The American University Law Review VOLUME 18 DECEMBER, 1968 NUMBER 1 SOURCES OF MONOPOLY POWER: A PHENOMENON CALLED 'PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION' Charles E. Mueller* If you can measure that of which you speak, and can express it by a number, you know something of your subject. But if you cannot measure it, your knowledge is meagerand unsatisfactory. Lord Kelvin Antitrust is one of those branches of American law with such wide social, political, and economic significance that it has attracted-and deservedly so-a quite flattering amount of attention from a host of nonlegal scholars, particularly historians' and economists. The members of one of these groups, the economists, have indeed long since ceased to be mere observers or reporters of the antitrust scene and have become extraordinarily active participants, their empirical findings and analytical framework now forming the backbone of American antitrust policy. An entire branch of the economics discipline, "industrial organization," one numbering some eight hundred practitioners (approximately 7% of the entire profession), is now engaged solely or almost solely in antitrust work, teaching it in university economics departments, studying individual industries as scholars and consultants, and testing its theoretical constructs against the facts developed in those industry studies. * Staff Attorney, Federal Trade Commission. Member of the Illinois Bar. The views expressed herein are those of the author and not necessarily those of the Commission. 1. See Hofstadter, What Happened to the Antitrust Movement?, in THE PARANOID STYLE IN AMERICAN POLITICS AND OTHER ESSAYS (1967). 2. See particularly J. BAIN, BARRIERS TO NEW COMPETITION (1956) [hereinafter cited as BARRIERS] and INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION (1959) [hereinafter cited as ORGANIZATION]. I THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LA W REVIEW [Vol. 18 The central core of modern antitrust law rests largely on three major economic propositions or ideas plus the empirical work designed to test and measure the various phenomena associated with them, ideas that are quite essential to any meaningful grasp of the problem of monopoly: 1. There are basically two prices for any product, a "competitive" price and a "monopoly" price-and the difference between the two is what all the fighting is about. 2. A product can be "monopolized"-i.e., sold for a supercompetitive or monopoly price-without having its entire output controlled by a single seller. There are in fact two types of monopoly, "single-firm monopoly" and "collective monopoly." Moreover, there are two quite separate and distinct forms of this latter phenomenon, collective monopolization. On the one hand, there is the familiar example of outright collusion on price, the situation in which all the producers of a product agree among themselves to cease competing and to price their joint product in the same manner as if they were all under a common ownership and direction. There is, however, a second and far more subtle form of collective monopolization, one that does not necessarily involve any kind of overt collusion or agreement, namely, the so-called "oligopolistic interdependence" found in the tighter-knit oligopolies of most modern induistrial societies. That is to say, a certain form of market structure that bears no particularly striking surface resemblance to either the single-firm or collusive forms of monopolization-e.g., one in which, say, the "four largest" sellers account for 75% of the industry's total sales-can result in a price that is substantially identical to the one that would have been selected by either the single-firm monopolist or by a group of price-fixers acting in concert. 3. Monopolization can also be accomplished by means of a phenomenon called "product differentiation," which is generally described as the distinguishing of substitute products from one another (by advertising and the like) and thus the creation, in the minds of buyers of that product, of a conviction that it is superior to other products of the same general class, a conviction that permits it to command a supercompetitive price, one that exceeds the price being charged by other sellers for products that are in fact of comparable quality.' In other words, the high concentration that leads to the super-competitive or 3. Or, if there are differences in quality involved, it is the power to command a price differential that exceedi the quality differential (the latter being measured, as will be discussed more fully below, by the cost differences encountered, that is, by the difference between the cost of producing and distributing Brand A versus the cost of producing and distributing the other competing brands.) MONOPOL Y POWER 1968] monopoly prices mentioned above is frequently the result of "product differentiation," a development generally described as the process of first creating an "illusion" and then selling it for more than it cost,4 the ultimate, of course, in monopolization techniques. I. THE "COSTS" OF MONOPOLY The first of these ideas, the notion of a dichotomy between a "competitive" price, on the one hand, and a "monopoly" price, on the other, dates back to antiquity and was already fairly well developed by the time Adam Smith wrote the first "economics" book in 1776. "The price of monopoly is," Smith wrote, "the highest which can be got. The natural price, or the price of free competition, on the contrary," he suggested, "is the lowest which can be taken, not upon every occasion indeed, but for any considerable time together. The one is upon every occasion the highest which can be squeezed out of the buyers, or which, it is supposed, they will consent to give: The other is the lowest which the sellers can afford to take, and at the same time continue their business." 5 It is impossible to exaggerate the importance of this ancient concept in modern antitrust law, particularly in cases involving mergers and other acts and practices that are expected to have the "effects" of either "lessening competition" or "tending to create a monopoly."6 If one views a merger or acquisition of, say, all the firms in an industry as simply a transfer of sales volume from the original group of sellers to some other seller, with no anticipated effect on the unitprice charged the consumers of that product, then any decision to interfere with that 4. In economic analysis, "cost" is, of course, understood to include not only the traditional business or accounting expenditures associated with producing and selling a product but a "normal" or "competitive" profit as.well (e.g., 8% after taxes on the capital invested in the enterprise). Hence in economic terminology; any price that exceeds "cost" is, by definition, a monopoly price. (This notion of a "normal" profit was once explained to an early American Congress this way: When a domestic manufacture has attained to perfection, and has engaged in it a competent number of persons, it invariably becomes cheaper. . . . The internal competition which takes place, soon does away with everything like monopoly, [and] by degrees reduces theprice of the article to the minimum of a reasonableprofit on the capital employed. This accords with the reason of the thing, and with experience. A. Hamilton, Report on Manufactures 133, 2d Cong., 1st Sess. (1791) (emphasis added). 5. A. SMITH, THE WEALTH OF NATIONs 61 (Mod. Lib. ed. 1937) (emphasis added). 6. The more recent of the antitrust enactments, most notably the amended Anti-Merger (CellerKefauver) Act of 1950, prohibit the described acts or practices only where their effect may be to "lessen competition" or to "tend to create a monopoly." 15 U.S.C. §§ 18, 21 (1964). Similar standards are now being read into most of the other antitrust provisions. See generally the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-7 (1964); the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 12-27 (1964); and, although technically not an antitrust law, the Federal Trade Commission Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 41-58 (1964). THE AMERICA N UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 18 consolidation would presumably have to rest on an essentially political value judgment, namely, the idea that it is more desirable in some ultimate sense to have a large number of small firms in the country than a small number of big ones. But a great deal more than a mere transfer of sales volume is in fact involved in these situations. The purpose of the acquiring firm is generally not simply to acquire more sales volume at the same unit price, but to acquire the power to increasethe price itself a result that is of course injurious to the consuming public regardless of its effects-or lack of effects, as the case may be-on the competitors that lost the sales volume in question. The mechanics of monopoly pricing are illustrated in Figure 1, below. In this simplified example, the cost of producing the item in question, including a normal rate. of return on the assets employed by the enterprise, is by assumption $1 per unit (per pound, per gallon, etc.) and remains at that figure over a wide volume range. And because, as noted, a competitive rate of profit is already included in that $1 "cost" figure, that is also the price at which the firms in an effectively competitive industry would be willing to sell it. At that price (the competitive price), consumers of the product, as indicated by the demand curve, D, would be willing to purchase 10 units each, for a total expenditure of $10 per customer per period of time (e.g., per month or per year). A monopolist taking over this industry, on the other hand, would find that its profits could be increased by raising the price to $1.50 (Pm or the optimum "monopoly" price). While sales are now only $7.50 per customer (at the higher price, consumers will buy only 5 units each, and 5.times $1.50 FicuRE 1. Price (per unit) $-.50 1.00 0 HGAC I _ I 5 10 I 15 .I quantity (units) 7. See Buchanan & Tullock, The "Dead Hand" of Monopoly, I ANTITRUST L. & ECON. REV. 85, 88 (Summer 1968). 19681 MONOPOL Y POWER equals $7.50), costs have dropped still more, to $5 only, leaving a total monopoly profit (over and above the "normal" return built into the $1.00 per unit cost figure) of $2.50. (In other words, the consumer now pays $7.50 for a total of only five units, whereas he was formerly able to buy, under competitive conditions, 10 units for a total of $ 10.) Arithmetically, the aggregate loss of the individual consumer in this case is $3.75, consisting of the $2.50 "transferred" to the monopolist in the form of monopoly profits (5 units, with a 500 "overcharge" on each unit) plus another sum, $1.25, represented by the shaded "welfare triangle" 9 in Figure 1, so-called because it represents decreased production or lost output to society as whole, not just a "private" loss to the individual consumer in the form of excess or monopoly profits. Thus the $2.50 is a mere "transfer" of funds from one of society's members to another, while the $1.25 is a "leakage" from the economy as a whole, one that diminishes by that amount its total national income (or, more generally, its total output of goods and services, or GNP). This hypothetical illustration has many real-life counterparts, of course. In a recent Federal Trade Commission case, for example, some 50 bread bakers and a large supermarket chain involved in an alleged conspiracy to fix the price of bread in Seattle, Washington, and the surrounding area were ordered to "cease and desist" their prite fixing in December 1964.10 Later, in an unrelated economic study," the Commission's Bureau of Economics discovered an extraordinarily interesting price pattern in that Seattle bread market. As shown in Figure 212 below, bread prices there had been approximately the same as consumers of the product, as indicated by the demand curve, D, would be willing to purchase 10 units each, for a total expenditure of $10 per customer per period of time (e.g., per month or per year). A monopolist taking over this industry, on the other hand, would find that its profits could be increased by raising the price to $1.50 (Pm or the optimum "monopoly" price). While sales are now only $7.50 per.customer (at the higher price, consumers will buy only 5 units each, and 5 times $1.50 8. For a fuller description of this kind of figure and its interpretation, see Ranlett & Curry, Economic Principles:The 'Monopoly,' 'Oligopoly,"and 'Competition' Models, I ANTITRUST L. & ECON. REv. I n. I (Summer 1968). 9. The "welfare loss" is formally defined as the difference between the competitive and monpolistic price-quantity combinations, divided by two. Here, $10.00 (10 units, $1.00 each) minus $7.50 (5 units, $1.50 each), equals $2.50 and that latter figure, divided by two, equals S 1.25. 10. In re Bakers of Washington, Inc., Dkt. 8309 (1964), affd sub nom, Safeway Stores, Inc. v. FTC, 366 F.2d 795 (9th Cir. 1966), cert. denied, 386 U.S. 932 (1967). 11.FTC, ECONOMIC REPORT ONTHE BAKING INDUSTRY (1967). 12. Id. at 67. THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LAW REIPIEW [Vol. 18 the national average prior to 1954. Beginning in the middle of that year, however, the Seattle price had started to climb higher and higher above the national average, ultimately exceeding it by about 40 per 1-lb. loaf, or some 20%. Then, a few weeks after the Commission's entry of its final December 1964 "cease and desist" order, the Seattle price started to fall, ultimately dropping all the way back to the national average. "Had this conspiracy been nationwide-that is, had the Seattle price been successfully established throughout the United States-the nation's consumers would have spent about $270 million more per year for bread than they actually spent, or some $2.7 billion more over the decade involved."' 