Market Failure or Governmental Failure: a Study of China’s Water Abstraction Policies 1. Introduction The understanding of water abstraction policies in China is worthwhile, both as an illustrative application of market-based instruments in a developing country, and as a case which sheds light on improving China’s water management system. China’s attempt to use market-based instruments (such as water abstraction charges) to ease water demand and supply tensions has been fairly unsuccessful. Through licensing water usage rights and levying charges for possessing the rights, the aim of central government was to allocate water resources efficiently and cut back water use, especially industrial water use. However, in reality the implementation results vary considerably across regions. Areas where water is not abundant continue in overdraft conditions, even though efforts have been made to allocate water user rights and to levy charges. Under increasing signs of water shortages and depletion, fundamental questions need to be asked about why these market-based instruments that help some countries solve water over-exploitation problems did not work as effectively at the local level in China. Answers to these questions are crucial for the analysis of water resources management in China. Current studies on applying market-based instruments in China mainly explain their ineffectiveness by market failure, referring to the market’s inability to assess the precise scarcity value of water resources. Due to this market failure, abstraction charges are often set too low and provide insufficient economic incentives for users to save water. Analysis by Wu (Wu 2003), for example, argues that the main problem with China’s abstraction policies lies in low abstraction charges and thus the government should increase them. On the other hand, Wang (Wang 2007) suggests that to avoid a direct valuation of water resources, the government should build a water right transfer market and thus the ‘price’ of water will simply vary according to market conditions. These policy suggestions reflect the limitations of market-based instruments generally faced by regulators around the world: the difficulties in setting a correct level of charges. But while there is considerably success in some countries, 1 the question of why these instruments fail at the local level in China remains unresolved. This paper takes a distinct institutionalist approach to study China’s market-based instruments towards water abstraction. Besides looking at the economic rationale of the instrument itself, it focuses more on the role of governments in establishing and maintaining a robust institutional framework which is a requisite for effective marketbased instruments. It suggests that due to underlying deficiencies in China’s existing water management system, including a lack of a clear definition of the targets for abstraction policies, a dual-responsibility system, and a lack of effective institutional processes for river basin management, local governments have been influenced to act differently from the regulatory expectation. In particular, this paper concludes that institutional deficiencies could impede efficient water management and cause local governmental failure in several ways: (1) a low level of water abstraction charges, (2) the lack of necessary monitoring and sanctions, (3) low incentives to collect charges diligently, and (4) failing to provide accessible information for the public. Due to this governmental failure, water users in China lack sufficient economic or political incentives to reduce water usage. The focus of the paper is on how to manage the lack of water quantity through using market-based instruments. While a huge amount of research has been concentrated on China’s water quality problems, water depletion is not attracting as much attention as it should. However, failures to take water depletion seriously or delaying action could result in enormous economic, environmental and social costs for both current and future generations. The remainder of the paper is organized into 3 sections: section 2 starts with a brief outline of the economic rationale for water abstraction policies. It also identifies limitations of the instrument. Section 3 first reviews the development of water abstraction policies in China and then focuses on the institutional deficiencies that can potentially lead to governmental failure and eventually the ineffectiveness of water abstraction policies. Finally, section 4 concludes the paper with some implications for China’s future water resources management. 2 2. Water abstraction charges (WACs) as a market-based instrument Levying charges (WACs) for taking water from various sources is considered as a cost-effective way to correct allocative distortions in the market system (Hahn 1989; Hearne and Easter 1997; Cowan 1998). Besides, WACs are often used to serve other objectives in practice, including as a revenue tool to recover administrative costs (in the UK) or to recover average total costs of water projects (in Australia), and as an incentive tool to shift consumption behaviour from groundwater to surface water (in the Netherlands). As we discuss below, the various combinations of objectives chosen by governments stem from the limitations in the market-based instrument itself and the various dimensions involved in a sustainable abstraction target. As a consequence, rather than seeking to employ quantification of externalities as a basis for design of policy instruments, a subjective evaluation of what is an acceptable and safe level of abstraction from the governments is a more pragmatic approach to applying market-based instruments in reality. The basic idea of WACs is that governments assess a charge on the amount of water that a user directly withdraws from surface (rivers and lakes) or ground (aquifers) sources. As profit-maximizing units, water users will respond by reducing abstraction to a point where their marginal abatement costs equal charge rates. The benefit of using WACs is that they allow the desired amount of abstraction reduction to be realized at the lowest overall cost to the society, as those who can achieve reductions most cheaply will make the greatest reductions (Stavins 2003). In theory, when properly designed and implemented, WACs encourage users to adopt cheaper and better water saving technologies, if a sufficiently low-cost method is available and adopted (Downing and White 1986; Malueg 1989; Milliman and Prince 1989; Jaffe and Stavins 1995; Jung, Krutilla et al. 1996). Despite the soundness of the theories, it is important to note the instrument’s drawbacks before applying it in the real world. One drawback lies in the uncertainties with regard to users’ reactions to incentive signals. This happens particularly when the abatement costs are uncertain, or the risks of adopting