POLICY DOCUMENT Rent Control in the Private Rental Residential Sector 27 June 2014 Background A form of rent control exists in many countries, including Ireland. According to a 2009 Global Property Guide report, a form of control on rental increases exists in 40 countries;1 this number is diminishing as controls are loosened as a response to the threat of investors leaving the market, and as policy-makers focus on strengthening tenants’ rights above limiting rental increases. As the European Commission has recently noted in a survey of EU rental market regulation: “As young cohorts (most often corresponding to lower income ones…) struggle to enter the property ladder, a well-functioning and affordable rental sector would provide a viable alternative, cushioning the impact of existing [housing] constraints….During the build-up phase of a house price boom, affordable rental opportunities for young/low income cohorts would tame demand pressures and thus limit price increases.”2 A well-regulated rental sector is, therefore, of particular importance during a period of turbulent house price change, low supply or economic difficulty. In general terms, rent controls are most often introduced into the private rental sector to achieve two goals: to defuse public protest about high rents, and to assist citizens by providing an agreed framework for contracts, and so avoid post-tenancy litigation.3 In 1 Cruz, C. P. “Investment Analysis; the pros and cons of rent control” Global Property Guide (19 January 2009) 2 Cuerpo,C., Kalantaryan, S., Pontuch, P. “Rental Market Regulation in the European Union” (European Commission, Economic Papers 515, April 2014) 3 European Central Bank (March 2003) 1 general terms, the European Commission notes that “the regulatory environment in the EU rental markets generally attempts at setting the right incentives for Landlords and Tenants by striking a balance between social fairness and economic efficiency.”4 Part of such a regulatory environment may include limits on the rental increases, rent freezes and toughening eviction rules. Globally, three models are open to countries when setting the maximum allowable rent increase for sitting tenants: A fixed percentage (e.g. Dubai, Philippines, Pakistan, Tunisia), A fraction of the construction cost index (e.g. France) or consumer price index or CPI (e.g. certain cities in the US, Italy, Netherlands, Spain, Switzerland, Colombia, Uruguay) A combination of the two (e.g. Canada). There is thus no one single model, and each has potential difficulties with calculation, monitoring, fairness of application and flexibility in the context of a diverse rental market within Irish regions. Even within the EU, a variety of mechanisms exist to assist landlords and tenants agree a revised rent, including forms of indexation (whether based on housing costs (Sweden), or a specific figure (20% in a three-year period, Germany)). In most EU countries, there has been a general agreement that initial rents should be pitched at current market rates, and allowing only minor negotiation thereafter. Consequently, any rental increase within the period of a tenancy is determined by a multitude of various mechanisms. According to the ECB, “In most EU countries, rent adjustment is likely to be closer to the CPI or some housing cost measure plus or minus some factor that will reflect, among other things, public housing policy objectives and fiscal policy considerations.”5 The Irish Model By international standards, Ireland’s rental market is seen a pro-tenant, with a modern legislative framework and a resourced independent dispute-resolution body.6 The Global Property Guide comparison of landlord and tenant law notes the “curious system” of the four 4 European Commission (April 2014) European Central Bank (March 2003) 6 Global Property Guide: “Ireland: Tenant protection laws are significant but not onerous” (6 June 2006). The European Commission, on the other hand, uses a different weighting and puts Ireland in the pro-landlord group. 5 2 year tenancy cycles and that “It is generally accepted that landlord and tenant law is one of the most complex and involved fields of Irish law” and the relatively new Residential Tenancies Act (2004). The Irish model of rent control finds its origins in a cumulative application of common law and legislation, commencing during the First World War and culminating in the 2004 Act. Overarching all of this legislation are constitutional provisions regarding the right of ownership of property and the right to earn a livelihood; the Irish Supreme Court has been quick to strike down rent control legislation which appears to undermine landlords’ constitutional rights, particularly where no compensation for landlords subject to rent control is paid, or where rights of occupation almost permanently alienate the property from the landlord.7 Views of the Commission on the Private Rented Residential Sector In 2000, the Commission on the Private Rented Residential Sector, examined the (then) state of the legislative provisions surrounding the rental sector, and explored rent control models which would satisfy the requirements of both landlord and tenant, and avoid falling foul of the Constitution. The Report of the Commission on the Private Rented Residential Sector (2000) discussed the concept and workability of a rent control mechanism in the context of a property affordability problem, and rapidly increasing rents. Where house prices increase faster than incomes, affordability deteriorates; this has implications for the individuals involved, the provision of subsidised social housing, rent assistance, and decision-making in household formation. According to the Commission, the strongest way to preserve affordability is to make efforts to “more closely match the supply of housing to demands.” This would mean that the “operation of the market should bring rents back to more affordable levels, although this impact would not be felt in the short-term.” To overcome that short-term affordability problem, the Commission reviewed the principles and consequences of rent control. Under a proposed model, rent would be fixed at market levels at the start of a tenancy, and after a specified period, an increase could be applied annually in order to raise the rent to the prevailing market value. Both the frequency of reviews and the maximum percentage 7 Blake v