was a partnership binds the partnership, unless partner A has no such authority, and partner B knows A has no such authority. Also, the partners’ acts must apparently be for the carrying on of business to be binding, and mustn’t contravene a restriction established in the partnership. Section 13 - If A fucks up, all partners are liable. Section 14 - Clarifies partners’ liability. Section 15 - Further clarifies partners’ liability. Section 16 - If A claims to be a partner of B’s to X, and X acts in reliance to this claim, A is liable to X. b. Application 1) Scenario: Sarah, Sam’s daughter, goes to work for Sam. Sam says no to partnership, but pays her $20/week and 20% of profits. Time goes by. Sam occasionally pays bills addressed to “Spade and Spade”. Sam takes to drinking, gets in trouble with creditors, promises good things for Sarah if she helps him out, and Sarah pays some bills with her own funds. Sarah eventually leaves, but wants a share of Sam’s supposed ill-gotten gains that should have gone to the business. 2) Is Sarah a partner? Is Sarah a partner when she walks in the door? Do Sarah and Sam share both profits and control? UPA § 6. Partnership Defined Some profit sharing. But no sharing of control. No partnership 9 See also UPA § 7(4) – sharing profits as a way of paying an employee is not even prima facie evidence of partnership Later Sam tells Sarah to pay off creditors and says “we’ll work together.” Once Sarah starts paying the bills she’s entitled to profits and control. (a) What share of profits is Sarah entitled to? At least 20% – based on employment agreement Maybe 50% – If Sarah and Sam are now partners without an agreement, UPA default position is 50-50 split of profits. UPA § 18 (p. 86): “subject to any agreement between them… All partners have equal rights in the management and conduct of the partnership business.” Maybe 60% – 20% as wage plus 50% of leftover profits (ex: total revenue = $100; $100 – $20 = $80; ½ x $80 = $40; $20 + $40 = $60) (b) Does Sarah have to pay creditors’ bills where they were sent to Spade & Spade? Is there apparent agency? Then, yes.(?) Weaker case for liability for non-Spade & Spade bills. (c) Is Sarah responsible for Sam’s liquor bills? No. UPA § 9(1) – every partner is an agent of the partnership If liquor is an intrinsic part of the business, then she is responsible for the liquor debts. Sam misapplies funds – takes from client funds to buy liquor – UPA § 13: wrongful act partnership is liable; UPA § 14: misapplication of funds partnership must make good. 3. Cases a. Fenwick v. Unemployment Compensation Commission (p. 82) Facts: Mrs. Chesire was hired as a receptionist. After working for about a year, requests raise. Fenwick says he can’t afford to give her a raise but offers to make her a partner, giving her 20% of the profits at year’s end. Fenwick maintains all control, Mrs. C. doesn’t share in losses. Holding, Reasoning: Court finds C is an employee, using an eight-part test. 1) Intent of parties - Appears to be, but court rules intent isn’t enough. 2) Right to share in profits - Yes, but this point is not conclusive. 3) Obligation to share in losses - No. Prof.: sharing losses doesn’t matter, only sharing profits. 4) Ownership and control of the property - Fenwick had it all. 5) “Community of power in administration” - Precluded by Fenwick’s control. 6) Language - Specifically calls it a partnership, but court looks at “substantive” factors. 7) Conduct towards third-parties - Certainly acted like employer-employee. 8) Right to dissolution - In this case, no different than terminating employment. Note: How could Fenwick and Mrs. C. be partners but still let Fenwick maintain all control? Possibilities: 10 Make it look like she has some responsibilities (ex: Mrs. C. is in charge of reception – may not be enough for a court) Write in provisions for conferring and voting (ex: giving Fenwick a majority share of votes or giving him veto power with obligation to hear her out) Bring in more partners who are loyal to Fenwick (ex: his wife) b. Meinhard v. Salmon (p. 106) [J. Cardozo] Facts: Co-adventurers in the 20-year lease and renovation of a hotel (shops and offices). At lease’s end, building owner offers new lease with new terms to Salmon. Salmon takes offer for himself, not for partnership with Meinhard. Holding, Reasoning: Cardozo finds for Meinhard. Does it make a difference that in the course of the lease property values have skyrocketed (Grand Central was built a few blocks away)? Meinhard has profited substantially from Salmon’s deal. Why should Salmon be allowed to take this opportunity and the additional profit for himself? “Not honesty alone, but the punctilio of an honor the most sensitive, is then the standard of behavior” (p. 107) “Salmon put himself in a position in which thought of self was to be renounced, however hard the abnegation.” (p. 109) What would have satisfied Cardozo? Maybe just informing Meinhard of the opportunity. West hates this case, but I like it because it seems likely that the chilling effects of withholding information between partners would overshadow any benefits of allowing such behavior (like maybe efficiency). Cardozo’s a windbag, but a clever windbag. 4. Raising additional capital (pp. 128-30) a. Context: Restructuring companies going bad, doing M&A, creating companies. Applies to both partnerships and corporations. Ex: 40 people in a partnership 40 x $25,000 = $1,000,000 $9,000,000 $10,000,000 equity collected for business bank loans = debt total collected for project When the $ runs out, the property is worth $9,000,000. If we sell now, just pay debt, partners get no return on investment. If we finish the project, need to raise $500,000. Then property is worth $10,000,000 people get at least some of their investment back. Point system – analogous to shares of stock 40 partners x 25 pts. = 1,000 pts. b. How to raise capital: 1) Ask for it from everyone. Problem: no one is obligated to put $ in free-riding classic prisoner’s dillema: I lend I don’t lend 11 my equity my loan $12.5k $12.5k equity cash $12.5k $12.5k 2) Pro rata dilution Partnership issues more points. If you don’t pay, you’re share will be reduced. 500 pts. x $1,000 = $500,000 1,000 pts. [old] + 500 pts. [new] = 1,500 pts. Property value = $1,000,000 Pt. value = $1,000,000/1,500 pts = $666.66/pt. buy new points don’t buy new points equity equity 25 [old] +25 [new] 25 pts. at $666 = 50 pts. at $666 = $16,666 + $25k in cash =$33,333 = $41,666 3) Penalty dilution Sell new points: $250/pt. x 2,000 pts. = $500,000 1,000 pts. [old] + 2,000 pts. [new] = 3,000 pts. $1,000,000/3,000 pts. = $333/pt. Advantage: You spend $250 to get $333. If you don’t buy, someone else can buy your points and your share of the partnership ends up getting diluted. This can be abused by partners doing this only when they know you don’t have cash 4) Managing partner can sell new partnership shares to anyone at whatever price can be obtained. 5) Recap a) Loans (of $12.5k each) – free-riding problems b) Pro rata dilution (sell 500 new points for $1,000 each to get shares worth $667) (not a good deal, don’t buy, hope others do… on the other hand, value can rise) c) General partner pays/guarantees d) Penalty dilution (sell 2,000 new shares at a discount for $250 each, get shares worth $333) (good deal, buy) – some may not agree to this in advance since they fear that new shares will be sold when they can’t afford to buy them e) Pro rata loans (cap/no cap) f) Additional points to new investors (similar to corporate solution of selling shares) 5. Breach of fiduciary duty a. Bohatch v. Butler & Binion (Supp. pp. 3-14) Facts: Bohatch is an attorney and partner in B&B who reports that McDonald, a managing partner is overcharging a client. She reports him but no overcharging is found. In fact, the firm and client find that Bohatch’s work was unsatisfactory. The firm suggests that Bohatch leave and pays her in the meantime. She leaves and the firm expels her as a partner. 12 Holding, Reasoning: Court finds for D. No whistleblower exception exists for severing a partnership, even a good faith whistleblower. Partnerships exist by the agreement of the partners; partners have no duty to remain partners. Dissent: We should not discourage whistleblower activity b. What is fiduciary duty? Stems from agency – agent of a principal, agent of a corporation you’re an officer or director of, agent of a partnership you’re a partner of duty to play nice, do what you’re told duty of trust – comply with wishes of principal See Day v. Sidley & Austin c. Cases 1) Day v. Sidley & Austin (p. 135) Facts: Day ran the Washington, D.C. office of S&A. S&A merged with another law firm, the Liebman firm. Day approved of the merger along with the other S&A partners, but then got his ego severely bruised when he found out he would no longer be the “sole partner” at the Washington office, but rather co-chair. Day resigned and sued for breach of fiduciary duty. Background info: There was a culture clash between firms. Day got the job through his father-in-law, Burgess who was on the executive committee. By the time the merger occurred, Burgess was dead. Holding, Reasoning: Issue one: was the termination all right? Answer: yes. For this partnership, a unanimous vote wasn’t necessary. Fn.8 (p. 138) – executive committee will make major decisions, some subject to partners approval/ratification; majority is according to percentage of partnership interest, not of partners. Issue two: what are the fiduciary duties in this case? Fiduciary duties (pp. 139-40) The essence of fiduciary duty - a partner must not advantage himself at the expense of the firm Curtails reach of Meinhard v. Salmon. Basic fiduciary duties (1) account for profit acquired in a manner injurious to the interests of the partnership (2) not to acquire a partnership asset or use a partnership opportunity without consent of other partners (3) not to compete with the partnership in the scope of business Problems (p. 142) #2 Did S&A have a sensible system of control? Where you have a lot of partners, it makes sense to have an executive committee. #3 What should Day have done to protect himself? Sign a contract naming him the sole Washington office chairman; amend partnership agreement; get named to executive 13 committee; get buyout agreement to benefit him if pushed out of the chairmanship or voluntarily leaves (unlikely to get). What you can get depends highly on how much power the particular partner has. Note: Technically, when a partner leaves a firm, the partnership dissolves. The partner can then “cash out” her draw and whatever interest she may have. In real life, partnerships like law firms automatically renew. 2) Page v. Page (p. 155) Facts: Dissolution. -H.B Page and -George Page are brothers and partners. ’s corporation has a loan out to the partnership. Partnership hasn’t been doing well, now starting to show profit. wants out. claims bad faith/violation of fiduciary duty. Holding, Reasoning: Court finds none. If no specific term mentioned in partnership agreement, partnership is at-will. Problems #1 If wants to buy assets of partnership and continue business with new partner, what does he have to do? should inform of opportunity (Meinhard v. Salmon), have an auction, have assets appraised and offer half to . If it’s in good faith, it’s OK. #2 Suppose wants to liquidate business and pick up its better accounts through his corporation. How should he go about doing so? Set up a buy-sell agreement. (?) 3) Lawlis v. Kightlinger & Gray (p. 168) Facts: Alcoholic attorney admits problem to firm and is given opportunity to get better and would then be returned to full partnership. After one setback and another opportunity, Lawlis is better. After working for a while, requests to have his partnership share increased. The next day, Lawlis is told that he will be expelled from the partnership. Holding, Reasoning: Issue #1: Lawlis claims that he was let go in order to achieve the partners’ goal of improving the partner-associate ratio. Court does not find this claim to have merit. Issue #2: Lawlis claims he was wrongfully expelled, since he should be expelled by a 2/3 vote, not announcement of one partner. He says he was still a voting member afterwards. Court says that the partner informing him was not a unilateral act, but just a warning. Note: Did the firm do the right thing? The firm owes a duty to its clients, but what about its duty to Lawlis? Could have booted Lawlis after he relapsed the first time. That condition was not met, so they had no responsibility to restore him to his previous position. The rule to be learned from all this is that fiduciary duties may be specified in a contract. Problems #1 What result if fired when they first discovered his alcoholism? #2 What result if fired in August ’84? 14 Answer to both: These are trick questions. It really doesn’t matter. They’re being very generous. #3 What would a client have wanted the firm to do? Keep him, but not on my case. Questions: Should the bar have a flat rule ordering alcoholics to be expelled from firms? ordering firms to disclose attorney’s alcoholism to clients? Privacy issues. Does it impact on how the job is done? Does this create a chilling effect on alcoholics who are considering disclosure and seeking help? 6. Providing for a Break-up: Buy-Out/ Buy-Sell Agreements (p. 175) a. Prof: When structuring deals, lawyers should always advise clients to have a buyout agreement. Not having them is almost legal malpractice.. b. 2 types: 1) Right to sell to others of your choosing 2) Right to force partnership to buy your share. This one is good for getting out without having to find a new person. c. Hypo 1) David Silver and Valerie Mallone decide to start a chain of Peach Pit nightclubs, want to start a company called Peach Pit, Inc. 2) Obligation to buy – If Valerie is concerned that David may sell stock to someone she doesn’t trust right of first refusal. 3) Veto right - Can also handle the problem in #2. It may also be too harsh, leaving both parties with unsellable stock. 4) Valerie may want the right to force David or Peach Pit, Inc. to buy her stock. Might use it to extort interests, hold out for concessions. Securities laws and closed corporations statutes may require certain types of stock transfers. 5) Advancing estate planning – upon death of investor, remaining investors want to make sure that stock doesn’t pass on to unwanted investors; want to reduce taxes on own estate 6) Price – market value is easier to know where the stock is commonly traded; for closely-held investments, it’s more difficult to tell what each side’s investment is worth. Most common way to determine price is to hire an appraiser. There’s still an issue of who to hire, so often there are provisions for that (ex: each side hires their own appraiser, if they don’t agree, take average). Can also use formulas (ex: cash flow figures and multiplier), book value (doesn’t change even though outside investors may be more or less attracted to invest), set price (the other party can chose to sell his share or buy yours, 15 so you have an incentive to pick a number close to market price; only useful where both sides have sufficient funds), or propose a buy-out agreement. 7. Limited Partnerships a. Holzman v. De Escamilla (p. 186) Facts: 1 general partner and 2 limited partners. General partner = manager, limited for partnership debts Limited partner = not liable for partnership debts Holding, Reasoning: The court finds that the 2 limited partners are in effect general partners (so that a creditor can get debts repaid by them)? The 2 had control over the partnership’s money, forced the g.p. to resign and selected his successor, actively dictated which crops to plant and overruled g.p.’s choice of crops Rule: If you share profits and control, you are a general partner. b. RULPA* § 303(a): A limited partner who participates in control is liable “only to persons who transact business with the limited partnership reasonably believing, based upon the limited partner’s conduct, that the limited partner is a general partner.” c. More notes: Limited partnership is a liability device for the limited partner, control device for the general partner. Need at least one general partner who is liable for the firms debts. Note that the general partner can be a corporation (whose shareholders have limited liability) or other entity. A. Corporations 1. a. 1) 2) 3) 4) The Players Shareholders Shareholders get percentage of profits (or loss) via share value. Shareholders also get a residual (after buying creditors off if company closes down). Shareholders also get dividends. The number of shareholders changes the amount of risk and control. b. Officers 1) Can sign for the company, thus binding it. 2) Handle the day-to-day operations of the company. c. 1) 2) 3) 4) * Directors Elected by shareholders. Vote on major decisions. Liable for failing duties. Officers will put forth slate of directors for shareholders to vote on. Revised Uniform Limited Partnership Act 16 d. Note: Regarding agency, none of these three groups necessarily entails one is always either an agent or a player. 2. Incorporation a. Starting Up - De jure 1) articles of incorporation – name, address, purpose of corporation (sometimes any legal purpose), type(s) of stock. 2) bylaws (procedural items on how to run the company) – supermajority votes needed for certain decisions, notice of meeting (what kind, how often), how amended (by directors or shareholders). 3) You’re a partnership so long as you act like one. But, to be a corporation, you need a certificate of incorporation from a particular state. To certify, complete 1) and call up CT Corp = a company that files your articles of incorporation, can receive process in the jurisdiction you incorporate in. 4) CT sends forms. 5) Fill out forms, and send in with 1). 6) While waiting for certification, draft by-laws. 7) When you get the certificate of incorporation, you have a meeting of incorporators (even just one person) to elect directors who will appoint officers and sell stock 8) Some other processes that may be required in order to incorporate: clear the corporation name register with Securities and Exchange Commission – if you want to issue your stock to a large number of persons, sell it on the stock exchange or just have a lot of money involved b. Delaware 1) Most incorporation happens in Delaware. Probably 90% of Fortune 500 companies register there. Why? better corporation code, e.g., favorable tax treatment every else is doing it (don’t let competitors get marginal advantage, no loss of prestige) rules are clear, already in place, clear legal precedents, courts and attorneys are experts in corporate law, state dedicated to helping corporations changes to DE code require 2/3 vote of legislature – rules won’t be changed easily 2) Is this good or bad? 17 Bad – creates race to the bottom as states lower their requirements for incorporation, lowering liability to unconscionable levels, erosion of corporate duty Good – creates race to the top, enticement to managers to run companies to their fullest, unconcerned about unnecessary restraints of corporate law = Ongoing concern in an era of international incorporation. c. p. 189 – Old Dominion Hypos 1) Promoter = Any person who sets up a commercial venture [not an exam question promoters and pre-incorporation liability much of a focus in this course] A promoter falls under the general principles of agency law, end up incurring fiduciary liability. 2) Case 1 Ann buys land for $125k, sells to Sean for $200k. Does Ann get to keep $75k profit? Sure, unless she committed fraud or misrepresentation. She doesn’t have to volunteer the information (even if asked), just can’t lie about it. 3) Case 2 Paula asks Art to represent her in purchase of land. Art owns land already, purchased for $125k. Art sells it to Paula for $200k without revealing his interest in the transaction. He could have sold it to someone else for $195k. Art must disgorge the $75k profit. No disclosure to or ratification by principal, agent can’t keep profit. REST. § 388: “Unless otherwise agreed, an agent who makes a profit in connection with transactions conducted by him on behalf of the principal is under a duty to give such profit to the principal.” 