3 AVERAGE RETAIL PRICES FOR WHITE BREAD, SEATTLE AND UNITED STATES 1950 1952 1954 1956 1958 1960 1950-]967 1962 1964 1966 *1eceber 1963 ond January 1964 not comparable due to a revIsion in sampling procedure.. Source: Bureau of Labor Statiotics. How much do American consumers lose each year from monopolistic pricing? The economists specializing in antitrust have been offering some increasingly sophisticated insights into not only the sources of monopoly power in the country but into the sheer magnitude of its "effects" as well. One economist has recently estimated, for example, that monopoly 13. 1ANTITRUST L. &ECON. REV. 10 n.3 (Spring 1968). MONOPOL Y POWER 19681 drains the American economy of some 6%of total national income'4 or roughly $45 billion per year. Measurements of this type" are now believed to rather seriously understate the true losses from monopoly, however. Computed largely from published data on monopoly profits-returns on investment over and above a normal or competitive return-these estimates necessarily measure only the "gap" between prices, on the one hand, and a cost-plus-normal-profit figure, on the other. The difficulty here, however, is that one of the elements of this latter figure-the "cost" component-is itself inflated by monopoly, thus producing an artificially narrow gap, one that seriously understates the amount by which the ultimate price would be expected to fall if the 14. Kamerschen, An Estimation of the "Welfare Losses" from Monopoly in the American Economy (unpublished doctoral dissertation, Michigan State Univ. 1964); 1 ANTITRUST L. & EcON. REV. I n. I (Summer 1968). 15. Even the gains to the public from cases involving only "incipient" monopoly, e.g., merger cases, sales below cost cases, and the like, are at least conceptually measurable in these or quite similar terms. Given even crude data on (1) the unit cost of producing and distributing a product and (2) the elasticity of demand for that product, economists can then determine the potential "monopoly price," i.e., the price that would be charged by a rational (profit maximizing) monopolist if the law should fail to act and the current "incipient" tendency toward monopoly be allowed to develop into full-blown monopolization. Subtracting the known competitive price from that potential monpoly price gives a rough approximation of the potential loss to the consumers of that product. As such, of course, it is a presumably fair measure, to those consumers, of the economic value of a given antitrust proceeding. With the growing sophistication of economic analysis, such measurements are by no means impossible now. One of the analysts mentioned above, Dr. David R. Kamerschen, has estimated both of these essential magnitudes, cost and elasticity of demand, for all the country's major industries. The formula for making the monopoly price computation is a fairly simple one: MC P = E E Where P refers to the monopoly price, MC to marginal cost, and E to elasticity of demand. For example, if E=2 (meaning, for example, that a 10% increase in price will cause a 20% drop in sales volume) and if marginal cost is, say, $5.00, then the profit maximizing monopoly price would be S 10.00, a "markup" of $5.00 or 100%. Substituting in the formula: P = 2 $5 '$52 2- $52 1 - 1 = $10. And if elasticity had been, say, 1.1 instead of 2, the price would have been $55.00, a markup of $50.00 or 1000%. Substituting: P $5 1.1 See generally Ranlett &Curry, supra note 8. = $55. THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LA W REVIEW [Vol. 18 market in question were in fact to be made effectively competitive again. For example, another recent economic study reports that not only do prices tend to be some 35% higher during price fixing conspiracies, but that the conspirators tend to inflate their costs (e.g., in higher executive salaries) so drastically as to virtually invalidate estimates of monopoly pricing based solely on price-cost (profit) data.'" Still more recent research suggests further, however, that the annual costs of monopoly may be even greater than the sum of those two items mentioned above, i.e., the excess or monopoly profits plus the losses due to the grosser inefficiencies associated with non-competitive industries. This third loss-and it may well turn out to be the largest of the three-is said to stem from the tendency of monopoly to discourageinvention and innovation. In the 1940's and 1950's, Schumpeter's rather spectacular hypothesis 7 that monopoly was itself the source of invention and innovation-i.e., that monopoly supplies both the incentive and the wherewithal for the building of the kind of giant laboratories that were supposed to be the producers of 20th century technology-is now widely conceded to be crumbling before a mounting tide of empirical evidence that precisely the opposite is the case,'" that monopoly is in fact a powerful deterrent to the development of the new and the better. Thus a distinguished economist, Dr. Peter Costello of Smith College, has recently reported that the drug industry's inventive record during the past two decades, its success at discovering and marketing significant new drugs, has corresponded with rather startling precision to the periods in which the industry was relatively free of conspiracy. Thus in the five-year period preceding the tetracycline conspiracy studied there. 1948 through 1953, no less than four broad spectrum drugs had been introduced by three of the firms involved. "For the following 13 years, on the other hand, these coinciding with the establishment and maintenance of a monopoly through collusion among the firms in the industry, only two very minor innovations reached the market." And the most recent period, Dr. Costello reports, "one marked by the entry of a number of generic suppliers and the willingness of patent holders to license at least a select few, further supports the Hamberg hypothesis (that monopoly power is a deterrent to innovation) by suggesting that 16. Erickson, Price Fixing Under the Sherman Act: Case Studies in Conspiracy (unpublished doctoral dissertation, Michigan State Univ. 1965); 1 ANTITRUST L. & ECON. REV. I (Summer 1968). 17. J. SCHUMPETER, CAPITALISM, SOCIALISM AND DEMOCRACY (1942). 18. See generally W. Mueller, Comment on Galbraith's"New IndustrialState," I ANTITRUST L. & ECON. REV. 29, 33-57 (Winter 1967). MONOPOLY POWER 1968] the pace of innovation may well be increasing again now.' 9 Indeed, with further empirical research here and, perhaps more importantly, with further refinement of the tools of measurement used in this area, it might very well turn out that the so-called "microeconomic" losses from monopoly will be found to equal orperhapsexceed the rather grim magnitudes that are said to be drained out of the economy through a rupture in that other side of the economic coin, a lesion attributed to the "macroeconomic" problem of insufficient aggregate demand to keep the country's total resources-particularly its available labor force-fully employed." II. CONCENTRATION AND "OLIGOPOLISTIC INTERDEPENDENCE" While the notion of a "monopoly price" has been known, as noted, for hundreds of years, the idea that such a price could emerge in an industry without either (a) single-firm control of its entire production or (b) a collusive agreement that bound all of its sellers to behave as a single entity, is of comparatively recent vintage and is indeed not widely understood by many presumably expert legal practitioners in the antitrust field today. The explanation for this comparative neglect probably lies, at least in large measure, in the fact that the basic principle involved, "oligopolistic interdependence," like the idea of the monopoly price, turns on what is in essence a set of mathematical relationships, an area in which lawyers are not generally thought to be either notably comfortable or outstandingly proficient. The concept itself-the principle that price competition tends to be blunted by a sense of mutual "interdependence" when individual market shares reach a certain level-was first introduced into the mainstream of 19. Costello, The Tetracycline Conspiracy: Structure, Conduct, and Performance in the Drug Industry, I ANTITRUST L. & ECON. REv. 13,41 n. 53 (Summer 1968). 20. "Macroeconomic" losses are measured in terms of how much an economy falls short of its potential aggregate output of goods and services (Gross National Product or GNP), i.e., the difference between what a nation could have produced if its labor force had been fully employed, on the one hand, and what it did in fact produce, on the other. Thus, with "full" employment (defined as an unemployment rate of about 4%), it has been estimated that the American economy fell short of its potential output by roughly $40 billion in the recession year of 1960, the difference between an actual GNP of $504 billion in that year and a potential GNP of $544 billion. See SCHULTZE, NATIONAL INCOME ANALiSIS 112-13 (1964). In the depression decade of 1930 to 1940, this kind of loss totalled approximately $600 billion, or about $60 billion per year. Id. And even in the much more prosperous decade just past, these losses have remained appallingly high: "At the trough of the recession in the first quarter of 1961, the 'gap' between actual and potential GNP amounted to $57 billion (1966 prices). From 1958 to 1965, the cumulative gap totaled $260 billion." ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT 42-43 (1967). As indicated in the chart below, this "gap" between the THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LA W REVIEW [Vol. 18 economic analysis in 1933 by Chamberlin and Robinson." The physical phenomena involved, that is, the particular "concentration" patterns that had been emerging in the American economy in the preceding decades and the conduct and performance characteristics they had given rise to, is probably due in large measure to the country's early antitrust policies themselves. Notwithstanding the relatively unexciting level of enforcement activity during the years immediately following the passage of the Sherman Act in 1890 (Teddy, Roosevelt's Antitrust Division nation's ability to produce and its actual output has been continuously narrowed since 1961 and was closed in 1966: Gross National Product, Actual and Potential, and Unemployment Rate BILLIONS OF DOLLARS* (ratio scale) 700 GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT IN 1958PRICES 650 600 550 500 450 .I I 4001 ! I I I I I *SEASONALLY ADJUSTED ANNUALRATES. -JTREND LINE OF 34% THROUGH MIDDLEOF 1955TO 1962IV. 3%%FROM1962IV TO 1965IV, AID 4%FROM1965IV TO 1966IV. 21. E. CHAMBERLIN, THE THEORY OF MONOPOLISTIC ECONOMICS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION (1933). COMPETITION (1933); J. ROBINSON, 19681 MONOPOLY POWER boasted five lawyers and four stenographers at the height of its famous "trust-busting" career), the courts had made it abundantly clear that, at least in principle, both single-firm and collusive monopolization were wholly outside the pale of permissible industrial activity." This judicial blocking of those two obvious forms of monopolization thus put a premium on the search for a legally acceptable substitute way of accomplishing the same end, namely, the avoidance of price competition without, however, displaying the overt trappings associated with actual collusion among the firms in an industry or the acquisition, by any one firm, of a "market share" large enough to attract the hostile scrutiny of the courts. The solution, from industry's point of view, probably emerged more by accident than from any especially precocious insights into the future developments of economic theory. While the courts were unwilling to tolerate either a firm with 100% of a market or outright "agreements" to maintain prices at a monopoly level, they showed no propensity to "bust" challenged industries down to anything even remotely approadhing an "atomistic" market structure. Indeed, so lenient were the courts in this regard that, as recently as 1945, one of the ablest of American judges could declare that, while 90% of a market did indeed constitute a "monopoly," it was "doubtful whether 60 or 64% would be enough; and certainly 33% is not." 3 If it was permissible, however, for a single firm to hold 33% of a market without fear of successful challenge by the antitrust enforcement authorities, then little else was really needed to retain, if not the form, then surely the substance of monopoly in American industry. And so the goal of industry statesmen today is, indeed, not to "monopolize" a market, which is illegal, but to "oligopolize" it, which-at least in so many words-is not. The result, of course, in terms of the prices paid by the public, can be and frequently is substantially the same in both cases. A host of empirical studies by economists has fairly well established that, when a given market reaches a certain "concentration" stage-the boundary is generally placed at the point where the "four-largest" firms in the industry have roughly 50% or more of its total sales or, what is about the same thing, where the "eight-largest" have 70% or more 4-a mechanism tends to be triggered that causes the price to start climbing, 22. Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1 (1911); United States v. Addyston Pipe &Steel Co., 85 F. 271 (6th Cir. 1898). 23. United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F.2d 416,424 (2d Cir. 1945). 