PROPOGATING COMPETITION POLICY IN MALAYSIA: A ROUGH TERRAIN TO REALIZATION Anuar Ariffin, Ph. D 1 Introduction Competition policy, an instrument used to address market failures and to curb the market power of businesses, has only been introduced in Malaysia very recently. Although the idea to have a law aimed at encouraging competition in all sectors of the economy was first floated in the middle of 1990s, its realization takes longer time than it should have been due various factors. This paper examines the process and circumstances facing Malaysia in coming up with a competition policy. The Virtue of a Competition Policy: A Debate In Malaysia two perennial questions exist when someone talks about a competition policy. Does Malaysia really need a competition policy? Is a competition policy really beneficial to our businesses and economy? Two different groups give opposing views on these questions. The first group, a more dominant and at the forefront in championing the thinking of mercantilist-nationalists, argues that a competition policy brings more harm than good. This group claims that being a small open economy Malaysia needs an environment of a closed relationship not only between the government and businesses but also among businesses themselves. The existence of this environment would bring various benefits, initially to businesses and later to the economy as a whole. When businesses act together cooperatively they can strengthen themselves not only from the perspective that they are able to face challenges of turbulence economic environment but also by reining in cut-throat competition. Under a cooperative environment businesses would be able enjoy greater profits. Overtime, profit accumulation allows businesses to grow bigger in terms of size, capital and turnover. In the end the economy at large will benefit. Also, the existence of cooperative environment allows businesses to share various resources in trying to expand their present in overseas markets through increasing exports of domestic operations and exploring opportunities for potential investments. On the other hand, competition between businesses will make everybody worse1 Dr. Anuar Ariffin is currently the Head of Program, Economics and Business Management, Malaysian Institute of Public Administration, Malaysia. 1 off. Normal competition will at the very least push down profits of individual companies; cutthroat competition will force some companies to go under. Meanwhile, arguing from a different perspective, a second group – mainly economists and public officials from the Ministry of Domestic Trade and Consumer Affairs – claims that competition among businesses is not only beneficial but necessary. The benefits of competition to an economy can be viewed from various angles. First, competition will force businesses to continuously improve their products and productivity. For some businesses this is important in order to be ahead of their competitors. For others this may be necessary just to remain in business. Second, competition will force companies to innovate or even invent new system and technology. By doing this businesses can continuously produce better products at cheaper prices. Third, competition among businesses will generate enormous benefits to the people and the economy at large. These benefits not only come in the form of customers being able to enjoy more variety of goods and services but they are available at cheaper prices. To that end, each individual would be able to increase their utility by consuming more goods (and services) with the same amount of money. The thinking of mercantilist-nationalists is very dominant in Malaysia. The arguments of this group have always got the friendly ears of politicians and policy makers. Meanwhile, the thinking and arguments of the other group are seldom being bought, neither by the elite group of politicians and policy makers nor by a vast majority of ordinary people. Misconception and Misunderstanding about Competition Policy In Malaysia a majority of policy makers and political leadership view competition policy with suspicion since it has a direct impact not only on businesses but also on how policies, rules and regulations about behaviours of businesses are designed. In many circumstances monopolists and oligopolies are created by specific government policies. This is so because it is a dominant thinking among them that Government should have a big say and influence over country’s business and economic activities. As a result many economic sectors are highly policy-driven, to the extent that the number of players, outputs and pricing are determined by the Government. Not a long time ago, the number of sectors, identified as policy-drive, is huge. Of late however, the Government has pursued liberalization with greater vigour resulting in reduced number of policy-driven sectors and forces of markets are allowed to rule. Still sectors such as electricity (both generation and distribution), 2 telecommunications, iron and steel, automotive, as well as stapled food including rice, flour, sugar and cooking oil continued to be under heavy regulations. Initial Conception and Initiatives to Introduce Competition Policy in Malaysia The initial idea, in which Malaysia should have a specific and well documented competition policy, primarily emerged during the negotiations of the GATT’s Uruguay Round (UR). Discussions during the UR negotiations concern more with specific cases where domestic anti-competitive practices restrict trade between contracting parties. The WTO Agreements, signed by member states in 1994 following the conclusion of the UR negotiations, have implicitly embedded competition policy concerns in several provisions of the agreements. These include in the original General Agreement on Tariff and Trade (GATT) articles such as Article II, III, XI and some General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) articles and Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Right (TRIPS). Discussions and work programs concerning relationship between competition policy and its impact on trade continued under the auspicious of the WTO. A formal and more structured effort within the WTO began when members agreed to launch the Working Group on the