AB EXTRA – PRIVACY AND MERGER CONTROL PRICE AND PRIVACY Alec Burnside responds to an article in our previous issue on privacy and merger control, by Francisco Enrique González-Díaz I t is a truth universally acknowledged, that a single norm must determine the parties’ fortune when the European Commission is in possession of their merger filing. No-one doubts that the EU Merger Regulation prescribes significant impediment to effective competition as the test of compatibility, and that there is no broader public policy test. But to leap from that truism, as Francisco Enrique González-Díaz does in the last issue, to the view that privacy considerations can never be relevant in merger cases, is a sleight of hand that should not go unremarked.1 Consumer welfare has long been established as the goal of European competition law and policy, as Neelie Kroes noted in a speech of October 2005: “Consumer welfare is now well established as the standard the Commission applies when assessing mergers and infringements of the Treaty rules on cartels and monopolies. Our aim is simple: to protect competition in the market as a means of enhancing consumer welfare and ensuring an efficient allocation of resources.”2 A key facet of consumer welfare is for purchasers to have access to a wide selection of goods and services, varying not only by price but also in quality. This is reflected in the Commission Guidelines on horizontal mergers: “Effective competition brings benefits to consumers, such as low prices, high-quality products, a wide selection of goods and services, and innovation. Through its control of mergers, the Commission prevents mergers that would be likely to deprive customers of these benefits by significantly increasing the market power of firms. By ‘increased market power’ is meant the ability of one or more firms to profitably increase prices, reduce output, choice or quality of goods and services, diminish innovation, or otherwise influence parameters of competition.”3 Recent merger decisions bear out this emphasis. For example, in Ryanair/Aer Lingus, the Commission examined consumer preferences as follows: 36 mlex MAGAZINE July-September 2010 “In order to analyse the substitutability of scheduled airtransport services from different airports, the Commission has sought to identify the main factors which are relevant for individual customers when it comes to choosing between airtransport services out of different airports. The results of the Commission’s investigation show that the customers take into account mainly the following elements: (i) Travel time: All customers have a preference to minimise the travel time (and costs) and prefer, other things being equal, the closer airport to the more remote one...... (ii) Travel cost: Customers have a general preference for the cheapest solution for their journey….. (iii) Flight times/schedules/frequencies: Most customers also have a preference for a specific departure and return time and date and will chose (sic) the airline (and the airport from which it is operating) which corresponds most to their preferences. (iv) Quality of service:…air carriers offer different levels of service. Similarly, airports offer different levels of service. By way of example, shopping facilities at large main airports may be relevant for the airport choice of some customers, while shorter check-in times at some airports might be considered as an advantage by other customers. ”4 With these tools of analysis the Commission defined the markets in which competition was to be protected – competition in which price was only one of four relevant types of parameter, with quality and other non-price characteristics giving consumers the basis to distinguish between the services offered by competitors. More recently, the European Commission investigated Microsoft’s acquisition of Yahoo’s Internet Search and Search Advertising business. The Commission investigated potential theories of harm affecting the position of internet users, publishers, distributors and advertisers, i.e. the four main constituencies with an interest in Internet Search and Search AB EXTRA – PRIVACY AND MERGER CONTROL Advertising. With respect to users of Internet Search, the Commission investigated whether the transaction would: “post-merger influence the incentive of the players to innovate, to lower the quality of organic search (i.e. degrading the relevance of the results) and whether users will be harmed by a loss of variety.”5 On the facts of the case, not only did the Commission find these theories of competitive harm unlikely to materialise, but “the respondents to the market investigation stated that the transaction will be pro-competitive”.6 Nevertheless, the case illustrates that, in certain circumstances, the Commission will consider whether a merger will give rise to a significant impediment to effective competition by significantly increasing the market power with reference to non-price factors such as quality of service (e.g. degradation of search results by manipulation of these results). It is no surprise to see the Commission investigating the impact of a merger on non-price factors of competition, in view of the business model of many two-sided platforms operating on the internet: one category of market participants (often individuals) use the platform free of charge, while another category (for instance advertisers) pay for use of the platform. Given that the first group do not pay for use of the service, the merger can have no impact on price for that group. But it does not follow that the merger is automatically neutral as regards their interests. Rather, it may then be relevant to focus the investigation on other parameters of competition that influence those users’ choice of service, and whether market power will increase, and competition suffer, through a foreseeable impact on the services they receive. The relevant question to ask for present purposes is therefore whether internet privacy is such a non-price, quality of service, parameter of competition. In common with other pertinent questions of merger analysis, this question needs to be answered with regard to relevant empirical evidence rather than dogma. And there is indeed a recognition among users and competition authorities (and privacy regulators) that the respect for privacy shown by a service provider is a factor that influences consumer choice, and so may affect competition. There have been waves of media coverage recently reflecting consumer concern over the treatment of personal information, with consumers abandoning one service provider in favour of another that shows greater restraint in the use of private data. Of course privacy advocates call at such moments for action under specific privacy rules, but consumers may also switch provider to one showing greater restraint in the use made of private information received from users. And conversely, service providers compete to make their offerings attractive by the privacy attributes of their products. Privacy is an increasingly important quality-of-service element for users. As individuals, we expect our service