24. See the studies cited in C. Mueller, The New Antitrust: A "Structural" Approach, 1 ANTITRUST L. & ECON. REv. 87,92 n. 11, 117 n. 46 (Winter 1967). THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LA W REVIEW [Vol. 18 as in Figure 1, above, up from the "competitive floor" ($1.00 in that example) and toward the "monopoly ceiling" ($1.50 there). This mechanism itself, the phenomenon of "oligopolistic interdependence," stems simply, as noted, from a set of numerical relationships. Other things being equal, one can-and generally should-expect a quite radically different price to emerge in an industry where, say, there are 100 firms with 1% of the market each and one where there are only four firms, each with 25% of the market. In general, a firm with only 1% of the market is so small a factor in it that virtually no price movement it could rationally make would have any noticeable effect on any of the other 99 members of the industry. If it lowered its price sufficiently to double its own market share, for example-from, say, 1% to 2%-the extra volume gained at the expense of its rivals would be so small (a loss of only about 1% of its total sales by each of those 99 other firms) that none of them would be expected to take any notice of it. In effect, then, the individual firm in such an "atomistic" industry is free to, and does in fact, price with a sense of complete "independence," this being based on a quite reasonable conviction that its rivals will pay no attention to its price changes and thus will not respond by lowering their own prices. Pricing here is thus an entirely individual affair; a price increase or decrease by the individual firm is just that and no more, as contrasted with the situation in the highly concentrated industries where a price change by the individual firm must necessarily be a price change for the industry as a whole. Consider, for example, an industry where there are only four firms, each with 25% of the market. To double its market share-from 25% to 50%-the individual firm would have to gain an additional 25 percentage points from its three rivals, or just over eight percentage points from each of them. A loss of one-third of its entire market (1/3 of the 25% held by each of the three) obviously could not and would not be tolerated by any of those other firms and they would thus be compelled to reply with a matching price cut of their own. This would of course nullify the price advantage of the initiating firm and, with the market shares presumably settling back down to their former pattern again, each of the four firms would once more hold about 25% of the industry's total sales. But now they would all presumably be operating at a lower profit level. Unless the industry as a whole had previously (and irrationally) been pricing above the optimum monopoly price itself ($1.50 in Figure 1, above), whatever extra volume consumers could be expected to purchase at the lower industry price would not be sufficient to offset the losses due to the lower unit price itself In short, each of the four firms now has the 1968] MONOPOL Y POWER same share of the total "pie" as before (25%), but the size of thepie itself has now "shrunk." In time, this mistake will be recognized by the four firms and rectified. One of them (presumably the "price leader") will, tentatively advance its own price toward the optimum monopoly level 25 (e.g., toward the $1.50 price in Figure 1), and the others, recognizing that their own profits can be increased only by an increase in the industrywide price, will go along with that price hike, thus "validating," as the terminology goes, the "price leader's" leadership. The point, of course, is that the consuming public will be paying a supercompetitive or monopoly price for the product involved here (one somewhere between the competitive price of $1.00 in Figure 1 and the "optimum" monopoly price of $1.50) and that this undesirable result has been caused by nothing more exciting than a particular group of numerical relationships or "set of numbers." There has been no "monopolization" of the market in the grand tradition of the America's 19th century "robber barons," the single-firm acquisition of 100% of a market .by below-cost pricing, corruption of legislatures, or other such spectacular techniques. There has been no "conspiracy," no "contact" between the four firms, no "meeting by twilight of sinister persons with pointed hats close together, no collusion of any kind. There has been, in short, nothing to which an antitrust statute-or at least one interpreted as prohibiting only collusion, single-firm monopolization, 'and the general paraphernalia associated with those two phenomena-can apply. And understandably so, since an entirely different problem is involved here, one that has nothing to do with either of those two practices. Thus a price-fixing order in such a case, one directing those four firms holding 25% of the market each to stop engaging in "conscious parallelism"-to stop "matching" each other's prices-would be roughly tantamount to commanding water to flow uphill. It is hardly surprising that such orders, commanding, as they do, patently irrational behavior on the part of the firms involved, have not 25. There is of course a large element of "trial and error" in oligopolistic pricing. But the same force is at work on the "upward" as well as on the "downward" side of these price movements. Ifthe leader advances his own price and one or more of the others fails to follow, he must rescind his own price increase immediately, on pain of suffering a crushing loss of volume. The others know this-that he must come back down if they do not go up-and hence understand that there is no advantage to be gained in refusing to follow. On the contrary, they understand very clearly that, by refusing to go along, they are deliberately foregoing increased profits, an action that is plainly irrational and not to be expected with any great frequency. 26. Hamilton & Till, Antitrust in Action, in TEMPORARY NATIONAL EcONOMIC COMMITTEE, MONOGRAPH No. 16 (1940). THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LA W REVIEW [Vol. 18 been notably successful in bringing competitive pricing to industries of this character." III. CONCENTRATION AND "PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION" The various contributing "causes" of concentration are of course many and complex. In general, however, they can be divided into two broad categories, (a) those associated with "efficiency" considerations (scale economies in production, distribution, or both) and (b) those associated with deliberate efforts on the part of the firms in specific industries to monopolize (or "oligopolize") them through certain "concentration increasing" acts or practices, techniques designed to artificially "bunch" the industry's total sales in the hands of one or more of its larger members and impose disadvantages ("entry barriers") on potential entrants from the outside. These artificial devices include, for example, "non-efficiency" mergers, vertical integration, patent control, product differentiation, and the like, a host of other strategic moves that business firms can take to reduce the competitive pressure in their industry and acquire the power to charge a supercompetitive price. There are, however, a number of opposing or offsetting forces at work in the economy, "concentration-deterring" forces that exert a constant pressure toward less concentration, rather than more. Professor Bain considers the three most significant of these to be (1) the antitrust laws; (2) the natural or "psychological" desire of most businessmen to maintain their individual "sovereignty," a very human character or personality trait that makes most businessmen extremely reluctant to surrender their personal decision-making prerogative to the collective will inherent in, for example, collusive arrangements and mergers; and (3) the steady growth of the American economy as a whole, with its accompanying enlargement of the individual industries in it, a phenomenon that generally encourages new entry and thus reduces the percentage "share" of the larger, more firmly established organizations.5 The critical issue here, of course, centers on the question of whether concentration is currently increasing or decreasing in the American 27. One of the economists mentioned above, Dr. Walter B. Erickson, is said to have reported that "itructural forces (particularly the number of firms) are of overriding importance in making conspiracy possible and that the legal remedies selected in the past have been generally ineffective in stopping the price fixing, largely because (a) the fines and other sanctions imposed have invariably been smaller than the profits earned during the conspiracies and (b) the orders and decrees issued have failed to attack the industry structures that made the conspiracies possible in the first place." ANTITRUST L. & ECON. REV., supra note 16. 28. J. BAIN, ORGANIZATION 182-84 (1959). 19681 MONOPOLY POWER economy-i.e., whether the "monopoly losses" discussed above are becoming more or less burdensome to the public-and, if there is such a growth of that burden, of identifying the particular forces that are causing that unacceptable result. To anticipate the empirical findings reported below, approximately 25% of American manufacturing (or roughly 10% or so of the country's total economic activity) has been effectively "oligopolized"-reduced into so few hands that price habitually and persistently exceeds the competitive level. That is to say, "tight-knit oligopoly," the kind of market structure that, empirically, is found to be most commonly associated with supercompetitive pricing (generally, as noted, those displaying four-firm concentration ratios of 50% or more), and thus most of the losses associated with monopoly (or oligopoly) in America, stem largely from the activities of a relatively small but critically important sector of the economy, a group of generally very large manufacturing firms that, while they control only about 10% of the nation's economic activity, exercise a significantly disproportionate share of its aggregate pricing power. While the "oligopolized" sector of the economy is not currently growing at the expense of the competitive sector, to put the situation in these terms can be misleading. The fact is that concentration is decreasing in one sector of American manufacturing and increasing in another, with the apparently coincidental result that, overall, there has been no significant change in recent years in the share controlled by the tight-knit oligopolies as a group. More significantly, however, a failure to consider these two manufacturing sectors separately conceals the causal forces at work in both of them, the forces that are causing concentration to fall in one and rise in the other. Recent empirical studies indicate that concentration is falling in the country's "'producer goods" sector (so-called "heavy" manufacturing) and is increasingin its "consumer goods" sector (so-called "light" manufacturing). As discussed below, the former is occurring largely because (1) the growth rate of most heavy American manufacturing industries has significantly outpaced both the growth capacity of the larger established firms in those industries and the requirements of "scale" in them, if any, i.e., the increased size of most such industries and the "technological developments" they've enjoyed in recent years have generally combined to reduce rather than enlarge the "share" needed by the individual firm in America's heavy manufacturing industries -in order to produce at optimum "efficiency" (minimum per-unit cost), and because (2) a fairly effective anti-merger policy, particularly in the area of "horizontal" and "vertical" mergers, has prevented the dominant established firms from THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 18 using that acquisition technique to retain their earlier market shares. In the consumer goods sector of American manufacturing, on the other hand-the sector where the "scale economies" supposedly produced by 20th century technology are considered relatively unimportant-concentration has been increasing through the workings of a phenomenon called "product differentiation," particularly the use of (1) elaborate networks of "exclusive dealing" retail outlets and (2) vast promotional expenditures that act as barriers to prevent the kind of steady entry that has successfully eroded such a significant part of the market power formerly enjoyed by some of the dominant firms in the heavy manufacturing sector. Analysis of the empirical data on "concentration" requires a brief mention of several preliminary definitional concepts. First, the term "concentration" itself refers, in general, to both the number and the size distributionof the firms present in some given economic arena, that is, to the "share" -or percentage of all sales in some area held by some relatively small number of firms, e.g., by the 4-largest, the 8-largest, the 50-largest, or the 200-largest. Secondly, however, there are two rather widely differing but equally valid concepts of "concentration" that turn on the breadth of the economic "universe" in which the measurement in question is to take place. One of these, called "market concentration," refers to the share held by the 4-largest or 8-largest firms in a particular industry or market; the other, "aggregate concentration," refers to the share of sales of the economy as a whole held by the 50-largest or 200largest firms in the nation. There are two basic reasons, of course, for sharply differentiating these two ideas. First, the distinction is necessary in order to answer the basic question mentioned above, "Is 'concentration' increasing in the United States?" By the first measure-"market concentration"-there has been no general-increase in the past two decades; by the second measure-"aggregate concentration"-there has been a quite significant increase, one due largely to increasing "'conglomeration," a process that reduces the number of firms in the economy as a whole without causing a corresponding reduction in the number of firms in any particular industry. 