Interaction between Trade and Competition Policy (WGTCP) at the WTO Ministerial Conference in Singapore in 1996. Again at the 2001 WTO Ministerial Conference in Doha, Qatar, members put the competition question on the agenda, and defined a focus of future work for the WGTCP in paragraph 25 of the Doha Ministerial Declaration. “In the period until the Fifth Session, further work in the Working Group on the Interaction between Trade and Competition Policy will focus on the clarification of: core principles, including transparency, non-discrimination and procedural fairness; provisions on hardcore cartels; modalities for voluntary cooperation; and support for progressive reinforcement of competition institutions in developing countries through capacity building. Full account shall be taken of the needs of developing and leastdeveloped country participants and appropriate flexibility provided to address them”.2 Lights at the End of the Tunnel 2 At the subsequent WTO meetings, however, members failed to reach a consensus on the content of possible rules, mostly due to the objections of developing countries. Consequently as the September 2003 Cancun Ministerial Conference ended in deadlock, the General Council of the WTO dropped competition policy from the Doha agenda in 2004. 3 The subject of competition policy came to the forefront of policy debate and discussions in Malaysia only at the end of 1900s thanks to a small group of policy makers and economists who continued to propagate the imperative of having it and tried to push this issue into the national agenda. Efforts and initiatives to push the discussion on the need to have a competition policy to the forefront continued to gain strength toward the middle of 2000s. The Ministry of Domestic Trade and Consumer Affairs continued to engage other ministries and government agencies which have a clout over policies of specific economic sectors and industries. These include Ministry of International Trade and Industry, Ministry of Primary Industry, Ministry of Agriculture, Ministry of Finance as well as central agencies involved in economic planning. At the same time consultations were also held with trade and industry associations and captains of businesses. The consultations were done with two objectives in mind: educating relevant parties on the imperative of having a competition policy and on the best approach that Malaysia should take to introduce one. The engagement and consultations are unavoidably time-consuming as many policy makers, captains of industries and organizations representing businesses are sceptical about the virtue of having a competition policy. These sceptics are not only a reflection of misunderstanding and misconception about the policy but also a representation of an effort by beneficiaries of the prevailing policies to protect their business interests from greater competition. Only towards the end of 2000s, after more than a decade of struggles and perseverance, that a competition policy was table to the Malaysian Cabinet for a decision. Finally, after the Cabinet had agreed a bill on competition policy was sent and subsequently approved by the Parliament in 2010 under the name of Malaysian Competition Act 2011. The Components of Malaysia’s Competition Act Malaysia’s Competition Act is enacted with the purposes to encourage economic efficiency, innovation and entrepreneurship. The Act prohibits horizontal and vertical arrangements between enterprises. With this provision businesses are prohibited to have an agreement between them with the intention to (1) fix a purchase or selling prices (directly or indirectly) (2) share market or sources of supply (3) limit or control production, market outlets, market access, technical or technological development (4) bid rigging and (5) having the object of significantly preventing, restricting or disturbing competition in any markets for 4 goods or services. In addition, the Act also prohibits enterprises from engaging in any conduct which amounts to an abuse of a dominant position in any market for good or services. Among the conducts which can be deemed as abusing a dominant power include (1) imposing unfair purchase or selling price or other unfair trading condition on any supplier or customer (2) refusing to supply to a particular enterprise (3) applying different conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading partners (4) imposing unfair condition in any contract (5) resorting to predatory behaviour towards competitors (6) buying up a scare supply of intermediate goods or services required by a competitor. The Act also entrusts the Malaysia’s Competition Commission (MyCC) with powers necessary to implement the law. One of the powers provided is for MyCC to investigate cases suspected to infringe any provisions of the law, either based on a complaint by other parties or an initiative undertaken by the Commission itself. Others include a power requiring suspects to provide relevant information, access to records, access to computerised data as well as a power to search and seizure. Although the commission is empowered to start an investigation but the power to prosecute rests with the office of Attorney General (AG). What this means is that when MyCC completes its investigation a recommendation paper needs to be prepared for the consideration of the AG whether to prosecute or otherwise. Reflecting a long process of engagement and consultations with various parties, the Act provides a window of opportunity for enterprises to apply to the Commission for an exemption and relief of liability for the infringement of the provisions of the Act provided they can satisfy the following conditions: (i) There are significant identifiable technological, efficiency or social benefits directly arising from the agreement; (ii) The benefit could not reasonably have been provided by the parties to the agreement without the agreement having the effect of preventing, restricting or distorting competition; (iii) The detrimental effect of the agreement on competition is proportionate to the benefits provided; and 5 (iv) The agreement does not allow the enterprise concerned to eliminate competition completely in respect of a substantial part of the goods or services. In addition, the