Comparative Law and Economics of Contracts Cases slides Topic 3: Offer and Acceptance and Standard Terms Fernando Gomez Pomar Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona NYU School of Law NYU School of Law, Fall term Byrne v. Leon van Tienhoven • Facts: – Defendant, operating a business in Cardiff, sends a letter to plaintiff in NYC, on 1 October 1879 Offers 1,000 boxes of tinplates Hensol at a given price plus commission Bank acceptance on London or Liverpool Subject to acceptance by plaintiff through telegram by 15 October – Plaintiff receives letter on 11 October 1879 – Plaintiff sends telegram on 11 October: “Accept thousand Hensols”, and confirms by letter on 15 October – The letter contains reference to payment: letter of credit of Canadian Bank of Commerce on a London bank Byrne v. Leon van Tienhoven • Facts: – Defendant sends letter 8 October revoking the offer alleging turbulences and price increases in the tinplate market – Plaintiff receives revocation letter on 20 October and rejects the revocation claiming contract has been agreed and is binding. – Plaintiff requests delivery and informs defendant that goods have been resold at a net profit of $ 1,850 – Defendant replies on 25 October refusing to ship goods and returning letter of credit – Plaintiff sues for damages Byrne v. Leon van Tienhoven • Issues: – Timing of contract when offer and acceptance are not simultaneous – Timing of contract in the presence of a revocation of the offer – Whether the fact that the behavior of the offeree is not fully compliant with the offer prevents the contract from being considered binding • Outcome: – Court finds for plaintiff Byrne v. Leon van Tienhoven • Grounds: – Offeror may revoke offer, but revocation is considered made upon receipt by offeree – Offerees when they sent acceptance were unaware of revocation – A different rule would force offerees to wait to be certain of contract existence until a reasonable time for arrival of revocation had passed – Defendant could have refused delivery based on the terms of the banker’s credit documents, but this is not what defendant argued to refuse delivery Byrne v. Leon van Tienhoven • Analysis: – Different possible rules to determine the timing of contract when consent is sequential: Time Time Time Time of of of of acceptance of offer releasing acceptance from offeree acceptance reaching offeror offeror knowing of acceptance – Role of reliance by offeree? Should it affect the selection of the rule or the application, once a rule is selected? – Role of offeror’s steps to control timing of agreement – Are means of communication relevant? Should there be especial rules for e-contracts? – Application of mailbox rule when there are differences between terms in the offer and those accepted Gibson v. Manchester City Council • Facts: – Manchester City Council had at the time a policy of selling council homes to their tenants, and provided information forms – Plaintiff sent a form and received a letter stating: City prepared to sell for a specified price Maximum mortgage the City could offer Clarifies it is not a firm offer of mortgage Encloses an application form to formally apply to buy – Plaintiff completed application form requesting a lower price – City answered that no reduction was possible – Plaintiff sent a letter requesting the purchase to be completed – A new council was elected, with the policy of not selling houses, unless a binding contract was already in existence Gibson v. Manchester City Council • • • Issues: – When a firm offer or a proposal subject to contract exist – What is dominant in determining the above, language used or behavior undertaken – Scope of agreement: does it need to cover all relevant elements or only the core dimensions of contract Outcome – Court of Appeal found for the plaintiff – House of Lords reversed Grounds: – Traditional offer and acceptance view of consent should apply in the case – Wording of Manchester Council document made clear that it was a mere proposal, not a firm offer – Important elements of what was the standard sale contract of the Council (use as a private dwelling, no sale or lease for 5 years) had not been discussed Gibson v. Manchester City Council • Analysis: – Role of reliance by offeree – May the offeree waive knowledge or the need to agree on other elements of the transaction in exchange for the contract being binding with the terms supplied by the other party or terms favorable to the other party? Think of situations in which parties have a yet incomplete or non binding agreement One possible solution is the pro-defendant gap-filler (Omri Ben-Shahar, 2005) under which each party is granted an option to enforce the transaction supplemented with terms supplied by the other party or most favorable (within reason) to the other party Gibson v. Manchester City Council • Analysis: – Is language drafted by offeror to govern nature of communication of offer and acceptance, and when the contract becomes binding? – Should there be exceptions to this offeror-controlled regime? When rules of the game are set in standard terms? Are clauses “subject to contract” always enforceable vis-à-vis consumers? Are clauses depriving agents of authority to bind unless approval from superiors enforceable against consumers? (e.g. art. 84 (c) CESL) Should the reasonable expectations of the party who is not setting the “rules of the game” be considered? Should the purpose of the provision leading to the contract being non-binding be reasonable? Morrison