9 Secondly, these two measures are relevant, as suggested above, to two entirely different substantive questions. The first one, the share held by the 4-largest or 8-largest firms in a specific industry or 29. If Behemoth Industries, Inc. acquires twenty smaller firms, each in an industry with ten sellers, the total number of firms in the nation will have been reduced by 20, but each of the affected industries will still have 10 sellers in them, the conglomerate acquirer simply having been substituted for each of the acquired firms in each of the host industries. MONOPOLY POWER 1968] "market" is a measure of the intensity or effectiveness of the competitive rivalry in that industry and is thus relevant to the traditional economic questions of monopoly and competition. The other one, the shares of the nation's total, economywide sales or assets held by the 50-largest or 200largest firms, on the other hand, does not speak directly to the state of competition in the economy but measures primarily, instead, a politicosocial phenomenon, the "distribution of power" within the society in question.3 0 "Aggregate" or economywide concentration has indeed been increasing at a fairly rapid rate in the past two decades. As indicated in Table 1, below, the share of the country's total manufacturing assets3 held by the 200-largest manufacturing corporations increased from 46.7% in 1950 to 55.4% in 1965, an increase of 8.7 percentage points: Table 1 Concentration of Total Manufacturing Assets, 1950 and 196532 Percent of Total Assets Corporate Size Group 5 10 20 50 100 200 largest largest largest largest largest largest 1950 1965 9.6% 14.5 20.7 30.2 38.6 46.7 11.8% 18.0 24.6 35.2 45.4 55.4 30. For example, there is no theoretical reason to suppose that the effectiveness of competition in any single industry would in any way be lessened if the "aggregate" share of the country's economic activity accounted for by the 200 largest corporations should increase from its present 55.4% (based on 1965 data) to, say, a full 100%. Assuming an even distribution of sales among those 200 largest within each industry, the result would be, for each such industry, 200 competing sellers, each with 1/2 of 1% of the market-a "perfectly competitive" market structure by any standard, one that would presumably result in an ideal or optimum performance in all particulars, including prices, costs, and technological improvement rates. In practice, of course, there is rarely any such "even" distribution of market shares throughout any broad economic area. Firms engaged in extensive "conglomeration" tend to operate not merely in many different industries but to be "leaders" in all or virtually all of them, i.e.. to hold, if not the single largest market share in each, one that at least places them among the "four largest" in those various product markets. There are some commentators who believe that the sheer size generally associated with the larger conglomerates tends to generate its own form of "market power,". one that permits them to engage in a host of anticompetitive practices-price discrimination, tying arrangements, reciprocity, subsidized expansion, "lobbying" and the like-without regard to their possession of a significant share of the total sales in any particular market. See, e.g., Edwards, ConglomerateBigness as a Source of Power, in NATIONAL BUR. OF ECON. RESCH., BusINESS CONCENTRATION AND PRICE POLICY 331 (1955). 31. Both the term "manufacturing" and the term "assets" require a brief note of explanation. THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LA W REVIEW [Vol. IS Concentration data at the industry or "market" level is not as readily available for the earlier years and hence does not permit the sharp yearto-year comparisons for all of the country's 417 manufacturing industries33 that are possible when dealing with only the 200 or less of the nation's largest corporations. Some idea of what is involved can be gotten from some relatively recent and complete 1963 data, however. As indicated in Table 2, below, some 27% of United States manufacturing output was produced by "tight oligopolies" in that year, i.e., by industries in which the 4-largest firms accounted for 50% or more of the industry's total sales. 4 Table 2 Distribution of 417 Manufacturing Industries by 4-Firm Concentration-Radio Quartiles, 196335 Concentration Quartile 75%-100% 50%- 74% 25%- 49% 0%- 24% Industries Number Percent 29 83 165 140 7% 20% 39% 34% Shipments Value Percent (Billions) $ 29 $ 70 $132 $127 7% 20% 27% 36% A study of 215 essentially comparable manufacturing industries (total sales of $181.5 billion in 1963) suggests that there has been no significant Concentration data is available in a reasonably complete form for only the manufacturing sector of the economy, rarely for the others. However, it is the largest of the major sectors (accounting for somewhat less than half of the nation's total economic activity) and, because it strongly influences most of the others, is generally considered the most important of them. One can get slightly different aggregate concentration figures by measuring them not in terms of manufacturing "assets" but in terms of either "value added" (sales less cost of inputs bought from other industries) or "profits." The figures used here are the most commonly used and are generally considered reasonably good measures of the economic phenomenon in question. 32. Statement by Dr. Willard F. Mueller, Hearings on the Status and Future of Small Business in the American Economy, Before the Sen. Comm. on Small Business, 90th Cong., 1st Sess., pt. 2 at 468 (Comm. Print 1967). 33. Those 417 industries (4-digit SIC or Standard Industrial Classification industries) cover roughly 185,000 manufacturing corporations and another 230,000 non-corporate manufacturing firms. 34. Empirical studies suggest that this particular concentration ratio, a 4-firm share of 50% or more, marks something of a "threshold," a point on a spectrum above which the industry's members are able to charge prices significantly above a competitive level, below which they are not. See C. Mueller, supra note 24. 35. W. Mueller, supra note 32, at 474. MONOPOLY POWER 19681 upward trend in concentration at the industry or "market" level since 1947, i.e., that the number of industries classified as "tight oligopolies," those that make up the core of what we call the "monopoly problem" in the United States, appears to have remained fairly stable. More specifically, there have been increases in concentration in some industries, but this has been at least offset by decreases in others, with the net result being,' overall, a virtual "no change" situation. This is illustrated in Table 3, below. Table 3 Number of Industries and Value of Shipments by Changes in 4-Firm Concentration Ratios, 1947-1963 3 Industries in which 4-firm concentration ratio: Increased by 3 percentage Number of Industries Percent Distribution of Shipments points or more 81 33% Remained unchanged37 46 19% Decreasedby 3 percentage points or more 88 48% The critical finding emerging from this study of concentration patterns over time, however, is the fact that this apparently static situation conceals some enormously significant changes in the two major sectors of American manufacturing, the "producer goods" sector and the "consumer goods" component. In brief, concentration has been declining in the former and increasing in the latter, the two changes roughly cancelling, each other out and thus producing a misleading surface picture of an "unchanging" or static market situation. In addition, within the "consumer goods" group itself, the increases in concentration are bunched primarily in those industries that sell "highly differentiated" products (as contrasted with "undifferentiated" and "moderately differentiated" products)." Thus in the study of the 215 comparable manufacturing industries mentioned above, 56 of the producer goods industries (accounting for 58% of the total shipments of that group) showed a decrease of 3% or 36. Id. at 479. 37. Changed less than 3 percentage points. Id. 38. In terms of the two primary classifications-by number of industries and dollar volume of [Vol. 18 THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LA W REVIEW more in the share held by the 4-largest firms, while only 32 of the consumer goods industries (35% of that group's sales) showed such a decrease in concentration. And when the consumer goods group itself is broken down according to the degree of "product differentiation" found in the particular industry, 19 of the "undifferentiated" industries (67% of that group's sales) showed a similar drop of 3% or more in the share of the top 4, while among the "highly differentiated" group, only 3 industries (23% of the group's sales) showed such a fall in concentration.39 (Two of the others showed no significant change and 10, those enjoying 63% of the group's total shipments, posted an increase of 3 percentage points or more.) Table 4. Number of Industries and Value of Shipments by Changes in 4-Firm Concentration Ratios, 1947-6340 Industries in Which 4-Firm Concentration Ratio: Consumer Goods Producer Goods No. of Industries Percent of Shipments No. of Industries Percent of Shipments points or more 34 20% 47 50% Remained unchanged 30 22% 16 16% Decreased by 3 percentage points or more 56 58% 32 35% Increasedby 3 percentage sales-the 215 industries are broken down as follows: Type of Industry Producer Goods Consumer Goods Undifferentiated Moderately Differentiated Highly Differentiated No. of Industries Industry Shipments 120 $100,196,000,000 95 41 39 15 81,333,000,000 20,101,000,000 30,819,000,000 30,413,000,000 39. These are apparently accounted for by special circumstances in these particular industries, e.g., by a broadening of the "industry" itself due to the development and introduction of new products into the general product class in question. 40. W. Mueller, supra note 32, at 479. 19681 MONOPOLY POWER Table 5. Number of Industries and Percentage of Shipments by Changes in Concentration, 1947-6341 Industries in Which 4-Firm Concentration Consumer Goods Industries Ratio: Undifferentiated Moderately Differ. No. of Percent No. of Percent Dist. Ind. Dist. Ind. Highly Differ. No. of Ind. % Dist. Increasedby 3 percentage points or more 13 17% 24 57% 10 63% Remained unchanged 9 16% 5 17% 2 13% Decreasedby 3 percentage points or more 19 67% 10 26% 3 23% In summary, the finding here is that the phenomenon of increasing concentration at the industry or "market" level is prinarily one associated with "consumer goods" industries first and, within that relatively broad category, with "moderately differentiated" and "highly differentiated" products. "Almost two and a half times as many moderately differentiated consumer goods industries experienced concentration increases as experienced decreases, and over three times as many highly differentiated consumer goods industries experienced increases as decreases.""2 This data bears out, then, the earlier findings on this point by the pioneer in the field, Dr. Joe S. Bain of Berkeley." After an intensive study of 20 major manufacturing industries, he assessed the relative importance of the three types of entry barriers ("scale economy" disadvantages, "absolute cost" disadvantages, and "product differentiation" disadvantages) as follows. First, he concluded that "scale economies appear to be a fairly pervasive source of rather mild 41. Id. 42. Id. at 482 (emphasis added). Changes in the number of firms in these industries were also found to be closely associated with the degree of product differentiation present. "The highly differentiated industries experienced a 19 percent decline in the number of companies, whereas the undifferentiated product industries experienced an increaseof6 percent." Id. (emphasis added). 43. J. BAIN, BARRIERS; ORGANIZATION. THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LA W REVIEW [Vol. 18 barriers to entry" in most industries but only a "relatively infrequent source of high barriers to entry, having this influence in probably no more than 15 or 20 per cent of all manufacturing industries."" And " 'absolute-cost' advantages of established firms, aside possibly from those connected with large capital requirements, do not appear (from the industries sampled) to be a frequent source of important barriers to entry. In most industries," he found, "entrants would be at a nominal or transitory disadvantage in acquiring talented management personnel, production know-how, and perhaps other essential ingredients of an efficient productive operation, but in almost no case did these disadvantagesappearto impose more than a slight barrierto entry."I' The "product differentiation advantages" of the established firms, on the other hand, were found to be not only a somewhat more frequent source of at least moderate barriers but "a much more important source of great or high barriers to entry. In all but three of thirteen consumergoods industries (or industry segments) which were examined, productdifferentiation barriers were adjudged to be either moderate or high ... I46 Of the six industries in which Bain found "very high" entry barriers (those that confer on established firms the ability to raise their prices an estimated 10% or more above the competitive level without inducing entry by newcomers), "product differentiation" was either the dominant factor or a strong contributing factor. 7 In short, the important cases of monopoly power, those in which the power to price above the competitive level is present in genuinely significant amounts, arise primarily out of a phenomenon called "product differentiation." IV. MEASUREMENTS OF "PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION" As noted above, "product differentiation" refers to the distinguishing or setting apart of substitute products from each other in the minds of buyers. If there are, say, 10 producers in the "widget" industry, and if there is no "product differentiation" present-i.e., if it is a homogeneous 44. J. BAIN, ORGANIZATION, supra note 2 at 249 (emphasis added). 45. Id. at 250 (emphasis added). Patents and resource control (deposits of natural resources) rasied significant barriers to entry in only three of the twenty industries sampled. Id. One other entry deterrent of the "absolute cost" type, "capital requirements" (higher interests costs that new entrants are generally expected to face), was considered significant in about half the cases, but its magnitude has remained largely unmeasurable. 46. Id. at 249 (emphasis added). The industries named were: automobiles, cigarettes, quality fountain pens, distilled liquor, rubber tires, soap, high quality men's shoes, petroleum products, consumer brand flour and canned specialty goods. Id. 47. Id.at 247, 262. 