A Submission on “Improving Australia’s Law and Justice Framework – A Discussion Paper to explore the scope of reforming Australian Contract Law” Martin Doris∗ Introduction 1. In Improving Australia’s Law and Justice Framework – a discussion paper to explore the scope for reforming Australian contract law,1 the AttorneyGeneral’s Department has neatly summarised and briefly addressed many of the perceived difficulties facing consumers and businesses when contracting both domestically and cross border, including in online markets. The Government takes the view that as the economy emerges from the global financial crisis it is an opportune moment to reflect on ways to reduce transaction costs for business, bolster consumer confidence and generally enhance the international standing of domestic contract laws. It is therefore seeking the views of stakeholders on the merits of action, legislative or otherwise, and on the possible costs and benefits of ‘internationalising’ the law. The Attorney-General’s Department is particularly keen to receive data on the primary problems experienced by users of contract law in practice. Advice is also sought on how best to tackle any identified problem areas. 2. This emphasis on the need to identify specific problems experienced by stakeholders is reassuring and empirical data ought reasonably to guide the reform process going forward. That said, the discussion paper does highlight concerns with the wider accessibility and overall coherence of the law and this may in time prompt a more emboldened law reform strategy. 3. At the outset it is therefore important to stress that complexity is a feature of all modern private laws systems, and many of the difficulties encountered in practice typically arise at the intersection between contract, tort and property law. As European regulators discovered early on in seeking to promote ‘coherence’ in the field of contract law in the European Union, it is difficult to engage with ambiguities and inconsistencies in the law of contract without trespassing into other core sub-fields of private law. It is precisely in these areas of intersection where neat classifications, and the black letter rules that are to be found in textbooks on contract law, grate with the law-in-action. This is, of course, not a legitimate reason for the Government not to intervene in improving areas of private law, including with the laudable goal of making specific provisions and/or the law generally more accessible and user-friendly, however the Attorney-General’s Department appears to be particularly concerned that the law is at times to be found in ‘unexpected places’. The Assistant Professor, Faculty of Law, Chinese University of Hong Kong. ‘Improving Australia’s Law and Justice Framework – a discussion paper to explore the scope for reforming Australian contract law’, March 22, 2012. Currently accessible at: http://www.ag.gov.au/Consultationsreformsandreviews/Pages/Review-of-Australian-ContractLaw.aspx (last visited, 6 June 2012). ∗ 1 1 consultation paper argues that this could make the discovery of contract rules more onerous for ‘non-experts’, and cites the rules governing the assignment of contractual rights as an example. 2 The Government, for example, discusses the fact that these rules may be set out either in a ‘Property Law Act, a Conveyancing Act or equivalent’ depending upon the individual State or Territory concerned, and that as a result ‘it may be difficult for non-experts to find all the statutory rules relevant to their case’.3 Yet short of blanket uniformity through a single nationwide statute it is difficult to perceive how to remove such divergences. Moreover, before contemplating any action in order to resolve what would appear to be stylistic variations it would be appropriate to assess just how frequently ‘non-experts’ in the law do in practice seek to access such rules. Equally, and perhaps most crucially, although these contractual provisions are contained in legislation with differing titles, it is unclear from the Government’s consultation paper whether in practice there are any significant differences in the content of the contract rules themselves. 4. This is perhaps one useful illustration that many of the perceived difficulties that seemingly arise through the operation of the domestic law of contract may in fact prove more theoretical than actual. However, the Government is similarly concerned that the courts all too readily resort to equitable principles when resolving contractual disputes and/or fall back on general clauses such as good faith. In the view of the Attorney-General’s Department, if a matter is subject to litigation, parties are as a result, ‘often unlikely to be able to predict the outcome [of a dispute arising] under contract’.4 Moreover, a general ‘lack of clarity in several areas’, it is suggested, ‘may mean that businesses and other organisations are left to engage in a substantial amount of guesswork’.5 Unfortunately these ‘several areas’ are not adequately identified in the Government’s discussion paper. 5. Nonetheless, there can be few who would disagree that many features of the general law of contract could be better articulated and that the continued development of the law of contract through the courts does to an extent reduce its accessibility for users, particularly for overseas traders who may be dissuaded from offering goods and services to domestic consumers and/or from pursuing commercial opportunities with Australian businesses as a consequence. Indeed, foreign traders may currently be reluctant to seek legal advice on their rights and liabilities under domestic contract laws and may in practice judge that the search costs involved simply outweigh the benefits. In like measure, domestic consumers do often experience difficulties in determining their legal rights, particularly in areas of the law that are typically neglected by governments and regulators. Residential tenancy contracts, for example, and the law of tenancy generally rarely receive much political consideration by legislators despite the significant impact of the law on 2 Ibid at para. 3.6. Ibid. 4 The impact of equitable principles is referenced in the discussion paper as a general concern. The Attorney-General’s Department also observes that, “the interrelationship between common law rules, equitable doctrines and statute means that it is difficult to draw boundary lines around contract law”, n 1 above, at para. 3.4. 5 See Introductory comment on ‘Challenges for Australian Contracting’, n 1 above, at section 3. 3 2 citizens in their day-to-day life, and the coherence and/or accessibility of the law is rarely a political concern. At an early stage in the European coherence initiative, tenancy contracts were judged to be beyond the scope of the Commission’s reform agenda, given its focus on the proper functioning of the Union’s internal market.6 However, residential tenants do frequently experience difficulties both in understanding their legal rights and in determining how best to resolve disputes in practice.7 Much more could doubtless be done therefore to educate tenants, consumers and small traders on how best to seek practical remedies in the event of specific contractual disputes. For consumers and small traders there would appear to be a particular knowledge-deficit when faced with a legal dispute involving a trader based outside Australia.8 However, the accessibility of the general law of contract is of only limited practical benefit for individual consumers, particularly for those with no legal training. 6. Indeed, as this author has argued previously, the general coherence of the law of contract can be overly prized.9 This is particularly the case in relation to commercial contract law and the English law of contract, for example, is not renowned for its ready accessibility. In the modern digital age there is, for instance, no downloadable app providing users with a ready template of English contract laws. Nor are national contract laws as readily accessible as existing soft law instruments such as the Principles of European Contract Law (PECL) and the UNIDROIT Principles of International Commercial Contracts (UPICC) and yet both soft law instruments have failed to supplant the dominant position of English and New York laws in international trade.10 6 See however C. Schmid et al, ‘Tenancy Law and Procedure in the European Union’, Electronic Publications of the EUI European Private Law Forum (Florence). Currently accessible at: http://www.eui.eu/DepartmentsAndCentres/Law/ResearchAndTeaching/ResearchThemes/Project TenancyLaw.aspx (last visited, 6 June 2012). 7 Moreover, in addition to the general legal complexity involved, aggrieved parties in certain cases have no option but to seek to resolve disputes before the courts. See, for example: http://www.lawfoundation.net.au/report/older/FCC649FB42881BD6CA257081001ED439.html (last visited, 6 June 2012). 8 The Competition and Consumer Council has to date played a key role in advertising the rights of consumers and highlighting in particular the contractual remedies available to consumers. See, for example: http://www.accc.gov.au/content/index.phtml/tag/ConsumerRightsAndShopping/ (last visited, 5 June 2012). 9 See, generally, M. Doris, Dispute Avoidance and European Contract Law (Europa Law Publishing, 2008). 