new water saving technologies are high (Smith 1995). Furthermore, water users’ decisions are also influenced by political or even cultural factors. Applying cultural theory, Hoekstra 3 (Hoekstra 1998) illustrates that different groups and societies have very different perspectives on water and thus different ways of managing it. For example, in the fatalist view, people believe that they are unable to control the future, thus the introduction of charges for water would not make sense (Hoekstra 1998). Under the charging system, it is therefore unrealistic for governments to guarantee a precise quantitative abstraction reduction. Another challenge of applying WACs is to identify the appropriate charge rates (Schiffler 1998; Stavins 2003). The ideal abstraction charges are often known as Pigouvian taxes, which were initially suggested by Pigou to reduce the disparity between what he called social and private net product (Pigou 1932). In the case of abstraction charges, Pigouvian taxes should be levied at a level that is equal in value to the negative externality costs of abstraction. This idea of Pigouvian taxes is prominent in the literature, but not undisputed (Schiffler 1998). For example, Coase (Coase 1960) notes that when transaction costs are low, it is more profitable for agents to make a bargain than having governments impose taxes. In addition, the application of Pigouvian taxes requires full identification of the negative externality costs and their value. This is extremely hard because of the lack of information. Although economists have devised indirect methods, such as hedonic pricing and contingent valuation methods, to measure externality costs, these methods all have shortcomings (Pearce and Turner 1990; Hanley, Shogren et al. 1997; Field 2000).1 Giving the difficulties in measurement, most economists agree that identifying the correct level of Pigouvian tax is nearly impossible (Baumol and Oates 1971; Pearce and Turner 1990; Schiffler 1998). In response, Baumol and Oates (Baumol and Oates 1971; Baumol and Oates 1988) have suggested an alternative approach, known as the standards and prices approach. In particular, they proposed that as the actual value of externality costs is unknown, setting a charge system should begin with establishing an arbitrary target of environmental quality. Baumol and Oates demonstrated that once a target of environmental quality was set, the use of charges to achieve specific targets does possess a least-cost optimality quality (Baumol and Oates 1971). As to the selection of appropriate targets, they described it as a process of collective and political 1 Take the Hedonic pricing approach for an example. As it uses variations in housing prices to reflect the value of local environmental attributes, the method only captures people’s willingness to pay for perceived differences in environmental attributes. In other words, if people are unaware of the linkages between environmental attributes of their properties, the value will not be reflected in house prices. 4 decision-making, which involves decision-makers’ subjective evaluation of what is an acceptable environment. In the case of water abstraction, decision-makers should identify a desired target of abstraction level before using it to set the corresponding WACs. Although Baumol and Oates’ approach did not provide a fundamental solution to the information and measurement problems of charge-setting, it does shift decision-makers’ focus to more pragmatic issues: developing an appropriate target as well as tailoring the rules to achieve the target. To define an appropriate abstraction target, decision-makers should take into account the needs of both the ecosystems and the social economic system. An abstraction target that is sustainable involves several dimensions, ranging from ecological protection, economic efficiency, ethical equity, to financial viability of the policies (Massarutto 2007). These dimensions of a sustainable abstraction target have very distinct focuses and should be addressed separately in the process of target development. In particular, ecological protection means that water use in a river system should be below its carrying capacity and maintains water-associated ecosystem services. Economic efficiency refers to water allocation to regions and industries which have the highest value output. Since access to water resources is a basic human right, ethical equity requires satisfying the water needs of everyone in the society (intra-generational equity), and ensuring that the rights of future generations to enjoy water resources is not infringed (inter-generational equity). Finally, financial viability of the policies looks at whether sufficient revenue is available to recover administrative costs and support research and development of new water-saving technologies. Although there are conflicts among these dimensions and sometimes trade-offs are necessary, decision-makers should always avoid emphasizing one dimension too much and jeopardizing others, because the consequent costs could be enormous. For example, abstraction targets solely based on equity concern would lead to setting a much lower level of abstraction charge, or completely exempting low income-groups or industries from paying any charges. This will easily induce over-consumption, thus reducing economic efficiency and causing permanent damage to the ecosystem in the long term. In sum, abstraction charges can be useful tools to correct allocative distortions in a market system, under the assumption that the correct level of charges can be set. But as calculating the ideal abstraction charges known as Pigouvian taxes is nearly impossible, government setting of a subjective definition of an appropriate 5 abstraction target becomes necessary. In order to develop the target, decisionmakers should consider both the ecosystems and the socio-economic system based on water resources, and keep a balanced view on the distinctive dimensions of sustainable abstraction. 3. China’s water abstraction policies 3.1 Background China’s demand for water resources has continued to increase over the last decade (Zhang 2001). Industrial demand for water nearly tripled between 1980 and 2007 (Department of Water Resources Management 2003). In some coastal provinces where there are more manufacturing factories, industrial water use has increased by more than 300 percent and its annual growth rate over 5 percent. Figure 1 shows that from 1997 to 2007, national industrial water use has increased by nearly 30 billion m3. Ironically, from the year 2002 when China’s new Water Law was promulgated, industrial water use began to jump sharply, due to the industrial boom in several provinces such as Jiangsu and Hunan. Moreover, total household water use has also gone up steadily, increasing by 37 percent, due to population growth and urbanization. In contrary to the increase of demand, the supply of water resources in China is relevantly unstable. Annual rainfalls are distributed unevenly across regions and seasons. And the situation can be worse due to the global climate change, which often manifests itself through the lack of rain water. As a result, around 400 of the 600 largest cities in China suffer from water shortages to various degrees (OECD 2007). According to official statistics, China’s estimated annual water deficiency is around 20 to 40 billion cubic meters, which is equivalent to the total amount of water usage in Guangdong Province in 2007, and it causes losses to industrial production reaching 230 billion RMB per year (Zhang and Zhou 2006). The shortage of water has resulted in conflicts between industry and agriculture, between urban and rural areas, and between regions (WET 2006). 