1968] MONOPOLY POWER product, one with well-known qualities that remain substantially the same whether produced by Firm A or Firm B-then consumers of the product will be relatively indifferent as to whose widgets they purchase. This indifference, in turn, tends to have a very significant effect on another critical factor, "concentration." It means, in short, that consumers of the product, having no pre-determined "preference patterns" programmed into them, will tend to distribute their patronage among the 10 competing producers on an essentially random or chance basis, one that, over the long run, would tend to produce a fairly even division of the market between them, e.g., to distribute roughly 10% of it to each of the 10 producers. For example, if a given supermarket displays on its shelves 10 "brands" of a completely undifferentiatedproduct (and if those 10 "brands" are sufficiently rotated in their respective "shelf positions" from time to time to avoid giving one or more of them the preferential "eye level" spots where the housewife is known to do a disproportionate amount of her buying), the long-term result would predictably be, in accordance with well-known principles of probability, a quite equal division of the store's total sales of that product among the 10 competing firms. It is the function of "product differentiation" to disrupt this "randominzation" of the consumer's choices, to build into the shopper's consciousness a "bias" that will unerringly lead her-other things being equal-to "prefer" the version of the product made by Firm A over the version of it made by Firm B and the others, to make a pre-determined "knee-jerk" or reflex choice by reaching for the one and avoiding the others. The qualifying clause, "other things being equal," is important here, however, and leads to the vital concept of measurement in this area. Once "product differentiation" has been introduced into an industry, consumers of the product are no longer indifferent as to which of the several competing versions of the product they will buy. In the supermarket experiment just mentioned, for example, the analyst might learn that, say, so long as the price of all 10 of the brands remained the same, 50% of all consumers were persistently buying Brand A, with the other 50% being divided in varying proportions among the other nine competitors-a highly "skewed" or unequal distribution of the market, one with a high degree of "concentration" in the hands of one firm. It might be further found, however, that, with, say, a 10% increase in the price of Brand A-and with no corresponding increase in the prices of the other nine competing brands-Brand A's share would fall to, say, only 35%. And, with a still further increase in price-to, say, 25% above THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LA W REVIEW [Vol. 18 that of its rivals-Brand A's share might fall all the way down to its "normal" or random share of 10%. It is from this latter point that measurements of "product differentiation" are in practice made. Thus the height of a firm's "product differentiation" advantage over its competitors is measured by the extent to which it can raise its prices over theirs without losing market share to them. Put another way, it is a measure of the firm's power to command a "premium" price-one higher than those of its existing competitors-for a product of comparable quality.48 In the example given, where Brand A was able to charge a 25% "premium" price and still hold its initial or "even" 10% market share against the encroachments of its nine competitors, the analyst would say that it has a "25% product differentiation advantage" over those competitors. In short, it has succeeded in convincing consumers that they should be willing to pay 25% more for a product of comparable quality, over and above what they would have been required to pay those other, competing sellers for the same product. A comparable measurement concept-and indeed the more familiar one in economic analysis-is one that measures the height of the "product differentiation" advantage not in terms of the leading firm's advantage over its smaller- existing competitors but in terms of its advantage in this respect over potential competitors. If an industry has "easy" entry conditions-i.e., if a newcomer could produce and distribute at as low a cost and sell at as high a price as all of the established firms in the industry4 9-then any attempt on the part of its established firms to charge a price that exceeds the "competitive floor" (minimum cost, plus a normal or competitive rate of return on the invested capital) would simply induce new firms to enter the industry, expand its output, and beat the price back down again. If, however, there are barriers around the industry to handicap such potential newcomers-to impose on them higher costs or require them to accept lower prices-then this constraint is pro tanto removed from the shoulders of the established firms and they can, to that extent, proceed to raise their prices above that "competitive floor" without fear of triggering that self-correcting, "entry" mechanism. Thus if Brand A 48. Or, as noted, if there are differences in quality to be considered, it is the power to command a price differential that exceeds the quality difference (the latter being measured by the cost difference involved, that is, by the difference between the cost of producing and distributing Brand A versus the cost of producing and distributing the other nine brands). 49. For a detailed discussion of entry barriers and the other structural concepts employed in this area, see C. Mueller, supra'note24. 19681 MONOPOLY POWER here is found to have not only (a) the power to get 25% more than its existing competitors can get for the same product without enabling and inducing them to expand aid encroach on its market share but also (b) the power to charge a price that exceeds the minimum or "competitive" level (as defined above) without inducing new firms to enter the industry from the outside, then it would besaid that this producer enjoys a "25% product differentiation entry barrier." Such a firm is of course doubly blessed: it is, to that extent, freed from competition not only from within the industry but from without as well. It is here that the competitive significance of "product differentiation" appears in its clearest form. It has, as mentioned, two competitionrestraining roles, one as a damper on the effectiveness of established competitors in restraining its pricing policy, the other as an entry barrier restraining potential competitors. Had there been no "product differentiation" present in this example, Firm A's first price increase would thus have triggered not one but two self-correcting mechanisms. First, as its price rose above that of its existing competitors, the product's consumers, being indifferent as to which seller they patronized, would have promptly started abandoning Firm A and shifting their patronage over to the other nine firms selling the product, thus decreasing the former's market share and increasing the shares of the latter. Secondly, as the price of Brand A passed the "competitive" level,s" the point where more than a normal or competitive profit was being earned on the capital used to produce and distribute the product, potential entrants from outside the industry would have started entering and building new capacity, eventually transferring market share away from Firm A and over to themselves. In either case, the price increase would have been removed and the price eventually restored to its former level. "Product differentiation" interfered here, however, giving Firm A the power to charge a monopoly price, one that exceeded the competitive level by 25%, and to do so with impunity, with no fear of having that price beat back down either by existing or potential rivals. This latter concept-the idea of the "product differentiation" advantage as a rather direct measurement of the "overcharge" (above 50. The price level that will induce the expansion of existing firms and the entry of new ones is not necessarily the same. For example, the nine existing firms could be, conceptually at least, so inefficient that they would not find it profitable to expand until the price reached a level well above that which would induce an unusually efficient and progressive newcomer from, say, another industry, to come into this one. Thus the existing firms might be operating relatively old machinery (but which it is not yet economical to scrap), whereas the newcomer, saddled with no such outdated equipment, might be able to enter with equipment that would give him a unit cost that was substantially lower than that of any established firm. THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 18 the competitive price) to the consumer and thus as a quite accurate measurement of the intensity or effectiveness of competition in an industry-is of course particularly significant. With it, the "public interest" in a particular antitrust proceeding can often be determined within some fairly wide but nonetheless quite acceptable margin of error. For example, consider these two separate but parallel measures of the "product differentiation" advantages enjoyed by the largest firms in a certain hypothetical market. First, assume that a representative of each of the manufacturers is questioned as to how much, in his expert opinion, his firm would be required to lower its prices below those of the leading seller in orderto successfully enter a given metropolitanareafor the first time, "successful" entry being defined generally as the securing of sufficient volume to operate efficiently. Secondly, assume that each of those producer representatives is also questioned as to (a) the size of the differential between his "private label" price, on the one hand, and his "manufacturer'sbrand"price,on the other, and (b) thepercentageof his sales dollarthat he spends on "brand"promotion. In regard to the first question-the size of the price concession required of a newcomer in order to overcome an established competitor's locally-entrenched "brand" name and thus get enough of that local market to begin an efficient operation-suppose that the answers received vary from something on the order of 10% to as high as 50%. In other words, assume it is the fairly unanimous view that, in this industry, the newcomer would have to undercut his largest competitor'sprice by at least 10% (the products of all the competing sellers being admittedly identical in quality) in order to ever get enough business to operate profitably; at any lower level of output (or absent a correspondingly higher level of promotional expenditures), the attempted entry would be doomed to failure from the start. (Instances are related, however, in which newcomers have been unsuccessful in entering certain new geographical markets for the first time even when they gave price concessions as high as 50%, that is, in which their products failed to "move off the shelves" even when they sold to the retailer at 50% less than competing manufacturers were charging for a physically identical product, a price concession that was then "passed on" to the consumer in the form of 50% lower retail "'shelf" prices). The magnitude of the price concession required to "detach" the consumer from his "brand" preferences in this industry is found to be similarly large, let us suppose, where the measurement is made in terms of the second factor mentioned above, namely, the difference between the leading manufacturers' "private brand" price, on the one hand, and their 1968] MONOPOLY POWER own "manufacturer's brand," on the other. Thus one producer might explain that, whereas a price of, say, 170 per unit was available to the very largest "private brand" customers (e.g., the largest chain store customers buying under their own private brand), those same customers would pay perhaps 21.250 for the same product when it is sold to them under the manufacturer's "advertised" brand or label, for a differential of 4.250 per unit or approximately 20%. Since the product involved is physically the same, and since the customers themselves and the quantitiesinvolved in the purchases are also the same, that differential is presumably a fair measure of the strength of the "consumer preference" enjoyed by the "branded" over the "non-branded" product. It is also a presumably fair approximation of the degree of monopoly power exercised in the "branded" or major segment of the market in question: assuming the "private brand" price of 170 is not itself a below-cost price-that it covers all business costs, plus at least a competitive rate of profit on that portion of the firm's capital that is devoted to that segment of its output-then the higher 21.250 price charged for the "branded" product is, by definition, a supercompetitive or monopoly price. Measurements of these kinds can bring, of course, a highly desirable form of rationality into the antitrust decision-making process. While the height of "entry barriers" is hardly one of the routine business facts collected by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) and thus conveniently available in handy government publications,5 ' it is a measurement that can be made with a reasonable amount of investigative effort, 2 probably with a great deal less effort than is involved in some of the more traditional non-structural or "conduct" types of investigation. 3 And 51. Data on one of the three "structural" factors, "concentration," is compiled by BLS and published by the Senate Antitrust and Monopoly, Subcommittee. See Staff of the Bureau of the Census, Report on Concentration Ratios in Manufacturing Industry 1963, for the Subcomm. on Antitrust and Monopoly of the Sen. Comm. on the Judiciary, 89th Cong., 2d Sess., pt 1 (1966). 52. Dr. Bain made quite detailed and apparently highly accurate estimates of the height of the entry barriers surrounding no less than 20 of the country's major industries, including automobiles, petroleum refining, steel, and the like. J. BAIN, BARRIERS, supra note 2. 