10 O. Lando and H. Beale (eds), Principles of European Contract Law, Parts I and II (Kluwer, 1999) and O. Lando et al, Principles of European Contract Law, Part III (Kluwer, 2003). Parts I and II of the PECL provide annotated rules on a range of general contract law issues including the formation, interpretation and performance of contracts, and remedies for non-performance. The later Part III was published in 2003, and similar to the DCFR, covers broader issues such as assignment, plurality of debtors and creditors, set-off, prescription, etc. The twin volume UNIDROIT Principles of International Commercial Contracts (1994, 2010) were prepared under the auspices of the International Institute for the Unification of Private Law in Rome. For a recent discussion of the limited impact of the UPICC in the UK in particular, see S. Lake, ‘An Empirical Study of the UNIDROIT Principles – International and British Responses’ (2011) 16(3) Unif L Rev 669. (Lake highlights a strong opposition among members of the Bar in London toward the UPICC, and cites one commercial barrister who observed that it would be “an important professional fault to advise a party to use the [UNIDROIT Principles]”, at 689. Of course, Australian contract law has already departed from the English law in a number of substantive areas 3 7. The consultation paper identifies the English law of contract as the law of choice in international commercial contracts.11 Despite the high cost of litigation, various factors help to explain why parties to international business contracts commonly seek to resolve their disputes before English courts and provide for English law as the governing law of their contracts. The reputation and expertise of the English judiciary, the common law method, and perhaps most crucially the strategic advantages of resolving commercial disputes in the City of London are frequently cited as key drivers.12 In addition, it is likely that parties put much faith in a tried and tested body of contract laws that are not only commercially oriented but that are set within a wider, overarching and reasonably predictable legal framework. Of course, path-dependency also plays a significant role in that parties that choose the English law of contract and refer their disputes to the English courts tend to be large, risk adverse commercial parties who are generally unwilling to consider alternative laws and venues for dispute resolution without a sound justification.13 8. The dominant position of the English law of contract in international commercial contracts, and its wider impact on the development of global dispute resolution, is therefore highly relevant for the current domestic debate as it is clearly artificial to attempt to disconnect substantive contract law reform from the need to understand how contract disputes are resolved in practice. Indeed, as Murray Deakin, a partner at Middletons, notes, ‘[t]he number of cases involving contract law reaching the High Court [of Australia] is less than 5 per cent and that doesn’t suggest a problem’.14 That said, contractual disputes in common law jurisdictions tend to be ‘low visibility’ and there is a richer literature in the US, for example, on the types of repeat players that engage in contract litigation, the typical winners and losers at and there may be a strategic, economic advantage to be gained from aligning the domestic law with that slowly emerging in the EU. Indeed, Justice Douglas would appear to believe that Australian contract law has already arrived at something of a crossroads, still heavily influenced by the English law but increasingly taking note of wider developments in Brussels, see, J. Douglas, ‘England as a source of Australian law: For how long?’ (2012) 86 ALJ 333. 11 n 1 above, at para. 4.14. 12 See, for example, ‘London leads the world in commercial law cases’, The Guardian, January 2, 2012. Figures suggest that 9 in every 10 commercial disputes resolved in London have an international link. As Gregory notes, “English law has a lengthy provenance. It contains guidance on most conceivable areas and is based on the fundamental principle of freedom of contract, which is attractive to parties from jurisdictions that take a more interventionist and paternalistic approach. The English common law has been exported throughout the world and parties therefore tend to be familiar with its underlying principles.” See: https://www.lawgazette.co.uk/features/hopes-cement-international-disputes-uk (last visited, 6 June 2012). Moreover, a previous Gap Gemini report, published in 2001, estimated that annual invisible earnings for legal services in the City of London amounted to £800 million. See: http://ec.europa.eu/consumers/cons_int/safe_shop/fair_bus_pract/cont_law/comments/4.14.pdf (last visited, 6 June 2012). In the context of the current reform process it would doubtless be advantageous to conduct a similar study in order to determine the current economic return of the Australian legal services sector. 13 For a useful discussion of path-dependency in relation to the UN Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods (CISG) 1980, see L. Spagnolo, ‘Green Eggs and Ham: The CISG, Path Dependence and the Behavioural Economics of Lawyers’ Choice of Law in International Sales Contracts (2010) 6 J Private Intl L 417. 14 See G. Dent, ‘Easy does it’, brw.com, April-May, 2012 4 trial, and the number of contractual disputes that settle out of court.15 As part of the current reform process it would therefore greatly assist to have a much more accurate picture of the current state of the law in practice, and a better appreciation of the specific needs of stakeholders. In turn, data on the volume and type of contract disputes most typically litigated domestically, or referred to arbitration, would provide a clearer picture of the real law-in-action. An accurate analysis of any emerging data may, going forward, further assist courts and arbitrators to attract a greater share of the ‘market’ for international dispute resolution. It may also indicate the types of difficulties most commonly experienced by consumers, both in domestic and cross-border contracts, and allow thereafter for targeted solutions.16 II. Avoiding the ‘temptation towards elegance’ and blanket assumptions as to the merits of new contract law rules 9. In the absence of reliable supporting data, it would therefore be advisable for the Attorney-General’s Department to adopt a minimalist attitude to contract law reform. The Government should further carefully reflect on the perceived merits of new (soft law) contract rules, particularly those targeted at purely commercial, business-to-business (B2B) contracts. Above all, the Government must be careful to avoid what Smits has termed ‘the temptation towards elegance’ in private law.17 Elegant ‘solutions’ in the form of new Australian contract rules – including new codified rules and general principles, or rules imported on the basis of overseas ‘best practice’ – should be approached with a good degree of caution. 10. Equally critical, the reform process must not become unduly ‘academic’, nor indeed should any specific stakeholder group dominate the reform agenda, and in this regard it is important to bear closely in mind the recent European experience. A. Key lessons from the EU coherence initiative 15 M. Galanter, ‘Contract in Court, or Almost Everything You May or May Not Want to Know About Contract Litigation’ (2001) 3 Wisc Law Rev 577. 16 It will clearly remain an uphill struggle for domestic courts and the arbitration community to compete with leading Asian ‘hubs’ for commercial dispute resolution, such as Singapore and Hong Kong. Yet internationally Australia also currently lags behind other jurisdictions when it comes to exploring the potential use of online dispute resolution (ODR) in both commercial and consumer markets. The gap is particularly apparent when we compare domestic developments to those taking shape in the EU in favour of consumers. A number of jurisdictions, most notably the Netherlands and Belgium, have developed sophisticated consumer ODR platforms. Belmed.be is one notable public-private partnership involving the Belgian government. It assists consumers and small traders in resolving domestic disputes in the energy, travel, financial services and building sectors, and in tackling cross border disputes. The European Commission has further proposed a Regulation on online dispute regulation, which aims to provide a single EU wide ODR platform for the resolution of cross border disputes. The current draft Regulation is currently accessible at: http://ec.europa.eu/consumers/redress_cons/docs/odr_regulation_en.pdf (last visited, 6 June 2012). The proposal aims to ensure that European consumers will be able to resolve low value disputes online within 30 days. 17 J. Smits, ‘The Future of European Contract Law: on Diversity and the Temptation of Elegance’, available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=803144 (last visited, 1 June 2012). 5 11. It is perhaps unsurprising that the pursuit of a more coherent, uniform contract law for Europe’s internal market has to date proved both politically sensitive and controversial from a purely legal perspective. As this author has emphasised previously, ‘coherence’ in the law of contract, and private law generally, is not easily benchmarked18 and recent concrete initiatives at the EU level, including the compilation of the Draft Common Frame of Reference on European Contract Law (DCFR) and the more recent proposal for an optional instrument on a common European sales law (CESL), have rightly generated much adverse commentary, particularly from law-and-economics scholars.19 Both the DCFR and CESL have similarly prompted a noticeably lukewarm reaction from the wider European business community. Indeed the case for a new optional sales law, for example, is premised upon broad assumptions – concerning the perceived needs of businesses, consumer attitudes and behaviour, and the merits of optional contract law rules – that rest on weak foundations. 12. It will be recalled that in 2001, the European Commission kick-started a major consultation on the need to reform European contract law. Perhaps unsurprisingly, the Commission’s Green Paper, which was addressed to the European Parliament and Council and invited views from all relevant stakeholders, raised many of the very same issues identified in the AttorneyGeneral’s recent discussion paper.20 Of course, it should not be forgotten that the European initiative is principally a ‘market-building’ exercise with an emphasis on the need to remove obstacles for the proper functioning of the internal market. Moreover, ‘EU contract law’ remains a concept, not as yet a reality. In the interests of streamlining the internal market and encouraging cross border trade, much of the focus of the European institutions has been on assessing the extent to which variations between national contract laws discourage cross border transactions. For this reason, and in part due to competence issues facing the EU, variations in contract laws have typically been presented by the Commission and proponents of a European civil code as 18 See n 9 above, at 63-108. See, respectively, C. von Bar and E. Clive, Principles, Definitions and Model Rules of Private Law, Draft Common Frame of Reference (DCFR), Vols. I-IV (Oxford University Press/Sellier 2010) and the ‘Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on a Common European Sales Law’, COM (2011) 635 final, Brussels, 11.10.2011 (hereinafter DCFR and CESL). The Proposal consists of three main parts: a Regulation, Annex I to the Regulation containing the contract law rules (the CESL) and Annex II containing a Standard Information Notice. Despite the title of the draft Regulation, article 3 CESL indicates that it aims to cover not only sales contracts but also contracts for the supply of digital content and contracts for the supply of related services. The author is not aware of any comparative analysis of the draft CESL and comparable Australian (consumer) contract laws. Such a study would nonetheless be constructive in the context of the current reform agenda. Importantly, the Principles of European Contract Law form the bedrock of the DCFR, whilst the UNIDROIT Principles and the UN Sales Convention further served as templates for the content of both the DCFR and CESL. Vogenauer appears to view the DCFR in a negative light for having added unnecessarily to the existing international legal landscape which is in many respects already littered with soft law instruments, see S. Vogenauer, ‘Common Frame of Reference and UNIDROIT Principles of International Commercial Contracts: Coexistence, Competition or Overkill of Soft Law?’ (2010) 6(2) Eur Rev Contract L 143. 20 See Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament on European Contract Law, COM (2001) 398 final, 11.07.2001. 19 6 a de facto impediment to trade. Yet this economic argument in favour of a uniform set of contract rules is increasingly strained. Certainly studies have suggested that business transaction costs are higher as a result of divergences between the contract laws applicable across EU Member States, and that some consumers may be losing out as a result through a reduced access to specific goods and services, yet the idea that blanket substantive law uniformity in private law is the solution remains heavily contested.21 13. What therefore, if anything, should be done domestically in Australia in order to encourage cross-border contracting in the Asia-Pacific region, for example? Unlike the discussion paper, which is largely silent on how to deal with the absence of an Asian contract law, for example, the Commission’s 2001 Green Paper offered stakeholders four concrete proposals to deal with divergences across European national legal systems, which included: (i) A market solution, which admittedly was unrealistic. The Commission did nonetheless suggest the option of refraining from any action to allow any perceived problems to be resolved by the market; (ii) The development of non-binding common contract law principles, which could be used by contracting parties when preparing and drafting contracts, by national courts and arbitrators, and by national legislators when drawing up legislative proposals; (iii) A review of EU legislation in the area of contract law; and most controversially, (iv) The adoption of a new instrument at EC level. 14. The 2001 Communication resulted in a follow up Action Plan in 2003 with the Commission proposing a mix of non-regulatory and regulatory measures.22 The Commission refused to rule out the possibility of further sector-specific interventions in matters of private law, which was for long the subject of bitter academic criticism. Such piecemeal, or ‘pointillistic’, lawmaking at Union level was often criticised for disturbing the overall coherence of Member States’ national contract laws.23 In some EU jurisdictions, sector specific 21 The Commission is firmly persuaded that consumers are losing out as a result of legal fragmentation and that consumers seeking to take advantage of better deals in other Member States are often refused sale or delivery by traders, see V. Reding, ‘The Optional Common European Sales Law – Seizing the Opportunity’ (European contract law conference, Warsaw, November 2011) (noting too that only 7% of online shoppers purchase cross border). For additional data on impediments experienced by some EU consumers when seeking to access consumer goods and services that are available in other Member States, see ‘Consumer Protection in the internal market’, Special Eurobarometer Survey 298, 2008. From the reliable data gathered, the survey suggest that 1 in 10 cross-border shoppers have experienced difficulties because they reside ‘in a different jurisdiction from where the purchase took place’, at p.8. The study is less clear however on the types of problems encountered. 22 Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament on to the Action Plan on a More Coherent European Contract Law, COM (2003) 68 final, 12.02.2003. 23 For an earlier discussion of various difficulties encountered by civil law systems as a result of EC secondary legislation in the field of private law, see W.H. Roth, ‘Transposing ‘pointillist’ EC guidelines into systematic national codes – Problems and consequences’ (2002) 10 Eur Rev Private L 761. 7 lawmaking was further frequently criticised for lowering national standards of consumer protection or for introducing new rules that were considered inferior to those previously available under national laws, and/or for introducing novel provisions that were considered defective. Aware therefore of the limitations of continued sector-specific lawmaking the Commission rightly acknowledged that measures were needed to improve and simplify the burgeoning aquis communautaire in the area of contract law and to improve legislative strategies generally. The Action Plan further sought to promote the elaboration of EU-wide standard contract terms and conditions and more cryptically suggested the need to explore further the need for an ‘optional instrument’ on European contract law. 15. Following initial consultations with stakeholders, the European Commission seized on the stakeholder responses calling for a streamlining of the acquis communautaire and commissioned work to proceed on what was obliquely termed a ‘Common Frame of Reference’ (CFR). This CFR was to be a ‘toolkit’ that would assist European legislators when preparing future legislation impacting on European private law.24 It was further accepted that the process of compiling the Common Frame would require drafting input from a consortium of European academics and other stakeholders.25 It was understood that the CFR would serve to assist legislators in particular when drafting future private law legislation, particularly EU consumer laws. However, in terms of its design, the European institutions appear to have followed a path of least resistance in allowing for a comprehensive academic research project. Early on it would appear that the EU institutions took the view that encouraging this selected group of contributors to progress work on the ‘academic’ DCFR would in the first instance reduce the high level of discontent expressed toward European legislators by primarily civil lawyers. 16. As a consequence, the EU reform strategy, which has resulted thus far in both the DCFR and the proposed optional instrument CESL, is currently backfiring. Regrettably, instead of adopting specific, targeted reforms based on sound empirical analysis, and tailoring solutions to identifiable problems on the market, the project has to date produced two inadequate soft law instruments. As is discussed below, the CESL in particular appears unlikely to prove attractive for European businesses, whilst a significant body of opinion considers the academic DCFR – which built heavily upon the Principles of European Contract Law (PECL) – to be broadly defective. 17. Much energy has been expended in the pursuit of abstract, generalised principles of European private law, in addition to new agreed definitions of primary legal terms and model contract rules, yet leading commentators argue 24 See R. Madelin, ‘European Contract Law: The Way Forward’ (December 2004), available at: http://ec.europa.eu/consumers/cons_int/safe_shop/fair_bus_pract/cont_law/speaking_note_madeli n_en.pdf (last visited, 6 June 2012). (noting that the CFR would serve as a ‘toolkit’ and would, in particular, contribute to the goal of improving regulation and the simplification of EU legislation). 25 The umbrella “Network of Excellence”, or ‘Joint Network on European Private Law (coPECL)’ was founded in 2005 under the European Union’s Sixth Framework Programme in order to deliver the Common Frame of Reference on European Law ‘in the form of definitions, general concepts and legal rules’ with supplementary comments and ‘evaluative analysis’. For further details, see: http://www.copecl.org/ (last visited, 1 June 2012). 8 that if it were ever to be implemented into law the DCFR would significantly reduce party autonomy and would generate much unnecessary litigation. As Eidenmüller, Faust, Grigoleit, Jansen, Wagner and Zimmermann have observed it would create the conditions for ‘a massive expansion of uncontrolled judicial power’ for ‘[the academic DCFR] suffers from a great number of serious shortcomings’, including ‘unresolved or unconvincing policy decisions as much as ill-adjusted and inconsistent sets of rules’.26 The provisions of the DCFR are also seen as a significant body blow to party autonomy and are let down by an unrestrained reliance upon general clauses.27 The concept of good faith and fair dealing, in particular, occupies an unduly dominant position within the DCFR and indeed within the CESL, both as a standard for contracting behaviour and as a tool for contractual interpretation. This is very much in keeping with trends in soft law instruments such as PECL and the UNIDROIT Principles however the fear must remain that it would create unnecessary confusion and introduce a novel, unpredictable layer of private law that would in the first instance increase business transaction costs. As currently drafted the CESL also marks a significant rupture with current business practice across a range of specific sectors of the European economy. An added unknown is how, beyond B2C contracts, sweeping general clauses in CESL, such as good faith and fair dealing, would operate within common law systems, particularly in relation to commercial contracts. In like measure, the concept of ‘reasonableness’ is readily invoked by the drafters of the DCFR in some areas, whilst notably absent in other critical fields. It has been pointed out that the terms ‘reasonable’ or ‘fair and reasonable’ appear to be ‘the solution to every conceivable problem’, and that these terms are used on over four hundred occasions in the DCFR.28 Indeed the drafting decisions around the term ‘reasonableness’ have been rather provocatively queried: ‘some [DCFR] rules incorporate the notion of reasonableness and others do not, it would seem to follow that unreasonable interpretations are allowed where the term does not appear – an odd outcome indeed. Yet if one is not justified in reaching this conclusion, what is then accomplished by including the term reasonable?’29 26 H. Eidenmüller et al, ‘The Common Frame of Reference for European Private Law – Policy Choices and Codification Problems’ (2008) 28(4) Ox J Leg Stud 659, at 707. The authors consider the DCFR to be lacking in clear core aims and values, and that the ‘abundance of general provisions and open-ended legal concepts’ would herald a ‘massive expansion of uncontrolled judicial power,’ at 707. They further note that the balance of the DCFR is out of sync with reasonable commercial expectations and emphasise the fact that ‘the responsibility for the content of a contract is shifted from the parties towards the law and the judiciary’, at 707. They warn that if implemented it would result in ‘unbounded liability’ and the authors raise a ‘floodgates’ argument that they consider to be fully justified, at 686. 27 Moreover, many of the same general clauses are considered to be further ‘replete with indeterminate terminology’, ibid at 687. For an additional detailed analysis of the DCFR from a primarily common law perspective, see S. Whittaker, ‘The ‘Draft Common Frame of Reference’: An Assessment’, a report prepared on behalf of the UK Ministry of Justice (London, 2009). 