US-Japan Automotive Trade in the Reagan and Obama Administration: Explaining the Rise and Fall of Protectionism Craig VanGrasstek GTA Analytical Paper No.1 bcde GLOB L TR DE LERT GLOBAL TRADE ALERT GTA-AP1: US–JAPAN AUTOMOTIVE TRADE IN THE REAGAN AND OBAMA ADMINISTRATIONS: EXPLAINING THE RISE AND FALL OF PROTECTIONISM Craig VanGrasstek US–Japan Automotive Trade in the Reagan and Obama Administrations: Explaining the Rise and Fall of Protectionism Craig VanGrasstek, Center for International Governance Innovation Abstract This paper will present a structured comparison of policy responses by the United States to competition with Japan in the automotive sector in two difference administrations. It will examine one case in which the United States chose to impose protectionist measures and another in which it did not, in order to consider the effects of economic downturns on both the demand and supply of protection. After reviewing the facts of the two cases, this paper will evaluate four possible explanations that are variously legal, political and economic in nature. While these explanations are not mutually exclusive, and each may offer some part of the answer, the evidence suggests that the most persuasive case is based on long-term changes in the structure of the US automotive industry. Keywords: Introduction The outbreak of the financial crisis in late 2008, coupled with the recession that began the year before and memories of the Great Depression of the 1930s, produced warnings that a new wave of protectionism could be imminent. But is it the case that economic downturns always produce demands for protection, and that policymakers are unable to resist them? This paper addresses that question by presenting a structured comparison of policy responses by the United States to competition with Japan in the automotive sector in two different administrations. It examines one case in which the United States chose to impose protectionist measures and another in which it did not, in order to consider the effects of economic downturns on both the demand and supply of protection. Presidents Reagan and Obama both had to deal with uncertainty in the economy at large, and in the automotive sector in particular, in their first year in office. Both administrations inherited automotive policy initiatives that were already under development during the post-election transition. The Reagan administration took a protectionist approach, opting to concur in Japan’s imposition of restrictive (though putatively ‘voluntary’) quotas on imports of its vehicles to the US market. Twenty-eight years later, when members of Congress introduced bills that would aid the auto sector but discriminate in favour of domestic producers, the Obama administration negotiated with legislators to ensure that the bills made no distinction between domestic and imported vehicles. This was especially notable in the case of a ‘cash-for-clunkers’ programme that was non-discriminatory in theory, and in actual practice encouraged the scrapping of older, less efficient American cars for more fuel-efficient Japanese or Korean vehicles. What explains the outcomes of these two episodes? After reviewing the facts of the two cases, this paper presents and reviews four possible explanations that are variously legal, political and economic in nature. While these explanations are not mutually exclusive, and each may offer some part of the answer, the evidence suggests that the most persuasive case is based on long-term changes in the structure of the US automotive industry. Three decades of globalisation have seen the establishment of Japanese and other foreign ‘transplants’ in the United States, greater dependence on global supply chains and strategic alliances for the ‘Big Three’ US auto producers (Chrysler, Ford and General Motors), 2 a decline in the size and strength of the unionised workforce, and increasing numbers and influence for the auto dealers who sell Japanese cars. The result is a political landscape today in which there are fewer groups that perceive import protection to be in their interests, those few who do so are less powerful than they were a generation ago, and they face countervailing pressures from other interests. Review of the Episodes There are four different responses that a government may offer when an industry is in a decline that is associated with import competition. The first is to do nothing, and to let the industry either adapt or die. The other three options might be pursued separately or in some combination: provide various forms of assistance (grants, tax treatment, government procurement of its goods, etc) in order to help the industry re-establish its competitiveness; bargain with or threaten other countries (including the chief competitor[s]) in order to reduce their barriers to one’s own exports; or restrict imports through one means or another. As reviewed below, Presidents Reagan and Obama both took office at times when the automotive industry was in serious trouble, and the debate over these options was already well underway. In both cases their predecessors had already taken steps to extend government assistance to the industry, but had not imposed import protection. There the similarities end: while the Reagan administration extended import protection and also offered some regulatory relief, the Obama administration greatly expanded government aid without import protection. The 1981 recession and the voluntary export restraints (VERs) The proximate cause for the decline of the US auto industry in the 1970s was the twin energy crises of that decade. First as a sanction that the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries imposed against the West following the Yom Kippur War in 1973, and then as a consequence of the Iranian Revolution and the Iran–Iraq War (see Box 1), the price of oil and gasoline rose in two great waves. Americans responded by purchasing smaller, more fuel-efficient cars. The subcompacts then offered by the US producers were generally more expensive and less mechanically reliable than their Japanese counterparts. As can be seen from the data in Figure 1, imports from Japan rose at a sharp and steady rate. The Big Three took a big, collective hit. Production of automobiles dropped from an annual rate of 9.1 million units assembled in January 1979 to 6.2 million in January 1980, and took a further tumble down to 5.7 million in January 1981.1 The first policy response of the Carter administration was to provide aid to the Chrysler Corporation, which sought a loan guarantee in 1979 to forestall bankruptcy. The administration and Congress agreed that this firm was, in terms often repeated in the 2008–9 financial crisis, ‘too big to fail’. It was not until the next year that another of the Big Three producers, in this case Ford, proposed import protection. This took the form of Ford’s support for a petition that the United Auto Workers filed in June 1980 for relief under the ‘safeguards’ law. Also known as the escape clause, this provision of law (and the corresponding instruments of international law)2 allows a president to impose temporary tariffs, quotas or other restrictions on imports. That can be done only upon the recommendation of the US International Trade Commission (USITC), however, which must determine whether rising imports are a substantial cause of serious injury to the domestic industry. Although the Carter administration gave the impression that it was eager to aid the industry in this way, with the president asking the USITC to accelerate its investigation,3 this path was blocked when the USITC reached a negative determination. 1 Federal Reserve data at http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/G17/iphist/autohist_sa.txt. Safeguards are permitted under GATT Article XIX. The domestic law is s. 201 of the Trade Act 1974. 3 In the normal course of events the investigation would be concluded six months after the petition was filed; that would mean finishing in mid-December 1980. The Commission instead finished about one month early, announcing its conclusions a week after the presidential election. 2 3 Box 1: Key events leading to the 1981 auto VERs 1978 16 January 1979 15 July 1979 7 September 1979 Rising turmoil in Iran throughout the year, coupled with production cuts by other members of the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries, leads to the second energy crisis of the 1970s and higher gasoline prices. Fuel-efficient Japanese vehicles capture an ever-higher share of the US market. The Shah of Iran flees the country. President Carter outlines his plans to reduce oil imports and improve energy efficiency in the ‘Crisis of Confidence’ speech, calling the energy crisis ‘the moral equivalent of war.’ The Chrysler Corporation petitions the US government for $1.5 billion in loan guarantees to avoid bankruptcy. 4 November 1979 15 November 1979 The Iran hostage crisis begins when radical students take over the US embassy. Iran cancels all contracts with US oil companies. 20 December 1979 Congress narrowly approves the Chrysler Corporation Loan Guarantee Act. 11 January 1980 18 March and 3 April 1980 May 1980 3 June 1980 12 June 1980 10 July 1980 Honda announces that it will build the first Japanese ‘transplant’ in Ohio. The Joint Economic Committee in Congress and the Senate Banking Committee each hold hearings on automotive trade and competition with Japan. The Yasukawa-Askew Agreement commits the Japanese government to encourage economically viable investment in the United States by Japan’s auto and auto parts companies. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) announces that the United States has been in a recession since January 1980. The United Auto Workers (UAW), with Ford’s support, files a petition with the US International Trade Commission (USITC) seeking protection from automotive imports under the safeguards law. President Carter asks the USITC to complete the safeguard investigation ‘as expeditiously as possible’ because it has ‘become a matter of great national and international importance’. 23 September 1980 War breaks out between Iran and Iraq, causing oil prices to rise even higher. 4 November 1980 10 November 1980 Ronald Reagan is elected president. In a 3–2 decision the USITC votes against the UAW’s safeguard petition, finding that the standard set in the law (ie rising imports must be a substantial cause of serious injury to the US industry) has not been met. President Carter thus has no legal basis for imposing restrictions on imports. The House of Representatives approves by 317–57 a measure authorising the president to negotiate an ‘orderly marketing agreement’ to limit car and truck imports. 