ASSESSMENT OF TRANSMISSION CONGESTION PRICE RISK AND HEDGING IN THE BRAZILIAN ELECTRICITY MARKET F. PORRUA* PSR/MERCADOS DE ENERGIA Brasil L. A. BARROSO* G. B. SCHUCH UFRGS Brasil A. STREET M. JUNQUEIRA PSR/MERCADOS DE ENERGIA Brasil S. GRANVILLE Summary The objective of this paper is to provide a methodology for pricing, under a generation company (Genco) point of view, long-term energy contracts signed across different price zones in a zonal pricing hydro-based power system where classical Financial Transmission Rights (FTRs) are not available. The main result is the establishment of the overprice that a Genco must include in the contract signed in a neighbor zone (where the Genco faces the congestion risk) when compared to the same contract offered in its own zone (with no congestion risk). All relevant risks (hydrological risk, congestion risk, etc) are captured for the long-term through the use of scenarios. Based on these scenarios and on the risk profile of the agent modeled by Utility Functions (UFs), the pricing of crosszones contracts are determined. The approach will be illustrated with practical examples deriving from the Brazilian electricity market, which is hydro-based, has a zonal-pricing scheme and does not offer instruments to hedge against congestion risks, such as FTRs. Keywords Congestion Risk - Risk Pricing - Transmission Congestion - Utility Functions - Energy Auction. * Rua Voluntários da Pátria, 45 – 1507 – CEP 22270-000 – Rio de Janeiro – RJ – BRASIL fernando@psr-inc.com, luiz@mercados.com.br 2 1 – Introduction As widely discussed in the literature [1-4], the existence of transmission constraints in electricity markets based on nodal pricing scheme may create financial risks to market agents in different nodes of the network. Generators in the exporting bus but with financial contracts in the importing bus are exposed to the price difference between these nodes. This financial risk is also known as transmissioncongestion price risk. In order to hedge against this risk, generators may acquire FTRs [1-4]. These are contracts that exist between market participants — in fact, any individual or organization — and the system or market operator. FTRs are defined from a source (node) to a destination location. They are denominated in a MW amount and entitle the holder to receive the contracted amount (MW) times the spot price difference between the two nodes, thus becoming a perfect hedge against the pricedifference risk. The system operator does not need to take FTRs into account in the system operation because FTRs are purely financial instruments that can be settled outside of the spot market. Successful experiences with FTR implementation are observed in many markets, such as PJM, ISONE, NYISO, Nordic Countries, etc. The existence of FTRs markets allows the increase of competition in zones or nodes where just a few suppliers are present. On the other hand, in markets where zonal or nodal pricing schemes are adopted but no FTR markets are available competition may be reduced in certain zones or nodes. Without an FTR market, generators have to correctly price the congestion risk (in terms of spot price difference) in order to sell a cross-zone contract and this is usually translated into an overprice in the corresponding contract. This is the case of the Brazilian power system, where a zonal pricing system is adopted but there is no coupled FTR market. Therefore, Gencos usually overprice their financial energy selling contracts whenever it is settled in another zone than his. The calculation of this overprice is the main focus of the paper. One possible approach to price the congestion risk is by using the expected value of the forecasted spot price difference between the corresponding zones during the contract term as a surcharge. This risk-neutral approach is in fact carried out in some cases. Because Brazil is hydro-dominated and hydrological regimes in the main basins are highly diverse, the transfer of huge power blocks among regions is observed (depending on the hydrological condition) and, as a consequence, the probability distribution of the spot price forecast is extremely skewed. Therefore, depending on the generator’s risk profile, a higher overprice than the expected value of the spot price difference can be applied. The objective of this paper is to propose a methodology to price the transmission congestion pricerisk in cross zones long-term energy