4) Case 3 No difference between this case and Case 2, except a corporation is the principal and P is the president of the principal. Paula doesn’t have an action in her individual capacity against Art. 5) Case 4 Promoter sales P and A decide that there will be a checklist of points that must happen in order to complete the transaction. a) A forms corporation, C Corp. A sells C stock to P. A sells property to C for $200k. A must disgorge profit because as a promoter, he owes a fiduciary obligation to the corporation, like that of an agent to a principal (like in case 2). Same result: P has all shares of C, C owns property, A has the $ b) A sells property to P for $200k. P forms C Corp. 18 P sells/invests property to C. A has no duty to disgorge – no agency, no fiduciary duty. c) A forms C Corp. A sells property into his own corporation. A sells stock to P. ? = Form over substance. Same practical results, but different mechanisms yield different protection for parties. d. 2 additional ways to become a corporation besides properly filing forms 1) Corporation de facto – found by court where organizers a) try in good faith to incorporate b) had a legal right to do so c) acted as a corporation 2) Corporation by estoppel – found by court where person dealing with firm a) though it was a corporation all along b) would get a windfall if firm was not a corporation 3. Limited Liability - Piercing the Corporate Veil a. General Rule Corporation is liable for its own debts. A corporation is a person with a capital “P” (definition usually includes artificial persons). General principle of limited liability is that you can only lose as much as you put in. Can’t normally go after directors, shareholders and officers. b. When we pierce: Observe these 3 general rules: 1) If you observe the formalities of corporate life, you’re generally safe. Respect the separate existence of the corporation (separate bank accounts, records, etc.), avoid unity of interest. 2) If the formalities have been observed, shareholders and directors may be liable for fraudulent conveyance or improper dividends, but the liability is only for the amount paid out and not the full amount. If a corporation doesn’t have enough money to issue dividends, it shouldn’t be distributing dividends. Ex: Corporation A has $1,000 in the bank and 100 shareholders A spends $950 on office equipment, decides to authorize $1@shareholder in dividends. If the creditor says, you can’t issue that since you owe us money, you hand over what you have. If you already paid out, you are only liable up to the $100. 19 3) If the separate existence of the corporation has not been respected, the law is murky. a) Most commentators say need to also prove an element of injustice or wrong. b) Others say disrespecting separate existence of corporation is sufficient to pierce the corporate veil. c) Theory: if the shareholder doesn’t respect the unity of interest issue, we don’t make the creditors respect it either. d) Some require more in the way of proof of actual injustice, e.g., Texas requires proof of actual fraud. e) Often it doesn’t matter if plaintiff was aware of defendant’s disregard, just that there was disregard. f) Old-fashioned fraud is a separate cause of action, but requires proof of reliance. c. Cases 1) Walkovsky v. Carlton (p. 196) a) The case Facts: W struck by cab owned by Seon Corp. Seon, along with 9 other corporations is solely owned by Cartlon. Each corporation owns 2 taxis and is undercapitalized. C drains the money out of his enterprises, leaving only minimum insurance policies on the vehicles. Holding, Reasoning: Court finds for Carlton. Confusing case! Court starts with 2 theories for piercing the corporate veil: fraud and agency 2 agency situations described: (1) company is part of a bigger corporation that actually conducts the business (2) company is a dummy for an individual stockholder who actually runs the business Here, C didn’t run operation in his personal capacity no agency. Fuld’s reasoning seems pretty sparse, although he considers the deleterious affects that the opposite ruling would have on the city’s cabbies. Plaintiff didn’t bother to consider other agency situation, so the court needn’t consider it. In fact, plaintiff’s case is more like fraud, but neither C’s nor S’s behavior is fraudulent. Inadequate capital isn’t sufficient for piercing the corporate veil. Dissent: When corporation is run irresponsibly, shareholders lose privilege of limited liability. b) Three legal doctrines that could be invoked: enterprise liability - treat all 10 corporations as a single entity respondeat superior (agency) - liability depends on C’s control of S to make it an agent. disregard of the corporate entity (piercing the corporate veil) - All roads lead to C. Note: The court in this case tends to weave agency and piercing together. c) What if the court did pierce the corporate veil? All the shareholders would be liable as partners. 20 d) What if each of the 10 corporations is a large public corporation with many shareholders? All shareholders can be held jointly and severally liable as partners. Each could be liable for the entire amount. Other options? pro rata system – would require either legislative authorization or a very inventive court just officers and directors – would need adequate insurance in place or people wouldn’t want to be officers and directors. e) Policy options: Require higher minimum insurance or bond Pierce the corporate veil – may lead to some bad consequences Let the loss fall on the victim – does the victim have insurance? 2) Sea-Land Services v. Pepper Source (p. 202) Facts: Marchese owned several businesses incl. PS, ran them out of the same office, played with assets, used assets for personal expenses. PS owed S-L a lot of $, Marchese dissolved it. Issue: Can S-L “reverse pierce” Marchese’s other companies to get paid? Holding, Reasoning: Court establishes a 2-prong test for piercing the corporate veil: 1. unity of interest and ownership can’t separate corporation and individual/corporation 2. inequitable result otherwise = adhering to fiction of separate corporate existence would work a fraud or injustice Court rules in this case that #1 certainly holds. Court considers these four factors, and finds they all apply to Marchese: 1. failure to maintain adequate corporate records/comply with corporate formalities 2. commingling of funds/assets 3. undercapitalization 4. one corporation treats assets of another as its own #2 is allot trickier, since fraud and injustice are shifty concepts. The court here defines injustice as D skirting its responsibilities. P didn’t prove this, so the case is remanded. 3) Kinney Shoe v. Polan (p. 208) Facts: D formed two corporations. Very informal. P sub-leased building to D. D subleased part of building from corp #1 to corp #2. Sublease was #1’s only assets. D only made one payment, and P sued #1 for unpaid rent. Succeeded, but since #1 had no assets, P wanted to pierce corporate veil and go after D. Holding, Reasoning: Court rules that piercing the corporate veil = equitable remedy. Court uses two-prong test, and also applies third (optional) prong: it would not have been reasonable for creditor to conduct a reasonable credit investigation which would reveal gross undercapitalization. 4) Perpetual Real Estate Services v. Michaelson Properties (p. 211) 21 Facts: D started company to go into two joint ventures with P to convert apartments to condos. When purchasers sued one partnership for breach of warranty, P settled with them. P now wants indemnification from D’s company and from D. Holding, Reasoning: What must prove to pierce the corporate veil 1. corporation was alter ego of Court looks at existence of corporate records, history of dividends paid, observed formalities, and existence of offcers and directors. 2. corporation was device or sham used to disguise wrongs, obscure fraud, or conceal crime Court finds that #1 is satisfied, but that #2 isn’t. P went into arrangement with D knowing full-well what was going on. D did nothing to violate any contractual obligation. 5) Theoretical difference between torts and contracts cases It makes more sense for court to pierce the corporate veil in a torts case than in a contracts case. In the latter, the parties should be aware of how corporate structure and assets affect parties’ rights. RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS § 324(A): One who undertakes… to render services to another which he should recognize as necessary for the protection of a third person or his things, is subject to liability to the third person for physical harm resulting from his failure to exercise reasonable care… if (a) his failure to exercise reasonable care increases the risk of harm, or (b) he has undertaken to perform a duty owed by the other to the third person, or (c) the harm is suffered because of a reliance of the other or the third person upon the undertaking d. Due diligence 1) Definition: No court-enunciated definition. Before any mergers/combinations of corporations, the buying party does due diligence review. Usually done by buyers’ law firm, sometimes with [forensic] accountants. Client wants a detailed list of what they’re buying. Ex: See if company’s lease on office space says that it loses its lease if there’s a change in ownership. 2) In re Silicone Gel Breast Implants Products Liability Litigation (p. 215) Facts: Bristol-Meyers Squibb Co. (Bristol) bought all stock/is parent and sole shareholder of Medical Engineering Corporation (MEC) after due diligence review. MEC had a “paper” board of directors, and made periodic reports to Bristol. Bristol controlled all of MEC’s assets. Bristol and MEC were interrelated in a number of other ways; most notably, Bristol performed safety reviews for MEC. Issue: If MEC gets sued, should Bristol also be liable. Holding, Reasoning: Court finds corporate control by looking at the following factors: the parent and the subsidiary have common directors or officers 22 the parent and the subsidiary have common business departments the parent and the subsidiary file consolidated financial statements and tax returns the parent finances the subsidiary the parent causes the incorporation of the subsidiary the subsidiary operates with grossly inadequate capital the parent pays the salaries and other expenses of the subsidiary the subsidiary receives no business except that given to it by the parent the parent uses the subsidiary’s property as its own the daily operations of the two corporations are not kept separate the subsidiary does not observe the basic corporate formalities, such as keeping separate books and records and holding shareholder and board meetings Court makes a contract-tort distinction, holding that the latter doesn’t require fraud, injustice or inequity. In other words, torts actions only require a one-prong test. The logic behind this is that the plaintiffs never entered into an agreement with Bristol, only MEC. Prof: Corporate veil analysis by court is not very good. Isn’t this a contract claim? There are understandings and agreements with distributors, suppliers, doctors, and patients. Since the patients didn’t request any guarantees from Bristol, maybe they shouldn’t be allowed to succeed on a suit. There are better theories under which Bristol could be held liable. More sympathy for patients where case viewed as a contract case ex: name and logo used apparent agency claim (if Bristol wants to use its name to sell a product, should accept consequences) “There ought to be a law.” On the other hand, if there should be complete corporation responsibility, what sort of investors will get involved? Study: Never been a successful piercing claim against a publicly-traded corporation. Probably courts don’t see it as equitable. 4. Financing the Corporation: Debt and Equity a. Debt 1) Definition: Fixed claim, unconditional obligation to interest and principal paid by the debtor to lender over time 2) How gotten? a) From bank put in document called: Loan agreement b) From individuals, institutions (insurance companies, mutual funds…) put in documents called: Bond has security interest } put in documents called 23 Debenture is an unsecured obligation Notes used for either } indentures 3) Tools for giving sense of security to persons holding unsecured interests: a) Maintenance of property covenant – lender had to maintain property so that not devalued so that bondholder will have something to take b) Negative pledge clause – lender will not pledge any of his assets to another debtor c) Restrictions on dividends (note: there are legal limits on when they can be issued) d) Debt becomes due upon change of control – protection against takeovers e) Additional debt covenants, e.g., subordination agreements f) Risky projects limitation (difficult to draft, say that the lender gets to approve certain kinds of projects) 4) Some terms in the agreement: a) duration b) callable at option of issuer before due date b. Equity 1) Definition: share of stock, holder has residual claim, can control firm through, generally no control over company except through election of directors. Shareholder has a piece of the corporation. 2) Risk and return On average one is more highly compensated for taking a greater risk in the stock market. To reduce risk, develop portfolio of stocks. Diversification of risk may not offer protection from systemic problems. Beta = measure of stock volatility Beta = 1 – stock tends to move exactly with the market Beta > 1 – stock tends to go higher than market when market goes up 3) Efficient Capital Markets Hypothesis (ECMH) Stock prices incorporate all publicly available information. 4) Dividends a) Pro: Money in your hand, increases pressure on company to find new sources of capital ( discipline, innovation) b) Drawback: Doesn’t change value of stock, just how much money is available to company, c. Mixes of Debt and Equity 1) Convertible debt – converts into common stock on certain conditions (event, time) 2) Warrants – options issued by corporation that allow shareholders to profit based on future firm earnings, “sweetener”, often issued to management as part of their compensation packages 24 d. Debt/Equity Ratio 1) Borrowing is good, some of your money should be from debt, some say have a lot of debt more disciplined management 2) Don’t have complete debt or complete equity. e. Par Value Articles of incorporation indicate how many shares issued, par value of each share, and legal capital. ex: issue 1,000 shares, par value $1/share, legal capital = $1,000. Means you have to have $1,000 in your coffers. For the most part, this is a dead concept. Most restrictions on when to issue dividend are not tied to a legal capital test. =The written value of the share. Some meaning for accounting purposes. f. Options and Derivatives 1) Used to be that the only way for an investor to make money was from debt or equity. 2) Now, have options – 2 types: call or put – issued by third party outside the company. a) Call option – right to buy company’s stock in the future at a specified price b) Put option – right to sell company’s stock in the future at a specified price Shorting a stock – expect the price will go down, borrow shares sell them back later Derivatives – instruments that attach to underlying stock or stock index, has no value in and of 5. The Role and Purpose of the Corporations a. Business judgment rule: If management of a corporation makes an informed business judgment, courts will defer to management. From time to time courts have to reel in managers who stray their bounds, set limits. b. 1) Cases Questions to consider When can a corporation contribute to a public charity? When must a corporation issue dividends? To what extent can a person controlling a corporation use it to indulge private ends? 2) A.P. Smith Mfg. Co. v. Barlow (p. 264) Stockholders sue after corporation directors decide to give donation to Princeton. Their argument was that (1) ’s certificate of incorporation didn’t expressly authorize the contribution and under common-law principles and company had no implied power to make it, and (2) state statute that would so authorize the company was inapplicable because enacted after company’s incorporation. 25 Court: Corporations control lots of wealth that individuals used to give away. Good citizenship requires contributions by corporations. State enacted doctrine prior to incorporation of this company reserving the right to alter the state-corporation contract in the public interest. Standard: Donations bad if made indiscriminately or in furtherance of personal ends. Holding: As long as corporate ends are met (there must be some benefit to corporation – however tenuous), directors may make reasonable donations to charities. Most courts uphold charitable gifts. Shareholders are often working class with pension funds that hold stocks. CEOs tend to give to upper-crust charities. Moral high ground to take from workers and give to opera? Arguments in favor of corporate philanthropy 1. Good for America 2. Good P.R. Problem, p. 270 and statutes pp. 268-69 CEO wants to give $100,000 to charity. Corporation’s before-tax earnings are $20M. CEO wants gift to be anonymous. Issues raised: Pet charity? May be violative of fiduciary duty, but CEO could present to board with full disclosure for legitimizing approval Anonymous nature? Size of gift? 3) Dodge v. Ford Motor Co. (p. 270) Ford had issued large dividends in the past. Henry Ford announces that there will be no dividends and that profits will be rolled back into company to support pro-social corporate goals. Court decides that Dodge Bros. (who have a 10% interest in the company) get a dividend. Court: Ford’s business is to maximize shareholders’ profits. Ford must issue dividends. Why this doesn’t make sense: 1. It doesn’t make a difference whether dividends are issued. 2. Case is an aberration in law of dividends. Issue should be: Does the corporation have sufficient legal capital to issue dividends? 3. What’s the court thinking when they distinguish between dividends (court forces) and new plant construction (court ignores)? Court chickened out probably. Is Ford running company as a charity? No. Court misses the point. Ford didn’t want to be seen as a robber baron, wanted to help people and make a reasonable profit. 26 Court also missed conflict between Dodges and Ford. Didn’t want him to build plant that would enable Ford to decrease prices further. Dodges wanted extra capital for their own car business, didn’t want prices to go down so they could compete with Ford. Also, Ford would have had to pay 73% tax on them 4) Shlensky v. Wrigley (The Chicago Cubs Case) (p. 275) a) Case Stockholder brings suit to get lights installed at Wrigley Field, alleging that the lack of night games adversely affected the profitability of the ball club. Wrigley, the majority shareholder, was personally opposed to night games. Courts defer to directors’ judgment, presuming good faith effort to promote corporate interests, unless there’s fraud. Here didn’t prove that the lights would make the corporation more profitable. didn’t want to bother the neighbors and didn’t want night games. Court defers to directors’ decision. b) Analysis questions (p. 279) 1. If Shlensky wasn’t happy, why didn’t he sell his shares? It doesn’t cost much to sue. If he tries to sell, price will reflect lower profits. 2. Does the decision in this case leave open the possibility that Shlensky might have prevailed? Under what theory? Prove that corporation would have profited from night games. Claim that directors and management failed to investigate the possibility that night games would improve profitability. 3. If you represented Shlenksy, what strategy would you take with Wrigley? Get Wrigley to say what his motivations are – not profits, but personal distaste of night games; no research, just personal distaste of night-games. c) Problem 1. (pp. 279-80) Ann and Bill’s salami If no fraud… It depends on how Bill presents his reasoning. If Bill says, “I don’t care about profits, I care about my employees” he’s screwed. We set up corporations to be profitable [in the short run]. Unless we have a constituency statute like in PA that allows directors to consider other benefits. Alternatives: incorporate as not-for-profit, include agreement/definition in corporation papers (ex: “…incorporated to play the great game of baseball which is played only in the daytime”). 27 Question to ask: What is objective reality, is this an objective decision to maximize profits? A fully-informed fraud-less business decision may be sufficient in some courts, not in others. c. Derivative suit = action by stockholders against directors of corporation where directors are alleged to have done something bad. Instead of the corporation suing the board, the stockholders sue on behalf of the corporation. Right to sue is derivative of their being stockholders in the corporation (stockholders don’t sue in their personal capacities). If the stockholders win, the directors pay $ to the corporation (not the stockholders) out of their own pockets ( corporations may take out liability insurance for their directors). Since there’s limited profit to minority shareholders, often shareholders bring derivative suits for the principle of it (and attorney’s for the fees). Most jurisdictions say there’s no minimum shareholder requirement for suing. II. Fiduciary Duties and Shareholder Litigation A. The Business Judgment Rule 1. Introduction a. Aside: Formal model of organization is inaccurate at describing real distribution of powers in corporations. First work on this subject: Burley and Means The Modern Corporation and Private Property – separation of ownership and control. Shareholders can’t control corporation – dispersed, can’t get together to make decisions. Normally, you want ownership and control by the same people. Prof. Heller article The Tragedy of the Anti-Commons (Harv. L. Rev.): we always look at tragedy of the commons problems – how common owners can use common property most efficiently. Look at the anti-commons – entity whose ownership is divided up among too many people, where everyone has a tiny interest in the firm/project, can’t have effective governance. Ex: In the 50’s. Quaker Oats Corporation issued 1” squares of property to people. Can’t do anything with the property because owners are dispersed and own too little to do anything with it. How do we solve the anti-commons problem in corporation so that the managers and controllers of corporations are lined up? b. 4 ways to align management and shareholder interests: Shareholder voting – shareholder vote for managers reflecting their interests problem: shareholder who owns very little doesn’t care enough to vote Contract – write a K that tries to align interests ex: give directors stock options, conditions, bonuses tied to profits 28 Market – leave it to the market for corporate control, i.e., M&A market (raiders or other managers who think they can do it better will take over) Legal Rules – take care of two big problems: (1) duty of care combats sloth (2) duty of loyalty combats greed 2. Definition of the BJR - Courts will defer to the business judgment of the actors within the private sector. Apparently unwise decisions aren’t criminal; the court assumes that market participants are still the best representatives of their interests. Court grants immunity only if director’s judgment comports with: 1. no fraud, illegality [duty of good faith?] 