53. Bain notes, for example, that the present "prolongation and expense of antimonopoly actions results in large part from the fact that establishment of conduct offenses generally requires almost endless exploration of the minutiae of the business practices and policies of the defendants, and endless arguments about what can be inferred from these practices and policies." He notes that "five or ten years from initiation to conclusion of a monopoly case is not unusual. In effect, a conduct offense is much more difficult to establish than a structural offense would be." J. BAIN, ORGANIZATION, supra note 2 at 535. Further, he notes that litigated cases "centering on the details of market conduct, as monopolization cases at present must, are intrinsically lengthy and expensive, as innumerable details of conduct must he explored, defended and attacked, and ultimately evaluated . . . . Enforcement is [thus] hampered by the very high cost of each individual enforcement action." Id. at 607-08. He would favor a focusing of attention on the three "structural" THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LA W REVIEW [Vol. 18 once made, it provides, in combination with the "concentration" data more commonly presented in antitrust cases, the key to a truly meaningful estimate of the public interest at stake in a given antitrust proceeding. Once it has been determined, for example, that the prices actually being charged in an industry are, say, 20% above the competitive level, the one that would have prevailed in the absence of the challenged acts of monopolization (as in the example described above), it is a simple matter of arithmetic to determine the total number of dollars the monopolists in question are "redistributing" away from the consumers of their product and to themselves. Thus when Bain reports that a certain industry is not only highly concentrated but has a "very high" barrier to entry (defined as one that permits a price 10% or more above the competitive level without inducing new entry), and that this industry has annual sales of, say, $30 billion, he is saying, in substance, that an additional $3 billion (10% of $30 billion) in monopoly "overcharges" are being exacted from the consumers of that industry's product each year. A similar measurement for each of the country's highly concentrated industries, those in which the market shares of the few largest firms are big enough to permit them to exploit whatever entry barriers they may have been able to erect, would permit a complete tabulation of the "redistribution of income" monopoly produces each year in the economy as a whole. V. SOURCES OF "PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION" Not all products lend themselves to successful "product differentiation." First of all, one must eliminate, as emphasized above, virtually the whole category of products called "producer goods," those sold not to the consuming public but to other businessmen who use them in the production of their own goods, e.g., steel, copper, and the various other primary metals. Goods of this type are bought under conditions that make it virtually impossible to develop a really significant degree of "product differentiation." For example, the purchasers here-generally manufacturing firms of quite substantial size themselves-tend to buy in relatively large quantities, through skilled purchasing agents, men who are thoroughly familiar with the technical properties of the goods in question (frequently buying according to specifications of their own selection) and thus not subject to the kind of non-rational arguments elements-concentration, product differentiation and entry barriers-and a corresponding "shift away from the maze of acts, practices, and policies" that "are so much emphasized under the present law." Id. at 610. 1968] MONOPOLY POWER that are frequently more effective with consumers than presentations of purely technical data. In short, *the businessman himself is an exacting "shopper," one who employs highly skilled professionals, men with sharp pencils who insist upon knowing all of the relevant facts about the product in question and awarding their patronage strictly on the basis of price and performance. No purchaser of steel, for example, has yet been persuaded that the steel bars of Firm A are "worth" a penny more per pound than those of any other steel producer. The principal source of "product differentiation," then, is what Bain calls "buyer ignorance."54 In general, the susceptibility of consumers to successful "product differentiation" is in direct proportion to their lack of factual information about the qualities and characteristics of the goods they are purchasing and their lack of an adequate opportunity to acquire such information. Thus the bulk of the highly "differentiated" products falls into one or more of the following categories: 1. They are bought by consumers, rather than producers; 2. They are fairly durable in character and are thus purchased infrequently (a factor that tends to prevent the consumer from "experimenting" and thus becoming familiar with all or most of the competing brands); 3. They are complex in design or composition, thus making it impractical for the consumer to attempt to acquire the technical khiowledge that would be needed in order to make an informed choice between the various brand offerings." As Bain puts it: "[w]ith respect to the meat, canned vegetables, bread, stockings, and similar goods purchased repeatedly at short intervals, a housewife is likely to acquire a reasonably good knowledge of the quality and other characteristics of competing outputs, and to arrive at a reasoned and informed choice among alternatives. With respect to automobiles, major electrical appliances, home-movie cameras, and the like," however, goods that are complex in design and very infrequently purchased, "the average consumer is likely to have only the sketchiest notion of the relative performance, reliability, and other essential characteristics of competing brands, and is in effect ignorant or uninformed. In this situation," Bain suggests, "the buyer is likely to rely on the 'reputations' of the various products or their sellers; on popular lore concerning the performance and reliability of past outputs of a seller, on whether or not the seller has successfully remained in business 54. See, e.g., Id. at 214; J. BAIN, BARRIERS, supra note 2 at 124. 55. J. BAIN, ORGANIZATION, supra note 2, at 214. THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LA W REVIEW [Vol. 18 for a long time, and so forth. This reliance on seller or product reputationsby ignorantconsumers," he believes, is thus one of the major sources of the kinds of "preference" patterns 6 that breed high concentration and the other undesirable consequences of inordinately high degrees of "product differentiation." This lack of reliable factual information on the part of the consumer plays a still further role in the story, however. Most importantly of all, perhaps, it makes her susceptible to what Bain calls the "persuasive salespromotion activities of sellers," 57 particularly advertising of a certain kind: Inextricably interconnected with brands, trademarks, or company names, advertising and other sales promotion may of course be primarily 'informational'in its impact (thus tending to build a product differentiation based on a knowledge of the relative designs, qualities, and prices of competing outputs), but in our experience it is, instead, primarily 'persuasive.' It is aimed at creating product preferences through generally phrasedpraises of the attributesof various outputs (Winstons taste good, like a cigarette should), or simply through dinninginto thepotential buyer's mind an awareness of the product through endless repetition. Thus an important category of product differentiation is built primarily on a nonrationalor emotional basis,through the efforts of the 'ad-man. "8 Not all of the "nonrational" basis for "product differentiation" is the work of the "ad-man," however. One of the most important sources of this phenomenon is the use of large and elaborate "distributive and service facilities," 59 e.g., the chains of "exclusive" retail dealers used in such industries as automobiles and petroleum. By saturating an area with dealers handling their own respective products exclusively, the three or four sellers with the best-known brands can effectively deny their smaller existing and potential competitors access to the best sites and most efficient retailers, thus raising the per-unit sales and distribution costs of those actual and potential competitors while entrenching still further their own "brand" names in the minds of local consumers through the "advertising effect" of the elaborate local dealer establishments, organizations that control many thousands of square miles of gleaming floor space and flashing neon signs.60 In other words, 56. Id. at 215 (emphasis added). 57. Id. 58. Id. 59. Id. at 220. 60. Many of the costs incurred by automobile manufacturers and gasoline refiners in building and/or maintaining their nationwide dealership chains are more properly attributable to the advertising or sales promotion function than to distribution. Id. at 387-88. 1968] MONOPOLY POWER these exclusive dealerships or, as they are sometimes called, these "vertical-integrations-by-contract," are themselves a form of advertising, one that pre-empts the choicest media for itself, thus forcing any existing or would-be competitor to incur the sometimes prohibitive cost of developing its own separate chains of dealer outlets, establishments that will, by definition, be placed on less desirable sites and manned by less experienced operators, 6 thus raising that competitor's per-unit costs and, by keeping his product on the "back shelves," so to speak, lowering its acceptability in the eyes of consumers and thus the per-unit price it is able to command. This latter aspect of the problem is sharply illustrated by a recent private action, one involving the outboard motor industry." The plaintiff in that case, a marine dealer located near Annapolis, Maryland, alleged that it had handled the defendant's "Johnson" motors on an "exclusive" basis for some years but had recently been "cut off"-that is, denied the right to continue buying and selling the defendant's engines-for violating an unwritten "understanding" the latter allegedly has with its approximately 8,700 dealers across the country and taking on, in addition to the defendant's "Johnson" motor, a competing engine, the "Mercury" motor manufactured by the second largest producer in the industry. According to the plaintiff,6 3 there are some 12,000 to 15,000 marine dealers in the United States and hence the defendant's exclusive arrangements with approximately 8,700 of them thus constituted a foreclosure of some 58% to 72% of the total available retail outlets for outboard motors in the country. It was alleged further that this preemption of the bulk of the country's available marine outlets, particularly of the larger, more efficient outlets, served to further "differentiate" the defendant's engines from those of its competitors and thus increase the already high degree of concentration existing in the industry. Alleging that the defendant Outboard Marine, owner of the nation's two leading "brands" of outboard motors, the "Johnson" and the "Evinrude," holds roughly 60% of the industry's total sales volume (there are 11 other firms in the industry, but only three of them make a full line, the other eight producing only specialty engines), the plaintiff 61. In economic analysis, the most productive resources are always put into use first, the "marginal" resources being used only when the supplies of the more efficient have been exhausted. 62.. Amplex of Maryland, Inc. v. Outboard Marine Corp., 3.N F.2d 112 (4th Cir. 1967), cert. denied, 389 U.S. 1036 (1968). 63. See Plaintiff's Petition for Certiorari at 11, Amplex of Maryland, Inc. v. Outboard Marine, Corp., 380 F.2d 112 (4th Cir. 1967), cert. denied, 389 U.S. 1036 (1968). THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LA W REVIEW [Vol. 18 contended that the defendant's two brand names have acquired such widespread consumer acceptance (largely through the cumulative effect of their "exclusive" pre-emption of the better marine-dealer showrooms over the years) that dealers handling the outboard motors of competing manufacturers find it extremely difficult if not impossible to secure enough business to operate on an efficient scale of distribution, thus putting the competing manufacturers and their dealers at both a cost and price disadvantage vis-a-vis the defendant and its dealers. The plaintiff attempted to measure the height of the defendant's "product differentiation" advantage and thus the extent of its power to charge a supercompetitive price for its products by comparing the price charged for that manufacturer's "branded" motors (the "Johnson" and the "Evinrude"), on the one hand, with the price it charged for its comparable "private brand" engine, on the other. This engine, called the "Gale," was produced exclusively for a single large customer, Montgomery Ward, and was sold to that customer at approximately 15% less than the defendant's dealers paid for its two "branded" motors. Since the three were identical in quality6 4 the plaintiff argued that the lower price on the "private brand" engine represented the normal or "competitive" price level (the one that would have prevailed on all the motors, both "branded" and "unbranded," in the absence of the "product differentiation" disadvantages that faced both existing and potential competitors) and hence that the 15% higher price being charged for the "Johnson" and "Evinrude" was necessarily a monopoly price, one that overcharged the consumer by the amount of that differential, namely, 15%. The plaintiff drew a similar inference from the defendant's extraordinary profit record over a long period of years. Thus in the 10 year period 1952-1961, Outboard Marine had net (after tax) yearly earnings ranging from a low of 12.4% on stockholders' equity (excluding the recession year of 1961, when only 5.5% was earned) to a high of 27.3% in 1955. "The ten year average was 17.4%, a monopoly return by any standard. ' 65 In dollars, the 10 year total was $84 million, or some $8.4 million per year. 64. Id. at 11-12 n. 12. The testimony revealed the only differences to be in the paint job and the cover. 