contracts, considering the Genco’s risk profile which is modeled by means of UFs. The main idea is to find the contract overprice that leaves the Genco indifferent between selling a cross-zone contract and selling in its own pricing zone. Two different cases will be analyzed: (i) first, we analyze the case of a typical bilateral negotiation between a Genco and a distribution company (Disco), where for a given contracted amount and price offered to the Genco in a neighbor zone, we determine the overprice that must be added in order to leave him indifferent (in terms of Expected Utility – EU) between selling in the neighbor zone and in his own zone; and (ii) we construct a “willingness to contract” curve that, for each contract price (in a neighbor zone) offered, provides the optimal quantity to be contracted that maximizes the Genco’s EU. This approach can be used, for example, in auctions for long-term Power Purchase Agreements (PPAs). Practical examples will be provided with data from the Brazilian system. 2 – The Brazilian Power System Brazil started its power sector reform in 1996. As in many countries worldwide, the new rules were designed to encourage competition in generation and retailing [5]. In turn, transmission and distribution remained regulated activities, with provisions for open access. Other reform ingredients included the creation of an Independent System Operator (ONS), a short-term electricity market (CCEE) and a regulatory agency (ANEEL), as well as the privatization of distribution and some generation companies. The country has an installed capacity of 91 GW (2005), where hydro generation accounts for 85%, for a peak demand near 54 GW. The hydro system is composed of several large reservoirs, capable of multi-year regulation (up to five years), organized in a complex topology over 3 several basins. Thermal generation includes nuclear, natural gas, coal and diesel plants. The country is fully interconnected at the bulk power level by a 80,000 km meshed high-voltage transmission network (Fig. 1), with voltages ranging from 230 kV to 765 kV A.C., plus two 600 kV D.C. links connecting the Itaipu power plant (14,000 MW) to the main grid. The main direct international interconnections are the back-to-back links with Argentina (2,200 MW), plus some smaller interconnections with Uruguay (70 MW) and Venezuela (200 MW). Source: ONS, http://www.ons.org.br Fig. 1 – Brazil – physical system. Both generation and transmission resources are centrally dispatched on a least-cost basis by the ONS, that is, there are no price bids from generators or loads. In particular, hydro plants are dispatched with basis on their expected opportunity costs (“water values”), calculated by a multi-stage stochastic optimization model that takes into account a detailed representation of hydro plant operation, as well as inflow uncertainties. The solution algorithm is the Stochastic Dual Dynamic Programming (SDDP), an extension of the traditional stochastic DP recursion, which can handle hundreds of state variables in this case, reservoir storage levels (see [6-7]). Bilateral contracts are financial instruments and thus not considered in the centralized dispatch. Because system dispatch is cost-based, there are no “real” short-term prices, based on the equilibrium between supply and demand bids. In addition to the optimal production schedule for each hydro and thermal plant, the SDDP solution scheme calculates the Short-Run Marginal Cost (SRMC) – Lagrange multipliers of the stochastic dispatch model – for each network bus, which would then correspond to the well known Locational Marginal Price (LMP). Given that the energy production of each generator and the spot price are both determined by a computational model, the market settlement is an accounting procedure (clearing of net difference between the energy produced and the energy volumes registered in financial forward contracts). 3 – Congestion Risk in the Brazilian Power System For the purposes of accounting and clearing at the short-term market, the LMPs are calculated with a simplified procedure, where the network is divided into “zones”: the transmission limits of all circuits within a zone are made infinite; only the tie-lines between zones are retained1. The system today is currently divided into four zones, also called “submarkets”, (roughly) corresponding to the As discussed in [8], the price in each bus is calculated as the SRMC for a “reference bus” in each zone, adjusted by a loss factor but the wholesale market considers just the zonal prices for market settlement. 