6 Figure 1 China's industrial water and household water use changes water use (billion cubic meter) industrial use household use 140.00 120.00 100.00 80.00 60.00 40.00 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 Source: China Water Resource Bulletin 1997-2007 Note: Ministry of Water Resources publishes the water usage statistics based on the supply data from hydraulic projects. However, water withdrawn directly from sources is not included in the figure. Two signs of overdraft have also appeared which indicate that water overexploitation is worsening. First, increasing pumping costs, ground subsidence, soil salinity and saltwater intrusion caused by groundwater over-exploitation have been seen in more areas in China. 2 From 1997 to 2007, actual storage of shallow groundwater in the Northern plain has reduced by over 70 billion cubic meters and the average buried depth of deep groundwater also increased in most of China’s cities (China Ministry of Water Resources 2008). This continued over-extraction is a huge threat to the groundwater basins themselves, because eventually the gravel and sand in the water-bearing layer will compact so that it cannot hold as much water as it previously did. Getting groundwater in rural areas is reported to be more difficult and costly (China Ministry of Water Resources and Nanjin Hydraulic Research Institute 2004). In a recent survey of 73 villages from five provinces in China, over 60 percent of the interviewees believe that groundwater depletions have become a severe problem and have threatened their livelihoods3. This is because 2 Evidence on groundwater depletion and its impacts in China are contained in Ministry of Water Resources and Nanjing Hydraulic Research Institute (2004) pages 24 – 40. 3 See Li, Q., Y. Shen et al. (2005), page 96. These villages are in five provinces: Beijing, Henan, Ningxia, Inner Mongolia, and Shandong. A total of 547 questionnaires are collected. The five provinces chosen are known for their serious water shortage problems. The water availability per capita in these five provinces is even less than 1000 cubic meters. Yet, it is still shocking to find the serious impacts of water depletion on rural people’s livelihood. Another finding from the survey is that, 7 while using surface water for irrigation or watering stock animals, people in the villages generally relies on well water for drinking as it is less polluted. The second sign of overdraft is the serious drying-up of several rivers and the disappearance of lakes. In 2002, for example, the Hai River, the Liao River and the Yellow River, three of the main rivers in Northern China all suffered serious cut-off problems. And the mainstream of the Liao experienced cut-offs for as long as 158 days (China Ministry of Water Resources 2003). Nansi Lake, the biggest freshwater lake in northern China, was close to being completely dry (China Ministry of Water Resources 2003). Even officials from the Ministry of Water Resources have admitted that as water shortage problems worsen, it is urgent to re-examine the application of China’s fundamental water management policies: abstraction licence and abstraction charges policies (Huang and Gao 2002). As the tension grows, central government has to revert to planned engineering interventions such as building reservoirs and water transfer projects. As Table 1 shows, investments in water resource projects, which mainly include water supply projects and agricultural irrigational projects, jumped from 16.22 billion yuan in 2001 to 40.51 billion yuan in 2007 and became the largest part of the government investments in water conservancy projects. Table 1 China’s investments in water conservancy projects 2001 2007 56.07 94.49 % flood control projects 54.98 33.71 % water resource projects 28.93 42.87 Total investments(billion yuan, current prices): % soil, water conservation, and ecology protection 3.15 6.38 % hydropower project 5.37 7.04 % industry capacity building 5.01 0.94 % others 2.56 9.06 85136 85412 number of water reservoirs Source: Ministry of Water Resources (eds.), Statistic Bulletin on China Water Activities 2001, 2007, Beijing, China WaterPower Press due to the lack of surface water quality and quantity, over 42.7 percent of the villages depended on groundwater as a main source for irrigation in 2000 (page 74). 8 3.2 A brief review of the development of China’s water abstraction policies No instrument can be effective without the underlying institutions to support it. Institutions are important because they determine the process that defines a balanced abstraction target, the means by which the target is transformed into a concrete regulatory regime, and the mechanisms through which the regulations are enforced. In the context of China, although there were local attempts to use marketbased instruments towards water abstraction since the economic reform in 1978, their impacts varied considerably from area to area, indicating the important role of local institutions on water resource protection. In addition, while the central government had shown motivation to adjust water management institutions, the move was welcomed neither by departments that represented the interest of big industrial companies nor by protective local governments. In order to fully appreciate the nature of water abstraction policies in China, we should first understand these institutions in the historical context. Water abstraction licences and abstraction charges policies were first introduced by a few local governments in the late 1970s, purposely to curb groundwater depletions. This early implementation experience showed that abstraction policies tend to be more successful in cities than geographically larger areas such as provinces. Both Shanghai city and Shanxi Province, for instance, enacted regulations on groundwater abstraction policies in the early 1980s. While the amount of groundwater use in Shanghai city remained stable during the 1980s, Shanxi Province’s groundwater abstraction increased rapidly, causing