v. Thoelke • Facts: – Plaintiffs own a house in Florida and have negotiated the sale with defendants – Defendants execute the contract for purchase and mail it to plaintiffs, who are in Texas – Plaintiffs sign and execute the contract and mail it to defendants’ lawyer in Florida – Before mail arrives plaintiffs telephone defendants’ lawyer to cancel the agreement – Defendants plaintiffs sue register the contract nonetheless, and Morrison v. Thoelke • Issues: – Timing of contract in the presence of revocation • Outcome – Trial court finds for plaintiff and orders summary judgement – Appeals Court reverses and finds for defendants: the contract had been concluded • Grounds – Trial court considers that consent had been repudiated prior to receipt of acceptance and thus there is no contract – Appeals Court holds to the traditional mailbox rule and considers there is a binding contract, after careful and detailed review of all precedents on the matter – The possibility of withdrawing a letter according to postal regulations is irrelevant for the rule in Contract Law Morrison v. Thoelke • Analysis: – Is there a risk and cost free solution to the problem of the timing of the contract becoming binding and final? – Should the rule benefit the party who starts the communication process and thus may set rules on timing and conditions for the contract becoming binding? In this case, actually the mailbox rule does not favor offeree, but actually the offeror – Is loss of control of the acceptance a good rationale for mailbox rule? Morrison v. Thoelke • Analysis: – Is it having a default more important than what the default is? Other examples of certainty being more important than content: “conventional rules” Unlikely that the balance of costs and benefits is exactly the same for two alternative solutions, however “conventional” they may seem Changing a “convention” entails costs (learning, adaptation), but also benefits (change of circumstances, technological evolution) – Is anticipating the time of the contract being perfected a generally desirable effect? CESL on timing of contract formation • Article 35 CESL: Time of conclusion of the contract – 1. Where an acceptance is sent by the offeree the contract is concluded when the acceptance reaches the offeror. – 2. Where an offer is accepted by conduct, the contract is concluded when notice of the conduct reaches the offeror. – 3. Notwithstanding paragraph 2, where by virtue of the offer, of practices which the parties have established between themselves, or of a usage, the offeree may accept the offer by conduct without notice to the offeror, the contract is concluded when the offeree begins to act. CESL on timing of contract formation • Article 32 CESL: Revocation of offer – 1. An offer may be revoked if the revocation reaches the offeree before the offeree has sent an acceptance or, in cases of acceptance by conduct, before the contract has been concluded CESL on timing of contract formation • § 63 Restatement (Second) of Contracts: Time When Acceptance Takes Effect – Unless the offer provides otherwise, • (a) an acceptance made in a manner and by a medium invited by an offer is operative and completes the manifestation of mutual assent as soon as put out of the offeree's possession, without regard to whether it ever reaches the offeror; but (b) an acceptance under an option contract is not operative until received by the offeror. § 66. Acceptance Must be Properly Dispatched – An acceptance sent by mail or otherwise from a distance is not operative when dispatched, unless it is properly addressed and such other precautions taken as are ordinarily observed to insure safe transmission of similar messages BGH oven clocks and battle of the forms • Facts: – Defendant orders time-switch clocks to install in electric ovens, referring the order to its own standard contract terms of purchase Standard terms contains a clause stipulating that if supplier accepts the order, consents to the standard terms, and that if supplier consents but based on divergent terms, those of defendant shall apply anyway, unless defendant agrees explicitly in writing If supplier does not accept this result, must say so explicitly in writing Standard terms will govern future transactions with supplier Standard terms do not contain a reservation of title on purchased but yet unpaid products – Plaintiff confirms – Defendant places additional order – Plaintiff confirms order referring to its terms and conditions, which include a reservation of title clause – Defendant files for bankruptcy – Plaintiff sues to recover unpaid clocks BGH oven clocks and battle of the forms • Issues: – Rules to solve battle of the forms – The value of preventive clauses in standard terms on how to solve battle of the forms – The role of tacit consent in battle of the form cases – The scope of application of default rules when there is a battle of forms • Outcome: – Appeals Court and BGH find for defendant • Grounds: – There is no tacit consent on the part of defendant, as the strong preventive language of the standard terms is not contradicted by later behavior – The point in which standard terms and conditions of both sides diverge will be resolved by the default rules, and they do not provide for a reservation of title BGH oven clocks and battle of the forms • Analysis: – Possible solutions to battle of forms: Mirror image rule: no contract exists as there is dissent over non obviously immaterial terms (art 19 CISG; traditional rule in Common Law: Ardente v. Horan) Last shot rule: the last set of terms sent without being objected by the other party prevails First shot rule: the first set of terms prevails if the second does not explicitly reject the first (Dutch Civil Code, art. 6:225.