2 December 1980 3 December 1980 12 December 1980 20 January 1981 5 February 1981 3 March 1981 9 March 1981 1 May 1981 8 July 1981 The Senate Finance Committee approves a similar measure on a vote of 11–2. The Finance Committee’s measure survives a procedural challenge in the full Senate on a vote of 12–65, but the measure is dropped before the bill to which it was to be attached is enacted. Ronald Reagan is sworn in as president. The Iranian hostage crisis ends. Senators Danforth and Bentsen introduce an auto import quota bill. At a cabinet meeting the advocates of import protection (Commerce, USTR and Transportation) have the upper hand over those who favour an open market (especially Treasury). The Senate Finance Committee holds a hearing on automotive trade issues with Japan. Following indirect consultations and negotiations with the United States, Japan announces the imposition of VERs on auto exports. NBER announces that the recession that began in January 1980 ended in July 1980. (On 6 January 1982 NBER will announce that a new recession began in July 1981.) 4 Figure 1: US auto imports by value ($ billion), 1976–1984 $14 Japan $12 $10 $8 Canada $6 Western Europe $4 $2 Rest of World $0 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 Source: Calculated from US Department of Commerce data (FT990 series). That decision came early in the transition period between Carter and Reagan, and Congress seized the initiative in order to promote action in the incoming administration. Meeting in a ‘lame duck’ session,4 legislators attempted to enact a resolution that would authorise the president to negotiate import quotas. That resolution received majority and bipartisan support in both chambers of Congress, and although it was not actually enacted into law it served to underline the strong interest in limiting automotive imports from Japan. The Reagan administration had many options that it might have pursued in response to these pressures, as summarised in Table 1. The first option, which is not shown in the table, would be to do nothing and allow the market to decide whether and what kind of automotive industry would survive. That would have been the course of action most consistent with the pro-trade rhetoric of the Reagan administration, and there were voices in the new cabinet that advocated that position. Secretary of the Treasury Don Regan was outweighed, however, and the question soon became not whether but how the United States would restrict the market. Most of the options would have been difficult or impossible for the United States to pursue without violating its obligations to Japan and other exporters in the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). Consider, for example, across-the-board tariffs on imports of cars. Automotive tariffs have long been relatively low in the United States. Even under the notoriously protectionist Hawley-Smoot Tariff Act 1930, the United States imposed only a 10% tariff on automobiles. The rate was cut in successive tariff negotiations to 7.5% by 1960, 5.5% by 1968, and 3% by 1973.5 In the Tokyo Round negotiations of 4 The votes discussed here were cast in a post-election meeting of the 97th Congress (1979–80), including some members who either had not run for re-election or were defeated in the November 1980 election. The 98th Congress (1981–2) would not be seated until January 1981. 5 Toder et al (1978: 19). 5 1972–9 the United States made a commitment to cut it further, to 2.5%; that is where the tariff rate remains to this day (ie, the product was ‘off the table’ in the Uruguay Round negotiations of 1986–94). 6 Table 1: Advantages and disadvantages of different forms of US automotive import protection from the perspectives of distinct stakeholders Japanese firms and government Reagan administration US firms US labour Impose higher tariffs under the escape clause (ie, safeguards) The relative (un)attractiveness of this option would depend on the specific remedy chosen, which might include tariffs, quotas, etc Potentially a useful means but the negative determination in the 1980 case made it difficult for the Reagan administration to request new action The option was attractive enough for one of the Big Three firms (Ford) to join with labour in the 1980 petition The UAW already showed that it favoured this approach, but there was no reason to expect that it would get a different result a second time Impose higher tariffs without invoking the escape clause This option would too clearly violate Japan’s rights, and would require either renegotiation of the US concession or a disputesettlement case Problematic because tariffs could not be raised above the GATT-bound rate without violating those obligations or seeking a negotiated revision In addition to being vulnerable to a GATT challenge, this approach might encourage other countries to do the same This approach would be attractive if it were feasible Strict domesticcontent laws This option would be unattractive unless and until there was greater Japanese investment in the US parts sector Like tariffs, this approach would likely be GATT illegal This approach would make it difficult for the firms to pursue the increasingly favoured option of outsourcing parts production This was the most attractive of all options for the unions, as it would encourage production in the United States no matter who owned the firms Import quotas imposed and administered by the United States Like tariffs, unilateral quotas imposed by the United States would be too great a violation of the rules for Japan to avoid a GATT dispute In addition to concerns over GATT legality, this approach could make the pro-market president appear hypocritical This would be a more attractive option for the Big Three than a Japanese-administered quota programme This would be a more attractive option for labour than a Japanese-administered quota programme Export quotas imposed and administered by Japan This was the least unattractive option for Japan, being semilegal and allowing for greater flexibility in administration than would a US-imposed quota scheme This approach placed the least onus of responsibility and hypocrisy on the administration Though less attractive than a system administered by the United States, this approach was preferable to doing nothing Though less attractive than a system administered by the United States, this approach was preferable to doing nothing Light trucks comprise the one segment of the US automotive sector that is subject to relatively high tariffs.9 Concerns over GATT legality also weighed in the administration’s views of domestic-content legislation and US-imposed quotas. As one can appreciate from the summary in Table 1, the choice of the VERs over alternative means of protection was logical. While they were a second-best option for some, they were at least minimally acceptable to all of the concerned parties. First-hand10 and secondary11 accounts of the episode recount a highly indirect process in which President Reagan was loath to express a firm opinion to his subordinates on what the United States should seek, and the US negotiators did not make precise demands on Japan. The VER option in general, as well as its particulars, seemed to be chosen virtually as the default option, and then worked out with Japan through a process that might be called non-negotiations. In the end, however, it was clear that this was a restrictive instrument that Washington required of Tokyo, even though it did not explicitly bear a ‘Made in the United States’ label. The putatively voluntary and unilateral nature of the VER did not prevent US legislators who were opposed to Japanese imports from treating the policy as if it were a legal obligation, including claims that Japan had ‘violated’ its terms by shipping vehicles in excess of the stated limits. On 1 May 1981 the Japanese Ministry of International Trade and Industry announced that Japanese producers would limit their shipments to the United States for two years to 1.68 million units annually. The VER subsequently evolved in response to changing market and political conditions. Although the United States decided in 1985 not to request a further extension of the agreement, Japan nevertheless maintained the restrictions until they were terminated in March 1994. As the data in Figure 1 show, the quotas did not prevent growth in the total value of automobile imports from Japan. After plateauing in the first year of the programme, those imports resumed their steady rise in subsequent years. The reason was simple: Being restricted in the number of vehicles but not total value, Japanese exporters decided to make the most of the limitations and switch to highervalue units. They also accelerated the establishment of transplant factories in the United States. With a growing share of the Japanese firms’ sales coming from US-built cars, by the late 1980s the quotas were no longer ‘binding’ in the sense employed by economists (ie, actual exports were substantially below the ceiling level). Bilateral trade tensions increased once again in the early 1990s, however, leading Japanese officials to reduce the VER from 2.3 to 1.65 million units in 1992. The VER was formally terminated two years later, as part of Japan’s implementation of the Uruguay Round results. The VER had multiple consequences for producers in the United States, Japan and in third countries. According to one study, lifting the VER would have produced a gain of $9.8 billion for the United States.12 Another estimated that the VER reduction in 1992 saved 1,234 jobs in the United States, but also imposed a $1.7 billion cost on consumers and a quota rent loss of $1.2 billion.13 Yet another study stressed that the biggest losers were US consumers who had to pay an average of about $1,200 more (in 1983 dollars) per Japanese car, and suffered a combined loss of some $13 billion; the US economy as a whole suffered welfare losses totalling some $3 billion.14 From the Japanese perspective, perhaps the most important effect was the stimulation of quality upgrading.15 As can be appreciated from Figure 2, the VERs also created opportunities for other producers who sought to fill the gap left by reduced US imports of Japanese vehicles. Imports from Canada, most of which were supplied by the Big Three, began to recapture lost market share. European producers 9 Although such trucks are considered to be commercial vehicles in other parts of the world, in the United States they are used as both passenger and service vehicles. The 25% tariff was originally imposed in 1963 in retaliation for the European Community’s restrictions on US poultry exports. This so-called chicken tax was imposed on a most-favoured nations (MFN) basis, and hence created a barrier to imports from Japan that is still in effect. 10 See, for example, Stockman (1986). 11 See, for example, Cohen (N.D.). 12 De Melo and Tarr (1987: 108). 13 Hufbauer and Elliott (1994: 100). 14 Berry et al (1999). For a much lower estimate of the cost to consumers, see Dardis and Decker (2005). 15 De Melo and Tarr (1987: 78–81). 