28 See H. Eidenmuller et al, n 26 above, at 70. 29 n 26 above, at 675. It should in like measure be recalled that a number of past projects of the American Law Institute and the National Conference of Commissioners on Uniform States Laws have similarly been heavily criticized for an unrestrained resort to the concept of ‘reasonableness’. 9 17. The DCFR, as compiled principally by the academic study groups involved, is therefore perceived to be at once both overly technical and heavily detailed in a number of areas whilst also managing to be noticeably incomplete in other key sub-fields, thus creating unnecessary ambiguities and increasing, rather than reducing, legal uncertainty.30 Of course a detailed analysis of the institutional design process adopted at the European level and its impact upon the choice of specific private law rules is beyond the scope of this submission, however it clearly deserves much closer analysis, including by domestic lawyers, policymakers and the Attorney-General’s Department. More narrowly, on the basis of its limited impact in practice to date and the reaction of the European business community, it would be tempting to presume that the DCFR will be used solely by academics as a research tool. Yet there is a very strong possibility that it will continue to influence private law developments at the EU level and many of its provisions may indeed enter legislation via ‘the back door’ and appear in future legislative proposals, as is the case with CESL. 18. The DCFR process would therefore appear to be a suitable example of how not to advance any would be domestic law reform programme in the area of contract law. In addition to the perceived risks for contracting parties that a similar instrument would introduce, the DCFR is in reality a tool that is of very limited practical use for legislators. Indeed it is difficult to conceive of an instrument less like a ‘toolkit’ for lawmakers.31 Faithful to the views of many of its drafters, the DCFR is in effect the first draft of a pan-European code of private law. It ventures far beyond issues of general contract law and deals instead with select aspects of tort, property law, trusts, unjust enrichment, etc. As such, it functions as an ‘academic’ code, and it will doubtless serve the profession well in teaching comparative private law, yet much like the optional sales law instrument, it was rushed to market with undue haste and following inadequate reflection. This despite the fact that, as will be discussed below, both the DCFR and CESL are currently ripe for the lecture hall, not for the world of commercial deal making, nor careful contract drafting and planning. This was a criticism of the stunted reforms of UCC Article 2B and the broad collapse of the Uniform Computer Information Transactions Act (UCITA). 30 For criticism of the extent to which the process has been ‘academic’ driven to the exclusion of legal practitioners, see, for instance: The Law Society of England and Wales, ‘Response to Commission Green Paper on policy options for progress towards a European Contract Law for consumers and businesses’ (January 2011) (noting that ‘[t]he Society is concerned that the group of experts convened by the European Commission is mainly comprised of academics and would welcome the direct involvement of common law practitioners in the drafting process”, at 4) The Response is currently accessible at: http://ec.europa.eu/justice/news/consulting_public/0052/contributions/223_en.pdf (last visited, 6 June 2012). 31 Indeed the full edition of the DCFR is currently advertised as a ‘six volume opus’ on European private law and it is significant that initial dissatisfaction with the content of the DCFR resulted in a further round of review in 2010, which was carried out by a selected group of experts on behalf of the Commission. This resulted in 2011 in a feasibility study that produced a reduced set of 189 articles comprising ‘core contract law principles’ considered ‘fundamental to contractual relationships in the internal market’. For further details on the Feasibility Study, and the 106 responses that it generated from various stakeholders, see: http://ec.europa.eu/justice/contract/expert-group/index_en.htm (last visited, 6 June 2012). 10 B. Avoiding blanket assumptions 19. The EU coherence strategy has largely been premised upon a number of broad assumptions about markets and market participants. In particular, the EU institutions appear to hold a fixed view that harmonised laws and ‘level playing fields’ are in the best interest of business and consumers alike. Indeed as Epstein observes, ‘blanket assertions of the superiority of harmonization’ have characterised the work of the academics most directly involved, and this has impacted negatively upon the quality of the current reform proposals.32 Certainly the Commission, in particular, has been persuaded that: “Differences in contract law between Member States hinder traders and consumers who want to engage in cross-border trade within the internal market. The obstacles which stem from these differences dissuade traders, small and medium sized enterprises (SMEs) in particular, from entering cross border trade or expanding to new Member States’ markets. Consumers are hindered from accessing products offered by traders in other Member States.”33 20. Yet differentiated markets, particularly for consumer goods, and alternative options on consumer rights and remedies may in practice result in lower costs and greater contractual freedom for consumers. As is clear, consumers across the European Union frequently opt for cheaper flights on low-cost airlines, for instance, fully aware that many of their non-legal entitlements may be greatly reduced as a result.34 They do so equally aware that their experience may be much less pleasant should their travel arrangements not go to plan. In like measure, the ‘one-size-fits-all’ approach to consumer rights and remedies is therefore questionable both in domestic markets and particularly for cross border contracts where indeed traders may legitimately experience greater practical difficulties in guaranteeing identical goods and/or services to those currently available in other markets. Uniform private law rights and remedies can therefore serve as a straightjacket, unfavourably impacting upon those very same SMEs who are currently being encouraged to expand into new markets. In practice, as the European institutions are aware, SMEs operating cross-border in the internal market often simply target specific jurisdictions and tailor their contracts accordingly. Studies further reveal that variations in tax across Member States, concerns about possible corruption and/or inappropriate business practices, added to language and cultural differences are frequently more significant obstacles to cross border trade than divergent 32 See R.A. Epstein, ‘Harmonization, Heterogeneity and Regulation: Why the Common European Sales Law Should Be Scrapped’, (European Contract Law: A Law-and-Economics Perspective conference, Chicago, April 2012), at 5. 33 See ‘Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on a Common European Sales Law’, n 19 above, at 2 (of the ‘Explanatory Memorandum’). The Commission suggests that ‘the value of the trade foregone each year between Member States due to differences in contract law alone amounts to tens of billions of Euros’, at 3 (of the ‘Explanatory Memorandum’) 34 See also in this regard: http://www.law.ed.ac.uk/epln/blogentry.aspx?blogentryref=8912 (last visited, 6 June 2012) and J.J. Ganuza and F. Gomez, ‘Optional Law for Firms and Consumers: An Economic Analysis of Opting into the Common European Sales Law’, (European Contract Law: A Law-and-Economics Perspective conference, Chicago, April 2012). 11 contract rules.35 For this reason, the psychological barriers to cross border trade may be as problematic, if not more so, than existing variations in private law rules. 21. Similarly there is little convincing evidence that consumers are significantly dissuaded from entering into cross border contracts as a result of differences between national contract laws. A 2011 Ipsos/MORI study conducted across six European countries did report that 46% of consumers polled indicated that they would be more inclined to enter into online cross border contracts if there was a new uniform EU wide contract law. In the same study, however, 43% of those surveyed stated that a new EU wide contract law would make no difference to their online shopping habits.36 As is readily acknowledged, consumers frequently fail to read the very terms and conditions of specific contracts, particularly online contracts. It therefore seems highly doubtful that consumer confidence in Australia would be significantly enhanced by reforms introduced into domestic law aimed at reducing variations in the laws governing cross border consumer contracts. Indeed the primary concern of European consumers when purchasing online concerned not divergent contract laws but the security of online payment methods. 22. Whilst there is, as Posner notes, arguably a certain ‘branding’ advantage in a uniform law targeted at consumers, as they may be more readily inclined to enter into cross-border transactions if reassured about their rights, this is unlikely to reap significant rewards.37 Instinctively it could be argued that, under an optional CESL contract, for example, consumer confidence would gradually increase if it were to be made clear to consumers that specific B2C contracts governed by CESL would guarantee their European consumer rights. Of course, to that end, it would be necessary to widely advertise and promote the specific consumer-friendly features of the optional instrument. It is equally possible to envisage creative ways that such contracts for goods and services, governed by a future CESL, could be readily identified by consumers, particularly when online shopping. Yet such a glossy picture appears unconvincing due to the optional nature of the instrument. As Posner warns, ‘everything we know about consumer ignorance, and consumers’ inability and unwillingness to read and understand contracts suggests that this assumption is false. If it is false, then [the] availability of the CESL option will not increase the number of cross-border transactions between consumers and foreign sellers and sellers will not use the CESL in consumer transactions’.38 35 See S. Vogenauer and S. Weatherill, Harmonisation of European Contract Law: Implications for European Private Laws, Business and Legal Practice (Hart Law Publishing, 2006). 36 The study assessed consumer behaviour and attitudes in France, Spain, Germany, Great Britain, Italy and Poland. See Ipsos/MORI study, ‘Online consumer research’, January 2011. The study was carried out on behalf of Allen & Overy LLP and is currently accessible at: http://ec.europa.eu/justice/news/consulting_public/0052/contributions/6_en.pdf (last visited, 6 June 2012). 