2. duty of care – no negligence, sloth 3. duty of loyalty – no conflict of interest, greed B. The Obligation of Control: Duty of Care 1. Introduction Duty of care started as common law doctrine, now many modern statutes codify it. Negligence here is closer to gross negligence (egregious conduct). 2. Cases a. Kamin v. American Express Co. (p. 281) Facts: Stockholders seek remedy for ‘bad’ business decision to distribute depreciated stocks as in-kind dividend instead of selling them at a loss (which would have resulted in tax savings). Corporate directors chose to distribute the stocks to avoid bad net income figures on financial statement. Holding, Reasoning: Don’t sue unless you allege a clear case of fraud, deceit, oppression, arbitrary action, or breach of trust. This is a business question; it’s not our job to judge it. Boards can make bad decisions in good faith with impunity. “A complaint which alleges merely that some course of action other than that pursued by the Board of Directors would have been more advantageous gives rise to no cognizable cause of action.” (p. 282) Applying the BJR test: 1. No fraud or illegality. 2. No negligence. 3. No conflict of interest – well, maybe “hint of self-interest.” Financial theory: The market should know that AmEx’s stock has declined by $26M because of the devaluation ($30M $4M) of the stocks it holds. If AmEx’s stock price already incorporated the loss (under ECMH), then reporting it in the financial statement should be superfluous. It shouldn’t matter. Then again, the market doesn’t always work the way that Nobel laureates theorize it will. Moral: BJR protects directors from liability for dumb decisions. A decision doesn’t have to be smartest or best, just can’t be the product of fraud, illegality, negligence or conflict 29 of interests. If the decision is really horrible, will probably be able to show some sort of breach of duty. b. Joy v. North (p. 284) Facts: Citytrust makes bad investment. CEO dominated Citytrust. CEO supported investment in his son’s employer’s project. Board agrees. Shareholders sue directors (derivative suit). Corporation sets up Special Litigation Committee* which recommends to court that “outsider” directors not be liable and “insider” directors might be. *When a shareholder wants to sue directors, s/he serves notice on corporation and asks them to sue its own directors. Corporation will usually set up a Special Litigation Committee so that company can decide whether it will sue. If it decides not to, shareholder goes ahead and brings derivative suit against corporation (corporation loses control over case). If demand would be futile (because of the make-up of the board/committee), shareholder need not go to them. Court: The court acknowledges the BJR, but takes exception where a corporate decision lacks a business purpose. Here, North’s control over this matter, the lack of communication with the other directors, and the apparent negligence in the loan’s handling indicate North lacked a business purpose. “Outsiders” won’t be protected if found to be ostriches (breachers of duty of care). That “insiders” might be liable is an understatement. Note: Joy v. North cites Litwin v. Allen (famous case, see Clark hornbook) and seems to be saying that you can make a duty of care case if the decision creates a no-win situation. But according to what we’ve been saying, it shouldn’t matter how egregious a decision is. This is not what it appears to be. couldn’t prove conflict of interests so judge crafted a poorly-reasoned duty of care decision. A bad decision alone, not matter how bad, doesn’t prove that BJR shouldn’t apply. There’s no duty of intelligence. But where there’s smoke, there’s fire – will likely find a breach of duty of care or of loyalty. Question 4, p. 290 How do you suppose the court that decided Joy would have decided Kamin? Kamin – no neglect (heard and considered shareholders’ preference) Joy – neglect (didn’t seem to be asking the right questions) c. Francis v. United Jersey Bank (p. 290) Facts: Two sons inherit and then bankrupt a reinsurance broker business (by ‘loaning’ money to themselves). Mother/widow is largest single shareholder and the third director. Trustee in bankruptcy sues widow’s estate. Holding, Reasoning: Court finds her liable for breaching duty of care and that the breach was the proximate cause of the bankruptcy. Standard of liability: breach of duty breach is proximate cause of loss 30 Laundry list – bare minimum of directors’ duties: (1) understanding the business of the corporation (2) keeping informed of corporation’s activities (3) not ignoring corporate misconduct (no ostriches) (4) generally monitoring corporate affairs and policies (5) regularly reviewing financial statements (6) duty to inquire further (7) if illegal conduct found, duty to object (8) if no correction of conduct, duty to resign (9) sometimes: seeking advice of counsel (10) maybe taking reasonable steps to prevent illegal conduct, e.g., by threatening suit What could she have done? She could have read the financial statements and then she would have seen the decreasing funds in conjunction with corresponding loans. Then she could have protested, resigned, sued…. Problem, p. 295 Main points: obligations to creditors – no clear fiduciary duty, though some academics think you should; may have ethical obligations to other constituencies. [No fiduciary duty to creditors. Duties prescribed by K. Some say that creditors stand in same position as shareholders. Generally that doesn’t happen, though.] Can’t resign just because of a duty issue that arises during your tenure – first, do everything you can to prevent, stop or remedy it. Can’t distribute money to shareholders when you have outstanding obligations to creditors. Source: rules on payments of dividends, law of fraudulent conveyances, bankruptcy law. 3. The BJR and Mergers a. Usual situation: 1) Idea among management, hint of offer by inquirer. Becomes common knowledge, price may be driven up if buyer is well-known. Want a suitable buyer who will pay a high price for stock, other needs of company being acquired. 2) Hire merger assistants. Merger assistants make search public, look for suitable “fits”, and in some instances bargain with these parties. 3) Due Dilligence Phase: Lawyers set up data room – full of Ks, outstanding obligations, leases, potential lawsuit documents. Whoever is interested in buying is invited to check out the data room to do due diligence. 4) Agreement Phase: Letter of intent drafted by lawyers, states inquirer, inquiree, offer, sometimes lock-up agreement (locks inquiree into agreement subject to certain conditions). Merger agreement – indicates agreement to merge. 31 Closing – last step, all documents on table, sign, transfer stocks/assets, have a big party. b. LBO – Leveraged Buy-Out = purchase of a company financed by a relatively small amount of equity (common stock) and a large amount of debt (which provides the leverage). Often assets of the company are sold to pay of part of the debt. analogy: purchase of house that costs $1M. purchase price: $1,000,000 cash payment: $100,000 bank loan: $800,000 loan from friend: $100,000 at 21% interest. 90% of sale is financed by debt. If price of house goes up, can sell later and make profit. Or could lose everything. Business example: add lots of zeros, change buyer to corporation (ex: KKR), change friend to corporation holding junk bond for 21% interest (junk debt) – high interest, potentially high yield, high risk of default. A lot of 80’s LBOs ended in bankruptcy. c. MBO – Management Buy-Out When incumbent managers of target have equity involvement in buy-out. d. Smith v. Van Gorkom (p. 301) 1) The Case Facts: Part one: Trans Union’s cash-flow situation was excellent, but had difficulty in generating income sufficient to make use of investment tax credits. Available options: (1) issue dividends, (2) repurchase its own stock (to raise price of stock, since there are fewer stocks available) (3) acquire other businesses (4) sell corporation, let buyer deal with it Part two: Van Gorkem approaches retirement, has stocks. Likes idea of leveraged buyout (at about $55 per share), but vetoes managed buyout. Meets with takeover specialist Pritzker w/o consulting directors or management. Part three: V.G. didn’t really know what he’s doing – didn’t ask Pritzker what he thinks it’s worth, came up with an uninformed figure, didn’t consult with the experts on his board of directors. Pritzker decided on cash-out merger offer for $38 per share. V.G. helps establish financing. Handshake deal between VG and Pritzker on Thursday. Pritzker wants approval by Sunday night. Pritzker is interested in (1) cash on hand and (2) get benefit of ITC’s by combining taxable income with other corporations. 32 Part four: V.G. finally got around to telling management, although he failed to supply all pertinent information. Pritzker did agree to pay $55/share. Even so, management hated it, especially since the merger involved a 90-day bidding period where Trans Union could receive, but not solicit competing offers. Legal Counsel says that if they don’t take the offer, they could get sued. Hard to say no. Note: But, they could have easily gotten a fairness decision – investment bank comes in and generates a fair price for the firm. (But prof says they probably would have found the number to be fine.) [Interview for job at Salomon Bros.: Interviewer: What’s 2 + 2? Interviewee: 4. The interviewee who gets the job is the one who says, “What kind of figure did you have in mind?”] Part five: Board approved merger agreement, with supposed conditions of right to accept better offers and right to share proprietary info with potential bidders. Instead of letter of intent, merger agreement isn’t read by anyone, signed by VG, handed over at Opera house. Dissent among management led to VG and Pritzker modifying agreement. VG got directors to agree amendments - sight unseen! This blew up when the actual modifications were found to be very different from what VG told the directors they were. Part six: Two companies expressed interest. The first wanted the merger agreement rescinded, but Pritzker wouldn’t allow that, so it gave up. The second gave up, too. Part seven: Merger between Trans Union and Pritzker. Holding, Reasoning: Business judgment rule’s presumption of good faith rebutted where directors breached fiduciary duty by: (1) Not informing themselves of available/relevant info. Price is $17 above stock price on market. Salomon Bros. looked for other purchasers. Maybe Pritzker would have walked if he wasn’t locked-in. Isn’t this a good deal? BJR isn’t about the best decision, it’s about the process. What should have been done differently? Amendments voted on sight-unseen, Salomon Bros. called in too late. No one understood how the $55 figure was really generated (not as an end product, but investigated as a (random) starting point). The directors (1) did not adequately inform themselves as to VG’s role in forcing the ‘sale’ of the Company and in establishing the per share purchase price; (2) were uninformed as to the intrinsic value of the company; and (3) given these circumstances, at a minimum, were grossly negligent in approving the ‘sale’ of the Company upon two hours’ consideration, without prior notice, and without the exigency of a crisis or emergency. (308). (2) Continuing to act stupid. Salomon Bros. tried to find alternative suitors for company. 33 If directors didn’t act stupid, Pritzker and VG couldn’t have nixed the other potential deals as successfully as they did, ruling out the possibility of a better price (in other words, the auction never really happened). (3) Not disclosing material info to stockholders re. merger. Dissent: “Outside” directors were all experienced and knew better 2) Notes: a) Options for acquisition: (1) Creation of subsidiary – quicker, less paperwork than direct acquisition by public corporation. How can we get everything owned by Trans Union Corp. to be owned by Marmon Group.? Marmon creates “New T” which buys all assets of TU. To merge companies – need majority vote by board and shareholders of acquired company. Shareholders are sheep, do whatever board tells them. (2) Tender offer (common in hostile takeover situation) = direct appeal (through newspapers, mass mailings) to stockholders to sell their shares for a certain price ($, stocks of newly created company, purchaser). Drawback: need to get 50% of stocks, may have holdouts and not get enough.1 b) If the market knows best, why is Pritzker offering $55 for a stock that sells for $38? Why not offer 38¼, 39? Avoid bidding war $55 may be value as a merged company (can use ITC’s better than existing company) Shareholders less likely to pass it up 1 share is worth $38 (judged at market value to minority shareholder), but many shares may be worth more. After a certain point, there’s a control premium for each additional share. Stock value Increasing # of shares c) Lock-up option (1) gives original bidder a benefit even if outbid (2) gives successful new bidder an obligation to sell shares to original bidder at a given price d) Financing contingency Cumulative voting – percentage shareholding is represented on the board, i.e., if you have a third of stocks, you can elect 1/3 of board. So you may gain control with less than 50%. 1 34 If bidder can’t get $ from banks to pay for deal, has an out. Here, if contingency met or waived (gets $ otherwise), TU required to sell 1 million shares at $38/share. e) Board voted on agreement, why is there now dissent among the officers? Maybe some officers (who the directors who voted for this) are concerned about keeping their jobs or are interested in doing an MBO. Why did Pritzker agree to modifications? Maybe realized that VG didn’t have the backing of his people, might get sued, might lose good officers. f) Outrage followed the case. What should boards do about seemingly good offers now? Correctives: 1. Insurance industry: Boom in directors/officers liability insurance 2. DE Legislature: enacted Del.Gen.Corp.Law § 102(b)(7) – can limit liability for director’s breach of loyalty, non-good faith acts by directors, personal benefit impelled transaction by inserting a clause in certificate of incorporation. = Protects directors (not officers) from suits for damages (no injunction) from shareholders only g) Are there just madcaps running businesses? These people are on the hook for a lot of money. Liability can be substantially more than salaries. Outside directors generally don’t have packages that cover liability. Analogy: Truck driver for GM with family, equity of $100,000, savings of $50,000. These assets are exposed to risk of loss where driver negligently drives and causes an accident. Personal assets are at risk, person will be more careful. Same thing with officers/directors. 4. In re Caremark International Inc. Derivative Litigation (Supp. p. 30) Facts: Anti-referral payments law means you can’t pay doctors to advise patients to use certain drugs. Since Caremark employed doctors in consulting matters, gov’t claimed there were kickbacks, and Caremark got fined. Shareholders filed a derivative suit, and Caremark responded with a settlement. Holding, Reasoning: Court holds settlement reasonable. BJR: Directors who act in good faith with proper procedures will not be liable, no matter how stupid their decisions. Here, the directors didn’t originally know of the illegal activity, and took good faith steps to remedy the situation once they discovered it. Old rule: Directors don’t have to monitor employees as long as not on notice of misconduct. New rule: Duty of care does require monitoring of more important aspects of firm – via good faith effort to assure that adequate reporting system exists. Rule1: Whether a judge or jury considering the matter after the fact believes a decision substantively wrong, or degrees or wrong extending through “stupid” to “egregious” or 35 “irrational” provides no ground for director liability so long as the court determines that the process employed was either rational or employed in a good faith effort to advance corporate interests. BJR is process-oriented and informed by a deep respect for all good faith board of directors. Rule2: Absent grounds to suspect deception, neither corporate boards nor senior officers can be charged with wrongdoing simply for assuming the integrity of employers and the honesty of their dealings on the company’s behalf. Standard for being held liable: directors knew/should have known that violations of law were occurring took no steps in good faith to prevent/remedy situation this failure was proximate cause of loss. C. The Duty of Loyalty 1. General - Conflicts of Interest a. BJR yields to rule of undivided loyalty – designed to avoid (1) possibility of fraud and (2) temptation of self-interest. General rule: directors acting separately and not collectively as a board cannot bind corporation. Reasoning: (1) collective procedure is necessary to take deliberate action (2) directors are agents of shareholders, can only act as a board by law Failure to observe procedures is not fatal. b. Bayer v. Beran (p. 323) Facts: Celanese corporation wanted to differentiate their rayon-like product, went into radio advertising. In spending $1M on classy radio show, hired CEO’s wife to sing on it. She’s qualified, was fairly hired, didn’t have a lead role or make much money. Holding, Reasoning: Court finds no violation. Advertising “served a legitimate and a useful purpose and the company received the full benefit thereof.” P claims that decisions were made informally, without a meeting of the board of directors, and that this fails the general rule (see above). Court decides the rule isn’t applicable, since communication between the members of the board is sufficient in an informal way. Note: What should an attorney advise CEO Dreyfus? Go to board, fully disclose the fact that it’s your wife, seek approval of non-interested directors. To be really safe, the board could remove Dreyfus from this particular decision-making process. Court here says it will look at the actions of all directors (unusual). 2. Burdens of Proof - Lewis v. SL&E (p. 328) Facts: SLE = lessor (land) LGT = lessee (tire dealership) R, A, L Jr., L Sr., Etsberger = common directors of both corporations 36 Lewis gave his shares of SLE to his 6 kids. Kids agree that non-LGT shareholders will sell their shares to the kids who are LGT shareholders in 10 years. Conflict of interest present because of overlap of two boards: LGT shareholders are all SLE shareholders, but not all SLE shareholders are LGT shareholders. SLE artificially holds down rent for LGT. LGT shareholders and directors don’t care since they’re on both sides. SLE shareholders believe the book value of their stocks is lower than it should be because of the low rent charged LGT. They therefore refuse to sell to LGT shareholders at that book value as previously agreed. Board doesn’t acknowledge conflict = Unratified conflict of interest Holding, Reasoning: Court finds for non-LGT shareholders. If no conflict of interest has burden of proof, BJR applies usually director wins If unratified conflict of interest has burden of proving that transaction is fair and reasonable If ratified conflict of interest (disinterested directors or shareholders approve transaction) has burden of proof To ratify: see 3. (“Statutory Approaches” below) Note: This case and Celanese case are aberrations. Modern cases look at substantial financial interest, not just seat on board. Question on Compensation (p. 332) How can directors set their own salaries if they’re supposed to be avoiding conflict of interests? 