Attorney General [1982] IR 117 3 increase would be limited by legislation, and the review process would be overseen by an independent expert body, using market statistics (including consumer price movements, house-price inflation, interest rates etc.) A number of difficulties with this rent control model were identified in report: It was firstly held that by capping return on investment, any form of rent control would remove investor appetite and would therefore be detrimental to supply. Second, in a market where rents are expected to rise, initial rents will be front-loaded to compensate for any subsequent loss on investment before the review period. The report noted that this would initially inflate rents thereby exacerbating rental increases in a period where there was a lack of supply. Third, the report questioned the benefit to tenants of artificially lowering the rent for a defined period and then allowing it to suddenly rise to market rates at the end of a tenancy. As the report notes, “this would be a difficulty for tenants whose spending patterns have become used to reflecting the lower rents” who sought new premises. It was also noted that, depending on the figures used to calculate market rents during the period of the tenancy, even in a period where rents may be falling, tenants may be subject to rental increases. The report notes that if landlords could not increase rent yields to the level necessary to obtain a return on investment “it is reasonable to expect that a number would withdraw from the market and new investment would be deterred.” The report notes that in a period of low supply, the withdrawal of investment would “be to worsen an existing affordability problem.” Therefore, the report concludes “that no measures are implemented which would have the effect of forcing landlords to leaving the market or to seek to maximise their returns on rental property.” Current legislative framework Under the 2004 Act, the parties to a rental contract are free to negotiate rents, but the amount paid must not exceed the open market rate. The rent may be reviewed and adjusted to market rates once a year. Rent disputes go to the Private Residential Tenancy Board 4 (PRTB), itself a creature of statute. Security of tenure is determined both by contract law and statutory provisions which sit alongside each other. If a landlord and tenant agree a contract of a fixed period, any notice period, and grounds for eviction is set out in the contract. Under statute, a tenancy is effective for four years; during the first six months, the landlord can terminate the leasing contract without specifying grounds but once a tenancy has lasted six months, the landlord can only terminate the tenancy for the next three and a half years citing just causes.8 Such just causes include: Tenant has failed to comply with the obligations of the tenancy (Must first be given a warning and breach continues) The landlord intends to sell the dwelling within the next 3 months The dwelling is no longer suited to the needs of the occupying household The landlord requires the dwelling for their own occupation or that of a family member (If a member of landlord's family it must state the identity of person and their relationship to landlord) Vacant possession is required for substantial refurbishment of the dwelling (Must specify the nature of the work and if planning permission is required this must be included) The landlord intends to change the use of the dwelling.9 . Impact of Rent Control on Supply One specific complaint about many forms of rent control is that the system can lack transparency and predictability; while the Irish model is intended to provide transparency for both parties, its impact on the future predictability of the wider property market is less easy to evaluate. In Sweden, for example, where, following the introduction of rent control, of the approximately 30,000 dwellings completed in 2006, only 36% were intended for rental. In comparison, from 1990 to 1996 more than 50% of new dwellings completed were intended for rental. This flight of investment in the most commonly-cited argument for the loosening (or total abolition) or rent control. Indeed, in 2003, the European Central Bank reported “it is 8 9 Global Property Guide: Ireland (6 June 2006); Threshold “How your landlord may end your tenancy” Threshold “How a landlord may end your tenancy” 5 likely that the significant fall of real rents has led to significant decreases in the supply of rental accommodation.”10 The impact of rental control on the supply of property into the rental sector has been evaluated by the European Commission: The costs of rent controls outweigh the benefits especially in the case of transfer models. In theory, tighter rent controls should lead to a decrease in regulated rents, increasing the attractiveness of renting for tenants, and thus demand. Moreover, tenants would be better protected against sharp increases in rents and tenure security would be enhanced11. On the other hand, reduced rents would shrink the supply of rental accommodation via its impact on profitability of residential investment for rental use (rental yields), triggering a downsizing of the rental market12 partially offsetting the drop in rents and also fostering potential lock-in effects for sitting tenants, which would hinder mobility. The specific format of a rental control has also been examined by the EC who conclude: If rents are regulated only within tenure (tenancy rent control models), the efficiency losses could be lower, as rents would be freely set for new leases and allow thus for at least a sluggish adjustment of rents towards their market level. However, the tensions between landlords and tenants could be exacerbated as the former would have incentives to increase the rotation of contracts (for example by encouraging eviction processes, by a biased tenant selection or through a reduction in the maintenance investment) while the latter would opt for long duration tenancies as their fixed costs of moving increase over time.13 Rent controls appear to have a significant destabilizing impact on the aggregate housing market, increasing the volatility of house prices when confronted with different shocks (e.g. shifts in population, disposable income, residential investment and long-term interest rates). 