8 benefited from higher prices in the restricted US market. Korean producers benefited significantly from this opportunity, which fortuitously coincided with their entry into the North American market in the late 1980s. In the long term, as illustrated by the data in Figure 3, the VERs paused but did not halt or reverse the relative decline of the Big Three. Those firms’ combined share of the US market, as well as the share of the Japanese producers, fluctuated very little during the 1981–95 period. While the US producers did improve quality during that time, they continued to lose ground to Japanese and other foreign firms in the first decade of the 21st century. Figure 2: US auto imports by share of total value, 1976–1984 100% Rest of World Western Europe 80% Canada 60% 40% Japan 20% 0% 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 Source: Calculated from US Department of Commerce data (FT990 series). Figure 3: Shares of the US vehicle market, 1975–2009 100% All Other Japanese Nissan Honda 80% Toyota All Other 60% Chrysler 40% Ford 20% General Motors 07 05 03 09 20 20 20 20 99 97 95 93 91 89 01 20 19 19 19 19 19 19 85 83 81 79 77 87 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 75 0% Source: Calculated from Ward’s Auto data posted at http://wardsauto.com/keydata/historical/UsaSa28summary/. 9 The 2007–2009 recession and the automotive support package As was the case in the 1980–1 episode, the Obama administration inherited a policy debate that was already in development before the election and that ripened during the transition from the Bush to the Obama administrations. The proximate cause of the financial crisis that erupted in late 2008 was the bursting of the housing bubble, but the resulting economic turmoil affected all segments of the economy. The auto industry was hit especially hard, with consumers postponing purchases of ‘big ticket’ items. Automobiles were assembled in the United States at an annual rate of 4.0 million units in January 2008, but one year later this fell to just 1.3 million.16 Imports dropped as well, as can be seen from the data in Figure 4. The decline hit all major US partners in this sector. Unlike the 1980–1 episode, when imports rose from Japan at a far higher rate than imports from other partners, the data in Figure 5 show that shares of the US import market were remarkably steady both before and after the outbreak of the crisis. Figure 4: US auto imports by value ($ billion), 2001–2009 $50 Japan $45 $40 Canada $35 $30 European Union $25 Rest of World $20 $15 $10 $5 $0 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Source: Calculated from US International Trade Commission data. In a series of steps taken during late 2008 through 2009, the US government provided massive amounts of aid to both the financial and automotive industries (among others). Some of the principal events are summarised in Box 2. This included billions of dollars in loans and other forms of support to domestic automotive producers, though not in equal degrees; whereas the relationship between the government and GM has grown especially tight,17 Ford declined direct government aid. 16 Federal Reserve data at http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/G17/ipdisk/auto_sa.txt. The Obama administration and GM reached an arrangement on 30 March 2009 by which, in exchange for funds already committed by the US Treasury and a new injection of $30.1 billion, the US government will receive approximately $8.8 billion in debt and preferred stock in ‘New GM’ and approximately 60% of the equity. For more details see the Global Trade Alert description at http://www.globaltradealert.org/measure/united-states-america-support-general-motors-andchrysler. 17 10 Figure 5: US auto imports by share of total value, 2001–2009 100% Rest of World 90% 80% 70% European Union 60% 50% Canada 40% 30% 20% Japan 10% 0% 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Source: Calculated from US International Trade Commission data. Box 2: Key events affecting US automotive policy in 2008–2010 7–17 September 2008 The financial crisis breaks out in a series of takeovers, sales, bankruptcies, and bail-outs in the banking, insurance and brokerage industries. The stock market slide accelerates. 4 November 2008 Barack Obama is elected president. Representatives of the Group of Twenty hold an emergency meeting in Washington. The CEOs of the Big Three appear at a hearing of the Senate Banking Committee, stating that they need $25 billion in financial aid. 15 November 2008 18 November 2008 1 December 2008 NBER announces that a recession began in December 2007. 2 December 2008 The Big Three submit revised plans to Congress pledging deeper reforms. The House of Representatives approves the Auto Industry Financing and Restructuring Act by a vote of 237–170, but the Senate rejects the broader package in which it is included. 11 December 2008 31 December 2008 14 January 2009 20 January 2009 GM and the US Treasury sign a loan agreement. Two weeks after the 111th Congress convenes a non-discriminatory cash-forclunkers bill is introduced in the House of Representatives. 17 February 2009 President Obama is inaugurated. GM issues a new viability plan. President Obama signs into law a stimulus package providing non-discriminatory aid to the industry through government procurement and tax incentives. 18 February 2009 Chrysler and GM seek a second bridging loan for $5 and $16.6 billion, respectively. 20 February 2009 17 March 2009 The Presidential Task Force on the Auto Industry holds it first meeting. Representative Sutton introduces in the House of Representatives a new cash-forclunkers bill that would make incentives available only for the purchase of vehicles made in North America. 30 March 2009 President Obama lays out a framework agreement with GM. 30 April 2009 Chrysler files for bankruptcy after talks break down with its lenders. 14 May 2009 Chrysler announces the closure of one-fourth of its US dealerships. 11 19 May 2009 Following negotiations among the sponsors, the Obama administration, and stakeholders in the auto industry, the House Energy and Commerce Committee approves a compromise cash-for-clunkers proposal that does not discriminate between imported and domestic vehicles. 1 June 2009 GM files for bankruptcy after failing to negotiate deals with its bond holders. Most Chrysler assets are sold to ‘New Chrysler’ with $6.6 billion in Federal financing. The Consumer Assistance to Recycle and Save (CARS) Act is approved in the House and the Senate with $1 billion in funding, and President Obama signs the bill into law. The House of Representatives approves an appropriations bill requiring that any vehicles purchased with money provided in the bill be produced by the Big Three firms. The CARS programme is in effect, with Congress approving a further $2 billion in funding on 7 August after the initial $1 billion is quickly depleted. A House-Senate conference committee removes from the appropriations bill the requirement that government-purchased vehicles be produced by the Big Three. Representative Sutton and Senator Stabenow introduce resolutions calling Japan’s scrappage programme ‘unfair and discriminatory’ and directing the president to initiate immediate consultations. The New Democrat Coalition in the House writes to the ambassador of Japan to protest against the measure. The House Subcommittee on Trade cancels a planned hearing on discrimination under both the Japanese and Korean programmes after Japan announces changes to its scrappage programme. Japan releases a list of US auto models that qualify under the scrappage programme. 10 June 2009 9–24 June 2009 17 July 2009 27 July–24 August 2009 30 September 2009 5–20 January 2010 21 January 2010 3 February 2010 The question of whether this aid discriminates against foreign automotive producers is complex. On the one hand, there are no elements of the support packages that explicitly provide for blatantly trade-distorting measures such as tariffs or other border barriers, production or export subsidies, etc. On the other hand, government supports to industry can distort markets by erecting barriers to exit and favouring some producers over others. That is especially true for those kinds of support that are made available only to domestic firms and not to the transplant operations of foreign firms in the United States. It is also possible that the state may acquire control or influence over the decisions of the firm, and seek to exercise this power in ways that are intended to favour investment and production in the domestic market. While the US delegation to the WTO has stressed that the government loan to GM is intended to benefit all of the firm’s continuing operations without regard to geographic location,18 there is also anecdotal evidence to suggest that in at least one case the result may have been restrictive.19 Compared to the blatantly protectionist approach taken in 1981, however, the restrictiveness of these latest measures is quite minor. At no time has the Obama administration or Congress advocated or approved anything in the nature of new tariffs or quotas on imports of automobiles. To the contrary, there were two notable episodes in which some members of Congress advocated discriminatory initiatives but these were either defeated or significantly modified. In one instance 18 As cited by the WTO’s Trade Policy Review Body (2009: 45). The timing and content of two decisions simultaneously announced on 29 May 2009 suggest that the concurrent bargaining over government support, a new labour contract, and GM’s plans for investment may have led in at least one instance to a decision against multinational investment and trade. GM announced that day that its employees represented by the UAW had ratified key modifications to the GM-UAW 2007 National Labor Agreement. The modified agreement included concessions that will help GM reach the objectives of its Viability Plan. The company also announced that day that it plans to build a future small car in the United States, utilising an idle UAW-GM facility. That announcement came after GM was reported to be considering the production of a small car in China, with part of the output to be exported to the United States; those plans were then dropped. 19 12 Congress considered, but ultimately rejected, a Buy-America provision affecting the purchase of motor vehicles by several US government agencies. The House of Representatives had approved a provision in the ‘Energy and Water Development and Related Agencies Appropriations Act of 2010’ (designated as H.R.3183) stating that, ‘None of the funds made available in this Act may be used to purchase passenger motor vehicles other than those manufactured by Ford, General Motors, or Chrysler.’ This provision would not even permit the procurement of vehicles made in the United States by the transplant factories of foreign automotive companies. There was no such provision in the Senate version of the bill, however, and the Buy-American provision did not appear in the compromise version produced by a House-Senate conference committee in September 2009.20 The other measure, and our main focus here, was the ‘cash-for-clunkers’ programme. In this instance the initiative was ultimately enacted into law, but only after its discriminatory aspects were removed. As finally implemented, the programme was actually more beneficial to foreign than domestic automobile producers. The Consumer Assistance to Recycle and Save (CARS)21 Act 2009 is Title XIII of the Supplemental Appropriations Act 2009 (Public Law 111-32). The programme provided credits to consumers who traded in old, fuel-inefficient vehicles when buying or leasing new, more fuel-efficient vehicles. The law was notably non-discriminatory, applying equally to the purchase of domestic and foreign vehicles. The National Highway Traffic Safety Administration made that point clear in the website that it created to promote the programme, the ‘frequently asked questions’ section of which included the following exchange:22 I don’t drive an American car but I would like to trade in my old car for a newer, more fuel efficient one. Is this program only for American cars? No. You may trade in or buy a domestic or a foreign vehicle. Congress explicitly chose the non-discriminatory route by opting between two very different measures. One was the Accelerated Retirement of Inefficient Vehicles Act 2009 (H.R.520), as introduced in the House in mid-January 2009. This bill did not discriminate between domestic and imported vehicles. Two months later, however, another measure was introduced that would have provided credits only for North American vehicles. Sponsored by Representative Betty Sutton (Democrat of Ohio) and 35 co-sponsors, most of them from automobile-producing states in the Midwest, the original version of the CARS Act 2009 (H.R.1550) would have limited credits to the purchase of vehicles assembled in the United States or, for some classes of vehicle, in North America (ie, Canadian or Mexican vehicles would qualify).23 Although this was the bill that lent its name to the programme that Congress eventually approved, the discriminatory provisions in the bill did not survive the legislative process. Negotiations between the Obama administration, members of Congress, and stakeholders in the automotive industry led to agreement on a compromise measure that did not discriminate between domestic and foreign vehicles. On 19 May 2009 the Committee on Energy and Commerce in the House of Representatives passed the compromise by a bipartisan vote of 50–4. That vote appended the CARS Act to the American Clean Energy and Security Act 2009 (a wide-ranging bill dealing with climate change), but the CARS Act was later decoupled from that larger measure and considered by the House as a stand-alone bill. In the 9 June 2009 debate over this measure on the floor of the House of Representatives, the sponsors introduced letters of support from a wide range of interested parties, including US and foreign-owned automobile manufacturers as well as labour unions and business organisations. The House voted for the bill by 298 to 119, with Democrats favouring it overwhelmingly (239–9) and even a sizeable minority of Republicans giving their support 20 For further details on the episode see the Global Trade Alert description of the measure at http://www.globaltradealert.org/measure/united-states-america-government-purchase-vehicles-big-three-producers. 21 Note that the CARS acronym is also rendered in some places as the ‘Car Allowance Rebate System’. 22 http://www.cashforclunkersfacts.com/. 23 For example, a $4,000 voucher would be available for a ‘passenger automobile assembled in the United States with a minimum highway label fuel economy value of 27 miles per gallon’, or for a ‘passenger automobile assembled in North America with a minimum highway label fuel economy value of 30 miles per gallon’. 13 (59–110). The measure was later attached to an appropriations bill that both houses of Congress then approved during 16–18 June 2009.24 President Obama signed the bill into law on 24 June 2009. The programme proved to be much more popular than its sponsors or critics had originally expected, and ran through the initial $1 billion within a week of its implementation. Congress approved additional funding for the programme, but that money too was soon exhausted and the programme ended in August 2009. The program’s designers and administrators were well aware of the fact that many of the most fuel-efficient vehicles sold in the US market are either imported into or made in the United States by Japanese and Korean firms,25 and that the law was likely to be more beneficial to them than to the Big Three. The data on actual usage confirm that this was indeed the case: Of the 401,274 passenger cars, 274,602 light trucks, and 1,966 heavy trucks that were purchased using the program’s incentives, only 48.6% were manufactured domestically.26 Toyotas accounted for only 2.6% of the trade-in vehicles, for example, but for 17.8% of the new vehicles; 28.9% of the trade-ins were Fords, compared to just 13.3% of the new vehicles.27 One great irony of the cash-for-clunkers experience is that it was not the US programme but its Japanese counterpart that raised questions over discrimination against imports. The government of Japan introduced in 2009 an ‘Eco-friendly Vehicle Purchase’ that, like the US programme, provided credits to consumers who scrapped older vehicles for new, more efficient cars. The programme excluded, however, all vehicles that are certified under the government’s ‘preferential handling procedure’ (PHP) regulatory programme (a system that allows imported vehicles to be sold without individual inspection of each car or truck as it is imported). Significantly, all vehicles exported to Japan by the three US manufacturers enter Japan under the PHP regulatory protocol for certification. This meant that US cars, unlike their domestic or some other imported vehicles, were not eligible for the Japanese programme. There followed a series of protests and threats from members of Congress (see Box 2). As criticism mounted, Japan decided to change its programme. On 19 January 2010 the Trade Ministry posted a statement on its website clarifying that its car-scrappage programme was being altered to allow the incentives to be offered to suitable cars imported under the PHP. As of this writing the United States remains unsatisfied with the extent of the Japanese efforts to ensure that the programme is nondiscriminatory. Following the release on 3 February 2010 of a limited list of vehicles that qualify for the programme, US Trade Representative Ron Kirk expressed ‘disappoint[ment] with Japan’s announcement’, calling it ‘particularly unfortunate in light of its recent announcement to open opportunities for U.S. autos to qualify for its program, which was a welcome step’. He said that the United States ‘will continue to urge Japan to implement its program in a manner that is transparent and as inclusive of U.S. autos as possible’.28 Whether or not these complaints ultimately lead to further changes in the Japanese programme, two points are clear. The first is that, in the short term, the United States took a more liberal approach to its scrappage programme than did Japan. The second and more significant point is that the United States took a far more liberal approach in this latest episode than it did in 1981. Far from imposing unilateral import restrictions or encouraging Japan to restrict its exports, the rescue packages for the auto industry this time were remarkably free from the kinds of economic nationalism that Detroit demanded and Washington granted a generation earlier. Four Explanations for the Different Outcomes 24 Note that the Senate did not vote on this measure as a separate initiative and hence the partisan breakdown cannot be stated. 25 See the data posted at http://www.fueleconomy.gov/feg/bestworst.shtml. 26 US Department of Transportation, National Highway Traffic Safety Administration (2009: 36). Note that the report does not identify how many of these US-produced vehicles were Big Three versus transplants. 27 Ibid: 22 and 24. 28 USTR statement posted at http://www.ustr.gov/about-us/press-office/press-releases/2010/february/kirk-commentsrelease-list-us-autos-models-qualif. 14 The question that we must now answer is, ‘What accounts for the differences between these two episodes?’ If one were to hazard a prediction based on some of the common perceptions of US trade politics, the likelihood for a protectionist outcome would seem to be higher in the more recent case (a very deep, lengthy recession and a Democratic president) than in the older one (a brief recovery between successive recessions and a Republican president). Why then did the incoming Reagan administration take a much more protectionist approach than the incoming Obama administration? In this part we consider a series of explanations that might account for the differing outcomes. These might variously be attributed to (1) legal considerations (to what extent can the non-discriminatory results of the second episode be attributed to the rules established in the Uruguay Round of multilateral trade negotiations?), (2) political considerations (were there any respects in which the Obama administration had a ‘stronger hand’ than its predecessor, or simply played it better?), (3) short-term economic considerations (was the 1981 downturn qualitatively different from the more recent one?), and (4) long-term considerations of political economy (is it the case that the globalisation of ownership and supply chains has inhibited protectionist demands?). The evidence presented here suggests that while each of these explanations may provide some part of the answer, it is the fourth that seems to be the most persuasive. A legal explanation: changes in WTO rules One possibility is that international law constrained Obama more than Reagan. VERs were controversial though not unambiguously GATT-illegal in 1981, but were outlawed by one of the agreements reached in the Uruguay Round (1986–94). Just as the Reagan administration could not legally have raised the US tariff on automobiles a generation earlier, the Obama administration could not have requested or even acquiesced in the imposition of quotas in 2009 without violating US obligations to its partners in the World Trade Organisation (WTO). Putatively ‘voluntary’ restrictions on exports were, together with antidumping duties, the most typical form of trade barrier among industrialised countries in the 1980s. The GATT Secretariat identified 236 VERs in place in 1989, most of which were imposed during the 1980s, of which 17 covered the automotive sector.29 These ‘gray area’ measures occupied a realm of highly questionable GATT-legality, which led one prominent legal scholar to stress ‘the need for a negotiated rule discipline that will explicitly constrain the temptation to use export-restraint arrangements frequently as an instrument of trade policy’.30 This goal was indeed achieved in the Uruguay Round. The Safeguard Agreement prohibited new VERs, and provided that those in effect at the time the WTO entered into force had to be phased out. It could be argued that the VER-ban in the Agreement on Safeguards was indeed a critical consideration in the administration’s calculations. That would be part of a broader pattern in Obama trade policy that might be deemed ‘passive free trade’. On the one hand, the administration did almost nothing in its first year to deal with the pending trade agreements and negotiations that it inherited from its predecessor, attaching a very low priority to trade policy. On the other hand, the administration sought to restrain whatever protectionist impulses arose in Congress, and was especially eager to ensure that any measures enacted were consistent with US legal obligations under existing trade agreements. That was demonstrated very early in the administration’s tenure when it negotiated with Congress to ensure that the ‘Buy American’ provisions in the economic stimulus package did not violate US obligations in either the WTO or the existing free trade agreements.31 The administration was not always successful in these efforts to restrain Congress, as 29 Low (1993: 76–7). Jackson (1988: 497). 