1. Committee of outside directors set salaries 2. Hire consulting firms to set salaries Problem (p. 332) Singer who wants to break into opera circuit, marries wealthy Kane CEO and majority shareholder of magazine. Shares of magazine are worth $100M. 1. OK for magazine to give $20M donation to create opera (where Singer doesn’t sing)? Seems like a pet charity problem. Also, too much $$$. And, unlikely to get the value back in goodwill. 2. Can Singer sing for free in opera? If paid in line with others, would look more legitimate. If more objectively determined to be good, would look better. 3. What if Kane owns 100% of the stock? Then like privately owned, can ratify without opposition, no one has a right to sue. 4. What if Singer is a genuine star, hired after audition? Doesn’t look great, probably sufficiently sanitized. “Penumbra of conflict.” 3. Statutory Approaches to Immunizing Duty of Loyalty Issues a. NY BCL § 713 – maintain transaction’s validity by (1) disclosing in good faith to board (unless they already know) and board approves without counting interested director’s vote (2) disclosing in good faith to shareholders (unless they already know) and they approve Note: no disinterested requirement for shareholders. 37 b. ALI Principles of Corporate Governance See Supp. Pp 52. Unlike NY, ALI holds shareholders should also be disinterested. 4. Corporate Opportunities a. Definition 1) What is a corporate opportunity? Corporate opportunity doctrine is a subset of duty of loyalty. A corporate opportunity is an interest, expectancy, or necessity. interest – something to which firm has a contractual right expectancy – something which, in the ordinary course of things, the corporation could expect to receive ex: renewal of lease (reminiscent of Meinhard v. Salmon – partnership analog to corporate opportunity) necessity – right to goods and services that the corporation vitally needs Some define it as “anything in the company’s line of business” – can be too vague. 2) Energy Resources Corp., Inc. v. Porter (p. 333) Facts: ERCO hires Porter from MIT to direct a project on staged fluidized bed combustion of coal. Porter (on behalf of ERCO) and 2 profs from Howard go for DOE grant together with advantage of minority ties. One prof later decides he can’t work with ERCO as subcontractor because he’d feel like they were fronting for a non-minority institution. Offers Porter a way to stay in the deal by creating his own company (EEE) once they get the grant. Profs substitute EEE for ERCO on application. When asked by superior executives about how the grant was coming along, Porter told them that they weren’t going to get it (no elaboration). When profs get grant, Porter resigns allegedly to start a computerized car company. Holding: Porter can’t rely on Prof. Jackson’s refusal to deal with ERCO. Firmness of refusal to deal is not a defense to breach of fiduciary duty not to divert a corporate opportunity unless person has unambiguously disclosed the refusal to the corporation, together with a fair statement of the reasons for that refusal. Reasoning: can’t be tested by corporate executive alone, without full disclosure to corporation, can’t verify unwillingness to deal, corporation doesn’t have opportunity to test resolve of non-dealer “[A] fiduciary’s silence is equivalent to a stranger’s lie.” (Brown’s concurrence) Prof. Jackson’s reasoning is ambiguous – doesn’t want to be a minority front for a white subcontractor but also wants more money in the long run. Notes: Trial court judge found this defense adequate. Appeals court said no, it’s not a defense as a matter of law (since fact-finding occurs at trial court level). 38 KK: Or is it just that the facts before the court didn’t support the exception for using this defense, i.e., unambiguous disclosure of the refusal to the corporation, together with a fair statement of the reasons for that refusal.] If application had not originally mentioned ERCO, it would still be within line of business of ERCO. But why? Expectancy? The whole thing started on a summer vaction. Necessity? Maybe. The corporation may the right to goods it vitally needs (?) (Prof. West: maybe the guy has a better idea of whether his colleague is willing to deal) Racial implications - consider them. Any affirmative action defense possible? Perhaps not with high scrutiny. b. The Process 1) Director/officer offers Director/officer can take Is it a corporate opportunity to Corporation rejects? opportunity as his own corporation’s disinterested opportunity? directors/shareholders Test: interest? (contractual right) line of business? expectancy? necessity? 2) Broz v. Cellular Information Systems, Inc. (Supp. p. 46) The players: Broz (RFBC), CIS, Mackinac, PriCellular Facts: Broz is the president and sole shareholder of RFBC a small cellular provider (license for Mich-4). Broz also sits on the board of a larger competitor, CIS. Mackinac is a cellular provider looking to divest itself of a license for Mich-2 an area adjacent to Broz’s area (Mich-4). Mackinac approaches Broz as a potential buyer, but not CIS which is in no financial shape to buy it and which has no licenses in the area. Broz mentions deal to a board member and executives at CIS. All say, go ahead, we’re not interested. Broz does not present to the board, goes ahead and buys it by upping the purchase price of a competitor, PriCellular. PriCellular at that time was in negotiations to buy CIS but had not consummated the deal yet. Holding, Reasoning: Court held that Broz was under no obligation to let PriCellular get the deal. PriCellular had no interest or expectancy in the Michigan-2 opportunity (it couldn’t handle it, anyway). A formal presentation is not necessary without a corporate opportunity. KK: Broz has two different obligations – to his own company and to CIS – how far does he have to go for each? Not to the point where he was “required to consider every potential, future occurrence in determining whether a particular business strategy would implicate fiduciary duty concerns. Parallel to Salmon v. Meinhard – have to inform corporation of opportunity, but can still compete. Otherwise, it would make no sense for competitors to sit on each other’s boards. Notes: Financial capacity defense (p. 336) 39 Usually not a defense accepted unless executive has explicitly offered the opportunity to the corporation. Reasoning: too convenient, gives incentive to executives to fail to use their best efforts to help firm raise necessary funds Presentation of corporate opportunity to the board is a “safe harbor,” but not required. Values promoted: certainty, predictability, no undue restrictions on officers and directors. (See also ALI def of corporate opportunity - “Shareholders are sheep, they’ll follow whatever scraggly shepherd is leading them.” – Supp. p. 53) KK: this kind of fiduciary duty doesn’t seem intuitive to me… a guy helps a corporation and in return can’t conduct his own business as usual? Why would a little guy (which it turns out that Broz isn’t) want to be on a competitor’s board then? Why don’t all corporations use this as a strategy to take opportunities from their competitors? Individual director opinions don’t count – have to go to board formally. However, do directors Broz spoke to have an obligation to inform board of opportunity? Resignation of interested director? May not be best option (or allowed) Why didn’t PriCellular outbid Broz? Not want to get into a bidding war Thought they might win in court (at lower bid price) after losing on market Problems, p. 337 The barber shop hypo Suppose Louis invests his savings to form a new corporation that will take over the lease for Phabio’s salon, has he taken a corporate opportunity? 1. not in line of business 2. not a director or officer, just main employee – but maybe considered officer 3. no interest or expectancy 4. found out about opportunity in casual conversation 5. didn’t use corporate info or property to learn of opportunity If a firm makes employment Ks requiring employees to inform corporation of every opportunity – might not get all potential employees (too restrictive), shareholders might not want to deal with each opportunity that comes up 5. Dominant Shareholders a. Directors and Shareholders Directors have fiduciary duty, shareholders don’t. Shareholders don’t buy stock to look out for others’ interests, just to make $. ex: IBM enters merger agreement with Apple, submits agreement to shareholder vote. Directors with conflict of interest must disclose these. But we don’t expect a shareholders to say, “I should be disqualified from voting because I hold two shares of Apple.” 40 Sometimes courts impose fiduciary duties on shareholders because controlling shareholders can control board: A controlling shareholder can be: majority shareholder (> 50%) voting schemes under which less than 50% can control board have minority share but large enough to beat out other fractured interests Some corporate actions require shareholder vote – shareholder shouldn’t vote “unfairly” b. Sinclair Oil v. Levien (p. 338) Facts: Sinclair (parent) owns 97% of Sinven (subsidiary) stock. Parent causes subsidiary to pay out large dividends. Subsidiary able to survive, but not expand. Derivative suit claiming improper motive (parent’s need for cash). 3 claims: 1. Excessive dividends – Sinclair causes Sinven to issue large dividends (of which they receive 97%) – take cash out of company Court: no self-dealing because dividend issuance is equal to all shareholders 2. Corporate opportunity taken by Sinven for itself or other subsidiaries Court: BJR 3. Breach of K by parent’s wholly-owned subsidiary Test for parent-subsidiary dealing applied where there is (1) fiduciary duty and (2) selfdealing: Standard of intrinsic fairness = parent has burden of proving that its transactions with subsidiary were objectively fair basic situation: parent receives benefit to the exclusion and at expense of subsidiary Fiduciary duty? Y Self-dealing? Y Intrinsic fairness test N Business judgment rule c. Pepper v. Litton (cited at p. 342) A dominant or controlling group of stockholders = fiduciary actions held to standard of proving inherent fairness (Sounds a lot like intrinsic fairness standard) 41 Analysis questions (p. 342) How might one have resolved the case using only the law regarding the duty of loyalty of directors? In this situation, Sinven’s directors are the agents of Sinclair (principal) so Sinclair could be liable under agency principles. D. Relationships: The Shareholder Derivative Suit 1. General a. Definition Derivative suit = a suit in equity against a corporation to compel it to sue a third party brought by shareholder(s) on behalf of corporation to redress injury to corporation usually goes after director, directors decide whether to sue (protected by BJR) b. Derivative v. Direct Injury to corporation derivative action ex: manager runs off with company funds, corporation doesn’t go after him Injury to person direct action (personal suit, class action) ex: directors reconfigure shareholder rights to give more power to preferred class of shareholders over non-preferred class c. Incentives Management considers derivative suits to be nuisances. gets nothing – it’s the corporation that’s given a remedy. Cases probably only pursued because of attorney’s fees – win fee awards in 90% of settled suits (and most derivative suits settle for a third of the claimed damages) d. Eisenberg v. Flying Tiger Line, Inc. (p. 230) Shareholder sues to enjoin reorganization of company that will deprive him of right to vote on operations. Suit is representative/personal, not derivative (so shareholder doesn’t have to post security). Corporate maneuvers: (Rem: Eisenberg has shares of FT.) FT organizes FTC (wholly owned subsidiary) FTC organizes FTL (wholly owned subsidiary) 3 companies reorganize: FT merges with FTL. [shareholders approve] FTC renames itself FT. Shareholders end up with shares of FTC (calling itself FT and holding FTL, the real operating FT) Before: After: FT FTC holding FT ( has shares of FT) ( has shares of FTC) 42 Note: Why reorganize into a holding company (just holds shares of FT)? tax advantages get around regulatory requirements about diversification of businesses (ex: banks can’t hold stock) “Form over Holding, Reasoning: Not a derivative suit because doesn’t allege injury to corporationsubstance” Injury is to shareholder. Note: Is shareholder really hurt? Before: voted on FT operations matters After: elects directors who hold 100% of FT stock Could make duty argument that directors of FT still have fiduciary duty. But, could say that because shareholder’s power is now less direct, FT directors are more likely to shirk their responsibilities. 2. Demand Futility a. Definition 1) What’s a demand? Well, a demand is what the shareholder must first do before filing a suit against the board of directors. In other words, the shareholder must first demand that the board of directors bring the shareholder’s action. There are some situations where such a requirement would be unjust. 2) Marx v. Akers (Supp. p. 17) Facts: allege that directors approves excessive compensation for themselves and executives. claim failure to make demand or state a cause of action. Holding, Reasoning: Part one: Court acknowledges the intrusiveness of derivative actions, and its subsequent reluctance to permit such suits. The demand requirement is established to deal with this problem. Purposes of demand requirement (Supp. p. 18) 1. relieve courts from deciding matters of internal corporate governance by providing corporate directors with opportunities to correct alleged abuses 2. provide corporate boards with reasonable protection from harassment by litigation on matters clearly within directors’ discretion 3. weed out unnecessary or illegitimate suits/discourage “strike suits” commenced by shareholders for personal gain rather than for the benefit of the corporation Part two: Court next considers different methods of determining when demand would be futile. 1. Delaware approach (p. 236-37) Demand futile where: under particularized facts alleged there’s a reasonable doubt that 43 (1) directors are disinterested and independent, and (2) challenged transaction was entitled to BJR protection 2. Universal demand approach (Supp. p. 20) Demand required in all cases, can proceed in 90 days if not rejected earlier 3. New York approach (Supp. p. 21) Demand futile where: complaint alleges with particularity that (1) majority of directors are interested (2) directors failed to inform themselves by a degree reasonably necessary, or (3) directors failed to exercise business judgment Part three: Court picks the third approach (although both Del and NY approaches are quite similar). Court holds that demand requirement is still necessary, since “only three directors are alleged to have received the benefit of the executive compensation scheme.” The fact that the majority of shareholders acted out of personal interest might have been a factor, but P’s claim fails to state a cause of action. Note: DE’s and NY’s rules are both collapsible into the business judgment rule. b. Procedural Rules 1) Alford v. Shaw (p. 259) Issue: Whether a special litigation committee’s decision to terminate shareholders’ derivative suit is binding on court. 3 approaches to role of special litigation committee 1. Auerbach BJR applies. Court defers. Judicial review limited to committee’s independence, good faith, and sufficiency of investigation. 2. Miller Court defers to committee only if directors implicated don’t help select committee members. 3. Zapata Two steps: (1) Judicial review of committee’s independence, good faith, and investigative techniques (basically same as Auerbach) (2) Court can exercise its own “independent business judgment” – has wide discretion to reverse committee’s decision Court adopts a modified-Zapata test: Judicial review of substantive recommendation, may rely on it but not bound by it. 44 = substantive due care = procedural due care How are independent board members selected? CEO finds them, directors approve them. Note: Likely difference in practical effect of various rules? Not much. Delaware Law Futile demand? Particularized factual allegations of reasonable doubt that: majority disinterested BJR (broad leeway) Aronson Y N Demand excused Demand required Board sets up Special Litigation Committee? Demand made BJR governs Y Board can regain control of litigation N Shareholder- controls (No further board action) Demand accepted Demand rejected Corporation initiates and controls case Litigation may not initially proceed unless shareholder shows wrongful refusal BJR/Zapata Who is allowed to do this? Shareholders Which ones? Those holding shares at the time of the alleged injury. Some jurisdictions require holding for 6 mos. prior to demand. If board appoints special litigation committee, usually loses. Why? If they have enough confidence to set up special litigation committee, usually because was wrong to begin with. Ultimate end: settlement, very very few will make it to court. Why? Pretty good idea of allegations settlement easier 45 Parallel process in not-for-profits? Can have suit brought by company or public institutions (Attorney General). III. Shareholder Issues A. Shareholder Voting 1. Procedure a. FAQ When do shareholders vote? Shareholders meetings. Not technically required in every state. If number of shareholders is small enough can have telephone meeting. If shares are publicly traded, exchange will require actual shareholders’ meeting Sometimes called by officers/directors. Who votes? Only shareholders holding stock on record date can vote. Why? Elect directors. Approve director compensation. Vote on mergers or major asset sales. Why would people come together from across the country to vote? They don’t. Most don’t show up because most don’t care. Many shares are held by mutual funds (larger ones do care). Activism by larger institutional investors, especially when you have a lot of votes. What if people don’t show? For those interested enough, can vote by proxy. Appoint someone to vote on his behalf at shareholders meeting. Public corporations institutionalize the process because people don’t vote anyway. Technically speaking, shareholders are sheep. When enough large proxy votes come in, you can forego the meeting. West’s stump speech on shareholders’ meetings: Shareholders’ meetings are, by and large, meaningless farces... All they are is one of the directors standing up and talking about how they’ll do better next year and their accountants will guarantee it. Disney and Sony can have big multimedia presentations. If you’re McDonald’s you can have fries with it…Shareholders can come and protest about important social justice issues… I don’t think shareholders meetings advance the cause of democracy at all… If you don’t like what management is doing, dump your shares, get out and invest in a company you do like. 46 b. Cumulative voting = a method of allowing minority shareholders to elect a proportionate minority of the board members. # of shares owned x number of seats Ex: A and B are shareholders. A has 199 shares, B has 101 shares (total = 300). There are 6 candidates going for 3 director slots. B would have no say in any election if they used straight majority voting. B should have 1 of the 3 seats. The way cumulative voting works: multiply number of shares x number of director slots. Now all votes are spread over the 3 candidates you want. So B can put all 303 for one candidate and A picks the other 2. A = 199 x 3 = 597 B = 101 x 3 = 303 (Note: It’s possible for A and B to be stupid and mess this up. Generally, though, cumulative voting ends up with proportional minority representation on the board.) Why multiply them in the first place? Make sure there are no partial shares (since they usually can’t be voted). Works better in formula. If you have 11 directors, all you need is 8.5% to get a seat. The smaller the board, the greater the percentage of shares needed to put one person on the board. To get more control, majority shareholders, might suggest staggered terms. This decreases the number of seats elected at a given time, thereby increasing the number of shares you need to but someone on the board in a given year. c. Alternatives to reach the same result 1) Stagger the board. 2) Disproportionate voting Shareholders do not always want voting control to correlate with their investment interests. (Facially flies in the face of risk = control.) Ex: Struggling technology company recruits star technician George. He’ll invest firm-specific capital, learn firm-specific skills. In return, George may demand significant voting power. Firm is willing to give him more control than the value of the money he puts in (since he adds so much more). d. Indemnification (pp. 475-78) Insurance stuff arose after Smith v. Van Gorkem. Companies are likely to indemnify their directors. Del. General. Corp. Law allows indemnification of directors, officers, employees, and agents. D&O policies resolve issue of deciding whether or not to indemnify a person in an ad hoc decision. 