-3) Knock-out rule: Mutual destruction of conflicting terms and entry of default rules to fill the gap in need of a solution (§ 2207 UCC; Art. 2.122 Unidroit Principles; Art. 2:209 PECL; art. 39 CESL) The unilateral prevalence rule: Court makes overall assessment of standard term, and the set that is more favorable to the other side prevails – Is there a risk and cost free solution? BGH oven clocks and battle of the forms • Analysis: – Should one defer to meta terms on the value of terms and absolute rejection of terms of the other side (as in the German case, or PECL or CESL, or Unidroit principles? – Risk of arms’ race, as shown by the following: Upon learning that a prospective buyer wants to purchase, seller sends quotation inviting an order but specifically states that no agreement can be made until the parties sign a sales confirmation to be provided by the seller after the order details are specified The buyer specifies the details of its order If it does so by submitting a form purchase order with its own boilerplate terms, this will not be considered an acceptance and thus does not create an enforceable contract with conflicting terms→ whatever terms contained in the purchase order are inconsequential BGH oven clocks and battle of the forms • Analysis: – Risk of arms’ race Seller sends a sales confirmation to the buyer, detailing the order placed by the buyer and stating the seller's terms Confirmation contains an integration or merger clause stating that those terms govern the sale and supersede all prior terms that may have been discussed by the parties Buyer may counter-attack by using same strategy – Is conflict between terms the same as non-conformity of terms? – Should we try to harmonize the terms from both sides? CESL rules on battle of the forms • Article 39: Conflicting standard contract terms – 1. Where the parties have reached agreement except that the offer and acceptance refer to conflicting standard contract terms, a contract is nonetheless concluded. The standard contract terms are part of the contract to the extent that they are common in substance. – 2. Notwithstanding paragraph 1, no contract is concluded if one party: (a) has indicated in advance, explicitly, and not by way of standard contract terms, an intention not to be bound by a contract on the basis of paragraph 1; or (b) without undue delay, informs the other party of such an intention. Hill v. Gateway • Facts: – Plaintiffs make a phone order for a computer – Computer arrives in box containing also standard contract terms and conditions, including an arbitration clause Terms indicate that if buyers keep the product for 30 days, the standard terms will govern the contract – Plaintiffs use the computer for more than 30 days, and then sue for malfunctioning of components and other legal grounds – Defendant opposes suit asking enforcement of arbitration provision Hill v. Gateway • Issues: – Validity of “pay now, terms later” – Disclosure of standard terms, notice of their existence, and opportunity to read – Relevance of the content of the disputed clause? • Outcome: – District Court finds for plaintiffs, as contract is concluded when consumer pays, and terms not communicated at that time are unenforceable – Court of Appeals reverses Hill v. Gateway • Grounds: – Pro CD v. Zeidenberg applies even if in the former case buyer was not a consumer – Contract was in fact concluded when the Hills did not return computer within 30 days of delivery, and then they had had opportunity to read the terms – Standard terms not communicated in advance to buyers save significant transaction costs, and these savings benefit consumers as a group – Contract and payment preceding terms is common in many industries, like transportation – The arbitration clause is per se enforceable until Congress says otherwise Hill v. Gateway • Analysis: – Should the Law require sellers to have their standard terms easily available contracting? for prospective buyers before – Are transaction cost savings of not forcing “opportunity to read” on firms significant? If they are, what are the conditions for these cost reductions to benefit consumers? – Are all systems to agree to the standard terms comparable in terms of how buyers are likely to react? Prior availability Simultaneous availability Posterior availability coupled with time to return if buyer disagrees with terms Hill v. Gateway • Analysis: – Some reasons point towards the negative: Sequential specific investments in contracting→ further down the road in the contracting processes buyers have made more irrecoverable investments in contracting with a given seller Biases towards the existing alternative may be stronger at later times and when payment has been made: – Statu quo – Availability heuristic and real or imaginary lack of alternative suppliers – Sunk investments, return costs and loss-avoidance – Endowment effects – Framing – Learning may help buyers make the right choices, at any time in the contracting sequence, when transactions are repeated However, there are ways in which firms can interfere with buyer’s ability and incentives to obtain information, or learn from previous interactions Hill v. Gateway • Analysis: – Should the rules be the same in this regard for