several cities to experience serious land subsidence (China Ministry of Water Resources and Nanjin Hydraulic Research Institute 2004). The different implementation results could indicate the importance of institutional capacity on applying water abstraction policies (WAPs) effectively. WAPs in China were based on a self-reporting system and local authorities verified data reported by water users through checking internal data consistency and conducting surprise inspections. In cities like Shanghai, abstraction activities were more concentrated, thus applying abstraction policies there required less institutional capacity in terms of government’s ability to enforce, monitor, as well as sanction non-compliance activities. Compared with Shanghai city, the administrative area of Shanxi Province 9 was 25 times larger, and water users in Shanxi Province were smaller in scale as well as dispersed across the whole province. It would require a much stronger institutional capacity to achieve the same rate of compliance, which Shanxi Province did not have. Thus, the implementation results of the same instruments were poor. In 1988, water abstraction policies were introduced on a national scale, as the fundamental water management policies in China’s first Water Law (1988 Water Law, article 32, article 34). Despite previous mixed implementation results at the local level, abstraction policies were chosen probably because they were easier to fit into the existing institutional framework and thus countered less resistance. It was stated that individuals or companies that withdraw water directly from surface or ground sources over a certain limit should apply for a licence and pay the corresponding charges. The main targets of abstraction policies were industrial firms and water supply companies, as irrigation was exempted from paying abstraction charges. Provincial governments were given responsibility to design and implement regulations with local characteristics. Moreover, to justify local governments’ authority to approve abstraction licences, the Water Law asserted state ownership of water resources, subject to management by China’s governments (1988 Water Law, article 3). Thus the ‘water rights’ which could be obtained by industries referred only to user rights. Most of these provisions remained unchanged for the next 20 years and formed the basic framework for China’s abstraction policies. One positive in the 1988 Water Law was that it showed recognition of the need to manage water as a state-owned resource rather than as an open access resource. Water, as a resource, was no longer free to access or free of value. As a result, WAPs were introduced and the Ministry of Water Resources (MWR) was reorganized to take charge of China’s national water resource management together with its local water resources bureaus (WRBs). Moreover, seven river basin management committees were set up underneath MWR, one for each of China’s major basins, to coordinate water allocation across provinces. The institutional obstacle in this period, however, mainly lay in bureaucratic frictions. Although MWR and its WRBs were given responsibility to implement WAPs, authority was not fully removed from other sectors. At the local level, for example, there were at least two other bureaus, together with WRBs, involved in urban groundwater management. Conflicts arose in decision making because each bureau had its own interests and priority lists (Ke 1998; Liu, Wang et al. 2003). These conflicts eventually curbed 10 information sharing and hugely increased bureaucracy. In addition, bureaucratic frictions also extended to the central level. The inconsistency of the rules towards hydroelectric and thermal power plants belonging to central departments was a good example of this, indicating the discrepancy in interests between the MWR and the Ministry of Electricity and Industry.4 In 2002, two events marked China’s water history. First, as water shortages became more acute, especially in Northern China, the central government began the most controversial South-North Water transfer project, which aimed at diverting water from the Yangtze River to the Yellow River and the Hai River. Second, the State council promulgated a new national Water Law. These two events reflected the increasing urgency felt by the central government to take whatever steps possible to tackle water shortage problems. Developments have been made in strengthening the institutions concerned with WAPs since the 2002 Water Law. One significant step forward is the restructuring of China’s water administration system from a multisector administration into a more unified one (2002 Water Law, article 12). As a result, approvals of abstraction licences are now solely administered by the MWR and its WRBs. This has ended the long-term bureaucratic conflicts and has improved efficiency in decision-making. In addition, seven river basin management committees (RBMCs) have been given more administrative authorities (2002 Water Law, article 48). At the time of writing, all provinces, autonomous regions, and municipalities in China have enacted regulations with respect to abstraction policies (Hong Kong and Macao are excluded from this study). 4. The real issue: governmental failure Since local authorities are the main designers and managers of the water abstraction system, they should meet with new institutional requirements. Studies on water resource management find that an efficient institutional environment pools resources 4 In 1993, the Ministry of Electricity and Industry issued a circular to provincial governments stating that hydroelectric and thermal power plants must be exempted from abstraction licence and abstraction charge policies since the power production process did not actually consume water (Circular on Problems Concerning Levying Abstraction Charges and Reservoir Development Fees for Hydroelectric Power Plants, 1993). However, the Ministry of Water Resources immediately issued a circular in the same year to provincial governments renouncing the exemption of hydroelectric and thermal power plants (Circular on Collecting Abstraction Charges, 1993), stating that abstraction charge is a user fee applied to whoever uses the resources. It is not difficult to imagine the difficulties faced by provincial governments in designing these policies during this period. 