2. Shareholder Voting Control 47 a. Stroh v. Blackhawk Holding Corp. (p. 541) Class A 87,868 x $3.40 initial sale at $4 stock split Class B 500,000 x .0025 Class B stock doesn’t have the “economic incidents” of shares of stock – no dividends, no residual rights. Just voting rights. This is reflected in price of share. Why do this? Management wants to retain control of firm. Stock split = dividend equal to the value of the stock you currently hold given to you in the form of stock, not $. Why do this? Some companies think their stock price is too high, use this to keep stock price reasonable. Share is a unit of proprietary interest in a corporation. Court: Proprietary right = right to participate in control or surplus/profits or distribution of assets. Class B stock has right to vote. That’s all that’s needed. To retain control, management could also issue non-voting stock to the public. But, the IL constitution at the time (but no longer) didn’t allow the issuance of non-voting stock. 1988 SEC adopted 19c-4 – barred NYSE from listing shares of corporation that dilute the minority with dual class shares as they did here. Rule vacated for exceeding the authority of the SEC. But the NYSE and AmEx decided to adopt the rule anyway, putting limits on disproportionate control/ownership. b. Ways for management to maintain voting control without having it correlate with investment: Ex: 3 participants in an industrial endeavor Investor Cartman Stan Kenny total Investment Voting interest $10M 20% $6M 30% $5M 50% $21M Voting interest is disproportionate to investment How do we get this structure? 1. Issue multiple classes of stock with different incidents of ownership. Stroh v. Blackhawk 2. Allocate one class of regular stock in proportion to desired voting interest. Then invest additional funds in other instruments, e.g., non-voting stock, preferred stock (get dividends first, guaranteed dividends), or debt to others. (Investors probably won’t want non-voting common stock (for tax purposes inter alia).) 48 Investor Cartman Stan Kenny total Investment Voting interest $10M 20% $6M 30% $5M 50% $21M Purchase Price of Stock $2M $3M $5M 3. Have class-specific board members and issue different classes of stock. Define stock classes by how many board members they are entitled to elect in accordance with desired split. 4. Voting trust. Cartman places some of his stock in trust, giving Stan and Kenny the right to direct its vote as trustees (= transfers legal title, remains equitable owner – retains incidents of ownership, e.g., gets dividends). 5. Vote pooling arrangements. 6. Irrevocable proxies. May be conditioned on something like the holder of the proxy working at the firm, their loan remaining outstanding, their being alive, etc.) Analysis (p. 544) What’s the public policy behind banning non-voting shares? At formation, don’t want promoters to take unfair advantage of other shareholders. Midstream, board may be taking unfair advantage of investors. Power without accountability. Directors could elect themselves through gaining cheaper shares. Investors won’t want the power without economic benefits. Don’t put product on market that people don’t want. Risk that manager will buy B shares and deliberately mismanage corporation and drive down value of A shares (without transgressing BJR or opening to derivative liability), but A shares, bring company back up, make profit. [KK: Shareholders with control but no financial interest in company may not make efficient decisions. No, because economic interest is still tied to stock price which reflect value, regardless of dividend sharing. Well, maybe still since they have less economic interest.] In Stroh, after shares initially sold, Class A stock fell in value, Class B stock rose in value. Why? How do you know what the value of B shares is? Were Class A shares treated unfairly? Don’t know how value of B shares is set. Market does it. [KK: maybe it indicates that shareholders don’t see the value of shares to be that disparate – try to bring them closer together in value.] Hard to argue that A shares were treated unfairly. They knew what they were buying. As long as B shares aren’t deliberately acting to drive down price of A shares, no problem. 49 Would you be willing to buy shares in a corporation where the people in control will use that control to give above-market rate salaries to themselves and their children? If you have the info going in and believe that investment is worth your while, then invest. Maybe, at a lower price here. Problem (p. 545-46) Investor All Management You # shares 1,000,000A 300,000A 1,000A Price1 $4 Price2 $6 You think that an outside investor will buy all shares for $9. Management offers new shares of A at $5 for each share held or 5 new non-voting B shares at 1 cent each. What to do? First simplify problem: Investor Outstanding Me You # shares 150 100 50 Price1 $6 Total value $900 $600 $300 Me puts in $500 more for 100 new shares at $5@. Me $1400 You 200 $1120 out of a corporation worth = 4/5 of stocks = 4/5 of corporate value 50 $ 280 = 1/5 of stock = 1/5 of corporate value So, by doing nothing, you lose $20 of value while retaining the same number of stocks. Though you’ve done nothing, you now have a smaller slice of the aggregate pie. You’re better off buying some additional shares. Should the board be able to put you to the choice of buying one more voting stock or 5 more non-voting stocks that are really cheap? No. If you don’t come up with the money, the effect is that you lose. Unfair for management to thrust it upon you. (If the exchange is fair to shareholders there’s no problem letting them consider it.) B. Proxy Fights Battle for control carried on specifically by proxy. Cards collected, votes counted. 1. Levin v. Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer, Inc. (p. 485) 50 Conflict for control between two groups in company. Outsiders claimed that incumbents spent money on PR and proxy firms at corporate expense unfairly. Issue: Is it illegal or unfair for incumbent directors to use corporate funds to defend themselves? Holding: No. Background concern: Is this being done for the firm, or to protect management’s jobs? Here, groups are advancing differing business policies. Problem (p. 488) Management has conflict of interest. 2. Rosenfeld v. Fairchild Engine & Airplane Corp. (p. 488) Shareholders ratify reimbursement of both sides in control contest. Court finds that management and successful contestants may be reimbursed for reasonable expenses in a proxy fight over policy. Rules: 1. Corporation can’t reimburse either party unless dispute concerns questions of policy (as opposed to personnel). (Rosenfeld) 2. Corporation can reimburse only reasonable and proper expenses. (Rosenfeld) 3. Corporation may reimburse incumbents whether they win or lose (Levin) 4. Corporation may reimburse insurgents only if they win and shareholders ratify payment. (Rosenfeld) Critiques: Policy/personnel distinction is difficult. Disputes are often personnel decisions framed as policy issues. Asymmetry in letting management be reimbursed whether they win or lose, but insurgents only if they win. Personnel dispute could have onerous consequences for the incumbent. Fictional distinction between policy and personnel. Reviewed rules for reimbursing parties in a proxy fight. Problem (p. 494) Citizen Kane is a rich EIC of NY Inquirer and CEO and 33% owner of its parent company. Geddes owns 10% and thinks he’d be a better CEO and EIC than Kane. Kane throws lavish party at country estate for shareholders and gives shpiel about why he should stay in control. Geddes throws a lean-and-mean party for shareholders on his yacht where he tells them why he should be in charge. Can either be reimbursed? 51 is policy at issue? Or personnel? – will probably find a policy rationale reimbursable are expenses reasonable? – only reasonable expenses reimbursable who won? – incumbent always reimbursed, contestant reimbursed only if wins Virginia Bankshares, Inc. v. Sandberg (p. 495) Confusing opinion. FABI owns 100% of VBI. VBI owns 85% of Bank. (s own 15%.) FABI does a freezeout merger of Bank into VBI, pays cash to stockholders. Stock value offered was $42. Directors described it as a high value. But it was not as good a value as they could get – stock was probably worth $60. [KK’s] Take-aways: A statement of reason by directors on a proxy is actionable under SEA § 14(a) if disbelieved by directors and false and misleading w.r.t. the subject matter. There was no causation of damages to a minority shareholder whose vote was irrelevant to the outcome. Why did they go to the shareholders if they didn’t have to? (p. 499) 1. Good PR 2. Ratify resolution of conflict of interest under VA law Question: Did the board misstate the underlying facts? D. Shareholder Proposals 1. Federal Rules a. SEC Rule 14a-9 (17 C.F.R. § 240.14a-9) Prior to this rule, had only state law fraud action. This federalized these categories of fraud through the hook of proxies (figured out how to get people for all securities fraud later). Rule 14a-9 gives a private cause of action for breach of § 14(a), i.e., soliciting proxies by means of materially false and misleading statements. Court gets cute (p. 500): Only get immunization from state law conflict of interest issue if you get ratification after full disclosure… Don’t have good ratification if you lied in your proxy materials… If no ratification, company went ahead with merger without good ratification (which it was allowed to do) so there’s no causal link. Had you not lied, you’d have ratification, but no claim. Take-aways: 1. There are private actions (not just SEC, state law fraud claims) for (federal) proxy rule violations. 2. Need causation (what’s meant is somewhat unclear). 52 3. There is a materiality element. Here, was statement of board that $42 was a good price a material one or not? (“material” = sufficient to change the vote of a prudent investor) b. Rule 14a-8 New rule – Q&A format – easier for lay people to understand Institutional shareholders = large shareholding blocs that use their power to influence management. Some popular shareholder proposals in last few years: 1. remove poison pills –defensive takeover tactic gives existing (non-raiding) shareholders right to buy additional shares at a discount upon certain trigger events ex: outside investor purchases a specified percentage of firm “flip-in-flip-over” pill (flip-in gives common shareholder right to buy common shares of stock, flip-over gives shareholder right to buy stick in bidder at time of merger at a substantial discount = substantial deterrent to hostile takeovers). In no case has a raider swallowed a poison pill. Rather, raider goes in and talks to board which then faces a BJ decision on whether to remove poison pill. 2. require annual re-election of directors 3. require secret balloting 4. require directors to hold a specified minimum amount of corporate shares (make them sensitive to stock price, align interests with shareholders) 5. adopt cumulative voting 6. prevent same person from being CEO and Chairman of the Board 7. prohibit green-mail (once-popular takeover tactic: someone would buy 30% of shares in firm, tell management that he’s ready to takeover, agrees not to if bought off at high stock price) 8. make all board committees headed by outside directors (?) 9. management’s slate should have more nominees than seats for elections – gives shareholders a choice 10. link director pay to corporate performance 11. require the compensation committee (that sets the salaries of directors) be composed entirely of independent directors and have its own compensation consultant 12. create a committee of shareholders who advise the directors Some of these are nuisance proposals, some backed by big investors. Most proposals now focus on corporate governance. 2. Cases a. ACTWU v. Wal-Mart Stores (p. 507) 1) The Case 53 Proposal: Corporation will prepare and distribute of reports re. its affirmative action and EEO policies, programs, and data plus a description of the company’s efforts to publicize its EEO policies to suppliers and purchase goods and services from women- and minority-owned suppliers Issue: Can exclude ’s proposal under the “ordinary business operations” exception (R.14a-8(c)(7))? Holding: Proposal concerns a significant policy consideration and therefore does not fall within exception (though some stuff is day-to-day stuff and should be excluded). Rule: The “ordinary business operations” exception applies to “proposals that are mundane in nature and do not involve any substantial policy or other considerations.” (italics in original) How do you know if it’s mundane or involves substantial policy? “[T]he line between includable and excludable employment-related proposals based on social policy considerations has become increasingly difficult to draw.” Examples of day-to-day employment matters: employee health benefits general compensation issues not focused on senior executives management of the workplace employee supervision labor-management relations employee hiring and firing conditions of employment and employee training and motivation Other reasons for legitimately excluding proposals: see below: (7), (1), (3), (2), (4), (6), (12) 2) Notes: Case-by-case analysis Overturning Cracker Barrel position (that employment-related social policy proposal may be excluded from a company’s proxy materials). This proposal concerned only preparing reports. Deadlines concerning these can be excluded under (1) or (6). Does J. Wood miss the point? The Proposal’s phrasing allows management to refuse to comply with “request” while insulating them from the BJR. Why is it such a big deal if the proposal lost miserably anyway? Good PR, management doesn’t want to be perceived as not being in control. 3) SEC Rule 14a-8 governs shareholder proposals a)Bases for the Board excluding a shareholder proposal Note: Under the old 14a-8, the following 13 subsections appeared under 14a-8(c). Under the new 14a-8, the following 13 subsections appeared under 14a-8(i). 54 (1) improper under state law (2) violation of state, federal, foreign law (3) violation of commission’s proxy rules (false/misleading statement) (4) personal grievance, special interest (convey private benefit, not shared by shareholders at large) ........................................................................................................... Austin v. ConEd (5) irrelevant ........................................................................................................ NYCERS v. Dole old: pertains to less than 5% total assets + 5% net earnings and gross sales + is not significantly related to business new: pertains to $10M or less gross revenues or total costs; or 3% gross revenue or total assets if that # is less than $10M [no “significantly related to business” language more objective] (6) absence of power/authority to effectuate/implement ..................................... NYCERS v. Dole (7) ordinary business operations ......... ACTWU v. Wal-Mart, NYCERS v. Dole, Austin v. ConEd (8) election to board (9) conflicts with company’s proposal at same meeting (10) moot/substantially implemented (11) duplication (substantially duplicative of proposal previously submitted by another proponent which will be included) (12) substantially the same as a prior proposal submitted within previous 3 years (of a 5 year period?) provided that old: if submitted 1x, got < 3% of votes cast if submitted 2x, got < 6% of votes cast 2nd time if submitted 3x, got < 10% of votes cast 3rd time new: if submitted 1x, got < 6% of votes cast if submitted 2x, got < 15% of votes cast 2nd time if submitted 3x, got < 30% of votes cast 3rd time (13) specific amounts of cash or stock dividends b) Revisions: Eligibility old: new: 1% or $1,000 for at least a year and on day of meeting R.14a-8(1) 1% or $2,000 for at least a year and on day of meeting R.14a-8(b) Old version: 14a(c)(7) New version: (i) Question 9 (7) “specific business decisions normally left to the discretion of management” 55 b. NYCERS v. Dole Food Co., Inc. (p. 518) Proposal: should set up a committee to study and report on various health care plan alternatives being considered by Congress. Issue: Can exclude ’s proposal under any of these exceptions: a. “ordinary business operations” R.14a-8(c)(7) b. “insignificant relationship” R.14a-8(c)(5) [not part of new R.14a-8(i)] c. “beyond power to effectuate” R.14a-8(c)(6) ? Holding: No, no, and no. a. It’s hard to argue that national health care is part of Dole’s ordinary business. b. This would involve a substantial weight on Dole. c. NYCERS seems disingenuous w.r.t. the third prong. Dole would only have to study health care reform. But that’s what’s fishy about this: what does “study” mean, anyway, and why should a study be enforced at the expense of the corporation? The truth is, the petitioners probably wanted Dole to lobby for health care reform, backed off and said just to study it. The overall goal of the proposal is policy-based; real corporate goals should be about money-making. OTOH, shareholders own the company, should be able to do whatever they like. [KK: court overlooked the fact that the health care plans being studies were not even viable options yet – none of them might be approved by Congress. What’s the point of investigating them if not to get involved in advocating for the one that’s best for the corporation?] Take-aways: Even if a proposal concerns ordinary business conduct, it can still involve significant strategic decisions that will significantly alter the way a company does business. Considering the court costs and ’s attorneys’ fees (at least in ACTWU v. Wal-Mart) in the foregoing two cases and the fact that both proposals at issue lost miserably when put to a shareholder vote, maybe it makes more financial sense to put lame proposals in the proxy materials. c. Austin v. Con Ed (p. 522) Proposal: non-binding endorsement of a retirement planning allowing employees to retire after 30 years of service, regardless of age Issue: Can exclude ’s proposal under any of these exceptions: “ordinary business operations” R.14a-8(c)(7) “confer a personal benefit on proponent” R.14a-8(c)(4) Holding: Excludable based on “ordinary business operations” exception. Worker issues are generally going to be thought inappropriate. Take-aways: An “audacious” proposal on a mundane topic is still mundane. The availability of other fora (e.g., collective bargaining) can be an indicator that a proposal is not extraordinary enough to be voted on by shareholders. d. Disingenuous aspects of these cases 56 Wal-Mart – the proponents didn’t want to publicize affirmative action policies, rather to promote them NYCERS – didn’t want research into health care plans, rather wanted lobbying for one Austin – employees wanted terms they couldn’t obtain through labor bargaining process Problems (p. 525) 1. Firm X makes 3 models of cars: 2 popular luxury sedans, 1 souped-up sportscar that always loses money. Firm keeps souped-up car because it helps their market for the other cars. Which shareholder proposals to stop producing the sportscar are excludable? Proposal A: company shall discontinue Proposal B: shareholders recommend that company shall discontinue Proposal C: amend by-laws to limit production to sedans A – is it “ordinary business operations” or not? (probably not since it involves a major strategic decision) B – may be proper, although the same question as above applies C – by-law amendments are things that shareholders can validly concern themselves, can probably limit business operations in this way. (How much shareholders can use by-laws or articles to affect ordinary business operations is an open question in the law.) Problems with measuring 14a-8(I) exceptions: Exception #7: How do you determine magnitude (ordinary v. extraordinary)? This is a question of fact to be decided by the jury. Exception #4: Conveying a private benefit to the proponent Union cases are extreme, although there may be specific benefits for anyone who would bother to bring a proposal. Generally, private benefit isn’t ambiguous. [KK: Thinking about shareholder loyalty: Controlling # of votes fiduciary responsibility Non-controlling # of votes can’t convey too personal a benefit through proposals you make – although someone else could make the proposal.] D. Shareholder Inspection Rights 1. General Shareholders who want to get involved in a proxy fight need to be able to contact, inform, and lobby other shareholders. Governed by SEA of 1934 § 14: Proxy rules provide for some kind of communication – either: (1) mail materials for proponent (can charge insurgent for expenses) or (2) give a copy of the shareholder list so you can do it yourself. Insufficiencies in §14: Not all firms are under § 14 since they may not be registered under the Act. 57 Insurgents may want to communicate directly, don’t want companies to mail material for them. Insurgents may want other information in addition to shareholder lists. 