providers to handle our sensitive and confidential data with due care. This can be illustrated by the very strong reactions in the wake of Google’s Street View “screw-up.”7 According to a report in The Economist,8 the global leader in internet search explained that an experimental software project designed to gather data from unencrypted Wi-Fi networks had been rolled out along with its Street View initiative, which uses cameras mounted on cars to film streets and buildings. As a result, Google collected and stored sensitive private data over a number of years. A representative of the Electronic Privacy Information Center commented that this “really flies in the face of [Google’s] assertion that customers should just trust them.”9 The close and increasing trend for consumers to choose service providers whom they ‘trust’ with their data is noted by the UK’s Ofcom in its 2010 Media Literacy report: “...internet users are becoming more knowledgeable about security issues and less willing to provide personal information online, according to new Ofcom research. It reveals that 80 per cent of adults with a social networking profile are now more likely to only allow friends or family to see it, compared to 48 per cent in 2007.”10 The dynamic process of service providers adapting the privacy settings of their offerings, in face of consumer expectations, was amply demonstrated when Google launched Buzz as a direct competitor to Facebook. Thus “at launch, [Google] set the default to link Gmail users to people they had frequently emailed.”11 It then retreated, in the ensuing furore over this extended use of consumer information that it held for other reasons. In this episode one can see both privacy issues in a regulatory sense, but also a competitive dynamic in which Google must have formed a view as to how best to attract users. This called for a judgment on privacy attributes of its existing and new service offerings, and it was one that soon produced a consumer response. In line with this description, competition authorities have considered the impact of privacy policies in merger cases. Google’s acquisition of DoubleClick brought together two leaders in the online advertising space (Google, a leader in the intermediation of ads, and DoubleClick, a leader in various adserving tools used by publishers and advertisers). In the US, this merger was reviewed by the Federal Trade Commission, which noted that it had: “…investigated the possibility that this transaction could adversely affect non-price attributes of competition, such as consumer privacy.”12 And on this point the minority was aligned, Commissioner Pamela Jones noting the argument that: July-September 2010 mlex MAGAZINE 37 AB EXTRA – PRIVACY AND MERGER CONTROL “…if network effects lead to a reduction in the number of search competitors, consumers will suffer from a diversity of choice among search engines, which will reduce the incentives related non-price dimensions.”13 The European Commission also reviewed this transaction, but did not explicitly consider a theory of competitive harm however, at issue in its more recent decision in TomTom/Tele Atlas. TomTom is the European market leader in software for personal navigation devices (PND), using the global positioning technology. It proposed to acquire Tele Atlas, one of only two providers of digital maps (the other being NAVTEQ) with a complete coverage of Europe and North America. In its decision, the Commission noted that: concerns can be considered as similar to product degradation in that the perceived value of the map for PND manufacturers could be revealed [by Tele Atlas, post-transaction] to TomTom. As a consequence, Tele Atlas’s map database could be perceived as relatively less valuable than NAVTEQ’s map database. to consider switching to NAVTEQ.”14 The Commission ultimately dismissed this theory of harm, to mitigate third-party concerns related to its treatment of legitimate source of concern for customers, in a manner that is relevant to merger analysis, and also how suppliers respond to those concerns, likewise in a manner that is relevant to merger analysis. So, both TomTom/Tele Atlas and Google/ DoubleClick were cleared, on their facts, but that is no basis for excluding generally the relevance of privacy attributes as a well be a matter of legitimate interest with its own body of open to consideration in competition cases. In view of case law, commercial realities and consumer behaviour, therefore, privacy is entirely germane in an assessment of market dynamics and consumer welfare, for competition-law purposes. It is a crucial qualitative element for consumer choice. Far from falling outside the scope of European and US merger control, it is unavoidable that privacy considerations are included in competition analysis as one relevant non-price attribute, in order to maintain a market in which a multiplicity of competing providers offer consumers a choice between services with greater or lesser respect-forprivacy attributes. Competition authorities will therefore pride themselves on privacy laws are without prejudice to their doing so. n Alec Burnside represented Microsoft in the Microsoft/Yahoo merger proceedings, and as a third party in the Google/DoubleClick proceedings. Footnotes 1 Privacy and Merger Control in the EU, Francisco Enrique GonzálezDíaz, MLex Magazine, April-June 2010 (58-60). 2 Neelie Kroes, London, October 2005, quoted in Richard Whish, Competition Law (6th Edition), Oxford 2009, p19. 3 38 Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers under the Council Regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings (2004/C 31/03), paragraph 8. 4 Case No COMP/M.4439 – Ryanair / Aer Lingus, [73-74]. 5 Case No COMP/M.5727 – Microsoft / Yahoo! Search Business [202]. 6 Ibidem, para. 256. 7 Sergey Brin, quoted in ‘Brin Says Google ‘Screwed Up’ Collecting Wi-Fi Data (Update1)’, Bloomberg Businessweek, 19 May 2010 8 Lives of others, Economist, 24 May 2010. According to The Economist, no less than ten privacy “watchdog” authorities around the world are currently investigating privacy aspects of Google’s business practices. mlex MAGAZINE July-September 2010 9 Google: Street View spycars did slurp your Wi-Fi, The Register, 14 May 2010, (http://www.theregister.co.uk/2010/05/14/google_street_ 10 http://www.ofcom.org.uk/consumer/2010/05/uk-internet-usersbecoming-more-security-conscious/ 11 Facebook’s Open Disdain for Privacy, John Gapper, Financial Times, 13 May 2010. 12 File No. 071-0170 - Google / DoubleClick FTC, pp.2-3. 13 File No. 071-0170 - Google / DoubleClick FTC, dissenting statement of Commissioner Pamela Jones Harbour, footnote 25. Similarly BEUC (the European Consumers’ Organisation) noted in a submission to the European Commission in this case that: “The monopoly power that Google will acquire through this acquisition will further weaken its incentives to compete on the non-price aspects of its services, including such quality factors as the privacy protections it offers consumers”. 27 June 2007. http://epic.org/ privacy/ftc/google/beuc_062707.pdf 14 Case No COMP/M.4854 - TomTom / Tele Atlas [274, 276].