1 4 country’s major geographical regions: South, Southeast/Center-West, Northeast and North2 (see Fig. 2). When adopting a zonal pricing scheme, an important aspect to be analyzed is the real physical dispatch in the system, when compared to the “zonal” dispatch. Given that the centralized “zonal” least-cost dispatch does not consider any real transmission constraints within the zones, the so-called constrained-on and off generation in the real dispatch (when considering all transmission constraints) may be considerable. Additional operating costs to compensate those generators that have produced more in the physical dispatch than in the “zonal” dispatch are paid by the ONS. Otherwise, if the generator produced less in the physical dispatch than in the “zonal” dispatch it has to compensate the ONS for the corresponding operating cost. The difference between generation cost in the physical and commercial dispatch is always greater zero and are charged to the consumers as the System Services Charge, which increases as the number of zones in the system decreases. NORTH-NORTHEAST INTERCONNECTION S.LUIS NORTHEAST SYSTEM NORTH SYSTEM V. CONDE SOBRADINHO IMPERATRIZ P. AFONSO L. GONZAGA XINGÓ B. ESPERANÇA TUCURUÍ MARABÁ S. J. PIAUÍ P. DUTRA 750 MWmed 200 MWmed COLINAS NORTH-SE INTERCONNECTION R. TOCANTINS MIRACEMA R. S. FRANCISCO GURUPI 550 MWmed S. MESA SAMAMBAIA R. PARANAÍBA ITUMBIARA T. MARIAS S. SIMÃO A. VERMELHA R. GRANDE kV MALHA - 345/440/500 I. SOLTEIRA JUPIÁ EL O me MW 48 30 R. PARANÁ SOUTHEAST-CENTER WEST REGION IBIUNA CC d T. PRETO 40 30 MW m ed ITABERÁ IVAIPORÃ MA 4700 MW med R 0 /2 00 SOUTH-SE INTERCONNECTION 670 MW med F. IGUAÇU AREIA S.SANTIAGO ITAIPU R. IGUAÇU ITAIPU 60 Hz = 4700 MWmed ITAIPU 50 Hz = 4830 MWmed Caption ITÁ CAMPOS NOVOS R. URUGUAI 345 kV GRAVATAÍ 440 kV 550 kV 750 kV SOUTH REGION ONS - 1999 - 0029c Fig. 2 – Brazilian zones (S: South, SE/MW: Southeast and Center-West, N: North and NE: Northeast). In case of transmission congestion in the tie lines, Gencos may be financially exposed in their cross-zones bilateral contracts3, thus facing the “congestion risk”. In the Brazilian system, the exposure due to cross-market contracting can be extremely high, since in some circumstances (associated to hydrological events) the price differentials due to congestion can be huge. For example, during the rationing period in 2001, there was a major congestion in the tie-lines from the South region (which experienced no drought) to the Southeast region (which was under rationing). For several months, the energy spot price in the South was about 2 US$/MWh, whereas the Southeast prices reached the regulated price ceiling, about 300 US$/MWh [7-8]. This created a very serious financial exposure for generators located in South region, which had supply contracts to loads in the Southeast. As mentioned before, Brazil has no FTR market available. The so-called “transmission surplus”, used in some markets for the backing of FTR payments, is collected by the system operator and mainly used to mitigate congestion risks due to mandatory cross-zones vesting contracts4 and to other special existing mechanisms5. Therefore, in Brazil Gencos must deal with such risk independently for any new cross-zone contracts to be settled. This topic will be analyzed next. The definition of zones boundaries is such that the major “structural” transmission constraints lie on the tie lines between those zones. Definition of zones in the Brazilian system is analyzed in [7]. 3 If there is no transmission congestion in the tie lines, the spot price in two different zones is the same (except for the loss factors) and thus there is no price-difference risk and the cross-zone contract can be interpreted as being in the same Genco’s zone. 4 As part of the transition to a market-based model, all Brazilian Gencos have signed mandatory vesting contracts, called Initial Contracts. Because some of these contracts are across zones, an “automatic FTR” (a share of the transmission surplus) was assigned for them. 5 Such as the Energy Reallocation Mechanism (ERM), which is a mandatory mechanism for hydrological risk sharing among all hydro plants [9]. 