2. Crane v. Anaconda (p. 527) Facts: Crane announces tender offer for Anaconda stock. Anaconda refuses. Underlying strategic reason: If Crane has the list, it can send out all kinds of propaganda against management and in his favor. Stated reason: Crane has an improper purpose (i.e., has a purpose other than the business of the corporation) Issue: Whether a qualified shareholder (Crane) may inspect the corporation’s stock register to ascertain the identity of fellow shareholders for the avowed purpose of informing them directly of its exchange offer and soliciting tenders of stock. Holding: Anaconda must let Crane inspect the register. Rule: A shareholder desiring to discuss a tender offer with other shareholders should be granted access to the shareholder list unless the list is sought for a purpose adverse to the corporation or its shareholders. NY Statute in Crane (p. 527) – qualifying shareholder (“qualifying shareholder” = shareholder of record for preceding 6 mos. or 5% of shares) has right to see shareholder list and other corporate records DE Statute in Pillsbury (p. 529) – no shareholder qualifications, constrains shareholder by differentiating between shareholder lists and other business documents (more closely protected) Tender offer buyer (a.k.a. “raider”) instead of going to management to work out a merger, goes directly to shareholders and make them an offer for their stock. A good offer will be above market price. The offer is publicized in newspapers, by banks, etc. Shareholders tender their stock to the raider, well actually to a depository bank that holds shares in escrow until conditions set forth by person making the tender offer are met. Crane is an IL corporation. Anaconda is a MT corporation. Suit brought in NY where Crane is a foreign corporation doing business. Why sue in NY? Favorable law. KK’s Take-aways: Liberal construction of a statute in favor of stockholder whose welfare as a stockholder/welfare of corporation may be affected. (Sadler v. NCR too) Right to inspect stockholder list derives from property right of the stockholder and right to protect that interest. (In Sadler, court also notes NY statute’s intent to place shareholders and management on equal footing w.r.t. access to shareholders) 3. State Ex Rel. Pillsbury v. Honeywell (p. 529) 58 Pillsbury buys stocks because he cares about the morality of Honeywell’s work. Requests corporate records on bombs because he wants to stop them. Court denies him access because he doesn’t say anything about concern with return on investment. “Power to inspect may be the power to destroy” Options for “socially responsible” shareholders? invest in politically correct mutual funds do your thing more easily in a closed corporation If Pillsbury said that he was interested in financial effects of the anti-social policy, he could have had a case. Morality alone doesn’t cut it. The reason you have your shares publicly traded is to get capital. The people buying stock are making an economic investment (at least the court presumes and recognizes only economic interest) and want a good return on investment. If you want to maintain control over your company and your primary goal is morality, don’t issue stock. DE statute distinguishes between demand for shareholder list and corporate records. Burden of proof: shareholder list – company must prove the shareholder has an improper purpose corporate records – shareholder must prove that s/he has a proper purpose Shareholders may be embarrassed to have it known that they have stock in certain companies. Ex: Universities Can hold stock in street name – broker doesn’t write down beneficial owner’s identity. So it looks like Merrill-Lynch owns 15% of the company and Merrill-Lynch is not going to give you the names of the beneficial owners. You can get a NOBO list – Non-Objecting Beneficial Owners. Most shareholders are included. Shareholder lists List of record owners (CEDE list) – includes brokers holding shares in street name NOBO list – company calls brokers and asks them to compile list of beneficial owners listed (actual owners who gain the benefit of the shares) who don’t object to being 4. Sadler v. NCR (p. 533) AT&T launches tender offer for NCR (MD corporation doing business in NY) AT&T has no right under NY or MD law to get shareholders list. Under NY law, AT&T’s ally, Sadler has the right to get the shareholders list. Request both CEDE list (a.k.a. street list) and NOBO list. Court disagrees with Chancellor Allen, finds that NOBO lists aren’t all that different from CEDE lists. 59 Court notes the statutory purpose of “seeking ‘to the extent possible, to place shareholders on an equal footing with management in obtaining access to shareholders.” Problems (p. 540) proper purpose: promoting stock split improper purpose: provide service to shareholders (through upscale junk mail) E. Insider Trading 1. Introduction: Hypos #1: X wants to buy 51% of company. Current value is $100/share but X planson increasing value through cost-cutting measures. X purchases for $120/share, and folks starting selling for more than $100. That’s ok. Arbitrage = trading in two separate markets in the same commodity/stock Decreases ability to get huge gain, should get some on margin Arbitrageurs = traders who trade based on information (e.g., rumors of tender offers), not interested in long haul or improving long-term value of company. ex: Boesky – cheated by buying information about tender offers from loan officer Exxon prices are down due to outstanding environmental claims. #2: X gets loan from Y (loans officer) to buy company. Y calls Z and Z buys stock, knowing it will go up in value. This is inside information. It’s also insider information to know whether tender offer will succeed or fail. Who’s hurt by insider trading? 1. target shareholders – sell stock to insider instead of holding onto it and making more money [KK: but don’t they have to decide to sell on their own before they find out if there’s a buyer?] 2. other arbitrageurs 3. other issuers – public loses confidence in other issuers, makes it more difficult for them to issue stock and sell it (BUT no empirical support for this) 4. acquirer – more stock bought by acquirer more likely news of offer will leak; target managers put on notice, take defensive measures Arguments that insider trading isn’t a bad thing compensate/reward managers (investors can always watch and see what managers do and then do the same) more arguments from text: Most insider trading escapes detection banning it officially gives investors the mistaken impression that it doesn’t happen 60 There are no victims in need of protection – does anyone suffer a loss? should that person be owed any duty by the insider? 2. “Rule 10b-5” a. History Common law action for deceit False representation Of material fact With knowledge of falsity (or reckless disregard) With intention of causing reliance Justified reliance Damages b. The Statute 17 CFR § 240.10b-5 Employment of manipulative and deceptive devices. It shall be unlawful for any person, directly or indirectly, by the use of any means or instrumentality of interstate commerce, or of the mails or of any facility of any national securities exchange, (1) To employ any device, scheme, or artifice to defraud, (2) To make any untrue statement of a material fact or to omit to state a material fact necessary in order to make the statements made, in the light of the circumstances under which they were made, not misleading, or (3) To engage in any act, practice, or course of business which operates or would operate as a fraud or deceit upon any person, in connection with the purchase or sale of any security Common law action for deceit Statutory action 1. Rule 10b-5 1. false representation a. materiality 2. of material fact b. scienter 3. with knowledge of falsity (reckless c. causation disregard) d. reliance e. duty to person harmed (Dirks) 4. with intention of reliance by 2. New-fangled 10b-5 Misappropriation/ 5. justifiable reliance by Fraud on the source (O’Hagan) 6. damages 3. Mail/Wire fraud 4. Rule 14e-3 (1980) – get around duty requirement goal: protect market goal: protect individual investors { 61 c. SEC v. Texas Gulf Sulphur (1968, p. 364) Facts: Mining firm makes big find, tries to keep it quiet. Employees and their tippees buy stock before public is fully informed of magnitude of find. Company releases statement to quell rumors and speculative newspaper articles. Issue1: Did employees and tippees engage in illegal insider trading? Materiality 1. Test of materiality: Whether a reasonable person would attach importance in determining his choice of action in the transaction in question. info disclosing earnings and distributions of a company facts which affect the probable future of the company + which may affect the desire of investors to buy/sell/hold securities 2. The fact that an insider traded on it is evidence of it being material. Holding1: Yes. Can’t act on info until it is available to the public in a manner readily translatable into investment action. Issue2: Was the press release misleading (conveyed a false impression of the situation)? Disclose or abstain 1. Duty of abstinence ceases when info is incorporated into stock price/reaches investors 2. Current studies say that info is incorporated into stock prices in 15 minutes Holding2: Remand. The press release wasn’t quite false, but probably misleading to investors because it’s gloomy. To be liable under R.10b-5, the press release must have been released in connection with the purchase or sale of a security. The company itself isn’t buying or selling. Court: doesn’t matter so long as it meets the materiality standards and a reasonable investor would rely on it in a decision to buy or sell stocks. The reasonable investor’s decision to buy or sell meets the “in connection with” requirement. d. Notes Purpose of SEA ’34: prevent unfair practices, insure fairness in securities transactions Policy goal: protect justified expectations that all investors trading on impersonal exchanges have relatively equal access to material information Essence of insider trading rule: (Matter of Cady, Roberts & Co.(1961)) Anyone who has direct or indirect access to information intended to be available only for a corporate purpose and not for anyone’s personal benefit may not take advantage of the information, knowing it is unavailable to the investing public. So, you don’t have to be an actual insider, just have inside information (*not according to Chiarella (1980), though, see p. 378) see Dirks! (p. 378) If you have inside information, you have two options: disclose abstain from trading/tipping 62 State of mind required for liability for false/misleading statement: recklessness Private Securities Litigation Reform Act of 1995 Created “safe harbor” for forward-looking statements that are hedged by meaningful cautionary statements identifying important factors that could cause actual results to differ materially from those predicted. Blue Chip Stamps v. Manor Drug Stores (p. 377) Buyers and sellers are protected by R.10b-5, not would-be buyers and sellers who conducted no securities transactions. Problems (p. 374) 1. a. Martha inherits a farm, hires a geologist, discovers oil under George’s land, buys his land without telling him. Is George entitled to recover profit? No. No cousin-cousin fiduciary duty. Martha may/should profit from her investigation. b. What if Martha gives him misleading info – “How would I know any more than you?” Duty not to lie. Liable for lying, misleading. c. What if the leasing agent buys George’s land? In order to be liable, need duty. If no duty to purchase and sell, then no duty. If general agent whose role extends to purchase, may have duty. No duty no liability, except where there’s fraud. 2. Juan and Betty are partners. Partners owe each other a fiduciary duty. Juan breaches his fiduciary duty by investigating ore and buying land from Betty without telling her there’s ore. If he only has a tenuous theory on the presence of ore, result is uncertain, can’t be sure if it’s material info. 3. Eve is a shareholder who overhears a company geologist say that the company found a new ore deposit. Eve buys Bob’s shares. Eve is not liable. No co-shareholder duty/liability. 4. Federal law and state law differ. (all you need to know) 3. Dirks Facts: Dirks, an investment analyst, received info about alleged fraudulent practices at Equity Funding from Secrist (former officer of EF). Dirks investigated, believed there was fraud, advised clients and other investors, and urged the WSJ to write story on it (declined). While Dirks investigated and spread the word, stock price fell from $26 to <$15. Fraud was then found by authorities. Issue: Did Dirks aid and abet violations of § 17(a) of the Securities Act ’33, § 10b of the SEA ’34, and SEC Rule 10b-5 by repeating allegations of fraud to members of the investment community? SEC approach: there should be equal info among all traders Court: no criminal liability – Tipper didn’t violate any fiduciary duty by tipping Dirks Dirks has no derivative duty to breach 63 3 Take-aways 1. Whether tippee violates 10b-5 depends on: whether tipper violates fiduciary duty to firm’s shareholders in giving tip and whether tippee knew/should have known of the breach 2. Definition of duty (for purposes of insider trading only): Fiduciary duty breach occurs only where a tipper earns a personal benefit from the tip Duty of care violations don’t matter, just duty of loyalty violations. 3. Lawyers and accountants are temporary insiders for the purposes of insider trading. can’t trade on client’s info, have same duty not to disclose. (fn.14) Precedent: In re Cady, Roberts & Co. corporate insiders have common law affirmative duty of disclosure non-insiders could by obligated to disclose or abstain basic principle: there should be equal info among all traders Two-part test for Rule 10b-5 violation (Cady, Roberts & Co and Chiarella) 1. existence of relationship affording access to inside info intended to be available for corporate purposes only 2. unfairness of allowing a corporate insider to take advantage of that info by trading without disclosure Chiarella No general duty to disclose – duty arises only from a specific fiduciary relationship (trumps 2nd bullet above) Duty is breached only where there is manipulation or deception, secret profits basic principle: only some people, in some circumstances, will be barred from trading while possessing material nonpublic info. Analysts often ferret out and analyze info by talking with corporate insiders. This info can’t be made simultaneously available to the corporation’s shareholders or the public generally. Rules: 1. Insiders can’t give info to an outsider for the improper purpose of exploiting it for personal gain. 2. Tippee derives duty to disclose or abstain where he knows or should know that the insider breached his duty. Questions to ask (Dirks): Is the info material? 64 Is the info nonpublic? Is disclosure of the info a breach of duty? Will an insider directly or indirectly benefit from disclosure? (no personal gain no breach) If so, is tippee under a derivative duty to disclose or abstain? Does the tippee know or should he know that there’s been an insider breach? 4. O’Hagan a. Background: Carpenter - the news rumor case. Rumors do affect pricing, so the column is material information. Under Dirks - Nothing wrong. No fiduciary duty relationship. But court in this casehas duty to Wall Street Journal. “Contents of columns. . . were journal’s private property prior to publication.” What this means: duty turns on whether tipper has internal rule against taking the information. Problem: should we have criminal charges based on civil arrangement? Courts say “sure”. The Skinny: Assuming Carpenter is good law, would publishing statistics too early in error mean breach of fiduciary duty? No, because that isn’t intentional. What the court is concerned about here is misappropriation. b. The Case: Facts: O’Hagan was a partner at a law firm, but not the principal attorney in this project. (Question: Does liability extend to entire firm?) O’Hagan used knowledge acquired to make big money via trading. O’Hagan is indicted. Holding, Reasoning: Part One: Misappropriation Under the “new” reading of 10b-5 and 10(b), a fiduciary’s undisclosed use of information belonging to his principal for personal gain constitutes fraud in connection with purchase or sales of security. Court finds misappropriation, even though O’Hagan bought shares of target, but he owes duty to acquiror. It’s not a traditional violation, since he had no fiduciary duty to the target. The Dirks test would fail. Part Two: Rule 14(e)(3) Introduced in 1980, this rule applies only to tender offer, but applies to all third parties who use information for personal gain via trading these securities. This includes agents of tender offerors (no back-door action there). Although O’Hagan feels this is too broad of an extension, the court defers to the SEC in interpreting and administering 10b-5 (within reason). Part Three: Mail Fraud. Just know it’s out there. c. Notes 1) Problem: Court doesn’t clarify fiduciary relationship between lawyer and client. ABA rule only covers attorneys who act in a manner disadvantageous to the client after 65 disclosure to and consent by client. What is the disadvantage in O’Hagan’s case. None, really. 2) Hypos: a) Bud Fox gets law firm associate to pass insider information. Buys target stocks. Gains. Shares profits with associates. Dirks: Violation for target associate only. O’Hagan: Yes. b) Fox’s dad is an officer for airlines. Dad learns FAA has formed airline liable. Trouble? Dirks: Did dad breach duty? As an officer, looks like dad received personal benefit. O’Hagan: What is the airline’s internal rule? c) Mitsubishi develops new home video camera. With press release, M stock will go up, and Sony will go down. Your Mitsubishi’s outside patent lawyer. You buy stock. Liable? Under fn. 14, yes. You sell Sony stock. No duty via Dirks, but you do as an attorney under O’Hagan. Harris dilemma: no harm done! Think of it more in terms of equality of information. Patent lawyer for government buys stock. No Dirks, but what about O’Hagan? Does an internal rule exist? IV. Mergers, Acquisitions, and Takeovers (p. 670) A. Mergers and Acquisitions 1. Merger Mechanics a. [Statutory] merger – separate legal entity is formed of two legal entities with the former ceasing to exist and the latter existing as owner subject to the liabilities of both. Merger agreement made between two boards of directors. Shareholder approval under provisions DE General Corporation Law §§ 251, 262. Exceptions to shareholder approval: (a) short-form merger – typically done when one company owns 90% of the other; remaining shareholders have appraisal rights (= right of opponents to merger to be paid off in cash for the fair value of their shares) (b) disparate size and number of outstanding shares (outstanding shares will only increase by 20% after acquiring the target) b. [Practical mergers] 1) Stock swap – exchange of shares by acquirer issuing shares to target in return for target shares. Target becomes subsidiary, can be dissolved or use a short-form merger. Problem may arise if a minority of shareholders don’t want to go along. Partial solution: minority has to accept a share exchange approved by majority of target shareholders. (DE) Variation: Acquirer pays cash for shares 66 2) Asset purchase – acquirer purchases assets of target for stock in acquirer; target ordinarily liquidates and distributes acquirer stocks to its shareholders Variation: Acquirer pays cash for assets acquirer doesn’t deal with shareholders no(?) unforeseen liabilities takes a lot of paperwork – what the inventory is, who has title to it… State laws vary w.r.t. need for: shareholder approval – most require approval for sale of assets, acquirer may not have to vote on asset acquisition appraisal rights – most grant ‘em, not DE though if the majority went along with it (they aren’t getting a raw deal, should be no difference in value) c. Triangular combination – acquirer creates subsidiary, shares of target go to subsidiary, acquirer merges target into subsidiary, target shareholders get shares of parent ensures that there’s no minority interest remaining Why do a triangular merger? tax benefits dissenters/appraisal rights – rights that corporate statutes give to target’s shareholders to sell their stock to the corporation at its “fair value” Notes: Rights only apply where shareholder dissents to specified corporate transactions Fair value = appraised value of stock immediately before the transaction Why these rights exist: State may want to protect shareholders rights in investment – firm shouldn’t be able to transform investment into something else (another firm entirely, substantially changed nature of firm) Mergers, etc. impose higher risk of economic loss. This would not be a problem if the shareholder could just sell his stock easily. DE recognizes that in a fluid market, shareholders can sell their shares. See Del. Gen. Corp. Law § 262(b) (Supp. p. 81): No appraisal rights if (i) stock is listed on a national stock exchange or (ii) held of record by more than 2,000 holders. 