11 and reduces risks. The same studies, however, show that inefficient institutional environments continue to be a constraint in developing countries (Russell and Powell 1996; O'Connor 1998). In China, despite the central government’s efforts in developing a regulatory system, there are still at least three evident and peculiar features in the present water management institutions which inevitably influence the effectiveness of WAPs: First, the absence of a clear definition of the targets for WAPs is an evident feature of China’s water management system. As discussed before, a subjective definition of an appropriate target that balances the distinctive dimensions of sustainable abstraction is necessary for setting abstraction charges. However, in reality the system and principles to identify abstraction targets in China require significant improvements. Particularly, the process through which local governments identify the maximum amount of abstraction licences allowable within their administrative areas is complex and inflexible, as well as making performance review difficult. Following the 2002 Water Law, the system of total abstraction quantity control (zong liang kong zhi) was introduced, which required that the amount of abstraction licences approved in a river basin or an administrative area not exceed the amount allowed by upper level authorities. In particular, basin-level water allocation plans are approved by the State Council first, in which the desired aggregate level of water abstraction for provincial governments is determined. Then on this basis, provincial governments fix systems of total abstraction quantity control for prefectures, based on provincial abstraction targets minus the quantity of abstraction licences issued directly by provincial WRBs. In the same way, prefectural governments fix systems of total abstraction quantity control for counties. It is not surprising that success of the system depends largely on the perfect cooperation among all levels of WRBs and the availability of reliable monitoring data, neither of which is common in China’s current case. In addition, the current system of total abstraction quantity control requires that central government is capable of identifying a clear and balanced abstraction target right from the beginning. However, targets fixed by the central government in the river basin-level water allocation plans are often unidentified and non-comprehensive. Take targets fixed in the 1987 Yellow River Water Allocation Plan as an example. Rather than giving a proportion of available flow, the plan used a fixed volume of water for each province as the abstraction targets for over 10 years, by assuming 12 that the river’s natural flows were constant every year (Table 2). The problem is obvious: it did little to respond to the climate variability along the Yellow River, let alone paying balanced attention to the various dimensions of sustainable water abstraction. Since in reality water flows fluctuated every year, it was impossible for provincial governments to identify proper abstraction targets from the allocation plan. Consequently, authorities gave out abstraction licences to anyone who applied. And actual water withdrawn in most of the provinces exceeded the targets set in the allocation plan (Zhang and Pan 2006). Unsurprisingly, these unidentified and noncomprehensive targets contributed to the more frequent and longer periods of river cut-offs along the Yellow River basin (Peng and Hu 2006; Zhang and Pan 2006). Table 2 water distribution in the 1987 Yellow River water allocation plan Province Amount (billion m3) Qinghai Sichuan Gansu Ningxia 1.41 0.04 3.04 4 InnerMongolia 5.86 Shaanxi Shanxi Henan Shandong Total 3.8 4.31 5.54 7 37 Another feature in China’s current water management institutions is the lack of an effective institutional process within the river basin management committees. The main issue with abstraction in river basins is that although abstractions are local activities, their effects entail both local water shortages and externality costs on other jurisdictions (Dinar, Rosegrant et al. 1997). Decentralized local governments have little control over the amount of water available within their own boundaries, as water availability depends on aggregate level of abstraction in other jurisdictions. Therefore, as long as political priorities and efforts to enforce water protection policies differ between regions, the effects of any individual policy on the river basin are bound to be limited. In order to achieve river-basin level optimality, there is consequently a need for an effective basin-based institutional process to facilitate the design and enforcement of abstraction policies. Through a basin-based institutional process, governments can co-operate and address abstraction at the basin level, including collecting hydrological data, researching interactions among various sources of water, forecasting meteorological events, evaluating monetary impacts of abstraction, proposing overall planning of water allocation, and fixing standards for abstraction charges. 13 In China’s current case, however, legislation does not provide a legal basis for the seven river basin management committees (RBMCs) to integrate an effective institutional process. This can be seen from several aspects: (1) RMBCs’ administrative rights are rigorously restricted to those prescribed by legislation. The 2002 Water Law stated that China’s water resources management is a combination of jurisdictional management and river basin management. In other words, RBMCs have to share river basin management authority and responsibilities with provincial governments. Fundamental authorities such as fixing levels of abstraction charges and collecting them, distributing funds to protect water resources, supervising or penalizing negative abstraction activities are not given to RBMCs. (2) RBMCs can only approve or reject plans of abstraction from main streams of the rivers, but have no authority over abstraction from tributaries or ground sources (Lohmar, Wang et al. 2003). Such an approach does little to facilitate integrated river basin management, because it runs counter to the principle that main streams, tributaries and groundwater sources in a river basin are closely interrelated. (3) RBMCs lack an inherent system to share and discuss critical information on abstraction with provincial governments, such as the annual amount of abstraction licences given by local authorities. As a result, it is nearly impossible for RMBCs to enforce systems of total abstraction quantity control. (4) Current legislation does not enable RBMCs to establish a commission of stakeholders from provincial, prefectural and county levels, or have consultative mechanisms to bring in voices of communities and non governmental organizations (NGOs) (Turner 2005). This greatly reduces the benefits of public supervision and participation in river basin management. Finally but not least, the dual-responsibility system in water administration remains a potential constraint to water management in China. The dual-responsibility system refers to the fact that provincial/prefectural (county-level) water resources bureaus (WRBs) are led by and responsible to both upper level WRBs and provincial/prefectural (or county-level) people’s governments. In other words, while receiving technical assistance and infrastructure investments from upper-level WRBs, local WRBs also depend on people’s governments for more funding to build and maintain water projects (Lohmar, Wang et al. 2003). Especially in recent years, dependence on local revenue has increased rapidly due to the worsened financial capacity of the central government (Hu, Wang et al. 1995; Wang 1997; China Ministry of Water Resources 2003; China Ministry of Water Resources 2008). As Table 3 shows, local revenue has overtaken central revenue, becoming the biggest 14 source of investments in fixed assets for water conservancy. In 2007, local investments account for over half of the total investments. 