Act also provides a special exemption to enterprises established and operated under the Communications and Multimedia Act and Energy Commission Act.3 It should be noted that the Act specifically says that its provisions apply only to agreements between enterprises. On the surface of it the Act applies only to official undertakings between enterprises whereas unofficial anti-competitive actions and behaviours seem to be beyond the coverage of the Act. In a way this reflects a leniency of the Act in comparison to other established competition laws.4 Costs and Benefits of Malaysia’s Competition Act The costs relating to having a competition law are primarily in terms of expenditure in which the Government has to fork out to ensure a smooth implementation and enforcement of the Act. These include expenditure for the operation of MyCC, the agency established to implement the competition law. In addition the Government needs also to beef up prosecution officials at the AG’s office. It is estimated that for these purposes the Government needs to spend RM200 million for the first 3 years from the date the Act comes into effect, which begins this year (2012). Considering the important of the Act to the Malaysian economy it could be argued that it is worth the money for tax payers to bear since the biggest beneficiaries of the Act are the people at large. Benefits It should be admitted that it is much more difficult to estimate direct benefits of the Competition Act, especially in terms of nominal monetary values in comparison to estimating the costs. From the perspective of economics, it is for sure that the Act brings enormous benefits. These benefits come in three different forms: (1) increase economic efficiency (2) 3 This specific exemption is provided in First Schedule of the Act, and the Minister of Domestic Trade and Consumer Affairs can amend the First Schedule by an order published in the Government’s Gazette. 4 The US antitrust law for example has three broad classes of activities which are unlawful: (1) Collusive behaviours such as attempts by oligopolies to fix prices or form cartels; (2) Mergers that reduce competition and raise industrial concentration to unacceptably high levels; and (3) Monopolization of an industry by a dominant firm. 6 address problems associated with market failures and (3) curb the market power of businesses. Increase Economic Efficiency For an economy to be efficient it needs to achieve two conditions: productive efficiency and allocative efficiency. Productive efficiency has two aspects, one concerning production within each firm and the other concerning the allocation of production among firms in an industry. Productive efficiency for the firm requires that the firm produce any given level of outputs at the lowest possible cost. Productive efficiency requires that the firm uses the least costly of the available methods of production. Meanwhile, productive efficiency for the industry requires that the industry’s total output be allocated among its individual firms in such a way that the total cost in the industry is the lowest (minimized). If an industry is yet to be productively efficient, it is possible to reduce the industry’s total cost of producing any given output by reallocating production among the industry’s firms. Therefore, productive efficiency for the industry requires that the marginal cost of production must be the same for all firms. Allocative effiency, meanwhile, concerns with quantities of the various products to be produced. An industry is allocatively efficient when, for each good produced, its marginal cost of production is equal to its price. Therefore, market is at the most efficient when both productive efficiency and allocative efficiency are attained. The only market structure that satisfies these two conditions is perfect competition, in which each firm produces outputs at the lowest point on its long-run average cost curve.5 At this point its cost is minimized. However it is to be noted that perfect competition exists only in few industries in modern economics. A vast majority of other industries operate under market structures characterised either by monopolistic competition, oligopoly or monopoly and economic efficiency could not be attained under these three market structures. Because most industries operate in imperfect markets a competition policy is thus needed to provide the Government with a mechanism to try to increase overall economic efficiency. 5 Perfect Competition is characterised by 4 main elements, (1) firms sell identical products (2) Consumers know the nature of products being sold and the prices being charged by each firm (3) Firms are small in comparison to industry and they are price takers (4) The industry is characterised by freedom of entry and exit. 7 Address Problems Associated with Market Failures An ideal market structure for an economy is perfect competition. 6 In perfect competition the market is the most efficient, therefore there is no market failure. Whenever there is a market failure, the market is considered inefficient. A market failure exists when industries operate in market structures other the perfect competition. A market failure also reflects the situation where firms in an industry set a selling price higher than its marginal cost, thereby enjoying abnormal profits. Of the four market structures discussed in the previous section, the highest degree of failure (or imperfectness) is monopoly, the second highest is oligopoly and the least is monopolistic competition. The whole idea of having a competition policy is for the government to address this problem by devising policy in trying to influence markets to move toward perfect competition, achieving if possible, the characteristic of monopolistic competition. If perfect competition is impossible to attain then monopolistic competition should be the next target. Curb the Market Power of Oligopolies Many businesses operate in oligopolistic industry, whereby only a few enterprises exist. This gives them a market power in terms of having the ability to set price rather than a price taker, as it is the case for firms operating in perfectly competitive markets. A firm has a market power in the sense that it faces a negatively sloped