2 5 4 – Pricing of Congestion Risk through Utility Functions The main uncertainty parameter associated to the pricing of the congestion risk of a long-term energy contract is essentially the spot price difference between the involved zones. In this paper, this uncertainty is modeled by scenarios, in a fundamental (or “structural”) forecasting approach: a probabilistic modeling is applied to the main source of uncertainty (inflow conditions) and spot prices are calculated from the solution of a generation dispatch model (production costing tool) [6], with a similar methodology than used by the ONS for system dispatch. Based on a long-term “supply x demand” expansion scenario, we project spot prices for the associated zones for the contract horizon. Therefore, one approach to price the congestion risk is through a risk-neutral approach, where the expected (present) value of the scenarios for price differences between zones over the study horizon can be used as the overprice in the contract. However, most of Gencos are in fact risk-averse and their risk profile must be captured. This is discussed next. 4.1 – Risk Measure In this paper, risk profile of agents is represented through a UF, which takes into account the whole range of scenarios by “translating” monetary revenues into “utility units” [10]. The objective is then to maximize the EU. For example, a risk-indifferent Genco would have a linear UF. This means that a revenue increase has the same impact as a reduction; as a consequence, the expected utility is equal to the expected income. A risk-averse investor would have a concave UF, as shown in Fig. 3. In this case, the loss from a “bad” result is not “compensated” by the gain from a “good” result: for each value of income (R), the UF (U(R)) attributes a respective utility unit. We see that a decrease in the income (-d) around a reference value (Ro) results in a variation of the UF (DU-) greater than an increase of the same amount (+d, which results in DU+). This is the characteristic of risk aversion profile. Theoretically, agents can be risk-averse, risk neutral or even risk taker, but, in the “real world”, most agents are risk-averse. Therefore, this aversion profile is considered here. This paper adopts a piecewise linear representation of utility function (PLUF) [11], which is flexible (adjustments in the breakpoints slopes define different risk profiles) and avoids the need of nonlinear curves and algorithms. Any concave non linear UF can be represented through a concave PLUF, by choosing an adequate number of linear segments (see Fig. 4). The PLUF can be represented by the following linear programming (LP) problem: U x Max s.t. (1) a k x bk k 1, ..., K where K represents the number of linear segments; ak represents the angular coefficient of the k-th segment; bk represents the linear coefficient of the k-th segment; and is a scalar (always smaller than all segments). Figure 4 illustrates a PLUF with four segments, with Qk representing a break point (point of slope changing) where the “satisfaction growth rate” changes. In the PLUF approach the agent is locally risk neutral, but, globally risk-averse; and the risk aversion coefficient is represented by the segment slope variation, around each break point, slightly different from traditional definition [10]. U(R) U(Ro+d) U(Ro) DU+ U(x) DU- x x x U(Ro–d) a(k=4) U(xo) k=2 Ro– d Ro Ro+d R ($) k=1 Q1 Q2 k=3 xo k=4 Q3 x (risk averse profile) Fig. 3 – Concave UF representing a risk-averse profile. Fig. 4 – Risk aversion profile through the PLUF. 6 5 – Congestion Risk Pricing: a bilateral contract approach In this case we assume that the Genco is analyzing a contract proposal to be settled in another zone. The contract amount and price proposed by the counterpart are also assumed to be known. Therefore, we determine the overprice that must be added to the contract in order to leave the Genco indifferent (in terms of the average net present value ( NPV ) of its expected utility) between settling the contract in a neighbor zone and in its own zone. That is, we are searching for the overprice Op ($/MWh) that makes: v NPV E U R PCv Op NPV EU RP u u C where R PCv Op represents the Genco’s total cash flow if the contract is in another zone (labeled “v”) with price PCv Op (where PCv is the given contract price and Op is the overprice (decision variable)). The expression R PCu is the Genco’s cash flow if the contract were settled by a price PC in its own zone (labeled “u”). In this scheme, we are modeling the risk profile of the Genco by its utility function. A risk-neutral approach (linear UF) would be equivalent as to working with the average values. 