5 In fact, local governments tend to have far more authority over WRBs than their upper-level WRBs do, because they play a decisive role in appointments of senior officials at WRBs. Some research has shown that support from local governments has a pivotal role in the enforcement of environmental regulations in China (Lo and Fryxell 2005). Table 3 Investments in fixed assets for water conservancy 2005-2007 2005 2006 2007 Total investments (billion yuan, current prices) 82.74 93.27 102.65 % central 32.83 33.07 33.29 % local 48.14 47.34 52.08 % foreign 2.22 1.24 0.85 % domestic loans 9.85 12.01 8.40 % industries and private 5.20 3.10 3.03 % others 1.76 3.25 2.36 Source: Ministry of Water Resources (eds.), Statistic Bulletin on China Water Activities 2005, 2006, 2007, Beijing, China WaterPower Press The main problem with the dual-responsibility system lies in the fact that it separates WRBs’ responsibilities from their sector interests, making WRBs less independent and failing to have water resources protection as their sole purpose. As WRBs are directly led by local governments, their initiatives to protect water resources greatly depend on the “attitude” of local governments. Since the economic reform in 1978, however, local governments often have more incentive to prioritize economic growth above anything else. This is because, firstly, the central government evaluates the performance of local governments according to local output level (Yang 1990; Zhu 1992); secondly, as the decentralization of power is not fully guaranteed or stipulated by law, local protectionism emerges and local authorities tend to maximize their own short-term benefits (Long and Ng 2001). Most importantly, fiscal developments since the 1978 economic reform have gradually brought about local government’s growing pursuance of their own interests by asserting their own economic identity, as 5 Take the 2008 fourth quarter’s water conservancy investments as an example. According to data from the Ministry of Water Resources, the central government increased its water conservancy investments to 18 billion RMB in the quarter. Yet WRBs still need 16.8 billion RMB from local governments as supporting investments to implement the projects. Source: Ministry of Water Resources, 2008 fourth quarter increased investments from central government, http://www.mwr.gov.cn/ztpd/2009ztbd/jksljs/jztb/2009040716384448066a.aspx 15 provinces are cut off from central support and become economically self-reliant (Hendrischke and Feng 1999). Therefore, when abstraction policies contradict local governments’ pervasive “pro-growth” priorities, WRBs are required to make decisions that “take into account the overall economic situation” (Liu, Wang et al. 2003; Cao, Fang et al. 2008). It is not rare to read that local governments use exemption from abstraction charges as a preferential policy to promote trade and attract investments (Feng 2007; Wu 2007). If local WRBs insist upon exercising their responsibilities to protect water resources, they could be in opposition to the local governments, eventually affecting their own sectoral interests. Thus, this dualresponsibility system leaves WRBs in a relatively passive position. The lack of government support would easily force officials to seek refuge in a bureaucratic style, manifested in a strict adherence to the book or in the generation of meaningless paperwork in the course of regulatory enforcement (Braithwaite 1993). The implications of the above deficiencies are significant. They have given local governments more independence to deal with water abstraction activities from a local perspective. Amid the pervasive ‘pro-growth’ priorities at the local level, this independence could increase the possibility of governmental failure in formulating and maintaining the institutions to carry out abstraction policies effectively. In particular, this governmental failure is manifested in several ways in the local areas: • A low level of water abstraction charges; • The lack of necessary monitoring and sanctions; • Low incentives to collect charges diligently; • Failure to provide accessible information for the public. In the following sections, analysis will be focused on each of these aspects of local governmental failure. (1) A low level of water abstraction charges (WACs) As the central government did not provide a clear target of abstraction, it is therefore impossible for local government to design a levy system and set WACs based on any specific abstraction target. Instead, provincial governments are given the freedom to design the levy system and set WACs standards with local features. A common practice among provinces is to assess charges based on the actual 16 abstraction volume and a unit charge rate, which is determined by the types of users and abstraction sources. In general, levies for abstractions are calculated as follows: Vij × Rij Vij < Pij Pij × Rij + (Vij − Pij ) × E ij Vij > Pij Lij = where, for type of users i that withdraw water from source j , Lij is the total levies, Vij is the actual volume of water withdrawn, Rij is the unit charge rate, Pij is the volume of water permitted on the abstraction licence. If the actual abstraction exceeds the permitted abstraction, a progressively higher charge rate E ij is levied on the excess volume. Both R and E are set by provincial governments and vary by type of user and source of abstraction. Much more detailed guidelines on designing the levy system and setting WACs should be given to the provincial governments. At present, the only charge-setting principle given by central government to local governments is that both scarcity and ability to pay should be considered while fixing the abstraction charges (The 2006 Regulation on Management of Water Abstraction Licences and Water Resource Charge, article 29). Although the principle sounds equitable, it has limited applicability in provinces where an undeveloped economy coincides with water shortage. In fact, a large number of China’s provinces are in this position. Figure 2 illustrates the level of per capita surface water availability and GDP per capita by province in 2007. As we can see, provinces in the bottom left part of the graph suffer from both a low GDP per capita and low surface water availability per capita. On one hand, the lack of ability to pay requires provincial governments to fix a low level of abstraction charges; but on the other hand, the scarcity of water requires them to promptly increase the level of charges to curb depletion. In this context, the excessively general principle does not provide much guidance for provincial governments in setting charges, but creates the risk of governmental failure in favour of the local protectionism. 