65. Id. at 15 n. 17. "For the private sector of the economy the range of 5 to 6 per cent would seem about appropriate. This, then, is the opportunity cost of equity capital, the minimum normal rate of profit, based on what it could earn in other uses." R. CAVES, AMERICAN INDUSTRY: STRUCTURE, CONDUCT, PERFORMANCE 103 (1964). See also C. KAYSEN & D. TURNER, ANTITRUST POLICY 63 (1959): "If normal profits are of the magnitude of say, 6 to 8 percent on invested capital, an average profit rate of 9 percent over ten years could not be identified as supernormal with any confidence, but one of 12 percent could." 19681 MONOPOLY POWER At a competitive rate of return (e.g., 8%) rather than the 17.4% it has in fact averaged, its aggregate dollar earnings over that period would have been just under half that total, some $40 million (or $4 million per year). Therefore, even ignoring the inflated costs that monopoly generally produces and doubtless has produced here as well (e.g., the small scale production and inefficient dealer-distribution systems defendant has imposed on the industry), at least $4 million per year in monopoly profits are readily identifiable here, money wrongfully extracted from the dealers in the first instance and, ultimately, from the consuming public." In the plaintiffs view, the "product differentiation" advantage that permitted this monopoly pricing "is a creature of defendant's exclusive dealing.policy." "There is no serious dispute here," it argued, "that this exclusive dealing policy has the straight-forward effect of enhancing the sales volume (and market share) of the defendant and shrinking that of its competitors. If a Johnson dealer takes on Mercury engines as a second line," the plaintiff maintained, "his sales of Mercury engines increases and his sale of Johnson engines falls. Repeated across the nation, this would mean a sharp re-aligning of market shares in the industry. If this plaintiff and the defendant's other 8,700 marine dealers throughout the country were permitted," the argument ran, "to display competing engines-the Mercury, the Scott, the West Bend, and others-in their larger, more attractive, higher-traffic showrooms, defendant's 'product differentiation' advantage and its present 60% share of the national market in outboard motors would obviously start to dwindle and that of its competitors (both individually and collectively) would correspondingly start to increase. ' 61 The alleged net result would be lower costs, 6 intensified competition, and eventually lower prices to the consuming public. "Thus a 15% reduction in the price of the average outboard motor ($458, in 196 1) would be approximately $69 per engine, or a total saving to the American consumer of some $23 million on the 66. Petition for Certiorari, supra note 63, at 15 n.17. 67. Id. at 12-13. 68. Id. at 13:"With their fixed costs spread over larger volumes of production and distribution, per-unit costs of those competing manufacturers would be expected to fall and, with more nearly equal market shares among the industry's 12 already established manufacturers in 1961, plus potential entry by newcomers that could be expected to find the industry more attractive in this improved climate, the vigor of competition at the manufacturing level should be enhanced." And "lower costs and enhanced competition would be expected to lowerthe price from the manufacturer to the dealer, eventually eliminating most, if not all, of the 15% 'premium' price defendant is now able to charge for the Johnson and Evinrude brands. Competitidn should also be enhanced at the dealer level, thus assuring the passing on to the consumer of those lower manufacturing costs and prices." THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 18 $155 million 'worth' of outboard motors bought by the consuming public in 196 1.'69 This potential landmark case, alas, was never heard by the Supreme Court, not so much, one suspects, because of analytical problems, but because of problems of proof on the substantive "legal" question of whether the plaintiff had carried its burden .of proving the unlawful exclusive dealing "condition" required under Section 3 of the Clayton Act and apparently read into the Sherman Act in cases of this character. 0 Economists continue to lament the Court's lack of action in this area of exclusive dealing," pointedly noting that "product differentiation" is at the heart of the country's monopoly problem and that, in a number of industries where the advertising in question is accomplished not through the use of a large "ad budget," as such, but through the maintenance of a tight grip on an elaborate dealer structure that constitutes the only access to the consumer's subjective "preference" patterns," an enormous potential for improvement in competitive performance remains almost wholly unexplored. Bain concludes, for example, that Section 3 of the Clayton Act, the exclusive dealing provisions, "could provide a broad basis for removing or averting the exclusionary effects of exclusivedealing contracts between manufacturers and distributors in numerous industries,""' suggesting that vigorous action here, "by opening previously closed distributive channels to new entrants and small firms, might significantly increase the force of both actual and potential competition." 4 It hardly takes a great dealof insight into the intricacies 69. Id. 70. The district court had dismissed the plaintiffs case after hearing only five of its 42 witnesses, the testimony of the others having been presented in somewhat truncated form, as a proffer of proof. Id. at 23. 71. See, e.g., Mann, 'Prioritiesin Antitrust'; Some Communications, I ANTITRUST L. & ECON. REv. 20, 21 (Spring 1968), observing that "the Supreme Court had a good opportunity to undermine exclusive franchising in the automobile industry in the General Motors case, decided in May, 1966." 72. BAIN, ORGANIZATION, supra note 2, at 391. Neither the automobile nor the outboard motor industry spends an exceptionally large percentage of its total sales dollar on advertising. Inclusion of the "advertising component" in the cost of maintaining their respective dealer organizations, however, would doubtless produce an advertising/sales ratio in the "very high" range, that is, one well into the "over 5%" category considered suspect by Bain. Id. 73. Id. at 615. 74. Id. at 616. He believes that "in cases like those of the automobile, farm machine, and petroleum refining industries, the elimination of integration and quasi-integration through contractual exclusive-dealing arrangements, would tend to reduce the over-all advantages of large scale at the manufacturing level and to lower the barriers to entry perceptibly." J. BAIN, BARRIERS, supra note 2 at 213. "Where product differentiation advantages of established firms rest heavily on 19681 MONOPOLY POWER of economic theory to predict with some modest degree of confidence that the market share of, say, American Motors, would start to climb significantly if it should suddenly find the way cleared for its "Ramblers" to be displayed on the floor of the country's many thousands of "Chevrolet" dealers.75 While the appropriate policy solution in the case of "product differentiation" entry barriers created by "exclusive dealing" would probably be one of outright prohibition (with, however, an exception where it could be persuasively demonstrated that there were substantial efficiencies to be gained from such "quasi-integration," that these could be achieved in no other way, and that they could in fact be expected to inure to the benefit of the consuming public), a more delicate problem is presentedby the work of the "ad-man." A great deal of advertising is of course highly beneficial to the public interest, particularly the factual, "informational" kind that makes up the bulk of that appearing in, say, newspapers, and much of the magazine or periodical advertising. Conceptually, at least, it is easy enough to separate the "procompetitive" and the "anticompetitive" forms of advertising. As Bain puts it, "a certain modicum of selling activity and cost devoted to informational purposes are functionally justified, or essential to the effective working of a market system. It is necessary and useful to inform potential buyers of the availability of goods, of their specifications and qualities, of their prices." But "selling activity and cost with a persuasive orientation are not similarly justified from the standpoint of aggregate economic welfare, since they reflect, in large part at least, a diversion to sales promotion of productive resources which would otherwise be devoted to producing and distributing a larger volume of useful goods and services.17 6 In his view, much of American advertising falls into the latter category, rather than the former, i.e., "a large proportion of observed promotional activities and costs have, to all distributive integration, either through ownership or through contractual arrangement, disintegration and-prohibition of further integration would tend to reduce [such] product differentiation barriers to entry" and would be highly desirable from the public's point of view. Id. at 217, 219. 75. Dealers handling the major brands generally find it quite profitable to take on additional "lines" of the product, the addition to revenues generally exceeding by a substantial margin the additions to cost. This is evidenced, of course, by the lengths to which the dominant manufacturers in these industries obviously go in order to keep their dealers "persuaded" of the virtues of an exclusive dealing policy, an effort that would hardly be necessary if the proffered policy was in fact consistent with those retailers' own self-interest. In other words, exclusive dealing is primarily in the interests of the manufacturers, not the dealers. 76. J. BAIN, ORGANIZATION, supra note 2, at 389. THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 18 appearances, a dominantly persuasive orientation, and this relative emphasis is generally greater as selling costs are larger in proportion to sales. Therefore, a substantial portion of all sales-promotion costs probably are socially wasteful in character, and this wastefulness is probably acute in industries in which selling costs are relatively high in proportion to sales revenue."" In his own study of 20 major American industries, Bain found that a fifth of them had an advertising/sales ratio of 5% or more and that "practically all industries with very high advertising costs (costs equal to 5 percent or more of sales revenue) are industries producing consumer goods. It is common to these industries that they have high or very high seller concentration, and that they have a strong product differentiation that is largely created by advertising, the opportunities for physical product differentiation (in design or quality) being rather limited." 8 He concluded that "all or most of the industries with relatively high advertising costs are seriously suspect of undesirable or 'unworkable' performance in the matter of selling costs, in the sense that wasteful promotional costs have exceeded the 'limit of tolerance' or 'margin for error' which should probably be allowed in making normative evaluations of the social desirability of market performance."" There are said to be a number of reasons why the antitrust laws either could not or should not be directed to the problem of monopoly pricing that flows from this kind of promotional effort, including the following: (1) advertising, both "informational" and "persuasive," is allegedly essential to the maintenance of full employment in the American economy and hence any legal restrictions aimed at reducing anticompetitive product differentiation would thus pose the danger of throwing the nation into a recession or depression; (2) both kinds of sales promotion are said to enjoy an absolute immunity under the first amendment's free speech guarantees and hence any action against the "ad-man" would be unconstitutional; (3) both kinds of sales promotion are allegedly essential to the maintenance of "free consumer choice" or "consumer sovereignty" and hence any legal action against either of them would necessarily have the effect of restricting the variety of products available to the consumer, of producing a drab uniformity of design and the like, not to mention the generally lower quality that could be expected to follow if "brand-name" rivalry were curtailed; and (4) it would allegedly be practicallyimpossible to distinguish, for purposes of 77. Id. 78. Id. at 391. 79. Id. 19681 MONOPOLY POWER antitrust case work, the desirable or pro-competitive forms of "informational" advertising from the undesirable, anticompetitive forms of "persuasive" advertising. Few reputable, informed economists harbor any of these fairly primitive notions. Consider, for example, the rather spectacular hypothesis implicit in the first one, the notion that the nearly $900billion-per-year American economy is kept on a full-employment course not by the constant, painstaking adjustments in fiscal and monetary policy made by the nation's duly authorized officials at the Federal Reserve Board, the Treasury Department, and the Council of Economic Advisers but by the unsolicited, purely private efforts of an unsupervised advertising industry's $20 billion budget. Bain gives the idea an unflattering two sentences, simply noting his "rejection of the oft-made but unsupported assertion that persuasive sales promotion is really needed to stimulate an expenditure of available purchasing power sufficient to sustain full employment and production in our enterprise economy. We deny, that is, the idea that we must have persuasive sales promotion to induce people to buy all the goods and services we are able to, or optimally should, produce." 