consumers and businesses? – If legal constraints are considered necessary, should they focus on contracting process or on content? – Are rules concerning how consent is expressed effective in improving overall welfare from transaction? – Are there ways in which firms may use Modes of agreeing to terms Substantive terms to distinguish between buyers of different types and screen them? – Are there advantages of using arbitration in consumer contracts? Any type of arbitration? CESL and Hill v. Gateway • Article 70: Duty to raise awareness of not individually negotiated contract terms – 1. Contract terms supplied by one party and not individually negotiated within the meaning of Article 7 may be invoked against the other party only if the other party was aware of them, or if the party supplying them took reasonable steps to draw the other party's attention to them, before or when the contract was concluded. – 2. For the purposes of this Article, in relations between a trader and a consumer contract terms are not sufficiently brought to the consumer's attention by a mere reference to them in a contract document, even if the consumer signs the document. – 3. The parties may not exclude the application of this Article or derogate from or vary its effects. CESL and Hill v. Gateway • Article 71 CESL: Additional payments in contracts between a trader and a consumer – 1. In a contract between a trader and a consumer, a contract term which obliges the consumer to make any payment in addition to the remuneration stated for the trader’s main contractual obligation, in particular where it has been incorporated by the use of default options which the consumer is required to reject in order to avoid the additional payment, is not binding on the consumer unless, before the consumer is bound by the contract, the consumer has expressly consented to the additional payment. If the consumer has made the additional payment, the consumer may recover it – 2. The parties may not, to the detriment of the consumer, exclude the application of this Article or derogate from or vary its effects CESL and Hill v. Gateway • Article 84 CESL :Contract terms which are always unfair (d) exclude or hinder the consumer's right to take legal action or exercise any other legal remedy, particularly by requiring the consumer to take disputes exclusively to an arbitration system not foreseen generally in legal provisions that apply to contracts between a trader and a consumer; ECJ- Caja de Ahorros v. Ausbanc • Facts: – Defendant savings bank includes in its standard terms for mortgage loans with variable interest rate (typically, a baseline rate + an additional rate, 1%, 1.5%, 2%) a clause “rounding up” the rate to the next (higher) quarter of percentage point: e.g. if the resulting rate, given the baseline rate (EURIBOR, as the most common) for the next period is 3,66, the interest rate would be rounded up to 3, 75 – A Consumer Organization sued to declare the term unfair, under national legislation implementing Directive 93/13 – After winning on first instance and appeal, the Spanish Supreme Court refers questions to the ECJ for preliminary ruling ECJ- Caja de Ahorros v. Ausbanc • Issues: – Terms affecting the main subject matter of the transaction (price, quality of goods, and the price/quality trade-off) may be considered unfair under EU Law even if clauses are clear and intelligible to consumers? – What terms should be considered as affecting the main subject matter or the basic contractual trade-off? • Outcome: – The ECJ answers that EU Law does not preclude national Law of MS to subject terms affecting main elements to unfairness test, even if they are drafted intelligibly • Grounds – Directive is minimum harmonization, and the exclusion of main subject matter from Directive’s scope is not binding upon MS, who may protect consumers to a larger degree ECJ- Caja de Ahorros v. Ausbanc • Analysis: – Are the main elements of the transaction typically salient to consumers? Is adverse selection likely to be an acute problem with respect to them? – If main elements subject to fairness controls, do we replace market by courts in defining terms of trade? – Can there be non-salient terms affecting price or quality? – What is considered the main subject matter uniform across contract types and other circumstances? – Are all terms equal and should they be treated equally in terms of fairness or unfairness? Are they not all part of the “product package”? ProCD v. Zeidenberg • Facts: – Pro CD sells a database containing many telephone – – – – – directories in CD-ROM format The product comes in two versions, one for commercial users at a high price, other for personal use at a low price The license for personal use version forbids commercial use of database License is not communicated beforehand to prospective buyers, it is enclosed in the box with the discs. The box shows language indicating that the product comes with restrictions formulated in the enclosed license Defendant buys the consumer package but resells the information on database on a commercial basis Pro CD seeks an injunction against defendant ProCD v. Zeidenberg • Issues: – Enforceability of shrinkwrap licenses – Which standard terms drafted by seller will be binding on buyers – Extent of proper Government’s and Law’s interference with the terms through which firms do business, and the form in which those terms are communicated to buyers • Outcome: – District Court considers the restrictive license ineffectual and finds