10 European Central Bank (March 2003), p. 26 Arnott, R. (1995), "Time for revisionism on rent control?," Journal of Economic Perspectives, Volume 9,1, pp. 99-120. 12 European Central Bank (2003); Lind, H. (2003). "Rent regulation and new construction: With a focus on Sweden 1995-2001," Swedish Economic Policy Review, Vol. 10, pp. 135-167. 13 European Commission (2014); Arnott, R. (1995) 11 6 The European Commission note: “Therefore, when setting controls on both rent levels and rent increases, policymakers should bear in mind their broader implications for housing market stability and consider them within the context of existing incentives for home ownership such as taxation incentives (deductibility of interest rates, property taxation vs. other assets, etc.) or macro-prudential measures (LTV caps, amortization rules for mortgages, etc.).” In terms of policy recommendation, European Commission concludes: The drawbacks of rent controls in terms of unintended consequences for housing market stability and negative effects on labour mobility would advise against their use for redistribution purposes. Social concerns such as the provision of affordable housing opportunities for young and lowincome households and the prevention of homelessness situations require more targeted policies, which would be welfare-enhancing while not taking a toll on rental market efficiency.14 Scope of Legislative Reform in Ireland Since the collapse of the property market in c. 2006 Government policy has been to support investment from institutional actors in the residential property sector, and to foster the development of a viable private rental sector to complement home-ownership. As a result, Ireland has seen a large increase in its rental sector, although it remains modest by European standards. Again, by European standards, Ireland’s residential rental sector is largely “amateur” in that the bulk of landlords own one or two properties; they undertake their landlord duties in addition to normal paid employment. Rent received from those properties is used, either to pay buy-to-let mortgages or as income supplement. As noted earlier, the right to own and enjoy the benefits of private property is recognised in both Articles 40 and 43 of the Constitution of Ireland. Article 40 states that “the State shall, in particular, by its laws protect as best it may from unjust attack, and in the case of injustice done, vindicate the life, person, good name, and property rights of every citizen.” Article 43.2.2 notes, however, that while all citizens enjoy the right of “private ownership or the general right to transfer, bequeath and inherit property” this right may be “delimited by law…with a view to reconciling their exercise with the exigencies of the common good.” In 14 European Commission (2014) 7 Blake, the Supreme Court held that legislative provisions which limited the ability of landlords to determine the rent was constituted an unjust attack on the property rights of landlords, and had failed to reconcile the right to ownership of property with the need of the common good. They were therefore repugnant to the Constitution and struck down. Any legislative reform which interferes with the right to own property will be judged against Articles 40 and 43 of the Constitution and it is likely, therefore, that any legislative reform in this area will be subject to legal challenge by landlords on the basis that rent control is an unwarranted infringement of their constitutional rights to own and enjoy property. It is recognised that high rents constitute a clear and present concern for tenants, and provisions which are likely to lead to lengthy constitutional challenges in the courts should be avoided in favour of measures to support the increased investment into the sector, thereby easing pressures on the sector. Recommendations Property Industry Ireland recommends that no further form of rent control is introduced in Ireland. Given the rights of property ownership which are enshrined in the Constitution, and the ruling in Blake as well as the opposition to rent control which is evident both from academic literature and reviews by the EC and ECB, any proposed restrictions on rental increases in Ireland would need to satisfy an extremely rigorous test. Uncertainty about future legislation in this area is likely to undermine investment activity into the sector at a time when it is needed most. It is also likely to have an inflationary impact on rents in the short-term as landlords seek to impose higher rents in advance of any new form of control. The 2004 legislation provides a clear regulatory framework in which landlord and tenant operate, and by international standards, this framework is modern, well-resourced and enforced. While it is recognised that residential landlord and tenant law is complex, great efforts have been made by PRTB, Threshold and others to inform tenants of their rights, both prior to occupation and while in tenancy. The rapid increase in residential rents seen in some parts of Ireland in recent months is a consequence of historically low construction of rental property, improved macro-economic activity and a legacy of weak residential property investment levels, particularly in the institutional investment sector. 8 Internationally, there has been a gradual erosion of strict limits on rental increases in an effort to tackle concerns about flights of investment. For Ireland, a limit on return on investment through rental control poses a real risk to the fledgling institutional investment market, especially amongst international investors. Ireland’s REIT market has brought welcome injections of investment capital into the Irish property market, and Ireland’s first residential-specific REIT has recently begun raising funds. PII believes that many of the problems facing tenants because of rapid rent increases could be mitigated against through encouraging further construction and investment in property, and through targeted market segmentation by, for example, supporting the construction of purpose-built student accommodation. Property Industry Ireland believes that as the supply of new property increases, the current pressure on residential rents will begin to improve. It is important that the regulatory framework surrounding the private rental sector is put in place for the long-term and that it is not subject to policy reform merely to mitigate against any temporary problems. 9