0 In fact, consumer spending habits are not the problem at all in maintaining full employment (Americans consume approximately 93% of their income year-after-year, with quite reliable constancy); business spending for new plant and equipment is the really volatile factor in the employment equation, a factor that turns on the subjective "optimism" or lack of it of thousands of individual managers throughout the country and thus produces the wide "swings" in total expenditures from year-to-year that have to be offset or compensated for by fiscal and monetary expansion or contraction.' The second argument mentioned above, the idea that the first amendment gives an absolute immunity to advertising designed to persuade consumers that a product is "better" or "superior" to other products when this is not a fact-or that its "superiority" is greater than is the fact-is not likely to find wide currency among constitutional lawyers. Hundreds of "deceptive advertising" cases eloquently attest to the readiness of the courts to draw a sharp line indeed at the point where advertising becomes "unfair" to either the consuming public or to competing businessmen. Given the long line of cases sustaining the Federal Trade Commission's authority to stop advertising that amounts to an "unfair method of competition" 8 -that unfairly disadvantages 80. Id. at 389. 81. See generally, E. SHAPIRO, MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS 262 (1966). 82. See, e.g., Federal Trade Commission v. Winsted Hosiery Co., 258 U.S. 483 (1922). THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LA W REVIEW (Vol. 18 competing firms-the constitutional protection available to an advertising or promotional effort that can be shown to have caused a "substantial lessening of competition" or a "tendency to create a monopoly" (the tests under, for example, the anti-merger statute) would seem to be something less than impregnable. The notion that "product differentiation" is essential to the maintenance of a viable "consumer sovereignty" and "variety" of product is a particularly stubborn myth, one that is evidently nurtured with considerable diligence by some of monopoly's more articulate apologists. No proponent of a free market economy denies, of course, that the ultimate test of a product's "worth" is indeed the value placed on it by a fully-informed consuming public, one exercising an unrestrained "free choice." The truth of the matter is, however, that "product differentiation" restricts the consumer's choices, not enlarges them, that it produces less product "variety," not more. The same kind of "oligopolistic interdependence" that leads to the avoidance of price competition between rival oligopolists tends to produce, as noted above, a parallel policy in the area ofproduct competition. To be sure, members of the tight-knit oligopolies regularly turn out a profusion of seemingly different designs and qualities. In fact, however, those so-called differences are often a great deal more apparent than real, generally little more than surface variations in design or style that conceal a monotonous sameness in real performance characteristics. Bain comments, for example, that in a number of industries, including "the automobile industry, the highly imitative product policies of rival oligopolists seem to lead to substantialuniformity of available products and to a suppression of the potential variety in products which might be made available to buyers." 3 Meaningful product variety, like the other elements of desirable economic performance, stems from an effectively competitive market structure, not from industries that have been monopolized or-in the second half of the 20th century-oligopolized. To say, in short, that the consumer "chooses" Brand A over a lowerpriced but physically identical product is to engage in verbal judo, not serious analysis, since the necessary pre-condition for such a "choice" on the consumer's part is his or her unawareness of the physical identity of the two products; once that essential condition for successful product differentiation is gone, a new-and obviously more genuine-consumer choice appears, one that promptly reallocates that consumer's patronage away from the higher-priced product. As Turner puts it, "the consumer 83. J. BAIN, ORGANIZATION, supra note 2 at 401. 1968] MONOPOLY POWER is likely never to have been confronted with the real alternatives involved, and/or likely to be unaware of the long run consequences of the choices he makes at any particular time. The point can be made most clearly," he suggests, "by using the example of a completely standardizedproduct such as aspirin or chlorine bleach, where promotional expenditures have been heavily resorted to with evident success. In both instances consumers will pay a substantialpremium for heavily advertised brands. This of course reflects a consumer choice among the alternatives actually offered," but those consumers "were never given the opportunity to decide whether they wanted to be subjected to advertising expenditures or not." For example, suppose that, "before any producer of aspirin had undertaken promotional expenditures beyond the purely informational variety, consumers had been asked the following question: Which of the following alternatives would you prefer: (a) no advertising expenditures at all, so that every aspirin will in the long run continue to cost no more than one dollar per thousand; or (b) heavy advertising expenditures that will succeed in convincing you that you should pay three dollars per thousand for aspirin that is in fact exactly the same?"8 To ask the question is to answer it. The fourth argument mentioned above-that it would be impossible, in practice, to distinguish the "informational" and "persuasive" forms of advertising-is similarly somewhat less than overwhelming in the force of its logic. If the courts are competent to weigh and decide such genuinely heroic economic issues as whether a given merger is likely to have the future effect of "lessening competition" or "tending to create a monopoly"-and there seems to be considerable agreement among the informed professionals that the courts are in fact doing a quite creditable job in the merger areas8 -it is hardly an obvious proposition that they are incompetent to decide, with the help of expert economic testimony, whether a television advertising campaign spread on the record before them is likely to have the effect of "informing" its viewers of certain provable price and performance characteristics of the product in question or of "persuading" them of various non-provable claims that give it an imaginary "differentiation" and a higher price tag than the one carried by a number of physically identical products. Deciding whether a television commercial conveys information or noninformation is not likely to be regarded by professional economists, either now or in the 84. Turner, Conglomerate Mergers and Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 78 HARv. L. REv. 1313, 1334 (1965) (emphasis added). 85. See generally Mann, supra note 71. THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LA W REVIEW [Vol. 18 foreseeable future, as particularly taxing intellectual work. This is not to say, however, that there would be no difficult evidentiary problems involved in implementing a meaningful program against some of the more highly concentrated industries that owe their noncompetitive market structures to the "product differentiation" entry barriers produced by such non-informative advertising. The problems involved, however, would be the traditional ones of proving the "effects" alleged in the proceedings, particularly in detailing the "relevant market" involved; the "shares" held by the leading firms (individually and in the aggregate); the causal connection between the promotional expenditures challenged as "unfair," on the one hand, and the noncompetitive industry structure described by those market shares (particularly the height of the product differentiation barrier erected around them), on the other; and any number-of other equally challenging factual propositions. The question remains, of course, as to whether this particular kind of non-informational advertising, notwithstanding its proven capacity for creating highly concentrated markets and blunting or eliminating the more desirable forms of price and product competition, should nonetheless be permitted as a legitimate form of monopolization, one exempted under, say, the exception in favor of those who find monopoly "thrust upon" them, who "unwittingly find themselves in possession of a monopoly," who have survived by reason of "superior skill, foresight and industry" and who "do not seek, but cannot avoid, the control of a market.""6 Put another way, the question might be phrased as whether this kind of "competition"-and there can be no doubt that rivalry in promotional effort is indeed a form of competition-is within the range of those varieties the courts have, at least up until the present time, sustained even when they have had the paradoxical effect of lessening or eliminating "competition" itself.87 Certainly it can be demonstrated that this particular variety of noninformative promotion can produce-and has in fact produced-supercompetitive or monopoly prices (as in Figure 1, above) in many industries, a result that one would suppose is "unfair" to the consuming public, this latter conclusion resting, as it were, on a value judgment no more novel than the 86. United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F.2d 416 (2d Cir. 1945). 87. Under the price discrimination statute, for example, the Court has held that the "meeting competition" defense is available to the Price discriminator even in a case where it has been affirmatively established that the discriminatory price has, in fact, had the effect of lessening competition or creating a monopoly. Standard Oil Co. v. Federal Trade Commission, 340 U.S. 231 (1950). 1968] MONOPOLY POWER proposition that competition is preferable to monopoly or that there is no particular virtue in encouraging or permitting a non-functional "transfer" of income from the relatively poor (consumers) to the relatively rich (stockholders). Secondly, it can also be demonstrated rather profusely that this particular practice promotes "undue concentration," erects entry barriers, and otherwise excludes other businessmen, both actual and potential, from an "opportunity to compete" on the basis of economic efficiency, rather than on the size of the advertising budget or other species of "war chest"-again a presumably "unfair" competitive technique, one that is injurious to all of the values associated with, for example, small business, economic efficiency, and democratic pluralism. VI. CONCLUSION The devices for building "product differentiation" quite clearly could not survive a strictly economic test for measuring the social desirability of the several types of "competition." A practice that inflates the costs of consumer goods in so many ways-by producing large expenditures on non-informational, mutually-cancelling advertising, by acquiring and then exercising the power to add a supercompetitive profit "mark-up" on top of those inflated promotional costs, and by imposing on the smaller firms in the affected industries the higher production and distribution costs associated with inefficiently small volumes-is not likely to get high marks for social performance in the kind of tests used here. The major economic criterion for evaluating a particular variety of competitive rivalry turns on its relative contribution to the ultimate economic objective of providing the consumer with the maximum quantity of the goods most urgently desired at the lowest possible longrum prices (consistent with their continuing production). Price competition ranks first, of course, since it, by definition, assures that, in Professor Machlup's penetrating phrase, "the buyers gain all that the sellers give up.""5 A modified form of price competition, say one in which the sellers spend 2¢ for a trading stamp that entitles the consumer to perhaps 10 worth of gift merchandise, would rank second in social desirability, since it at least gives the buyers a part of "what the sellers give up." Other varieties of promotional expenditure, particularly those that cost the sellers themselves large sums of money but confer no discernible benefits on the buyers, are considered not merely "lacking in 88. Machlup, Oligopoly and the Free Society, I ANTITRUST L. & ECON. REV. 11, 18 (JulyAugust 1967) (emphasis added). THE AMERICAN UNIVERSITY LA W REVIEW (Vol. 18 any redeeming virtue" and thus valueless as a form of "competition," but a negative influence, one that puts the consumer and the economy as a whole in a worse position than the one they would have been in if there had been no competition at all in the industry. It may well be sound public policy to ignore noninformative promotions so long as they cause no clear and direct harm to the competitive mechanism itself. But where they have demonstrably "lessened competition" or set in motion an unmistakable tendency toward the high concentration ratios (tight-knit oligopolies) Congress was concerned about in the anti-merger and other statutes, they endanger not merely the nation's economic interests in a more abundant material welfare, but one of our more abiding democratic values as well, access to a genuinely free marketplace, one that is equally open to all, not just to a privileged few. A society struggling to meet a vast array of particularly pressing social needs, to bind up the wounds of its less advantaged members and win their abiding conviction of the essential justice of its central institutions, can ill afford the appearance of any new devices for monopolizing industrial markets, for "transferring" from the relatively poor to the relatively affluent each year a sum of money many times that required to make a meaningful beginning on the road toward the first great victory against man's most ancient enemy, the curse of poverty.