17 Figure 2 Surface water per capita and GDP per capita in 2007 Source: China Statistics Yearbook 2008, and 2007 China Water Resources Bulletin There are several studies indicating that some provincial governments have set WACs standards too low, and the WACs have lost their function as an economic lever (Liu, Wang et al. 2003; Cao, Fang et al. 2008). For example, being one of the most arid provinces in Northern China, Ningxia Province levied a charge rate at only 0.07 RMB per m3 for industrial abstraction from surface sources in 2006, which is lower than most of the other provinces in China. Without an efficient charge setting, the licence scheme provides companies little economic incentive to reduce water use. Instead, the bureaucratic application process for abstraction licences reduces the competitiveness of small privately owned enterprises and increases the possibility of rent seeking. (2) The lack of necessary monitoring and sanctions To ensure that water users would comply with the regulations, WAPs requires an accurate method for measuring water volumes as well as the regulators’ capacity to exercise sanctions. Water users’ compliance decision depends on a comparison of 18 the cost of compliance (abatement costs) with the possibility of getting caught as well as the expected penalty for non-compliance (Becker 1968). However, local WRBs often lack incentives to enforce compliance. One official from the Ministry of Water Resources, for example, admitted that the incentives for local WRBs to strengthen monitoring and exercise sanctions rely entirely on administrative decrees from upperlevel WRBs.6 Under the dual-responsibility system, however, upper-level WRBs face the principal-agent problem of how to ensure that local WRBs do their own job. Not surprisingly, while industrial development remains the top priority of local governments, there is an inhibiting effect on WRBs’ enforcement of monitoring and sanction. Table 4 Staff establishment in central and local water conservancy authorities 2001 Total number of staff (thousand people) Number of staff in MWR and its subordinated agencies (thousand people) Number of staff in local WRBs (thousand people) 2004 2007 1314 1182 1067.6 66 64 71.5 1249 1118 996.1 Source: Ministry of Water Resources (eds.), Statistic Bulletin on China Water Activities 2001, 2004, 2007, Beijing, China WaterPower Press In addition, monitoring and sanctions activities of the local WRBs may also be hindered by their limited capacities in terms of personnel and funding. Since China’s administration reform, there has been a continuing reduction in local WRBs’ personnel. Table 4 shows that while the number of staff in central water conservancy authorities increased, the WRB staff at the local level was reduced by one fifth between 2001 and 2007. One concern is with the insufficient personnel to enforce monitoring and sanctions at the street level. An officer from Shihezi city WRB in Xinjiang Province complained that there was only 1 staff member in charge of approving water abstraction licences and another 2 in charge of collecting abstraction charges for the entire region (Yang and Wang 2008). Another concern is the unavailability of sufficient funding to help small industries to install and maintain water meters. The current abstraction policies give no financial incentives or penalties to ensure that monitoring equipment is operating accurately. Companies are responsible for installing and maintaining monitoring equipment at their own cost. 6 Interview, 27 May 2009. 19 However, small-scale industries especially those managed by township and village governments tend to lack the support to invest, and most of them have been outside the control of WRBs and are hardly monitored at all. Lack of reliable monitoring data inevitably leads to serious accountability problems, which increases local WRBs officials’ discretionary power in identifying non-compliant water users, and raises the possibility of unlawful acts and other governmental failure. (3) Low incentives to collect charges diligently China’s current institutions do not adequately emphasize the supervision of its own governmental authorities. Under the dual-responsibility system, one consequence is the insufficient charge collection. In the 2002 Water Law, central government stated that revenues from abstraction charges should be delivered directly to treasuries, under administration by financial bureaus. At the same time, local WRBs receive funds separately from financial bureaus to cover administrative costs. This move to separate revenue from expenditure can reduce the initiative of local WRBs to collect charges diligently. Insufficient charge collection is a common phenomenon in many areas, particularly in remote and rural places (Wu 2003; Jin and Miao 2005; Cao, Fang et al. 2008). Kaifeng city in Henan Province, for example, reported to have collected in total 138.5 million RMB from abstraction charges in 2007 (Kaifeng Statistical Yearbook, 2008), However, according to published data, Kaifeng city should have collected at least 167.8 million RMB in abstraction charges from its water supply companies alone, which does not even include revenue from other direct withdrawing activities.7 In an interview, one local WRB staff said: “collecting more charges or less makes no difference for us.” Furthermore, as the ability of local WRBs to get administrative funds now depends more on the bargaining power of officials or their relationships with local governments, enforcement of WAPs become less independent. (4) Failure to provide accessible information for the public Public participation based on adequate information can increase the possibility for abstraction policies to achieve efficient outcomes. This is because local users tend to identify issues relating to local natural resources clearly and have relatively accurate 7 In 2005, Kaifeng people’s government adjusted its level of abstraction charge. In particular, public water supply for household usage was charged at 0.15 RMB/m3, and for other usage at 0.25 RMB/m3. According to Kaifeng Statistical Yearbook 2007, Kaifeng city’s total water public supply is 753.5 million tons, of which 205.5 million tons is for household usage and 548 million tons is for other usage. Therefore, abstraction charge revenue from public water supply companies alone should reach 167.8 million