31 See the Global Trade Alert description of this measure at http://www.globaltradealert.org/measure/united-statesamerica-buy-american-provisions-stimulus-package. 30 15 was shown by one provision that slipped past in blatant violation of the free trade agreement with Mexico,32 but at least its overall intent was clear. The chief weakness of the legal explanation is that it deals with only one form of protectionism. As the 1981 episode demonstrated, industries or policymakers that seek to restrict imports can be quite creative in finding a way around legal restrictions. If one path is blocked, of even if several of them are, the demandeurs and their policymaking allies may find some other way to restrict import competition if they wish to do so in the first place. One way that the Obama administration could have restricted the US auto market, had it wanted to do so, would have been via a safeguards case. President Obama proved that he was willing to go down this route in September 2009 when he granted a safeguard request involving a small segment of the automotive industry (tyres imported from China).33 One can only speculate on what the USITC might have ruled, and what President Obama might have done in response, if a new safeguards petition had been filed for automobiles. What is most notable in this instance is that there were no such efforts made by either the industry or the administration. A political explanation: the differing positions of the two administrations What of the differing political conditions of the two administrations? There are at least three distinct but related political matters that we should consider: the ideological differences between the two presidents, the two presidents’ political capital, and the partisan differences between the congressional Democrats and Republicans with whom they had to deal. Apart from the fact that they were both newly elected, it is difficult to think of any pair of recent American presidents who were less alike than Reagan and Obama. Focusing on just one of the differences between them, to what extent can we attribute the results in these two episodes to their respective political and economic ideologies? This question related to a recurring controversy in the political economy of trade policy. Some political scientists argue that the post-1930 turn towards free trade in the United States can be explained by the triumph of liberal economic ideas, and that this victory can be attributed in large measure to the negative experience with protectionism during the Great Depression of the 1930s.34 Policymakers, it is argued, remember the dire economic and political consequences that followed upon the enactment of the highly protectionist Hawley–Smoot Tariff Act 1930, which is widely associated not only with the transnational spread of protection but indeed with the outbreak of the Second World War, and have since learned to restrain their own worst impulses. Whatever the merits of that explanation may be for the ‘big picture’ of postwar trade, it would appear to be inapplicable to the present problem.35 There is no doubt that free trade ideas played very different roles in the two presidents’ public personas: Reagan often expressed his faith in the market in general and especially his devotion to free trade, while Obama is generally seen as more a pragmatist than an ideologue and very rarely makes any mention of trade. In that respect their 32 See the Global Trade Alert description of this measure at http://www.globaltradealert.org/measure/united-statesamerica-access-mexican-trucks. 33 Like the 1980 auto case, the petition in this instance was filed by a labour union. See the Global Trade Alert description of the measure at http://www.globaltradealert.org/measure/united-states-america-safeguards-against-imports-consumertires-china. 34 Judith Goldstein is the most prominent advocate of this view. In a detailed examination of US trade debates in the 19th and 20th centuries she found evidence to support the contention that ‘ideas … become predictors of the direction of policy at least as powerful as are simple calculations of interest’ (1993: 3). 35 One might even go farther to argue that the contrast between these two cases points to fundamental problems with the ideological explanation in general. No one could seriously contend that the fundamental economic arguments in favour of open markets changed significantly in the period between the Reagan and Obama administrations; the development of the concepts first of absolute (Smith, 1776) and then comparative advantage (Ricardo, 1817) predate even the earlier of our two episodes by over a century and half. And if it is indeed the case that it was the Great Depression that drove this lesson home, we should expect that lesson to be more distant, and less influential, after the passage of 80 years than it was after just 50. To put matters in personal terms, Reagan (born in 1911) was a young man during the Great Depression, while in Obama’s case even his mother (born in 1942) knew that economic catastrophe only from history books. 16 positions adhere more or less to the popular perception that Republicans are free-traders and Democrats are, at best, indifferent to free trade. In actual practice, however, their actions in the automotive episodes demonstrated just the opposite attachments. Nor is the contrast between these two presidents in this one sector a unique case. From Carter through Obama, most of the significant concessions to protectionist demands have been made by Republicans. Consider the case of steel, where the decisions of two successive administrations followed the same pattern as we saw for autos in the Carter and Reagan administrations. President Bill Clinton (a Democrat) rejected demands in his second term that he impose import restrictions on steel, only to see his decision reversed by President George W. Bush (a Republican) in 2001.36 Similarly, the protection that Republican presidents Reagan and George H.W. Bush extended to the steel industry in 1984 and 1989, respectively, was more thorough (in the form of global quotas) than the protection that President Jimmy Carter extended to that industry via the ‘trigger price mechanism’ for antidumping cases in 1978. His rhetoric notwithstanding, Ronald Reagan made the most compromises of all. In addition to the deals he made with the steel and auto industries, these included apparel, sugar and softwood lumber. This is not to say that he always yielded to such demands, or did so without purpose. Most of these concessions were made in a ‘one step back, two steps forward’ approach in which the administration was willing to cut deals when it sought to win congressional approval for major initiatives such as a new round of multilateral trade negotiations and a free trade agreement with Canada. In that sense one might argue that Obama has not yet been obliged to make the ‘one step back’ of a major protectionist concession because he has also not attempted ‘two steps forward’ in the form of, for example, a new request of negotiating authority in order to complete the Doha Round. The question nevertheless remains, why did the Reagan administration feel compelled to ‘cave’ on this one demand so early in its tenure? Why did it not oppose the auto industry as strenuously as, for example, it did the apparel and footwear industries when congressional majorities – including key members of the president’s own party – demanded even stricter quotas? Those fights went down to the wire, with the president having to veto bills twice, and coming uncomfortably close to seeing his vetoes overridden by Congress. The answer to that question does not seem to be a function of that somewhat amorphous thing we call ‘political capital’. Though not strictly measurable, there are some indicators that we can use to gauge it roughly. As can be seen in Table 2, there are several grounds for concluding that Reagan started his presidency with at least as much, and arguably more, political capital than did Obama. First, Reagan had won a more decisive victory in the presidential election, as measured both by his share of the electoral votes and by his share of the popular vote. Second, although Reagan’s popularity was lower at the very start of his term vis-à-vis Obama’s, he saw that figure rise throughout his first six months in office. Obama’s fell during the same timeframe. The only respect in which Obama was better off than Reagan was in the fact that he enjoyed fully unified government, with Democrats controlling the House, the Senate and the White House. Reagan’s Republican allies held a majority in the Senate, but not the House. This then leads us to the role of Congress. Trade is ultimately a congressional responsibility, as provided under the US Constitution, and presidents can accomplish little in this field without the approval of the legislature. Republicans have long enjoyed the reputation of being more devoted to free trade than Democrats, and there is substantial evidence in both rhetoric and voting patterns to support that contention. In the 1980–1 episode, however, those differences were not so evident. It is notable that when both the House and the Senate went on record in late 1980 in favour of import restrictions the proposal received majority support from both parties. When the House voted on 2 December 1980 the measure was favoured by 214 of the 230 Democrats (ie 93.0%), and by 103 of the 144 Republicans (ie 71.5%). The motion in the Senate to table (ie defeat) a similar measure was opposed by (and thus the measure itself was supported by) all but three of the 42 Democrats (ie 36 For a detailed examination of this case study see Rosegrant (2002). 