37 See E.A. Posner, ‘The Questionable Basis of the Common European Sales Law: The Role of an Optional Instrument in Jurisdictional Competition’, (European Contract Law: A Law-andEconomics Perspective conference, Chicago, April 2012). Similarly, for an insightful analysis of consumer behaviour in relation to standard form contracts, including online contracts, see: O. BenShahar, ‘The Myth of the Opportunity to Read’ (2009) 5(1) Eur Rev Contract L 1. 38 Ibid. The author is not aware of any stress tests or other assessments, whether carried out on 12 Moreover, sellers would be unwise to opt into the current draft CESL, and unlikely to do so if it is considered to be notably pro-consumer when tested against alternative domestic contract rules already available on the market. In the crucial short-to-medium term the domestic rules are also likely to be considered much more predictable than the CESL from a purely legal standpoint. 23. Alarmingly, just as the EU institutions appear to have misconstrued the preferences of businesses operating cross-border in the internal market, the Commission in particular, would appear to have overestimated the degree of time and interest that stakeholders in business and industry would be willing to devote to law reform strategies in the field of contract law. The Commission appears to have struggled to generate business interest in its initiative since the 2003 Action Plan. The proposal for dedicated work on EU standard terms and conditions is a notable example. It will be recalled that under the Action Plan it was suggested that the Commission would host a website to allow commercial enterprises to share information regarding standard form contract terms. It was envisaged too that through such an information exchange, commercial enterprises would be better able to identify the types of standard form clauses in regular use across the EU and in specific national Member States. It was also suggested that the website would help identify ‘best practices’ in specific sectors. Whilst perhaps a laudable goal in seeking to reduce the need for regulation at the EU level, this proposal revealed a critical lack of awareness of business interests. Indeed the Action Plan rather unconvincingly identified only one EU trade association, ‘Orgalime’, in relation to its proposal.39 This displayed not only an apparent lack of interest in the work undertaken by other relevant trade associations but the Commission further overlooked the already well-established and prominent role played by bodies such as the International Chamber of Commerce (ICC) in Paris. 24. As was highlighted at the time, commercial standard form contracts represent a key commercial resource for companies and it would appear that in-house lawyers, and other stakeholders in business and industry, were reluctant to meaningfully engage with the proposal. More alarmingly, it would appear that this general lack of engagement resulted in negative spill over effects on the wider coherence initiative. Certainly the EU project has been fundamentally an academic rather than a practice-oriented project from the outset, yet the quest for common, abstract principles of European private law has resulted in inadequate attention being devoted to trade practices. As Bernstein emphasises, for example, the drafters of the Common European Sales Law have: behalf of the European institutions or other bodies, designed to test whether European lawyers would currently recommend the draft CESL to their clients. The Law Society of England and Wales has previously indicated that it would oppose an ‘optional instrument’ on European contract law on the ground that the ‘need’ for such an instrument has not been demonstrated, n 30 above, at 3. The submission of the Law Society further suggests that English lawyers would be reluctant to recommend an ‘optional instrument’ to clients. 39 See Action Plan, n 22 above, at 22. ‘Orgalime’ issues guidelines and develops general conditions and model rules for traders operating in the mechanical and electrical engineering sector. See: http://www.orgalime.org (last visited, 1 June 2012). 13 ‘simply assumed that trade usages and commercial practices that are known by traders both exist and extend across the relevant boundaries of trade. In particular, the drafters of the CESL seem to have assumed that these usages are likely to be relatively uniform across significant areas of the [European] market or within industry sectors that are ripe for an increase in [the] volume of cross border trade’.40 25. As is apparent therefore, the European Commission-led ‘coherence’ initiative does provide a number of useful signposts for the Government but it also indicates a series of hazard markers and dead ends that should reasonably be avoided. The Action Plan’s proposal for work to proceed on the elaboration of EU-wide general contract terms is perhaps the most significant dead end. Put simply, the initiative has misfired. More generally, however, the ‘coherence’ project remains unduly politicised and has generated controversy as a result of the institutional choices made. These design flaws have further seeped into concrete proposals such as the optional EU sales law, and the resulting negative consequences are clearly relevant for the development of the current reform agenda, particularly with the Attorney-General’s Department discussing openly the need for ‘optional rules’. Indeed, as is discussed below, if implemented, the current draft CESL may significantly increase transaction costs for businesses operating in the EU, particularly in the immediate shortto-medium term, simply as a result of its optional character. III. The modernisation of domestic [private] law and the scope of any new reform initiative 26. In seeking to learn from the recent EU experience, it will therefore be necessary to give careful consideration to the scope of any domestic reform and the goals to be achieved. It should be recalled that the European Commission had sought initially to limit the ‘coherence’ initiative solely to the field of contract law yet this ultimately proved futile. Another means of potentially limiting the scope of the project, perhaps with the aim of reducing costs, could be to focus exclusively on those difficulties experienced by parties to commercial contracts, given that the law governing consumer contracts has reached a high degree of uniformity and was recently revised.41 One obvious drawback of ‘compartmentalising’ the reform strategy and excluding consumers is that, although the law has been recently updated, the practical application of the law may still require further consideration. 40 L Bernstein, ‘An (Un)Common Frame of Reference: An American Perspective on the Jurisprudence of the CESL’, (European Contract Law: A Law-and-Economics Perspective conference, Chicago, April 2012) (noting that the CESL provides that, in addition to the written terms, any “usage which the traders have agreed should be applicable” as well as any “usage which would be considered generally applicable by traders in the same situation as the parties” [see Art. 67 CESL]. In addition, courts interpreting the CESL would be required to consider practices that “grossly deviate” from “good commercial practice”. Given the sweeping nature of these provisions, Bernstein argues that comparable provisions in the UN Sales Convention are preferable to draft CESL). There are four specific references to ‘good commercial practice’ in CESL (in relation to precontractual disclosure, fraud and unfair terms between traders and unfair terms related to late payment). 41 Australian consumer law rules are now principally to be found within the Competition and Consumer Law Act, 2010. 14 Similarly, it will be important not to overlook those SMEs and other small traders who may require greater protection from larger commercial enterprises in practice, and who may currently receive a lower standard of protection under the domestic law in discrete sectors of the economy, or may simply be unable to benefit from an adequate standard of protection through a lack of bargaining power. 27. It is perhaps significant that the Attorney-General’s Department considers the need to remove problematic inconsistencies and technicalities regardless of the status of the contracting parties. The Department also appears keen to explore how changes to contract rules may serve to promote greater cross border trade. Certainly if the Government opts to focus on pure commercial risk, and the potential loss of business opportunities for domestic companies, it will likely identify a significant number of Australian companies, particularly SMEs not privy to legal advice, that are currently dissuaded from entering into cross-border contracts, particularly with potential trading partners in the immediate Asia-Pacific region. Despite an apparent trend towards regionalism in international trade, perhaps wisely there has been little movement of significance towards a comprehensive pan-Asian private law.42 Yet similarly there has been little meaningful research conducted on the impact of legal divergence in the region and what steps, if any, could be taken to counter or minimise the possible negative impact of private law variations. 28. Divergence in contract laws may mean that in practice domestic SMEs are dissuaded from entering into overseas markets. The law governing contractual negotiations, for example, differs significantly between common and civil law systems which is relevant for cross border contracting in the region, including under international sales contracts governed by the UN Sales Convention.43 Though SMEs may be ignorant of the competing legal rules, they may instinctively have genuine concerns that cross border contractual negotiations could prove costly and time consuming and/or that they could be found to be in breach of specific contractual obligations in a foreign court. Similarly, parties to failed contractual negotiations may, for example, be found liable for breach of precontractual obligations and the legal obligation to negotiate in good faith is problematic in practice both domestically and cross border. For this reason, it would be appropriate to consider in the first instance what may be classified as ‘invisible’ risks in contract law. 29. Whereas parties can plan, albeit at a cost, for most eventualities through careful contract drafting, cross border contractual negotiations can create such ‘invisible’ risks. Common law courts often appear ill equipped to resolve disputes arising out of failed negotiations and in practice it can prove difficult for commercial parties to contract around precontractual duties, particularly 42 In the late 1960s, there was a degree of Australian academic interest in the design of an Asian contract law – see, for example, D. Allan, Asian Contract Law (Melbourne University Press, 1969) and more recently a number of scholars, particularly in Japan, Taiwan and Singapore have been promoting the Principles of Asian Contract Law (PACL), and have adopted the PECL as a key inspiration and model. 