demand curve, thus its marginal revenue will be less than its price. When it equates marginal cost to marginal revenue, as all profit maximizing firms do, marginal cost will be less than price. This inequality implies allocative inefficiency. Competition policy has sought to create more competitive market structures wherever possible, to discourage monopolistic practices, and to encourage competitive behaviour where competitive market structures cannot be established. By having a competition policy the government can devise laws and regulations to deal with uncompetitive behaviours of oligopolies thereby curbing their market powers. Challenges in Implementing Competition Law in Malaysia The Malaysia’s Competition Act, which was passed by the Parliament in 2010, comes into effect only this year. A substantial time is provided for the Act to take effect may be 6 It is important to re-emphasis that perfect competition is a theoretical ideal that exists in a small number of industries, is at best only approximated in some industries, and is not even closely resembled in most. 8 argued to represent two things. One is to allow businesses to have a good understanding about the provisions of the Act and to come to terms with those provisions. The other is to ensure proper preparation can be made on the part of the Government to implement and enforce the law. These include the setting up of the MyCC, training its staff and coming up with detail guidelines and procedures in relation to conducting its investigation. At the outset two major challenges could be foreseen for MyCC to implement and enforce the Act. The first challenge is to deal with the lobbying power of policy-created monopolies and oligopolies. In Malaysia it is still a dominant idea that the bigger and stronger a business is the better for the country. This idea does not only exist in the minds of captains of businesses, but also in the minds of vast majority of public officials and policy makers. It is also a kind of thinking among them that they know inside-out of a particular industry. These include the situation of demand and supply for a particular product, therefore it is imperative for them to determine how many players should be in that particular industry. In addition, it is a common sense argument among these people that too much competition is not good for the country, especially if there are cases of businesses that do not survive and have to wind up. Whereas it is a standard argument among economists that a competitive market resembling perfect competition should be represented by an active role of market participants. This includes not only the entry of new players into the industry but also the exit of existing players from the industry, some of them unavoidably due to stiff competition. Supplementing this thinking is the lobbying power of businesses themselves. More often than not captains of businesses have a closed connection with top echelon of Malaysian leadership. It is reasonable to expect that when a particular business or industry runs into problem in terms of infringement with any provisions of the Act they would lobby leadership at the very top for exemption or special treatment to the extent that it warrants an amendment to the Act. The second challenge comes in terms of establishing a prima facie case on suspects by investigating officers from MyCC. As this agency is still at the infancy stage it is natural to expect that it needs a lot of training and capacity building programs for its staff. As we learn from antitrust cases in other countries establishing a case against businesses infringing provisions of competition laws is not an easy task and require special skills, expertise and experience. 9 The third challenge is in relation to the adequateness of the Act to deal with anticompetitive behaviours of businesses. In the present form the Act specifically targets infringements of its provisions contained in official agreements between enterprises. Again as we learn from countries with lots of experience in dealing with the market power of oligopolies and anticompetitive behaviours of businesses many of them are done unofficially, not through official agreements. To have a full benefit from having a competition policy a broad class of activities which may result in anticompetitive behaviours need to be taken into account, possibly on a gradual basis. These include the formation of cartels, collusive behaviour in whatever forms, mergers which result in reduced competition and predatory pricing. However, at the moment, the step by step approach undertaken by MyCC in dealing with multiple issues surrounding competition policy may be appropriate given the circumstance that Malaysia has faced. Conclusion Malaysia has taken close to two decades before it can finally introduce a competition policy. This reflects difficulties faced by proponents, mainly officials at Ministry of Domestic Trade and Consumer Affairs, to convince not only leadership at the very top but also captains of businesses about the virtue of having this policy for the country. The Competition Act, which was approved by the Parliament in 2010 will only come into effect two years later, beginning in 2012. The enforcement of this Act will not only bring benefit to ordinary people but will also improve economic efficiency of the economy. 10 References Fox, Eleanor M. 2003. International Antitrust and the Doha Dome. Virginia Journal of International Law 911. Government of Malaysia. Competition Act 2010. Accessed at www.mycc.gov.my/web/home on 2 February 2012. Graham, Edward M., and J. David Richardson, eds. 1997. Global Competition Policy. Washington. Institute for International Economics Hoekman, Bernard, and Kamal Saggi. 2004. International Cooperation on Domestic Policies: Lessons from the WTO Competition Policy Debate. Discussion Paper No. 4693. Centre for Economic Policy Research. Jackson, John. 2006. Sovereignty, the WTO, and Changing Fundamentals of International Law. New York. Cambridge University Press. Taylor, Martyn D. 2006. International Competition Law: A New Dimension for the WTO. New York. Cambridge University Press. World Trade Organization. 1994. The Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations: The Legal Texts. 11