17 92.9%), and by all but nine of the 35 Republicans (ie 74.3%).37 These results suggest that the partisan differences in 1980–1 were matters not of kind but of degree, and those degrees were not very great. Table 2: Comparative political positions of Presidents Reagan and Obama, 1981 and 2009 Electoral votes won in 1980/2008 Share of two-party vote won in 1980/2008 Gallup poll ratings in 1981/2009: January February March April May June Number of Democrats in 1981/2009: House of Representatives Senate Reagan Obama 489 (91.4%) 55.4% 365 (67.8%) 53.7% 51% 55% 60% 67% 68% 59% 67% 62% 63% 62% 64% 59% 242 (55.6%) 46 (46.0%) 257 (59.1%) 59 (59.0%) Notes: The number of Democrats in the Senate in 2008 is the number produced by the election, counting two independents who vote with the Democrats but not counting the results of later events in the 111th Congress that caused that number to rise and then fall (one party switch, one death and one special election). Note also that one of the Democrats elected in 2008 did not actually take office until July 2009, after all legal challenges to the election were exhausted. Sources: Election results from Wikipedia. Gallup poll ratings from the Roper Center (http://webapps.ropercenter.uconn.edu) and the Gallup poll (http://www.gallup.com), using in each case the poll done closest to the fifteenth day of the month in question. The widespread and only semi-partisan support for automotive restrictions undoubtedly weighed heavily in the Reagan administration’s decision. There is no doubt that the president could have vetoed any bill that Congress enacted to restrict the market, and that it would prevail in any efforts to override such a veto. The decision to restrict the market was, in brief, even more ‘voluntary’ for the Reagan administration than the VERs were for Japan: This was a fight that it could have won, had it chosen to do battle, but it decided instead to accommodate the protectionist demands. Trade policy has grown more partisan since the early 1980s, but that does not mean that it has become more restrictive. To the contrary, partisan conflict has increasingly been devoted less to the core commercial issues of trade policy (open versus closed markets) and has instead been deflected to matters that have become politically tied to trade. That is especially true for labour rights and the environment, with Democrats often demanding that further liberalisation be conditioned upon achievements in these areas and Republicans objecting to links between trade and ancillary matters. The 9 June 2009 vote in the House of Representatives on the CARS Act can be seen within that context, as it did not directly involve a question of trade per se (the discriminatory provisions having already been removed) but instead was seen as an effort to promote both the environment and economic recovery. Involving as it did some basic differences between the two parties’ economic and environmental policies, the resulting pattern of votes was highly partisan. The measure received overwhelming approval (97.5%) from Democrats representing the 20 states with automotive assembly plants,38 and an almost identical level of support (95.2%) from Democrats representing the other 30 states. The level of support among Republicans from the automotive states (29.7%) was actually below the level for Republicans from non-automotive states (36.8%), but not by much. Like 37 38 Congressional Quarterly (1981). These states are enumerated in Table 3, below. 18 many other trade-related votes of the past two decades, this measure was thus seen more through partisan and ideological lenses than as a particularistic benefit for a specific industry. It is reasonable to conclude that the broad and bipartisan support for import restrictions was a decisive factor for the Reagan administration. That nevertheless leaves open the question as to why this option was so popular in Congress at the time, especially by comparison with the more recent episode. To answer that question we now turn to both short- and long-term economic factors. A short-term economic explanation: qualitatively different downturns These two episodes offer contradictory evidence in support of the proposition that economic hard times breed demands for protection from imports. The association between downturns and protectionism is at least as old as the panic of the 1890s, and was solidified by the role that the Hawley–Smoot Tariff Act 1930 played in deepening and spreading the Great Depression. It was with that latter experience in mind that economists were quick to warn early in the financial crisis that the ‘political pressures demanding import protection to protect employment are surfacing with increasing intensity around the world’39 and that ‘the risk of a devastating resurgence of protectionism is real’.40 Subsequent events have confounded those expectations, however, with the lack of protectionism in the US auto industry being just one of many dogs that have not barked. One possibility worth considering is that not all recessions, depressions, or crises are alike in their causes and symptoms, and that different types of downturns may be more or less likely to produce demands for import protection. While it is well beyond the limited scope of the present paper to suggest anything like a taxonomy of recession types, we can at least ask how the differing economic conditions of the 1980–1 and 2008–9 episodes might have affected the outcomes. There are two principal distinctions that we can draw here: the severity of the two downturns, and the differing ways that trade flows responded. Let us consider first the question of a recession’s severity. One might speculate that a run-of-the-mill recession may produce only a slight up-tick in the demand for protectionism, but that a bona fide financial crisis that threatens to descend into a real depression will produce much higher demands. The twin episodes reviewed here, however, run precisely counter to that speculation. The economic downturn that the Reagan administration experienced during its first six months in office was not even a recession, though policymakers could not be sure of that fact at the time. The only certainty was that the NBER had announced in mid-1980 that the US economy entered a recession in January of that year. NBER did get around to declaring that this recession had ended in July 1980 until July 1981.41 By contrast, the recession of 2008–9 lasted much longer (though we do not yet know precisely by how much) than the seven-month recession of 1980, and was far more devastating to the economy. This observation tends to deepen rather than resolve the conundrum as to why the auto industry received import protection in 1981 but not in 2009. A second possibility is that a downturn will produce protectionist demands only if imports are perceived to be an essential part of the problem. The data shown in Figure 6 highlight the fact that a merchandise trade deficit was still a relatively new phenomenon at the time of the 1980–1 episode, with the account having been in balance as recently as the start of 1976. Though the deficits that the United States ran in the late 1970s and early 1980s were much smaller in both absolute and relative terms than those of the early 21st century (see Figure 7), they were seen at the time with great alarm. And while the overall deficit came close to disappearing in the recession of 1980, with imports dropping at a time when exports continued to rise, that was not the case for automobiles. The ever-larger imports of Japanese vehicles, and the resulting increase in the US automotive trade deficit, definitely made trade appear to be a significant part of the overall economic problem. 39 Gamberoni and Newfarmer (2009). Dadush (2009: 1). 41 Ironically, that July 1981 announcement coincided with the start of a new recession. The recession of July 1981 would not be declared until January 1982. 40 19 Figure 6: Quarterly US merchandise trade ($ billion), 1976–1984 $350 Imports Recessions $300 $250 $200 Exports $150 Deficit $100 $50 . . 19 84 . 19 83 . 19 82 . 19 81 . 19 80 . 19 79 . 19 78 . 19 77 19 76 $0 Figure 7: Quarterly US merchandise trade ($ billion), 2001–2009 $2,500 Recession Recession Imports $2,000 $1,500 Exports $1,000 Deficit $500 . 20 09 . 20 08 . . 20 07 . 20 06 . 20 05 . 20 04 . 20 03 . 20 02 20 01 $0 Source: Calculated from US Department of Commerce data at http://www.bea.gov/national/nipaweb/index.asp. Note that the end date for the 2007–9 recession is speculative; no official determination has yet been reached. 20 By contrast, one of the first effects of the outbreak of the financial crisis in late 2008 was a rapid decline in imports. Exports also fell, as can be seen in Figure 7, but not by a lesser degree. The result was an approximate halving of the trade deficit in the space of just a few months. This is one reason why policymakers in Washington devoted so little attention to trade, as compared to other aspects of the economy, in the last months of the Bush administration and the first months of the Obama administration. The trade deficit was something of a ‘self-licking ice cream cone’, and neither the administration nor Congress felt compelled to devote much time to a problem that appeared to be solving itself. It was not until his second year in office that President Obama began to stress the importance of trade as a means of promoting economic recovery, and then did so only by stressing export-promotion rather than efforts to cut imports. The qualitative differences between these two recessions thus appears to supply part of the answer. The changes in the trade were seen to be one of the causes in the first case, and merely a symptom in the second. A long-term political economy explanation: the consequences of globalisation That short-term economic explanation seems persuasive, but also incomplete. For a more comprehensive understanding of the differing results we need to examine longer-term changes in the structure of the US automotive industry and the impact of these changes on the politics of trade. The final explanation presented here, and the one for which the evidence seems strongest, is that the differing outcomes of these two episodes can be understood as the consequence of long-term changes in the composition and interests of the US automotive industry. That industry has undergone four changes major changes over the past few decades: (1) greater globalisation through the outsourcing of parts manufacture and strategic partnership with Japanese and other foreign firms; (2) the rise of ‘transplants’ in US parts and vehicle manufacturing; (3) reduced influence of the unions, both through declining production in the United States and the migration of production to states with lower levels of unionisation; and (4) the increasing strength of automobile dealers, especially those who sell imported vehicles. The net result has been a decrease in the number and influence of those who perceive a benefit from import protection, and a concomitant rise in the size and power of those who favour an open market. Put another way, the differences between 1980–1 and 2008–9 can be best understood not by looking at the decisions of those policymakers who choose whether or not to supply protection, but instead at those private sector interests who demand it. There is no reason to expect a commodity to be supplied if there is little or no demand. From the 1930s through the 1950s the US automotive industry and its associated labour unions were key members of the domestic coalition in favour of a liberal trade policy. There was no irony intended when the authors of one of the classic studies of trade politics at mid-century entitled a chapter ‘Detroit: Hotbed of Free Trade’.42 Nor was the pro-trade sentiment confined to the firms. Many forget that from the mid-1930s through the early 1960s the labour movement formed part of the backbone of the pro-trade coalition in the United States, and that this was due in large measure to the interests and influence of the United Auto Workers. This posture in support of open markets began to change in the 1960s and 1970s, when competition first from German and then Japanese producers led to a gradual upturn in import penetration. Since that time the Big Three have gravitated back towards a more pro-trade posture, at least when it is managed to their liking (eg, in free trade agreements with accommodating rules of origin),43 but the labour unions have left the pro-trade coalition for good. 42 Bauer et al (1963). Space does not permit an exhaustive examination of the more favourable view that the Big Three take of discriminatory free trade agreements (FTAs) than they do of multilateral liberalisation. Suffice it to cite two facts in support of this contention: The US negotiators in the Uruguay Round made no concessions on the 2.5% and 25% tariffs on passenger cars and pickup trucks, and from the US-Canada FTA of 1988 to the North American FTA of 1992 the two agreements’ rules of origin expanded greatly in length and complexity. 