43 L.A. Di Matteo, ‘CISG and the Presumption of Enforceability: Unintended Contractual Liability in International Business Dealings’ (1997) Yale J Intl Law 111. 15 when operating cross-border. Also, whether before the courts or through arbitration, disputes can prove costly, even under the English law, which provides a clear steer that parties are free to negotiate at arms length.44 PostWalford v Miles, an agreement to negotiate in good faith or an agreement to agree further agreements are both clearly unenforceable.45 The reason for such unenforceability is equally clear. The English courts take the view that there are no objective criteria by which a court can decide whether a party has acted unreasonably and that a duty to negotiate in good faith is not only unworkable but also inherently inconsistent with the position of a negotiating party. Agreements to reach an agreement with a third party are also unenforceable for the same reason.46 The current English position, though notably out of line with international ‘best practice’, does provide much greater legal certainty for parties ex ante and is seemingly much more economically efficient. That said, as was noted recently in Charles Shaker c Vistajet Group Holding SA, ‘parties still appear unclear that such commitments do not give rise to enforceable obligations under English law’47 and the law has been frequently ‘restated’ by the courts, revealing that such commitments are still the subject of relatively frequent litigation. 30. Care is therefore needed in seeking to modernise and/or internationalise the law in this field, particularly in considering the DCFR or CESL as potential model instruments. Neither the DCFR nor current draft CESL is likely to provide a useful template for domestic commercial contract law rules in the field of precontractual liability, for example. Under the CESL rules, parties to commercial contracts are similarly required to negotiate in accordance with good faith and fair dealing.48 Of course, in the EU, much secondary legislation 44 Admittedly ‘full-blown’ disputes in this area are comparatively uncommon however the mere risk that a party may be found liable for having negotiated in bad faith, for instance, may create a chilling effect on parties and/or a difficult dynamic in cross-border contractual negotiations generally. It may also encourage parties to commit more time to failing negotiations than they would otherwise domestically. 45 [1992] 2 A.C. 126 46 See Scottish Coal v Danish Forestry [2009] CSOH 171. 47 Charles Shaker v Vistajet Group Holding SA [2012] EWHC 1329 (Comm), 2012 WL 1684837. The dispute arose out of a letter of intent for the purchase of an aircraft. It was reiterated that an obligation to exercise reasonable endeavours is unenforceable in law. Teare J emphasized that the courts cannot police such an obligation and relying on the view expressed by Potter LJ in Phillips Petroleum v Enron Europe [1997] CLC 329, at 343 stressed that courts are, “unable to draw a line between what is to be regarded as reasonable or unreasonable in an area where the parties may legitimately have differing views or interests”, at pt.11. The court further reinforced that an obligation to negotiate in good faith is “inherently inconsistent with the position of a negotiating party”, at pt.7. In Charles Shaker, the court found in favour of the claimant who had argued that, “just as the obligation to exercise good faith and reasonable endeavours […] is unenforceable, so the alleged condition precedent […] is unenforceable”. The decision follows earlier cases that have outlined a very clear judicial standpoint on precontractual negotiations. See, for instance, including Multiplex Constructions UK Limited v Cleveland Bridge UK Limited [2006] EWHK 1341, at paragraphs 633-639 and Barbudev v Eurocom Cable Management Bulgaria EOOD [2012] EWCA Civ 548. 48 Art. 2b (under CESL Article 2 on ‘Definitions’) defines ‘good faith and fair dealing’ as “a standard of conduct characterised by honesty, openness and consideration for the interests of the other party to the transaction or relationship in question”. Art. 2(3) (The CESL Part I on Introductory Provisions) indicates that, regardless of their status, the parties may not exclude the 16 imposes concrete precontractual information duties in B2C contracts, however the drafters of the DCFR opted to abandon the distinction between B2B and B2C contracts. Under both the DCFR and the draft CESL, contracting parties are also subject to a broad, generalised duty of disclosure. Though traders may exclude or vary the duty of disclosure under Article 23(1) CESL, the default position provides that parties are required “to disclose to their contractual partners information concerning the main characteristics of the goods, digital content or related services to be supplied which the supplier has or can be expected to have and which it would be contrary to good faith and fair dealing not to disclose to the other party”. In determining whether a party has complied with the disclosure duty regard is to be had to the untried and untested standard of “good commercial practice”, among other factors.49 Macgregor has previously argued that complying with such a standard would involve ‘costs and possible [legal] uncertainty’ for business.50 31. Another key related area that deserves particular consideration in domestic contract law is how the courts should best deal with vague commercial commitments such as to use ‘reasonable’ or ‘best endeavours’ that are ubiquitous in practice. In a raft of commercial agreements, and particularly in real estate contracts, parties often give such undertakings without much thought as to the legal implications. This is one area of contract law in practice where it can be difficult for lawyers to adequately advise on the legal implications in the event of a dispute. As has been stressed, ‘the actual meaning of these expressions, and the extent of the [legal] obligations they impose, is not entirely clear’. In addition, the case law creates a somewhat complex and confusing picture.51 Similarly, where commercial parties operate in different jurisdictions or there is a degree of suspicion or uneasiness regarding another party’s commitment to a budding deal, the parties may more frequently fall back on letters of intent, memoranda of understanding and other ‘non-binding’ written statements. This again can be the source of friction in the contractual relationship and/or protracted, costly litigation. Such commitments prove problematic nationwide but they are potentially damaging for parties if used when contracting cross border.52 32. Finally, more may need to be done in specific sectors of the economy to curtail unfair commercial practices not only to protect consumers but also to protect SMEs from larger, more bullish companies. In specific sectors, application of good faith and fair dealing or derogate from or vary the effects of Art 2 CESL (the good faith and fair dealing provision). 49 See L. Macgregor, ‘Report on the Draft Common Frame of Reference: a report prepared for the Scottish Government on the Principles, Definitions and Model Rules of European Private Law’ (Edinburgh, March 2009). Macgregor noted at that time that, ‘[B]ecause there is no tradition in Scotland of providing such information, this [disclosure] standard may be difficult to apply’. It should nonetheless be stressed that Macgregor concluded her survey of the DCFR arguing that the ‘precontractual duties to negotiate in accordance with good faith and fair dealing are balanced [under the DCFR], and welcome in a B2B situation’. The report is available via: http://www.scotland.gov.uk/Publications/2009/03/05095153/0 (last visited, 6 June 2012). 50 Ibid. 51 Litigation e-bulletin, Herbert Smith, 3 September 2010. 52 For a discussion of the law governing precontractual reliance and the impact of preliminary agreements in European and US legal practice, see M. Doris, ‘Bargaining and Reliance in new European contract law’, http://www.indret.com/en/?ed=32 (last visited, 6 June 2012) 17 targeted government intervention may further be required to enhance the bargaining power of subcontractors. In the construction industry, for example, concerns have been raised recently in New South Wales at the extent to which subcontractors can be left facing financial ruin in the event that principals cease to operate. Legislation does currently exist that aims to protect subcontractors, including the ‘Security of Payments’53 law in such situations, yet in practice many of the contractual difficulties typically facing subcontractors stem from weaknesses in bargaining power at the precontractual stage, as they are often operating from a notably weak bargaining position. As such, they are frequently unable to secure more favourable contractual terms.54 IV. The wider risks and the limited impact of ‘optional’ contract law rules 33. The Attorney-General’s Department has further raised the possibility of distinguishing between domestic and international contracts and asks for stakeholder views on whether any would-be reform should be based on an opt-in, opt-out or mandatory model.55 Any moves toward a new mandatory set of rules is likely to be strongly resisted by business, particularly by large commercial entities that frequently benefit from those very technicalities and inadequacies in the law that the Government appears keen to address. Yet there is equally a need for caution when contemplating new contract rules that could be adopted by parties purely on an opt-in basis. At first blush, optional rules appear unthreatening, as parties are not required to adopt them into their contracts. Proponents also argue that they increase the choice of default rules available to contracting parties. However, such rules do carry latent risks both for the contracting parties and, perhaps more notably, for domestic contract law systems. 34. In the first instance, and in seeking to ‘internationalise’ the law of contract (including sales law), the Government should not hastily overlook the increasing impact of the UN Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods (CISG) 1980 throughout the Asia-Pacific region. Many of Australia’s leading trading partners, including China, the United States and Japan, are signatory states of the CISG, having ratified the Convention. Of course, the Attorney-General’s Department, citing Spagnolo,56 has correctly 53 For the relevant legislation in New South Wales, see: The Building and Construction Industry Security of Payment Act (NSW) 1999. The application of the Act is further well explained for users online, see: http://www.securityofpayment.com.au/nsw.php?hide=true (last visited, 6 June 2012). 