for defendant – Court of Appeals reverses ProCD v. Zeidenberg • Grounds: – The intention of Pro CD was to price discriminate between – – – – – business and consumer segment Price discrimination is desirable for both segments in these circumstances The separate license is important (though not crucial, for instance delaying the product for consumers was also possible) for such purposes The contract is not necessarily formed at time of payment, but at the time of using product without objecting to the terms enclosed in the box Informing beforehand of content of terms is not necessary for many contracts to be properly agreed, and to require it would be counterproductive UCC and Copyright Act do not affect the outcome ProCD v. Zeidenberg • Analysis: – Empirical evidence about “Pay now, terms later” contracts – Is the opportunity to read valuable for consumers? – Does it make sense to draw attention of consumers by Requirements of conspicuousness Requirements of separate signature of standard terms or some of them – Are terms inseparable from the good or service itself? Are contract terms part of the product? – Are reputational controls and market forces going to solve all problems in this setting? ECJ- Freiburger Kommunalbauten • Facts: – Plaintiff, a local council firm, sells to defendants a parking – – – – – space in a new multi-storey car park to be built by plaintiff A standard term in the contract determined that full price was payable upon receipt of a bank guarantee issued to the plaintiff in order to secure return of money or other claims by defendants against plaintiff Defendants refused to pay until the parking space was delivered and they took possession of it Plaintiff sued claiming interest on the price for the period between the time price was due according to standard terms and the time at which payment was actually made LG upholds plaintiff’s claim BGH refers the question to ECJ for a preliminary ruling ECJ- Freiburger Kommunalbauten • Issues: – The substantive unfairness test for standard contract terms and conditions: what is unjustified imbalance between rights and obligations, and the factors bearing upon it – How local or national the meaning of unfairness is • Outcome: – ECJ fails to respond • Grounds: – The particular circumstances of the contract and the case are decisive for an answer, and thus ECJ cannot answer in abstract terms – Distinguish form Oceano and Salvat Cases (C-240/98 and C-244/98) where the clause was unfair regardless of the type of contract and the circumstances CESL on general unfairness test • Article 83: Meaning of "unfair" in contracts between a trader and a consumer – 1. In a contract between a trader and a consumer, a contract term supplied by the trader which has not been individually negotiated within the meaning of Article 7 is unfair for the purposes of this Section if it causes a significant imbalance in the parties‘ rights and obligations arising under the contract, to the detriment of the consumer, contrary to good faith and fair dealing. – 2. When assessing the unfairness of a contract term for the purposes of this Section, regard is to be had to: CESL on general unfairness test – (a) whether the trader complied with the duty of transparency set out in Article 82; – (b) the nature of what is to be provided under the contract; – (c) the circumstances prevailing during the conclusion of the contract; – (d) to the other contract terms; and – (e) to the terms of any other contract on which the contract depends. ECJ- Freiburger Kommunalbauten • Analysis: – What is an imbalance between rights and obligations? What is the measure of balance? – How relevant default rules are for determining whether a standard term that departs from them may be unfair? – What factors to use to consider an imbalance justified? Only internal to the contract? Market practice? Terms that are to be expected (consumers’ expectation test)? A weaker form of consumer expectation test, the “surprise” term? Relative knowledge of the parties? – Is it desirable to have common unfairness standards across legal systems? How is it going to affect B2C crossborder trade? – Are black and grey lists helpful? Do they increase legal certainty? Williams v. Walker-Thomas Furniture • Facts: – Plaintiff operates a furniture store in DC – Plaintiff sells furniture and home appliances on credit to low-income families – Each purchase contract on credit is accompanied by a printed form, containing provisions to the effect: Title will remain with plaintiff until all monthly payments adding to the total stated value set in the form have been made to seller In case of default of any monthly payment, plaintiff could repossess the good Monthly payments were not credited to individual goods purchased, but pro-rata to all goods purchased on credit, implying that until all payments had been made, all goods remained under the plaintiff’s title – Defendants bought several items in the spring of 1962 and shortly thereafter they stopped paying the monthly installments – Plaintiff seeks to repossess all items sold on credit to defendants since December 1957 Williams v. Walker-Thomas Furniture • Issues: – The existence and basis of an unconscionability doctrine that would strike down unfair contract terms – The factors to take into account for making the fairness assessment of terms – The grounds and effects of such doctrine • Outcome: – The DC Court, though condemning in strong words plaintiff’s credit-giving behavior, found for the plaintiff – US Court of Appeals finds that the terms giving support to claim may be unconscionable – A vocal and strong dissenting opinion Williams v. Walker-Thomas Furniture • Grounds: – Unconscionable contract terms are not enforceable – UCC, although not directly applicable to the dispute, shows that the Law is clear in mandating courts not to enforce unconscionable terms – Circumstances of the case show that it is indeed possible that terms are so unfair as to deserve being non-binding Williams v. Walker-Thomas Furniture • Analysis: – Unconscionability test Lack of choice Terms unreasonably favorable to drafter – Court says that the cross-collateralization clause was – – – – “hidden in a maze of fine print”. Would it have been different if Plaintiff had explained the clause to defendants? Is the US test similar or identical to the EU test, as shown in Directive 93/13 or in CESL? Should disclosure be relevant for unfairness test? Should procedural unconscionability be a self-standing notion? What are the likely effects of unfairness control in these cases? Would it make credit more difficult for low-income families? Is this good or bad? How would you think a complete contract allocate risks of events lowering income? Williams v. Walker-Thomas Furniture • Analysis: – Augmented reality (our smart phones providing information at the time we are about to enter into the contract) should it affect how we apply the test for unconscionability? – A consumer who has accessed online consumer reports and rankings may claim that terms are unconscionable? – What is the role of behavioral biases? Does it support the doctrine or show its ineffectiveness since debiasing is very hard to happen? Signalling and screening through contract terms • • • If you remember the adverse selection problem – Individuals have hidden characteristics and a selection process results in a pool of individuals with characteristics unwanted by the other party to the interaction Signaling is an attempt by an informed party to send an observable indicator of his or her hidden characteristics to the other party in the transaction who is initially uninformed party To produce effect, the signal by one type of party must not be easily mimicked by the other types –less desirable in the eyes of the uninformed party – Example: costly education in employment contract; long hours in the office in the employment contract; large liquidated damages; harsh covenant terms in debt contract; extensive warranties in sales contracts Signalling and screening through contract terms • Screening is the attempt by an uninformed party to sort individuals according to their characteristics. Screening occurs when the uniformed party adopts a mechanism to elicit the information from the informed party • Often accomplished through a self-selection device – A mechanism in which informed parties are presented with a set of options, and the options they choose reveals their hidden characteristics to an uninformed party – Examples: leg room in plane seats (coach vs. business class); price discrimination in restaurants and Cable TV; limited warranties tied to lower prices; different terms linked to different prices or interest rates CESL on prohibited standard terms • Article 84:Contract terms which are always unfair – A contract term is always unfair for the purposes of this Section if its object or effect is to: (a) exclude or limit the liability of the trader for death or personal injury caused to the consumer through an act or omission of the trader or of someone acting on behalf of the trader; (b) exclude or limit the liability of the trader for any loss or damage to the consumer caused deliberately or as a result of gross negligence; (c) limit the trader's obligation to be bound by commitments undertaken by its authorised agents or make its commitments subject to compliance with a particular condition the fulfilment of which depends exclusively on the trader; CESL on prohibited standard terms • Article 84:Contract terms which are always unfair (d) exclude or hinder the consumer's right to take legal action or exercise any other legal remedy, particularly by requiring the consumer to take disputes exclusively to an arbitration system not foreseen generally in legal provisions that apply to contracts between a trader and a consumer; (e) confer exclusive jurisdiction for all disputes arising under the contract to a court for the place where the trader is domiciled unless the chosen court is also the court for the place where the consumer is domiciled; (f) give the trader the exclusive right to determine whether the goods, digital content or related services supplied are in conformity with the contract or gives the trader the exclusive right to interpret any contract term; (g) provide that the consumer is bound by the contract when the trader is not; CESL on prohibited standard terms • Article 84:Contract terms which are always unfair • (h) require the consumer to use a more formal method for terminating the contract within the meaning of Article 8 than was used for conclusion of the contract; • (i) grant the trader a shorter notice period to terminate the contract than the one required of the consumer; • (j) oblige the consumer to pay for goods, digital content or related services not actually delivered, supplied or rendered; • (k) determine that non-individually negotiated contract terms within the meaning of Article 7 prevail or have preference over contract terms which have been individually negotiated.