43 21 The first change that separates the 2008–9 episode from its 1980–1 predecessor is the greater globalisation of the Big Three. In that earlier incident the globalisation of these firms’ operations was limited primarily to the sourcing of some parts overseas, and ‘captive imports’ (ie, imports of vehicles purchased from foreign partners). At that time all three firms imported pickup trucks made by partners in Japan, and Chrysler also imported Japanese-made passenger cars.44 Apart from their own investments in Canada, most of the Big Three production in foreign plants was devoted to sales in the host countries or the surrounding region. Moreover, the Big Three’s captive imports were falling in relative terms: Whereas these transactions accounted for 40.5% of all vehicle imports in 1975, by the first half of 1980 they had fallen to 26.6%.45 So while the outsourcing of parts had reached a sufficiently high level in 1980 for the Big Three to prefer VERs over domestic-content legislation as the chief form of import protection, the industry’s overall level of globalisation was still low enough that the firms favoured a closed US market for finished automobiles over an open one. Since that time their dependence on global supply chains has grown considerably. The second major change over the past generation is the domestication of Japanese automotive firms, including transplant assembly operations as well as Japanese investments in the US auto parts sector. The decision to invest in the US market was not taken by the Japanese firms, nor indeed by one of their predecessors, solely on the basis of economic considerations.46 The Askew-Yasukawa Agreement of 1980, in which the US and Japanese governments agreed to promote Japanese firms’ investment in US parts and vehicle production, was intended to defuse tensions between Washington and Tokyo. Honda was the first Japanese automobile company to announce its plans to establish a production facility in the United States, with its first US-made vehicles entering the market in 1982 (ie, the first full year in which the VERs were in effect). Most other companies established facilities within a few years, including Nissan (1982), Mitsubishi (1985), Toyota (1985) and Mazda (1987). The relationship between the major Japanese producers and their US rivals also grew closer with the forging of strategic alliances. Each one of the Big Three paired up with a Japanese partner for activities ranging from collaborative R&D to joint production facilities: Chrysler with Mitsubishi, Ford with Mazda, and General Motors with Toyota. Chrysler was even more globalised during 1998–2007, when it was the junior partner in the ill-starred DaimlerChrysler venture.47 These alliances have all served to restore, at least in part, the US firms’ support for more open trade in automobiles. A great deal of scholarship,48 not to mention popular culture,49 has focused on the social or economic issues surrounding the transplant of Japanese production, managerial styles and even culture to US communities. Less attention has been paid to the impact that these transplants have had on the political interests and activities of people in those communities, and on those who represent them in Congress. As can be seen in Table 3, however, the raw numbers suggest that those states with transplant facilities (with or without Big Three facilities as well) now outnumber the few states in which the Big Three are the only producers. That latter group wields only 15.0% of the voting power in Congress, while the states in which transplants account for at least some of the automotive production have 32.8%. It is notable that the transplants tend to aggregate in the ‘right to work’ (aka anti-union) states of the south, a point that relates to the third major change in the US automotive industry since the early 1980s. Employment in the automotive manufacturing sector has fallen, and unionised 44 GM’s partner was Isuzu, Ford’s was Toyo Kogyo, and Chrysler’s was Mitsubishi. See USITC (1980: A-17). USITC (1980: A-25). 46 Volkswagen began production in the United States of the subcompact Rabbit in 1978, having purchased a plant that Chrysler owned but never used. Some observers believe it is no coincidence that this investment came at a time when protectionist legislation was under consideration in the United States. 47 Following Chrysler’s bankruptcy in 2009, it is now owned by the United Auto Workers, Fiat and the governments of the United States and Canada. 48 See, for example, Perrucci (1994). 49 See, for example, the 1986 film Gung Ho, a comedy about a Japanese transplant in the Midwest. 45 22 employment has plummeted at an even faster rate. This has diminished the political influence of the one segment of the US industry that has an unambiguous interest in restricting import competition. Table 3: Political strength of states by automotive production mix, 2008a No automotive production Transplant production only Big Three and transplant production Big Three production only 30 states Alabama California Delaware Mississippi Illinois Georgia South Carolina Indiana Kansas West Virginia Kentucky Louisiana Michigan Minnesota Ohio Missouri Tennessee Virginia Texas Wisconsin House seats: 193 House seats: 20 House seats: 161 House seats: 61 Senate seats: 60 Senate seats: 8 Senate seats: 16 Senate seats: 16 Share: 52.2% Share: 6.3% Share: 26.5% Share: 15.0% Notes: All states have two senators; seats in the House of Representatives are distributed according to population. Shares of total take into account the differing sizes of the House of Representatives and the Senate, such that each Senate seat receives 4.35 times as much weight as each House seat. a Congressional representation of states hosting automotive assembly plants that were in production in 2008; transplants include Japanese, German and Korean automobile companies. Source: Company websites and other sources. Employment in the manufacturing side of the automotive industry has declined sharply over the past few decades. As recently as 1995 there were 251,300 persons employed in the manufacture of automobiles and light trucks in the United States, but this figure fell to 119,500 in 2009. During the same period the number of persons employed in the manufacture of motor vehicle parts fell from 786,900 to 418,700. By way of comparison, in 2009 there were 316,200 persons employed in motor vehicle and parts wholesale trade, 482,200 in auto parts and accessories stores, 806,100 in automotive repair and maintenance, 827,000 worked in gasoline stations, and 912,600 were employed in new car dealerships.50 In short, the service-related segments of the automotive sector (broadly defined) now employ far more people than the manufacturing segment, and we should not be surprised if this leads to a corresponding shift in the relative power of the different segments to influence public policy. Parts production in the United States has shifted in two important respects over the past generation. First, the traditional Midwestern core of the US industry now accounts for a smaller share of the total, and forms just one part of a geographic region that is sometimes called Auto Alley. This is a North–South corridor that starts in the Midwest but extends far south into states that manufacturers seem to prefer in order to minimise the likelihood of a unionised workforce. The second change is that ‘[t]he percentages of parts made outside the United States and inside the United States by foreign-owned companies have increased’.51 While the first of these trends might appear to strengthen the overall political power of the automotive industry, insofar as it has diffused that industry among a wider range of states and congressional districts, the second one may make the representatives of those auto-dependent districts less inclined to favour initiatives that discriminate against foreign-owned firms. 50 All figures from the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS). Note that comparable data are not available for 1980–1 in most sectors (other than new car dealerships) due to changes in the BLS nomenclature. 51 Klier and Rubinstein (2008: 358). 