5.1 – Case study 9.0 8.0 Overprice required at Northeast (R$/MWh) Overprice Required at Northeast (R$/MWh) This section provides the result of a case study for a thermal Genco in the Brazilian system, with 450 MW of available installed capacity and 50% of this capacity available for contracting (the remaining 50% is already contracted). The Genco is physically located in the Brazilian Southeast zone and the candidate contract is in the Northeast zone (typically an importing zone and the risky one in this case). It is assumed a contract with 8 years of duration (from 2009 to 2016). A concave utility function was defined for this Genco, thus trying to capture a risk-averse profile. A sample of 100 spot prices of the relevant zones, as the Genco’s physical dispatch scenarios, were obtained usind a SDDP tool [6-7]. We have then calculated the overprices for several pairs of contracting amounts and prices offered in the neighbor zone. Figures 5 and 6 illustrate the results for the minimum contract overprice in both situations: a risk neutral approach and the risk-averse case. We observe that in the risk neutral case the overprice is constant, only depending on the spot price difference between the zones. On the other hand, when risk aversion is considered, we observe that the minimum overprice required decreases as the candidate contract price (contract price in the Genco’s zone) increases. All overprices are higher than those obtained with a risk neutral approach, thus highlighting that this can be a risky approach to price the contracts. We finally observe that overprices required for cross-zone contracting depend on both the candidate contract price and the total amount contracted, as shown in Fig. 6. 7.0 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 8.0 7.0 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 Contract = 45MW 3.6 3.5 3.4 3.3 3.3 3.1 3.1 3.1 3.1 3.0 3.0 Contract = 90MW 5.4 5.1 4.9 4.8 4.6 4.4 4.2 4.1 4.0 3.8 3.7 Contract = 135MW 6.7 6.4 6.2 5.9 5.6 5.3 5.0 4.8 4.5 4.3 4.1 Contract = 180MW 8.0 7.5 7.1 6.8 6.3 5.9 5.6 5.2 4.9 4.6 4.4 Contract = 225MW 8.9 8.4 7.9 7.5 7.0 6.6 6.1 5.7 5.3 4.9 4.6 1.0 0.0 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 Proposed 6.7 6.4 6.2 5.9 5.6 5.3 5.0 4.8 4.5 4.3 4.1 Traditional 2.0 2.0 2.0 2.0 2.0 2.0 2.0 2.0 2.0 2.0 2.0 Candidate Contract Price at Southeast (R$/MWh) Fig. 5 – Risk neutral and risk-averse results. Candidate contract price at Southeast (R$/MWh) Fig. 6 – “Iso-quantity” curves. 6 – Congestion Risk Pricing: a supply curve scheme While in the previous section the decision variable for the Genco was the overprice (contracted amounts were fixed), in this section we leave the contracting quantities to be decision variables for the Genco. In other words, we construct a “willingness to contract” curve such that, for each candidate 7 contract price offered, the optimal quantity to be contracted that maximizes the Genco’s EU is determined as the solution of the following LP problem: E C PC arg Max EC 1 S s t s. t. U ts a k Rt s bk U ts 1 r t (2) s, t , k Rts PC , E C g u E C PC E C u OR v E C EC EC k 1, ..., K s 1, ..., S t 1, ..., T Where: EC – quantity to be contracted (decision variable) (MWh); PC – candidate contract price ($/MWh); Rts – Genco’s cash flow, in scenario “s” and period “t” ($); g – Genco’s physical generation (MWh); u – spot price in the Genco’s zone “u” ($/MWh); u OR v – spot price in the Genco’s zone “u” or the neighbor zone “v”, depending on where the quantity EC is contracted ($/MWh); E C , E C – minimum and maximum available quantity to be contracted (MWh); r – discount rate (%). In other words, for a given contract price (either in its own or neighbor zone), the optimal quantity to be contracted is determined taking into account the agent’s risk profile, captured by the piecewise linear representation of UF as described in section 4. 