54 The recent financial collapse of the construction arm of the St. Hillier group is a useful example. The collapse stalled work on a series of public housing projects in Sydney and across New South Wales and had a significant financial and emotional impact on many of the subcontractors involved. 55 n 1 above, at 20-21. 56 L. Spagnolo, ‘The Last Outpost: Automatic CISG opt outs, misapplications and the costs of ignoring the Vienna Sales Convention for Australian Lawyers’ (2009) 10(1) Melbourne J Intl L 141. For a more recent overview, see B. Hayward and P. Perlen, ‘The CISG in Australia – The jigsaw puzzle that doesn’t fit’ (2011) 15(1) Vindobona J of Intl Comm Law and Arb 119 (noting that ‘in many respects the CISG and Australian domestic law are happily married together’, at 140, but that gaps and inconsistencies between domestic sales law and the Convention endure, including as a result of specific provisions of Australian consumer law). The authors further 18 identified the frequent neglect of the CISG in Australia, both by the judiciary and by academics. The discussion paper also highlights the strong tendency among practitioners in Australia – as is the case in other common law jurisdictions, most notably the US and Canada – to tailor contracts on behalf of their clients in order to avoid the Convention.57 Yet recent studies suggest that the CISG is gaining a notable foothold in China and that increasingly the Convention is being faithfully applied by arbitrators. This is particularly the case in CIETAC arbitrations.58 Considering therefore the established, albeit imperfect, position of the CISG in the region and the large body of existing international case law, added to the increasingly prominent role played by the CISG Advisory Council, the Attorney-General’s Department ought reasonably in the first instance to consider initiatives aimed at improving the domestic application of the UN Sales Convention. This would certainly be preferable to initiating a major academic research project modelled, for example, on the European DCFR process. The Government should furthermore reflect carefully on the views of law-and-economics scholars who warn that optional default rules can in practice serve to increase transaction costs for users. 35. It bears repeating that, particularly where optional contract law rules are considered to bear the imprimatur of State institutions they can quickly develop a momentum of their own. If a set of Australian default rules were indeed to emerge at some later point, a gradual path-dependency could set in promptly thereafter and this could prove problematic if such rules were later to prove defective in practice. It would also be damaging if they were later to be considered inferior to those currently existing under State and Territorial laws, given the likely difficulty in generating the political will and drive to remove or amend any new defective or malfunctioning rules. Such a process could further risk creating new, unintended conflicts with the CISG that may be difficult to address, again considering the low incidence of publicly litigated CISG disputes and a likely lack of political momentum.59 With a new optional set of default rules, the business community, the legal profession, consumer advice groups and other stakeholders would still be required to acquaint themselves with the operation of the new instrument, regardless of whether or not they choose ultimately to make use of it. And yet an analysis of the Government’s preliminary thinking in this regard reveals a notable parallel with the views of European regulators. The stated aim of the draft optional EU highlight an apparent disconnect between the treatment of domestic sale of goods contracts involving software and the approach of the CISG following the decision in St. Albans City and District Council v International Computers Ltd [1996] 4 All ER 481. The case concerned the Sale of Goods Act 1923 (NSW). See also, J. Douglas, n 9 above (noting at 342 that ‘optional instruments (such as the UN Sales Convention) must overcome a great deal of legal and commercial inertia before they affect the substantive law significantly’). 57 As is correctly identified in the Attorney General Department’s discussion paper at para. 5.11. 58 See, inter alia, M.R. Shulman & L. Singh, ‘China’s Implementation of the UN Sales Convention through Arbitral Tribunals’ (2010) 48 Colum J of Trans L 242; and Cf. Dong Wu, ‘CIETAC’s practice on the CISG’ (2005) 2 Nordic J of Comm L, available at: http://cisgw3.law.pace.edu/cisg/biblio/wu.html (last visited, 1 June 2012). 59 The number of CISG disputes in Australian courts according to the UNILEX database is currently twelve, which is highlighted in para 5.4 of the discussion paper. See http://www.unilex.info/dynasite.cfm?dssid=2376&dsmid=13354&x=1 (last visited, 6 June 2012) which further indicates that there have been no reported decisions since 2010. 19 sales law is to reduce transaction costs and create additional choice for parties through the development of an optional set of rules that parties would be free to ignore. Proponents of an optional 28th EU sales law regime have stressed these apparent advantages and have suggested that it removes from play the concerns of those stakeholders who fear the ‘imposition’ of centralised, mandatory rules. The optional instrument is further promoted as a tool for increasing party autonomy. The Attorney-General’s Department appears to be equally persuaded of the merits of optional rules, and notes in the consultation paper that: ‘an opt-in model would minimise the risks involved in reform. Under this model, it is argued, contracts would be governed by the existing law but that users of contract law could ‘make their own assessment on the merits of the new rules’.60 36. Unfortunately this overlooks the realities of the market. In practice the existence of an optional set of rules creates unnecessary complexity and a new layer of law, which to ever properly function in practice, will need to be interpreted by the courts. Indeed the discussion paper is candid in highlighting that ‘education would be necessary to give parties and practitioners the ability to assess the new rules on their merits’.61 Such an ‘education’ would however have significant cost implications for users, and the debate surrounding the European optional sales instrument provides timely consideration of the sorts of risks underlying an optional set of default rules. Indeed it is little surprise that a broad range of commentators are suggesting that the current draft CESL should be either redrafted or simply abandoned. The provisions of the Common European Sales Law firstly mark a significant departure from existing laws found in individual Member States and would, if implemented, impact negatively in practice in all jurisdictions. As Cafaggi observes: ‘the emerging picture in the Common European Sales Law (CESL) is rather complex and enhances the fragmentation of regimes currently in place, thereby multiplying, instead of reducing, search and transaction costs’.62 As a consequence, if introduced across the European Union, the CESL will give rise to: ‘a multilevel regime of sales law which partitions regulation along the international, European and Member State levels, according to the status of the contracting parties beyond the now-consolidated partition between B2B and B2C parties”.63 60 At n 1 above, at para. 7.4. It should be noted that the Attorney-General’s Department does recognize some of the limitations of opt-in rules briefly at para 7.5. The discussion paper also stresses that ‘[SMEs] and individuals may be less likely to have the legal sophistication to elect to use opt-in rules’. 61 At n 1 above, at para. 7.5. 62 F. Cafaggi, ‘CESL and precontractual liability: From a status to a transaction based approach?’ (European Contract Law: A Law-and-Economics Perspective conference, Chicago, April 2012) at 2. 63 Ibid at 3. 20 Where applicable, as Cafaggi notes, international sales contracts between purely commercial actors will continue to be regulated by the UN Sales Convention. Contracts involving large and small-to-medium sized enterprises may be governed by the new CESL, if implemented, or national systems including the CISG; whilst dual regimes, either the CESL regime or the national regime, could potentially apply to B2C contracts. This would generate needless legal uncertainty and it is little wonder why negative reaction has been swift. The optional character of the instrument would not allow commercial parties simply to ignore the instrument, as has been suggested. The CESL will, if implemented, gradually become ‘mainstreamed’. Most notably, SMEs in borderline transactions are likely to be attracted to the instrument, where wider search and transaction costs would be unjustified, and the ‘neutral’ character of the optional instrument is likely to be seen as a strong justification for adopting it, particularly in ‘first-time’ contracts involving parties with no prior business relationship. 37. There is furthermore the underlying risk that new, inferior optional contract rules gradually become the default position and that regulators seek to switch the ‘opt-in’ model to an ‘opt-out’ model. Indeed the Attorney-General Department’s discussion paper raises the possibility of introducing a body of new contract rules that could with time become the ‘default position’, thereby applying to a broader range of transactions.64 On a positive note there is recognition up-front by the Department that such a move could be costly in the event that changes to the law ultimately prove to be economically inefficient. Yet the risks underlying any new optional set rules, including on a purely opt-in basis, should not hastily be disregarded. Even two ‘competing’ contract law regimes would create unnecessary transaction costs for those businesses with sufficient resources to consider both options. For B2C contracts, SMEs in particular are only likely to opt-in to such new rules if they result in lower standards of consumer protection on a comprehensive scale, or if they are seen as providing other practical and/or economic benefits. An added complication is the design of the specific rules. If any new domestic default rules are similar in design to those found in the CESL, and there is a heavy reliance on general clauses and/or novel concepts, untried and/or untested domestically, it is highly probable that business will simply refrain from adopting these rules, unless and until required to do so. 38. In addition it is debatable whether the current draft CESL would in practice encourage opting-in. A number of leading US commentators suggest that the CESL is ‘hostile’ to any inter-jurisdictional competition over contract terms. Epstein warns that ‘the gains from the voluntary portion of the deal will be eroded by the implicit losses that both parties sustain when the state engrafts its own requirement to their agreement’.65 He considers the CESL to be a 64 The Department raises the possibility of an ‘opt-out’ model at para 7.6. of the discussion paper (n 1 above). 