2. De Facto Mergers Farris v. Glen Alden (p. 673) Facts: List owns 38.5% of GA, wants to merge the two companies. (Statutory) merger Sale of assets Glen Alden (PA law) appraisal rights appraisal rights List (DE law) appraisal rights no appraisal rights (with majority approval) 67 How to avoid appraisal rights? Have List (a larger company) sell its assets to (the smaller) Glen Alden. GA purchases Lists’ assets for stock. List liquidates and distributes GA stock to its shareholders. List shareholders end up with 76.5% of GA shares. List worked this by executing notice and proxy statement and mailing these to GA’s shareholders prior to annual meeting. Along with this notice were recommendations of amendments to articles of incorporation. This would allow authorization of more shares to cement deal. claims dissenters’ rights. Court: “When a corporation combines with another so as to lose its essential nature and alter the original fundamental relationships of the shareholders among themselves and to the corporation, a shareholder who does not wish to continue his membership therein may treat his membership in the original corporation as terminated and have the value of his shares paid to him.” To determine whether the change is fundamental, the court looks at several factors, including: type of corporate interests size of assets and liabilities management structure and personnel shareholders’ level of interest, and financial loss. In this case, all of the factors point to fundamental change, and that means a merger. There is an exception for sales, but the exception is really only one of form, and not of substance. It’s a de facto merger. Can’t avoid appraisal rights under our (PA) state law. The plaintiff therefore gets dissenters’ rights. This is a rare example of substance over form. Analysis questions 1. To keep the committee’s intent, the law could have been drafted as “no right to dissent even if the transaction has all the attributes of a merger… and we mean it!” 3. Freezeout Mergers a. Coggins v. New England Patriots Football Club (p. 692) Facts: Sullivan buys AFL franchise for $25,000. 10 investors, $25,000 for 10,000 shares each. 120,000 shares of non-voting common stock sold, $5 each. Sullivan ousted from control. Sullivan borrows money to buy voting shares for $102/share. To buy back the firm, Sullivan has to buy out shareholders. This is because Sullivan must offer assets, since he needs security for personal loans to buy stock (fiduciary duty). Sullivan can’t do this unless either shareholders approve or there are no minority shareholders to approve. Sullivan must freeze out shareholders. To do this, Sullivan creates a new firm, with the hopes of merging the two firms. Since Sullivan is the 100% owner of the new firm, it certainly approves of the merger. Under Massachusetts law, a majority of old firm 68 shareholders must also approve the merger. Sullivan offers $15/share to the non-voting shareholders, but what about voting members? It doesn’t matter, they approve! Coggins bought 10 shares for $50. (p. 694) Holding, Reasoning: Merger impermissible because need a business purpose. Mass. court gets this from Del. case: Singer v. Magnavox (acquirer bought 60% of Magnavox, then bought 16% through cash-out merger) – business purpose test Burden of proof: s must prove (1) legitimate business purpose, then (2) fairness to the minority. [goal: balance right to “selfish ownership” vs. fiduciary responsibility to minority owners] Can’t force a minority to submit their shares. Can buy shares on open market or through tender offer – but may have hold-out problems Remedy for an illegal freeze-out merger: rescission of the merger. Exception: too much 3rd-party good faith reliance on merger (for too long – 10 yrs.). Damages = present value of stock (what shareholders would have had if the merger was rescinded) Court finds value is $80/share. (Note, p. 698) Weird outcome since: 1. Del. courts under Singer might have allowed this merger. In the later Tanzer case, the court held that business purpose relating to majority shareholder suffices (might be enough that majority shareholder wanted to pay off his debts.). In other words, business purpose doesn’t necessarily imply a corporate business purpose. 2. If Sullivan wanted to show business purpose, could have shown one. 3. Singer was rejected in Del. by the time Coggins was decided. New test: fairness (Weinberger) – controlling shareholders owe a fiduciary duty to minority shareholders. Fairness - fair dealing + fair price One way to look at fairness is “was a majority of shareholders happy?” The fact that a majority of shareholders approved of a $15/share price should conclusively prove that they considered it fair. Is there a sheep problem here? These are Patriot fans are buying the shares, not professional stockholders. Probably were sheep. Maybe, thought it was better to get 3x the initial puchase price than to be owners of the team. Suspicious that it wasn’t offered as a tender offer? Analysis (p. 698) 1. Legitimate business purpose? Reminiscent of Schlensky v. Wrigley (baseball field lights), Dodge v. Ford (dividend investment), shareholder proposals. Probably, having a winning team is a legitimate business purpose. 3. What if funds were used for another business venture of Sullivan’s? 69 See Sinclair Oil Corporation (p. 338). Mass. applies business purpose test, relying on the DE case, Singer. DE rule is the fairness test as shown in Rabkin…. b. Rabkin v. Hunt Chemical (p. 699) [DE] Facts: Olin buys majority of Hunt stock from Turner & Newell with an agreement that if it buys any additional stock within a year (from other stockholders), it will do so at the same price ($25). Olin had always intended to buy the remaining stock, but waited until the year was up so it could get a better price ($20) through a cash-out merger. Prof: When was it clear that they always intended to own 100%? Not clear from case. Olin charged with bad faith. JB: It seemed pretty clear to me, since Olin purchased the remainder within weeks after the expiration date. Holding, Reasoning: Court held that facts support a claim of unfair dealing sufficient to defeat dismissal (looks like fairness test mentioned in last case). In addition, the stockholders’ remedies aren’t confined to appraisal, when fraud, misrepresentation, selfdealing, and other nasty stuff is going on (Weinberger). In this particular case, it would seem that D would have to have acted in good faith to ensure P received the contracted (?) price of $25/share. Test: fairness fair price fair dealing What did Olin do wrong here? Prof. sees nothing wrong with lying about when they would buy the stock. Nothing inherently illegal in what Olin did. What precisely Olin did wrong is unclear. Aftermath: judgment for s on remand. [KK: I don’t get it – they made no commitment to buy within the year or to buy as soon as they were interested in purchasing the remaining shares. What does this mean: “[I]nequitable conduct will not be protected merely because it is legal.” (p. 704)] Analysis (p. 705) What do s gain by blocking merger? Why would s reject appraisal in favor of other remedies? 1. A dissenting shareholder can get a risk-free investment – if company grows by more than market return, can elect to be treated as if he had held stock all along, free-ride on improvements. 2. A dissenting shareholder with a right to rescind/enjoin merger can hold things up and get a better price. Extortion 3. Attorney’s fees; Class action possibility (more attorney’s fees) Recap: DE rule: entire fairness 70 MA rule: business purpose Doesn’t make a huge difference which test is applied. Except in weird cases (usually occurring in mini-series and prime time soaps), can make a record of business reasons (a little perjury goes a long way, contort reasons a little). B. Takeovers 1. Hostile vs. friendly deals Depends on management’s approach. When management acquiesces, offer is friendly. Why does management acquiesce? Often, they get $$$ – indirectly or directly (ex: 5-yr employee Ks with high liquidated damages clause, golden parachutes, severance pay, consulting Ks) What does this mean to shareholders? Company value remains the same – so pay-offs to management are in lieu of $ going to shareholders Conflict of interest for management, though not often recognized. Heightened level of scrutiny for takeover defense cases. Romano reading 1. Market for corporate control theory: management will behave properly because if not, the company will be taken over. Raiders look for badly-managed companies to takeover and manage better. 2. Backlash against excessive takeovers. Not just about management and shareholders, there’s also workers to be concerned about. 3. Empirical studies of how companies did before and after takeovers by tender offers: Successful takeover targets have positive returns (stock price does better than the market). Unsuccessful tender offers initially have positive returns, but they are lost if there are no offers within next two years. Unsuccessful mergers result in neither positive nor negative net returns. 2. Williams Act Problem (handout) §§ 13(d), 14(e), Rule 13e-4(f) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 No definition of “tender offer” in Williams Act. Usually people know when they’re making one, but it’s not always clear. Schedule 13(d) is what you file when you reach the 5% threshold. 14(d)1 usually filed at the same time. 1. Can J secretly buy 20%? Obligation to file kicks in at 5% but has 10 days in which to file 13(d) and in those 10 days can get the other 15%. After 10 days, it’s no longer a secret. § 13(d)(1) 2. Can J and 3 pals agree to each buy 4.99%? Pals = associates, have to file 13(d) 71 § 13(d)(3) – aggregate purchases 3. Does J have to disclose his unconventional plans? Probably. § 13(d)(1)(c) – major change in business or corporate structure must be disclosed § 14(e) – untrue statement of material fact or omission of fact with respect to tender offer 4. Can J pull a “Saturday Night Special,” i.e., announce the tender offer on Friday afternoon and hold it open only until next Monday? No. Offer must stay open for at least 21 days. Rule 13e-4(f)(1) 5. J only wants 51% of stock, can he accept stock on a first-come-first-serve basis? No, must take on pro rata basis. § 14(d)(6) 6. J wants to start with a low price and raise it only if insufficient people tender. Can he? Yes, but the increased consideration applies to the early tenders as well. § 14(d)(7) Other points about rule – words are not always what they seem Who has to comply with 13(d)? Text What it means Any person who… person = groups too after acquiring directly or indirectly… If you’re a group, have to file when you form group, not just actually acquire beneficial ownership of any equity security… equity security = ownership interest in the company with residual rights registered pursuant section 12 of the SEA… company has to be big enough is directly or indirectly the beneficial owner… beneficial owner = person who has power to invest/divest of more than 5% of such class… Have to declare options to buy more later Do these rules mean anything? Do they increase shareholder value or help management? What are they designed to do? May facilitate auction for stock – prices may go up for shareholders. May impede tender offers – less options for shareholders, negative returns according to study in Romano 3. Cheff v. Mathis a. The Case Facts: Policy at stake – Cheff had their own retail sales force (would go door-to-door and “inspect” furnaces, deconstruct them, say there are missing parts and not reassemble it); 72 Maremont thought that sales could be taken care of with a handful of salesman in a wholesale way. Maremont starts buying stock, demands seat on board, refused. Employees start get worried. Holland Furnace bought its own stock on the market. Ultimately, Maremont is bought out above market – greenmail. Shareholders object to the stocks being bought with corporate funds. Holding: Corporate funds were properly used to buy corporation’s shares from would-be raider (Maremont) in order to protect against a change in policy/liquidation. Actual purpose was not just to perpetuate control. b. Note on stock prices: When selling big chunks of stock, selling price may include a “control premium.” 4. Director accountability re: takeovers DE court has been somewhat reactionary – originally think takeovers are a good thing, then back off in the late 80s. a. Ways of finding System order: 1) One way: Accountability of directors – virtual immunity for incumbents. (Cheff v. Mathes) More realistic scrutiny – (Unical and Revlon) Back to virtual immunity Back to accountability (QBC) Another way of looking at the cases: POSITIONS IN DEFENSE TACTICS (getting rid of raiders) Passivity Do nothing Auction What management does: Management should do nothing in response to a takeover bid. Management should lie down, where it’s in the best interests of the shareholders, let the shareholders vote. What management does: Management runs an auction. Give in to the idea that the company will be taken over, but have some discretion as to who takes over (since the offers are structured complexly) Theory: Takeovers are efficient, good. Ineffective management deserves to be taken over. Theory: Management should try to get the best price for the shareholders, Full Discretion Interposition What management does: Managers interposes itself between raider and shareholder. Theory: Stop short-termism. Interests of company to stick around for a while, broaden its market share, shareholders are in it for the quick buck and shouldn’t have a say in what happens. Constituency protection – groups within the firm deserve protection as much as 73 shareholders (e.g., employees, suppliers, lenders). Burden of proof Inside directors – direct conflict burden to justify purchase by showing (1) good faith and (2) reasonable investigation (a lot like duty of care) Outside directors – no such conflict (although do receive a small salary) lesser burden, just justify their actions Application of law to facts suggests extreme deference to BJR. Directors may have legitimate responsibility to employees. Should a company be allowed to hold itself up for ransom and its employees to be fired? If allow raider to come in, employees might be fired Company may go downhill anyway, with employees losing their jobs. So maybe it would have made more sense to let Maremont come in. In a perfectly competitive market, the employees can find other fraudulent door-to-door sales work. Greenmail - “An unfriendly suitor’s act of buying enough stock in a company to threaten a hostile takeover, and of then agreeing to sell the stock back to the corporation at an inflated price.” Generally causes a loss to a firm’s other shareholders. Buy stock at price above market value causes other stocks to fall, plus the stock is bought with corporate funds with a premium going to the raider. Analysis (p. 719) 1. Should the shareholders be asked about the change in policy? Should shareholders have a say in this? Is it an ordinary business operation? 5. What more could board members have done to protect themselves? They did a pretty good job – see list on p. 717: got professional advice, investigated… 5. Unocal v. Mesa Petroleum (p. 722) a. The Case Facts: Case got media attention because of the acquirer – Boone Pickens ( autobiography cleverly titled “Boone”) not such a nice guy Pickens (Mesa) gets 13% of Unocal and then makes a two-tiered front-loaded tender offer for the rest of the stock. First 37% get $54 cash/share, remainder get $54 junk bonds/share. Junk bonds are less desirable than cash. This is a coercive offer since people are more likely to tender early to get the cash. Unocal hires an expert who determines Pickens’ price is low. Unocal decides on a selftender offer – kicks in only when Mesa gets >50%, (Unocal would buy remaining 49+%). Mesa is excluded from this offer. Unocal will use assets from the original shares to purchase the stockets, lowering the value of the company. This is a scorched-earth tactic. 74 Is Unocal’s tender offer a two-tier offer too? Notes are allegedly worth $72 but may be tied to market price. Going through the numbers: Assume the company is worth $55/share, with 1,000 shares outstanding. Total value at takeover would be $55,000. Pickens buys 100 shares (10%) for $35/share. (= $3,500) Pickens needs 400 shares to reach 50%. Buys 400 shares at $55/share. (= $22,000) Company then starts self-tender offer – buys remaining shares in market at $70/share [$72 in actual case] for a cost of $35,000. Recap: Company starts out with a value of $55,000 Drained of $35,000 in self-tender offer worth $20,000. Company must be worth more than that to buy Pickens out for $25,500 ($3,500 + $22,000) To buy out Pickens and for Pickens to break even, company’s true value must be $60,500 ($60.50/share): $60,500 – $35,000 = $25,500 If the company buys all of its stock, the outstanding shares are all owned by Pickens, but company can still vote their shares (unless they retire the shares). Pickens as a result of shares being bought back by company is forced to pay a higher price. Shareholders complain about the 50% tactic – don’t wait that long. Unocal agrees to waive this condition – will take 50,000,000 shares no matter what. To finance the deal, borrow money (raises financial risk of transaction). Pickens’ complaint: Unfair for directors to give special deal to other shareholders and not to us Issue: Whether a corporation’s self-tender which excludes from participation a stockholder making a hostile tender offer is valid. Holding: Court finds for Unocal Two prongs: 1. Directors must show that they had reasonable grounds to believe that a danger to corporate policy and effectiveness existed due to another’s stock ownership, burden of proof satisfied by showing good faith and reasonable investigation. Cheff v. Mathes (prove duty of loyalty by proving duty of care) 2. Balancing – proportionality test: to be covered by BJR, actions of directors have to constitute a reasonable response to a threat reasonably believed to be posed. Court finds first part easily satisfied (nobody liked that scoundrel Pickens), and that the coercive/greenmail aspects of the proposed takeover indicate a severe enough threat to justify Unocal’s drastic measures. b. Defense tactics with “exotic, but apt, names” (p. 730) Crown jewel – profitable part of a large conglomerate White knight – friendly party to a corporate transaction that saves you from a hostile raider 75 Pacman defense – turn around and gobble up the raider, launch a takeover bid for them Golden parachute – lucrative severance/retirement package c. Ulterior motives? 1) Appraisal rights - Unocal directors don’t think much of appraisal rights, but shareholders could still this to avoid merger. Unocal directors were really more concerned with keeping their jobs. 2)This was when people had negative views of junk bonds. (Maybe they shouldn’t – high yield, high risk/control). Just ask yourself what weighs more: a pound of feathers, or a pound of junk bonds? Analysis questions Unocal standard is like BJR+. Unocal adds balancing/proportionality test: reasonable response to a threat posed. Is Pickens’ reputation as a greenmailer relevant? Board doesn’t have to pay him off. If he succeeds in taking over, he’s going to own 100% anyway. Junk bonds holders may end up holding debt obligations for Pickens’ own companies – may not be good investments since he’s an unsavory character. Would it be relevant if Pickens had a reputation for liquidating companies or would change company’s practices? List of other concerns directors can respond to include impact on other constituencies (e.g., employees) (p. 728), duty to preserve corporation enterprise Aftermath Unocal did well after Pickens left them alone, tightened their belts and made better decisions, cash flow improved. 6. Revlon v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings (p. 733) Background: Oral decision announced 5/85, written decision cam out 6/85. A few days later, Perelman2 (Pantry Pride) approached Revlon about acquiring stock for $40-45. Revlon didn’t like. Directors should be happy, since Unocal opinion says there’s a threat of shareholders getting lower price, allows them to justify rejection of offer. Firm is worth more in pieces than it is under their management. Defensive measures: 2 Perelman moved to NY at age of 35, borrowed $1.5M to buy jewelry stores, paid back loans and made $15M. Bought candy company, used it to buy other companies (e.g., Marvel). Paul, Weiss handled it, Prof. said “nice to meet you” to Perelman. Bought back remaining stock, bought Pantry Pride. Issue $75M in junk bonds. Had lots of money to go after Revlon. Lipton (Wachtel, Lipton) and Flom (Skadden, Arps, Slate, Meagher & Flom) were involved. Mild ethical questions – clients kept these guys on retainer since they didn’t want ‘em on the other side. Flom to this day owes Prof. a nickel because when Prof. spent summer at Skadden he gave him a nickel to buy a paper. 