6.1 Case study This section provides an application of the previous approach for a candidate contract in the Southeast and Northeast zones. The same Genco from the previous example is considered. We selected a discrete contract price range and, for each contract price, we calculated the optimal amount to be contracted (solution of problem (2)). Figure 7 shows for the optimal contracting for the two relevant situations: when the contract is offered in the Genco’s zone (SE) and in another zone (NE). Optimum bidding curve (MW) 450.0 400.0 350.0 300.0 250.0 200.0 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 NE auction 225.0 225.0 225.0 225.0 253.5 285.1 321.7 425.9 450.0 450.0 450.0 SE auction 225.0 225.0 225.0 229.9 289.4 354.4 450.0 450.0 450.0 450.0 450.0 Candidate Contract Price at Northeast (R$/MWh) Fig. 7 – Optimum bidding curve for a cross-zone contract. We see that since the NE is the risky contracting zone, the Genco contracts smaller amounts between R$65,00/MWh and R$85,00/MWh candidate prices than in the SE zone. 7 – Overprices Comparison In section 5.1 we have shown the minimum overprice required for cross-zone contracting, such that the Genco was indifferent between contracting in the SE and NE zones. In section 6.1, as a subproduct of the “willingness to contract” curve, one can also find a minimum required overprice in Fig. 7 as Op E C PCNE E C PCSE E C . 8 These overprices (from section 5.1 and 6.1) can be compared, as shown in Fig. 8. 10.0 9.0 8.0 7.0 6.0 Overprices (R$/MWh) 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0 Bilateral contract Willingness curve 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 3.9 4.2 4.6 5.0 4.9 5.2 5.7 6.3 6.3 6.2 6.4 6.2 8.0 8.0 7.3 8.0 7.7 9.2 8.5 7.6 Candidate Contract Price (R$/MWh) Fig. 8 – Overprices comparison. We can see from Fig. 8 that overprices obtained in section 5.1 are smaller than those found in section 6.1. This is not a surprisingly result, given that the approach of section 5 is to find the lowest overprice that leaves the Genco indifferent between selling in its own zone and in the risky one, while the approach of section 6 seeks for the optimal amount of energy that must be sold, that maximizes the agents profits for a given price. Therefore, the reduction in quantities found in section 6 are translated in higher overprices when the same (price; quantity) points are observed in the analysis of section 5. 8 – Conclusions This paper presented a methodology for congestion risk pricing for Gencos in cross zones bilateral contracts settled in electricity markets with zonal pricing scheme but without FTR markets available. In these markets, the adequate pricing of the congestion risk should be taken into account in order to sell a cross-zone contract. Because the risk profile of the Genco needs to be captured, the methodology is developed based on the expected utility theory. The approach is illustrated with practical examples for the Brazilian system and the results show the importance of considering the agent’s risk profile when compared to the risk-neutral approach. Although the core of the methodology was developed considering a zonal pricing system, it can be extended for any LMP-based system with centralized market for clearing purposes. 9 – Bibliography [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] [8] [9] [10] [11] HOGAN, W. W. Financial Transmission Right Formulations. Harvard University, mar. 2002. Available at: <http://www.ksghome.harvard.edu>. KRISTIANSEN, T. Markets for Financial Transmission Rights. Energy Studies Review, Canada, v. 13, n. 1, 2004. MA, X.; SUN, D. I.; CHEUNG, K. W. Evolution toward Standardized Market Design. IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, New York, v. 18, p. 460 - 469, may 2003. STOFT, S. Power Systems Economics. New York: J. Wiley, 2002. p. 431 – 441. ISBN: 0471150401. RUDNICK, H. et. al. The Challenges of Electricity Supply in South America, forthcoming, IEEE Power & Energy, July 2005. PEREIRA, M. V. F.; CAMPODÓNICO, N.; KELMAN, R. Long term Hydro Scheduling based on Stochastic Models. In: - EPSOM ’98, Zurique. London: IEE, sep. 1998. GRANVILLE, S. et al. Stochastic Optimization of Transmission Constrained and Large Scale Hydrothermal Systems in a Competitive Framework. Proceedings of IEEE PES General Meeting, Toronto, 2003. BARROSO, L. A. et al. Transmission Structure in Brazil: organization, evaluation and trends. Proceedings of IEEE PES General Meeting, Denver, 2004. BARROSO, L. A. et al. Managing Hydrological Risks in Hydro-Based Portfolios. Proceedings of IEEE PES General Meeting, Toronto, 2003. LUENBERGER, D. G. Investment Science. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1997. ISBN: 0195108094. PORRUA, F. Methodology for Risk Pricing and Analysis of Cross-Zones Contracting in the Brazilian Electric Sector. Master thesis, 139 p. Federal University of Rio Grande do Sul, Brazil, 2005.