65 Epstein laments the ‘threadbare justifications for optional new [EU] rules [under CESL]’ and supports the view of Bar-Gill and Ben-Shahar that they are ‘truly breathtaking in their scope’ in that they cover ‘mandatory provisions and binding disclosures, in addition to mandated rules for entering and exiting contracts, and sticky pro-consumer default terms’, see Epstein, n 32 above, at 7, and citing O. Bar-Gil and O. Ben-Shahar, ‘Regulatory Techniques in Consumer Protection: A 21 ‘state imposed tie-in arrangement’ and argues that ‘this brand of harmonisation sends the implicit message that more regulation is better, without offering any empirical check on that sweeping proposition’. 66 It is difficult to fault Epstein’s assessment. V. Possible paths forward 39. The Attorney-General Department’s has raised a raft of timely questions on both the current state and the possible need to reform the law of contract. The business community, consumer groups, academics and other stakeholders will likely welcome the initiative. Moreover, in time it is very probable that a consensus view will emerge that is broadly similar to that which developed at an early stage in the European debate. It is highly likely that stakeholders will favour the simplification of existing legislation and the removal of outdated or cumbersome rules. There may also be provisional support for academic work to begin on the compilation of a modern Restatement of the domestic law. In time, there may similarly be parallel moves towards the establishment of an Australian Law Institute, which in itself would be a positive development.67 40. Yet going forward it will be crucial to avoid imitating many of the recent European misadventures in the area of contract law. Despite a series of high profile political and academic initiatives during the last decade, the internal market continues to operate without an overarching and uniform EU contract law and, as the Commission itself acknowledges, ‘the knowledge of fundamental consumer rights remains disappointingly low among both consumers and businesses’.68 Indeed it is questionable whether a uniform law of contract aimed at improving the functioning of the internal market is either realistic or desirable. The coherence initiative has arguably thus far produced more heat than light. Spearheaded primarily by academic study groups broadly in favour of a future European civil code, it is perhaps unsurprising Critique of the Common European Sales Law’ (European Contract Law: A Law-and-Economics Perspective conference, Chicago, April 2012). Cf. C. Mak, ‘In Defense of CESL’ (European Contract Law: A Law-and-Economics Perspective conference, Chicago, April 2012) (who, similarly to Hesselink, emphasises the merits of a ‘legal-political’ CESL). See also the rather defensive views expressed by Eric Clive in support of the current CESL draft at: http://www.law.ed.ac.uk/epln/blogentry.aspx?blogentryref=8912 (last visited, 6 June 2012) (who suggests that much of the opposition to CESL by leading US law-and-economics ‘gurus’ can be explained away by these scholars’ ‘free market’ stance). For a more in-depth analysis of Clive’s views on CESL generally, see E. Clive, ‘A General Perspective on the European Commission’s Proposal for a Common European Sales Law’ (2012) 19(1) Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 120. 66 n 32 above, at 7. 67 The recent establishment in 2011 of the European Law Institute is in part the product of the ‘coherence’ initiative in EU contract law. Indeed the case for such an institute was broadly sketched by private lawyers in response to developments in the field of EU contract law. It has been pointed out that such an institute could play an important flanking role, particularly in the absence of a supporting common EU legal culture. See for example, M. Doris, ‘The Continued Resonance and Challenge of the ‘ius commune’ in Modern European Contract Law’ (2006) 34(2) Intl J Leg Info 14 (advocating a European Private Law Association. Doris promoted such an EPLA particularly as a means of encouraging the development of the Common Frame of Reference). 68 See Consumer conditions scorecard, 7th edition, May 2012. Available at: http://ec.europa.eu/consumers/consumer_research/editions/doc/7th_edition_scoreboard_en.pdf (last visited, 6 June 2012). 22 that it has generated a series of codification-styled legal instruments. Yet these draft instruments are not only ill-suited for international markets but pose risks in consumer markets.69 The DCFR and the draft CESL rest on weak economic foundations and the EU institutions have received little real return on a heavy investment of time and resources. There is also a clear contradiction at the core of the current European debate that is little considered. On the one hand, proponents of a European contract law advocate the goal of a uniform law on the basis that it has the potential to reduce business and consumer disputes. On the other hand, many of the same proponents regularly emphasise the need for new European private law courts to handle an anticipated increase in the number of disputes arising out of the new rules. 41. Increasingly it would appear that the EU coherence initiative erred both in moving away from the need for detailed empirical enquiry and when it began prioritising research on the academic DCFR. Clearly the neglect of detailed empirical enquiry has instead allowed for work to progress on compiling legal instruments that are well suited for the lecture hall but not for users in practice. The EU institutions appear to have been blindsided by focusing on an end product despite strong indicators that businesses operating in the internal market have no need for a pan-European civil code.70 Moreover, neither European businesses nor consumers seemingly benefit significantly from the current draft CESL. The EU institutions, driven on principally by the academic consortium leading the reform process, have also rushed the draft CESL to market with undue haste and it is perhaps unsurprising that leading commentators are suggesting that it should be shelved. 42. The Attorney-General’s Department ought reasonably therefore to reflect on the extent to which developments at the European level have been hampered particularly by the design strategy adopted at an institutional level. Defining the parameters of any new initiative at an early stage will likely avoid any would-be domestic reform project from becoming unwieldy and unduly costly. It would certainly be preferable to begin restrictively and to develop ‘bottom-up’. It will also be crucial to adopt an empirical approach from the outset and ensure that no one group of stakeholders in effect monopolises the reform process. 69 As evidenced in part by the decision in mid 2011 to exclude the financial services sector from the scope of any optional instrument on EU contract law. 70 This view is shared by Simon James, a partner at Clifford Chance, who argued back in early 2011 that for the European institutions, ‘the act of passing the law is what matters’ and not necessarily the content or quality of the instrument, see S. James, ‘European Contract Law: the Politics of Law’, Clifford Chance in-house publication (31 March 2011), available at: http://www.cliffordchance.com/publicationviews/publications/2011/03/european_contractlawthep oliticsoflaw.html (last visited, 6 June 2012). Hesselink has been one of the few proponents of the CESL who has publicly advocated for the instrument as much for its wider political merits, as for any strong economic case in its favour. See M.W. Hesselink, ‘The Case for a Common European Sales Law in an Age of Rising Nationalism’ (2012) Available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1998174 (last visited, 1 June 2012) (noting that the CESL should be considered as an instrument that boosts a sense of ‘European identity’ and enshrines ‘just rules’ for the internal market). Whilst the argument that the CESL enhances a sense of European identity is unpersuasive, the current draft CESL, despite its many weaknesses, does currently offer a notably strong pro-consumer body of contract rules. 23 43. As leading US law-and-economics scholars emphasise, the harmonisation of private law rules and the standardisation of consumer protection laws are not ends in and of themselves. Indeed there are practical advantages to a continued competition between various contract law regimes domestically, and differentiated consumer rules can often result in lower prices and other advantages for consumers. Maintaining a degree of competition across State boundaries can have positive side effects in this regard and in the pursuit of the ‘better rule’. Indeed, it is often overlooked that competing systems of private law can serve as ‘legal laboratories’ for the development of new contract law rules and doctrines. In short, therefore, empirical enquiry should dictate the pace of the reform process and particular attention should be devoted to examining what features of the domestic Australian legal system are particularly attractive to overseas businesses. It would also be particularly useful to have a more complete picture of consumer purchasing habits both domestically and cross border, and greater clarity on the types of goods and services typically purchased online. In the absence of a more accurate picture, it is crucial not to over state nor to over dramatise the difficulties experienced by business and consumers operating under the current domestic contract law. Indeed the Government should exercise particular caution in seeking to off-set any perceived inadequacies in the absence of reliable supporting data. New ‘solutions’ to perceived inadequacies can often produce unintended consequences that may have the effect of making business-to-consumer (B2C) transactions in particular, including cross border contracts, more costly and therefore less attractive. 44. Finally, rather than focus exclusively on the substantive law of contract, attention ought reasonably to turn towards the procedural enforcement of private law. As part of the ongoing reform process, the Government should commission a series of parallel studies to explore the current state of consumer confidence in domestic and cross border markets, and to examine a heightened role for online dispute resolution (ODR) in business-consumer disputes. It would certainly do little harm for regulators to introduce similar reforms to those currently being proposed at EU level aimed at cementing consumer ODR. This form of dispute resolution has the real potential to significantly reduce transaction costs. Though under explored in the literature, new purely public and/or public-private initiatives aimed at developing functioning ODR platforms for consumer dispute resolution may also offer new, more creative ways of improving the general accessibility of the law of contract and other related fields of private law. 24