23 Several factors have contributed to the decline in UAW membership, including some that are economic (downsizing and automation in the industry) and others that are at least partly political (the rise of employment in right-to-work states). The net result is that membership in the union, which broke the million-member level in 1950 and peaked at 1,527,858 in 1979, declined to 468,096 members in 2008 and 392,166 in 2009.52 Membership in the UAW is not a precise measurement of unionisation in the automotive industry, insofar as there are many auto workers who are not members of the union (especially those who work in transplant operations and/or in factories located in the southern states) and also many UAW members who are not part of this industry. The union also represents workers in some other industries that are closely related (eg, aerospace and defence, heavy trucks and farm equipment) as well as others that bear no apparent relationship to automobiles or parts.53 The membership numbers nevertheless offer a rough-and-ready gauge not of the size of the automotive labour force per se, but of its more organised and politically influential members. And those numbers are down. That shift can be contrasted with the fourth and final change in the structure of the US industry, which is the rise in relative power of automotive dealers in general and especially those who deal in Japanese and other imports. At the time of the 1981 policy debate, the ‘dealers who sold Japanese cars’ were the only ‘domestic actors with a vested interest in the established liberal policy’.54 Their numbers, however, were limited. As of 1980 there were 23,379 dealerships in the United States that sold vehicles made in the United States and Canada, and 16,967 that sold imported vehicles, but only 4,407 dealerships that sold Japanese cars.55 That number grew by more than 50% over the next few decades, such that by 2008 there were 6,811 dealer franchises selling Japanese brand vehicles in the United States, employing 310,575 people.56 That amounted to 32.8% of all new automobile dealerships in the United States.57 Dealers of imported automobiles did have a voice in 1980, which marked the tenth anniversary of the founding of the American International Automobile Dealers Association (AIADA). That group was originally formed in response to proposals that would have established quotas on cars and other imported products. Volkswagen was then the leading source of imported cars, and US Volkswagen dealers feared that their livelihoods were being threatened and that the National Auto Dealers Association refused to take a stand against protectionism. AIADA’s numbers were nevertheless too small in 1980–1 to form an effective counterweight to the combined position of the Big Three and the UAW. The data in Figure 8 illustrate just how much the world has changed since then. Whereas in 1981 there were 1.8 UAW members for every person employed in new car dealerships, by 2009 there were 2.4 persons employed in those dealerships for every UAW member. When one further considers the fact that auto dealerships are widely distributed, and that there are probably very few congressional districts without at least one of them, it is obvious that this group is in a better position than the UAW to exercise influence over members of Congress. 52 Data for UAW membership supplied to the author by the UAW Research Library; figures are thousands of average annual dues-paying members. 53 Included in the wide range of UAW members are workers in other manufacturing industries (eg, household appliances, brewing, lawn and garden equipment, etc), as well as technical, office, and professional workers (eg, draftsmen, industrial designers, engineers, etc). 54 Reich (1992: 7). 55 USITC (1980: A-22). 56 Figure provided to the author by the Japan Automobile Manufacturers Association. 57 Author’s calculation, based on the fact that (according to the National Automobile Dealers Association) there were 20,770 new car dealerships in the United States in 2008. 24 Figure 8: Employment in two segments of the US automotive industry (1000s), 1975–2010 1600 Members of the United Auto Workers 1400 1200 Employees in New Car Dealerships 1000 800 600 400 200 0 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Source: Data for new car dealerships calculated from US Bureau of Labor Statistics data; figures are thousands of persons in January of each year, and numbers for 2010 are preliminary. Data for UAW membership supplied to the author by the UAW Research Library; figures are thousands of average annual dues-paying members. Conclusions and Implications ‘It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expect our dinner’, according to Adam Smith, ‘but from their regard to their own interest’.58 That same observation offers useful guidance in assessing the demands that segments of the US auto industry made, and the responses they received from policymakers in the two branches of government, in the two episodes reviewed above. Knowing their interests and positions helps us to understand why protection was granted in the first case and not in the second. The different results in the two cases reviewed here can be understood as natural consequences of the changes in the structure, and hence the interests, of the industry itself. This analysis has drilled down through a series of possible explanations for the differing outcomes in the 1980–1 and 2008–9 cases. None of these explanations is entirely wrong, but a few seem to tell only a part of the answer. The legal explanation tells us why the Obama administration did not opt for precisely the same form of import protection that the Reagan administration did, but does not help us to understand why other means were not employed to restrict imports. The political explanation is also of limited assistance: The actions of these two presidents run counter to what one might expect from their respective ideological and partisan attachments, and Reagan’s somewhat larger reserve of political capital should have made it possible for him to fend off congressional demands. His administration nevertheless chose to give in to those demands, in part because they were made by majorities in both parties. This then begs the question, why was protection so much more popular in Congress a generation ago? Part of the answer comes from the differences between the two economic downturns, with trade having been more economically significant and politically controversial in 1980–1 than in 2008–9. We can get a more complete answer by looking beyond those short-term differences between the two episodes, and looking to the political consequences of processes that were put in march in the earlier case. The globalisation of the US automotive industry has greatly shifted the interests and levels of influence for different players, such that the Big Three firms have less interest in restricting imports, labour remains interested but has a fraction of the influence it once wielded, and both the Japanese producers and 58 Smith (1776: Book 1, Chapter 2). 25 the dealers who sell their cars are in a much stronger position to influence US policymakers now than they were a generation ago. What does this comparison tell us about the relationship between economic downturns and protectionism? The simplest lesson is that the link is not so simple, and that we should not assume that association observed between these two phenomena in the 1930s was the manifestation of a universal rule. Policymakers will indeed be under pressure to provide relief in economic hard times, but it does not necessarily follow that restrictions on trade will be a prominent part of the relief packages. They are unlikely to supply protectionism if it is not demanded, and in this instance we see how the processes of globalisation have reduced the likelihood that such demands will be made in the first place. References Bauer, R, Pool, I de Sola and Dexter, L A (1963), American Business and Public Policy: The Politics of Foreign Trade. New York, Atherton. Berry, S, Levinsohn, J and Pakes, A (1999), ‘Voluntary Export Restraints on Automobiles: Evaluating a Trade Policy’, American Economic Review 89 (3), pp 400–30. Cohen, S (N.D.), ‘The Route to Japan’s Voluntary Export Restraints on Automobiles: An Analysis of the U.S. Government’s Decision-Making Process in 1981’, Stephen Cohen Working Paper No 20. Available at http://www.gwu.edu/~nsacrhiv/japan/scohenwp.htm. Dadush, U (2009), Resurgent Protectionism: Risks and Possible Remedies, Carnegie Policy Outlook, Washington, DC, Carnegie Endowment. Dardis, R and Decker, S (2005), ‘The Welfare Loss of the Voluntary Export Restraint for Japanese Automobiles’, Journal of Consumer Affairs 18 (1), pp 47–63. De Melo and Tarr (1987), Gamberoni, E and Newfarmer, R (2009), ‘Trade Protection: Incipient but Worrisome Trends’, Available at: http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/3183. Goldstein, J (1993), Ideas, Interests, and American Trade Policy, Ithaca, NY, Cornell University Press. Hufbauer, G C and Elliott, K A (1994), Measuring the Costs of Protection in the United States, Washington, DC, Institute for International Economics. Jackson, J (1988), ______________________ Klier, T and Rubinstein, J (2008), Who Really Made Your Car? Restructuring and Geographic Change in the Auto Industry, Kalamazoo, MI, W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research. Low, P (1993), Trading Free: The GATT and U.S. Trade Policy, New York, The Twentieth Century Fund Press. Nelson, D (1996), ‘Making Sense of the 1981 Automobile VER: Economics, Politics, and the Political Economy of Protection’, in A Krueger (ed), The Political Economy of Trade Protection, Chicago, University of Chicago Press. Perrucci, R (1994), Japanese Auto Transplants in the Heartland: Corporatism and Community, New York, Aline de Gruyter. Reich, S (1992), The Reagan Administration, the Auto Producers, and the 1981 Agreement with Japan, Pew Case Studies in International Affairs, Case 119, Washington, DC. Ricardo, D (1817), On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. Rosegrant, S (1982), Standing up for Steel: The US Government Response to Steel Industry and Union Efforts to Win Protection from Imports, Cambridge, MA, John F. Kennedy School of Government. Smith, A (1776). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. 26 Stockman, D (1986), The Triumph of Politics: Why the Reagan Revolution Failed, New York, Harper and Row. Toder, E J with Cardell, N S and Burton, E (1978), Trade Policy and the U.S. Automobile Industry, New York, Praeger. US Congress, Joint Economic Committee (1980), U.S. Trade and Investment Policy: Imports and the Future of the American Automobile Industry. Hearing of 19 March. US Department of Commerce (2007), Foreign-Based Companies Investing in the U.S. Auto Industry. Available at: http://trade.gov/static/auto_reports_foreignautoinvestment.pdf. US Department of Transportation, National Highway Traffic Safety Administration (2009), Consumer Assistance to Recycle and Save Act of 2009: Report to the House Committee on Energy and Commerce, the Senate Committee on Commerce, Science, and Transportation and the House and Senate Committees on Appropriations. US International Trade Commission (1980), Certain Motor Vehicles and Certain Chassis and Bodies Thereof. Investigation TA-201-44. USITC Publication 1110. US President (1982), Public Papers of the Presidents of the United States: Jimmy Carter, 1980–81 Book II, Washington, DC, US Government Printing Office. World Trade Organisation, Trade Policy Review Body (2009), Report to the TPRB from the DirectorGeneral on the Financial and Economic Crisis and Trade-Related Developments, WTO document JOB(09)/62. 27 This paper presents a structured comparison of policy responses by the United States to competition with Japan in the automotive sector in two difference administrations. It will examine one case in which the United States chose to impose protectionist measures and another in which it did not, in order to consider the effects of economic downturns on both the demand and supply of protection. After reviewing the facts of the two cases, this paper will evaluate four possible explanations that are variously legal, political and economic in nature. While these explanations are not mutually exclusive, and each may offer some part of the answer, the evidence suggests that the most persuasive case is based on long-term changes in the structure of the US automotive industry. Centre for Economic Policy Research 77 Bastwick Street, London EC1V 3PZ Tel: +44 (0)20 7183 8809 Fax: +44 (0)20 7183 8820 Email: cepr@cepr.org www.cepr.org