76 Company repurchase up to 5M of outstanding shares – (1) get rid of extra cash, (2) get more control, (3) make it more expensive for M&F/PP/Perelman. Notes Purchase Rights Plan – if someone gets 20% of stock, shareholders can exchange stocks for $60/share. Poison pill. Rights redeemable by action of Revlon board. The Battle Round 1 2 3 4 Final M&F/Perelman approach Bergerac (Revlon CEO), make offer tender offer for $47.50/share contingent on financing and on NPRP rights being redeemed by board offers $42/share3 contingent on getting 90% offers $50… $53… offers $56.25 Annie Oakley clause (“Anything you can do I can do better”) $58 + lawsuit Revlon 1. Stock buyback 2. NPRP self-tender offer for 1/3 of stock for $100/share, incur additional debt Board looks for white knight White knight = Forstmann4 Management buy-out (MBO), golden parachutes, shareholders complain: to do MBO, you need to take on more debt, that would lower the price of the notes you gave us (lessens the chances that if they go bankrupt shareholders will be able to get anything out of the company) $57.25 + (1) lock-up option on crown jewels, (2) cancellation fee of $25M (too much debt to do MBO, Forstmann comes up with money/risk wants control) Holding, Reasoning: divides fight into 2 sections: 1. Before Revlon was definitely going to sold (Rounds 1-3), management’s actions met Unocal proportionality test. Round 1 goes to Revlon, but round 4 goes to M&F/Perelman. Why are these defensive tactics different? Board’s duty changes once break-up is inevitable. At that point, management has duty to get best price for shareholders. = “Revlon duties” Note: If Revlon duties are the rule, then all a white knight immediately implies Revlon duties. After all, looking for a purchaser seems to indicate a sale and/or merger is inevitable. The white knight strategy really seems to hog-tie the directors. Questions (p. 744) 1. Lock-up option gives White Knight ability to buy selected target assets in return for a particular price. 2. Board’s duty to act as auctioneer when sale or break-up of company become inevitable. Still lot of confusion as to when that happens. 3 Goes down because of debt, cash has flown out the window. Reflects declining value of shares. Shareholders who didn’t tender to Revlon were hurt. 4 Pseudo-hero of “Barbarians at the Gate.” 77 3. Board’s consideration of other constituencies must be rationally related to benefits for stockholders. Board’s has contractual and good faith duties to creditors. (p. 740) Aside: Who is Michael Milken? Believed that could finance saving the world through high-yield junk bonds (risky companies) Guiliani went after prominent insider trading and questionable transactions, targeted Ivan Boesky. Boesky implicated Milken. Parking violations (parking stock in excess of 5% so don’t have to file it = 13(d) violation). 7. Paramount Communications, Inc. v. Time Inc. (p. 744) Facts: Warner Bros. CEO = Steve Ross Not efficiently managed, loose corporate culture, didn’t treat shareholders well. Time, Inc. CEO = N.J. Nicholas Old stoic company, strong ethical position, supported shareholder rights. Ross doesn’t want to sign on to his resignation in 5 years. What’s really going on: Steve Ross knows he’s dying of cancer, wants to ensure that someone will take his place (which is hard because he thinks he’s irreplaceable). Original merger plan: Stock deal Stock prices: Time Warner T1 $105 $36 T2 $110 $42 T3 $109 $45 Exchange rate = .465 $51.15 Warner shareholders would have most control (62%). Time offers $51.15 for $45 shares (later, Time shareholders are offered $175 then $200 for their $109 stock. Triangular merger structure, use subsidiary, no shareholder vote required. But, NYSE requires vote because Time will issue 20% more shares (that go to Warner shareholders) than those they have in the market already in order to accomplish deal. Since this is a good deal, other companies may jump in. Defensive tactics: 1. “Confidential letters” - Go to big banks, pay small sum for them to agree not to finance a rival offer for Warner. 2. No shop clause (promise to reject other offers) 3. Automatic share exchange (can buy each other’s stock to keep it from raiders’ hands) 78 Time is proud to be doing it all for cash. (Debt, junk bonds unpopular) Enter Paramount… Paramount makes a ‘fully negotiable offer’ for Time stock. Offer based on three conditions: Terminate merger Cable franchises Judicial determination that Delaware anti-takeover statute doesn’t apply. Shareholder should be excited about Paramount deal – lots o’ $$$. Warner deal is only for $51.15/share, Paramount puts $175/share offer on the table. Note: Investment bankers who haven’t signed no-shop agreements are clued into possible windfall and have a better chance with getting a piece of the action. Warner deal goes up to $70/share in cash and securities. Borrow $10M to finance it. (So much for debt-less merger.) Time shareholders no longer get to vote under NYSE rules (because this is a tender offer). Warner stockholders don’t vote, just tender shares. Board approves deal. Shareholders don’t have opportunity to look at Paramount $175 deal offer. Paramount raises the cash offer for Time to $200/shares, negotiable, contingent on canceling Time-Warner deal. One key to case is that Time’s culture is important and unique, worth preserving. But Warner is as much of a change as Paramount is. At least they want to be able to dictate change in their culture and who it will change with. Paramount and some Time shareholders sue Time shareholders. Claims that they aren’t being allowed access to shareholders. Time shareholders are upset that they can’t even consider the $200 offer. Holding, Reasoning: Court goes with Time. Let’s consider what tests should get applied: Corporate conduct original merger deal and defensive tactics (e.g., no-shop) defensive tactics against Paramount Standard BJR proportionality test – was the response proportional to perceived threat? (Unocal) Revlon triggers: 1. company initiates active bidding process to sell itself, reorganize, or break-up company 2. company, in response to bid, abandons long-term policy and looks for friendly bidder (White Knight) 79 But is there ever really anything to satisfy any of these tests? Nope. What was the threat to the shareholders of a stock purchase for a good price? No threat. Look at corporate enterprise, not just short-term shareholders. And if a sale was definitely going to happen, the Paramount bid was by far the better bid for shareholder value. This is an awful lot of deference to the board of directors (back to Cheff). This could mean a number of things: (1) This is where Delaware is going. (2) Delaware doesn’t really know where it’s going with this. (3) Delaware really cares about preserving the corporate culture. (4) Delaware thinks that takeover bids that come too late in the game can have deleterious effects. (JB - maybe there are reliance issues here? Perhaps settling for damages would be a better solution). (5) Probably 2 and 4, with 1 and 3 also meaning something. . Aftermath: Time executives were uncomfortable as Warner culture prevails. Why distinguish pre-paramount offer tactics from post-paramount offer tactics? No real difference. Defensive tactics are defensive tactics. [KK: Maybe once there’s another offer on the table, there’s a likelihood that the board will entrench itself in its previous decision at the expense of choosing a better option for the shareholders?] Analysis (p. 752) 1. No good justification for denying shareholders opportunity to choose between offers. Maybe: (1) shareholders would have lurched at money, directors were interested in long-term benefit of the company. [But maybe shareholders are interested in longterm gains in the market. But, want fluid markets.] (2) Merger here was practically done. There would be reliance costs if it got busted up. 2. Shareholders screwed, but then again shareholders are sheep. Broader reading of proportionality test: back to BJR, deferential regime – court accepts board’s analysis of threat and response. But this reading may be further than the court intended. The court doesn’t rubber stamp the Time board’s decision, go through this whole Revlon, Unocal analysis. What is a company worth? What’s the value of each share? When you’re looking to get control, some shares are more valuable than others. control premiums, lower value for stocks over the target number 8. Paramount v. QVC (p. 753) Facts: (a) 5 years later. 80 (b) Viacom - run by one dude. c) Diller (QVC) and Davis (Paramount) hate eachother. (d) Viacom and Paramount make deal. Kinda puny (8.2 billion). The deal has the following defensive conditions: 1. No-shop provision unless: (a) 3rd party shows they the $ and (b) fiduciary duties require discussion with 3rd party 2. Termination fee ($100M). That’s coercive! 3. Stock Option Agreement – gives Viacom option to purchase 20% of Paramount’s outstanding stock at a certain price or get the cash they would have gotten as profit if they bought and sold the shares. (Where do the shares come from? Not from shareholders. Paramount can’t force a sale by shareholders to Viacom at a particular price. Paramount probably has to get them on the market and sell them to Viacom.) (e) QVC’s two-tiered tender offer: $80 for first 51%, common stock conversion on the back end. (f) Bidding war begins: Viacom’s tender offer: $85 QVC: $90 QVC sues. Live on CourTV Holding, Reasoning: Court uses test of enhanced scrutiny. Two triggers for enhanced scrutiny (instead of BJR): 1. approval of a transaction resulting in a sale of control or break-up of company 2. adoption of defensive measures in response to a threat to corporate control Note: Unclear how this is any different from Unocal/Revlon standards. If there’s a change in control or break-up of corporation directors have duty to get best value reasonably available to shareholders. Reasoning: current stockholders will become minority after merger, entitled to a control premium and/or valuable protective devices. If not, directors have primary objective/duty to get best value reasonably available to shareholders. Court finds deal to be bad. Distinguish Revlon and Time-Warner. This is not a break-up of the company. Didn’t overturn Time-Warner, pretend it’s still good law, make meaningless distinctions. Not clear how the “enhanced judicial scrutiny” test fits in with Revlon and Unocal. 81 Principles 1. Intermediate standard: when a board resists a takeover there’s a conflict of interest, not full-blown though (usually involves their jobs) so BJR doesn’t apply, but board doesn’t have to prove entire fairness. (QVC, hint in Cheff v. Mathes) 2. Two-part test for enhanced scrutiny: board’s actions in resisting a takeover are judged under a modified Unocal test: a. decisions made with adequate process, full information b. decisions that are in a “range of reasonableness,” (covers some proportionality test) not made to further personal interests, not draconian (Unitrin) 3. Maximization duty in the sale of control or breakup (Revlon duties): when it’s clear that corporation will be sold or broken up or control transferred and shareholders no longer able to command control premium, board must hold an auction. (QVC: Where there’s one person assuming control/concern over control premium stronger duty to hold auction.) 4. Unenforceable contractual obligations: if a board enters into an agreement with an acquirer and that agreement has provisions that are inconsistent with the above rules, then those provisions are unenforceable. 5. emeDon’t put too much stock in these principles… just where it seems like the court is going. 6. Aftermath: Redstone gets level playing field (no defensive tactics), auction starts, 7. nt has provisions that are inconsistent the above provisions are unenforceable. Paramount doesn’t drop poison pill.with Bidding goesrules, up to then 105,those Viacom goes to 107 in cash and adds contingent value right (CVR) – cash + securities (Viacom shares + compensation if stock doesn’t reach price targets over next three years.) 9. Hilton Hotels v. ITT (Supp. p. 90) Facts: Hilton launches hostile tender offer for ITT of $55/share, a.k.a. “Bear hug” = hostile offer used as an inducement to a negotiated transaction. $55 is a low offer (intended to get them to the table), later raises to $70. ITT rejects offer, sells some assets, announces comprehensive plan: (1) split ITT into 3 new entities the largest being ITT Destinations, (2) ITT Destinations would have classified/staggered board whose members can be replaced only by 80% shareholder vote (and 80% vote needed to eliminate these provisions), (3) a poison pill that would incur $1.4B in tax liability. ITT plans to implement plan prior to its annual meeting and without shareholder approval. Action: Hilton seeks mandatory injunctive relief. Standard: heightened scrutiny – Hilton must show irreparable injury, succeed on the merits Issue: Whether target of a hostile takeover can entrench itself by removing the right of shareholders to vote on board members. Holding, Reasoning: Ignores QVC. Why? Probably because it makes no sense to them either. QVC may (hopefully) be an aberration. Instead, court relies on Unocal/Blasius standard. Unocal – trigger: exercise of corporate power over corporate assets test: proportionality (BJR+) 1. Are there reasonable grounds for believing a danger to corporate policy and effectiveness exists? 82 2. Is the response reasonable in relation to the threat? Blasius – trigger: exercise of corporate power of power relationship between board and shareholders – defensive measure that touches on an issue of control, purposefully disenfranchises shareholders test: compelling justification 3. Did the board purposefully disenfranchise its shareholders? 4. Is there a compelling justification for this? In this case, the only threat is price inadequacy. The response looked more like entrechment not a compelling justification. Proportionality test fails - Classification and 80% votes to remove board officers has no purpose other than entrenchment disproportionate response Note: 3. See p. 94 – NV has a constituency statute. If the legislation allows consideration of groups like employees then maybe Revlon shouldn’t apply because company shouldn’t be focusing only of shareholder value through auction, there are other constituencies who may have other interests. Overall structure of DE law: After Unitrin, NE Hilton opinion (treated like commentary) Some element of unfairness – just because another bidder comes along, K can be scrapped. When defensive measures are put into place, e.g., lockup, usually put in place by both parties. As for QVC: Clear: When heightened Revlon standard come into play (triggers) – single dominant shareholder, shareholders will lose ability to sell control premium. Unclear: Range of reasonableness over proportionality. Overall: Enhanced business judgment rule. Poison pill resulting in tax liability – how does that work? Untraditional. Dunno. 10. CTS v. Dynamics (p. 767) State regulation of tender offers. Why would a state enact its own statute when the Williams Act is already out there? Protect local economic interests Management threatens to leave state (and take taxes with them) Facts: Part One: IN statute: What it does: Any entity acquiring “control shares” bringing its voting power above one of three thresholds (20%, 33-1/3%, 50%) gets voting rights only when shareholders vote to give them. Acquiror can require a special meeting to be held within 50 days of 83 submitting “acquiring person statement.” If shareholders decide not to restore voting rights, management may redeem shares at market value. What it means: Skews incentive for potential raiders increased risk that takeover attempt will fail for lack of voting power need majority behind offer to begin with To whom does it apply: New corporations provided they don’t opt out. Corporations must have either been incorporated in Indiana, have a business presence in Indiana, or have shareholders in Indiana. The corporation must also have at least 100 shareholders. Part Two:Dynamics owns 9.6% of CTS. Makes tender offer to raise interest to 27.5% (= probably what they need to gain control). CTS counters by invoking the IN anti-takeover statute. Dynamics sues on two grounds: 1. IN’s statute is preempted by the Williams Act? 2. IN’s statute violates the Commerce Clause? Holding2: no violation Reasoning2: (1) no discrimination against non-residents (2) not inconsistent with Williams Act (3) designed to protect IN shareholders (= acceptable purpose). Holding1: no preemption Reasoning1: (1) not impossible to comply with both (2) IN law doesn’t frustrate purpose of the Williams Act – to put shareholders on equal par with acquirer (really? Isn’t it more to help incumbent managers maintain power?) Note: This statute may actually help acquirers, by enforcing shareholder rules. (3) (less delays? Compare with Illinois statute in MITE) Possible Rules/Take-aways: No internal affairs takeover law is preempted unless compliance with both the statute and Williams act is impossible How substantially does it impede hostile tender offers Every takeover law preempted unless it mirrors the IN law Many states simply mirror IN. 10. DE Moratorium statute § 203 (p. 778) If a bidder acquires 15% of target’s stock, can’t engage in business combination with target for 3 yrs. 3 exceptions: 1. bidder acquires 85% or more of target stock 84 2. target board approves tender offer or business combination prior to acquisition of 15% 3. board approves merger after bidder acquires 15% and 2/3 of shares not owned by acquirer approve merger. Precedent: Edgar v. MITE – Williams Act preempts state statutes that upset the balance between target management and a tender offeror. Takeover wrap-up $1.4B tax liability “poison pill” (p. 91) Facts not in case – second element of comprehensive plan: spin-off ITT Destinations with complicated structure that would be tax free to shareholders, but if Hilton tried to buy ITT Destinations, they’d incur liability because they weren’t subject to initial transaction. So, not really a poison pill. Analysis (p. 777) 1. Choice of law rule: state of incorporation governs a corporation’s internal affairs If Congress wanted to enforce a uniform federal law to govern corporations’ internal affairs they could. Most industrialized nations do. Does it make sense that DE law covers about ½ the corporations in the US? More consistency/uniformity means better expectations BUT maybe Mom & Pop’s grocery store shouldn’t be incorporated under the same laws as the big corporations. BUT race to the bottom (states see how low they can go, minimum protections for shareholders to get taxes from managers) BUT rules do help shareholders, they look for DE incorporation, race to the top. 2. If IN statute is intended to protect shareholders from 2-tier coercive offers, is this the best approach? Overinclusive – covers all offers, not just two-tiered ones; could just say that the price should be the same on both ends political economy factors (pp. 778-79) – legislative motive is to keep companies in their state, taxes in their state, and workers employed “Management rejected the tender offer” = manager didn’t recommend the tender offer to shareholders (tender offer actually goes straight to shareholders) – if they had approved the tender offer, shareholders (sheep) would go along with it. V. Federal Securities Law A. Historical Perspective 1929 - Crash. Great Depression begins. 1933 - Securities regulations established to calm people down. 1933 Act - Disclosure ratings. 1934 Act - “Hodgepodge” of regulation. 85 Note: Before 1933, companies generally disclosed anyway, and only a fool would buy securities from a company that didn’t. But there are plenty of fools out there, and speculation may have been allot worse, and there were certainly enough crooks. One other thing: Blue Sky State Statutes - primarily to regulate qualify of securities. Good for the occasional headaches. B. Registering Securities 1. Exemptions Registration would be nice to avoid, but avoidance can lead to civil and/or criminal liabilities. Possible loopholes - claim its not a security. This is pretty hard, given the expansive definition of a security (see page 444). Exempted securities: include exclusive in-state securities and transactions (don’t get cute). Exempted transactions: Transactions by any person other than an issuer, underwriter, or dealer, and any transactions by issuers not involving any public offering (a private memo still required). 2. Reves v. Ernst & Young Facts: Business issues promissory notes paid on demand. It’s a way to raise money. Business then goes bankrupt. P goes after accounting firm for overvaluing firm, leading people to buy notes. Note: Is this aiding and abetting or direct involvement? There is no private cause of action for the former. Holding, Reasoning: Court looks at several tests: SEC definition: Unclear Landreth test: If it’s called a stock, it’s a stock. Howey test: What makes a note a security? Family resemblance test: Presume it’s a security, but rebut if it resembles a family of non-securities. Court then decides on a souped-up Howey test: Did the firm borrow money for general use or for minor asset? Did it distribute note broadly? Did investors think it’s a security? Does any regulatory scheme reduce the risk involved? Court finds loan was for general use, disbruted broadly, and folks thought it was a security (West: that’s weak). There’s also no regulatory scheme. 86