RMB. 20 information on local carrying capacity (Ostrom 1990; Dinar, Rosegrant et al. 1997). In addition, effective participation also leads to an adjustment of existing power relationships and reduces the possibility of governmental failures such as rentseeking behaviours (Ayres and Braithwaite 1992; Shen 2004). Research finds that when there is a deficiency of organized social forces, officials may adopt a much more flexible approach to enforcement (Sabatier and Mazmanian 1983; Scholz, Twombly et al. 1991; Lo and Fryxell 2005). One prerequisite for public participation, however, is to have a transparent institutional structure and accessible information (Dinar, Rosegrant et al. 1997). As to tackling the problems of water shortage, this is particularly important, as unlike other environmental problems that are immediately observable, water shortages are hard for the general public to sense. Currently, China’s legislation specifies neither the kind of information needed to be published nor the frequency of its publication. Indeed, most of the information is kept as internal resources by local authorities. Accessible information is either incomplete, brief, or uses inconsistent statistical standards. Very few enforcement results have been disclosed. For example, the amount of approved abstraction licences and abstraction charges revenues are often not made public in the annual reports. In the lack of information and thus the lack of public participation, accountability in the implementation process is almost non-existent. In addition, at the local level, the levy systems are designed in very different ways and their standards vary. When there is no system of accessible information, it is difficult for researchers to evaluate the impacts of WAPs. Consequently little advice could be given to improve the policies. 4. Implications This paper aims to shed light on reasons for the ineffectiveness of China’s WAPs. Striking evidence of water shortage indicates the urgent need for a review of WAPs’ design and enforcement in China. The paper argues that besides the limitations lying in designing water abstraction charges, three main deficiencies in China’s water management institutions work against the effective implementation of WAPs at the local level, creating a context where local governments deal with water abstraction activities from both a local and a short-term perspective. The implications are huge: although initially it was market that failed in allocating water resources efficiently, local governmental failure in the process of solving market failure becomes the main challenge for China’s governments now. As commitment from local governments to 21 WAPs enforcement remains weak, WRBs lack major contributing elements for implementation, increasing the possibility of governmental failure in formulating and maintaining the institutions to carry out WAPs effectively. While these results are not particularly surprising, this study goes some way towards revealing the manifestations of local governmental failure. It is observed that the level of water abstraction charges has been set too low to send enough economic incentives for industries to save water. It is also found that under the dualresponsibility system, local WRBs appears to lack political incentives to enforce compliance because they are under substantial pressure to ensure enforcement will not contradict the development strategy of local government. With limited personnel and budget, monitoring and sanctions activities are seen to be hindered. In addition, local WRBs’ initiative to collect charges diligently is reduced significantly because of the central government’s move to separate revenues from expenditures. Most critical of all, China’s current legislation has discouraged public participation, because the lack of accessible information. In summary, there is a need for more institutional changes in the way water is managed in China, from jurisdictional management to integrated river basin management, from emphasizing short-term output to focusing on long-term benefits of a stable water ecosystem, from government-based water allocation to government-led community-based water allocation. Reference: Ayres, I. and J. Braithwaite (1992). Responsive Regulation: Transcending the Deregulation Debate. New York Oxford University Press. Baumol, W. and W. E. Oates (1971). "The use of standards and prices for protection of the environment " The Swedish Jornal of Economics 73(1): 42-54. Baumol, W. and W. E. Oates (1988). The Theory of Environmental Policy. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Becker, G. S. (1968). "Crime and punishment: an economic approach." Journal of Political Economy 76(2): 169-217. 22 Braithwaite, J. (1993). The Nursing Home Industry. Beyond the Law: Crime in Complex Organizations M. Tonry. Chicago, University of Chicago Press. Cao, Y., G. Fang, et al. (2008). "Present situation and reform countermeasures of collection and utilization of water resources fee in China." Journal of Economics of Water Resources 26(3): 26-29. China Ministry of Water Resources (2003). 2002 China Water Resources Bulletin. Beijing, China WaterPower Press. China Ministry of Water Resources (2003). 2002 Statistic Bulletin on China Water Activities, China WaterPower Press. China Ministry of Water Resources (2008). 2007 China Water Resources Bulletin. Beijing, China WaterPower Press. China Ministry of Water Resources (2008). 2007 Statistic Bulletin on China Water Activities. Beijing, China WaterPower Press. China Ministry of Water Resources and Nanjin Hydraulic Research Institute (2004). China's Groundwater Exploitation and Conservancy in the beginning of 21st Century Beijing, China WaterPower Press. Coase, R. H. (1960). "The problem of social cost." Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1-44. Cowan, S. (1998). "Water pollution and abstraction and economic instruments." Oxford Review of Economic Policy 14(4): 40-49. Department of Water Resources Management, M. o. W. R. (2003). Summary on China's National Water Conservation Plan and Its Research. Nanjin, Hohai University Press. Dinar, A., M. W. Rosegrant, et al. (1997). "Water allocation mechanisms: principles and examples." World Bank Policy Research Working Paper NO. 1779. Downing, P. B. and L. J. White (1986). "Innovation in pollution control." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 13(1): 18-29. Feng, H. (2007). "Reflection on collecting water abstraction charge according to legislations in Dezhou city." Shandong Water Resources 2007(1): 54-57. Field, B. (2000). Natural Resource Economics. Boston, McGrawHill/Irwin. 23 Hahn, R. W. (1989). "Economic prescriptions for environmental problems: how the patient followed the doctor's orders." Journal of Economic Perspectives 3(2): 95-114. Hanley, N., J. F. Shogren, et al. (1997). Environmental Economics in Theory and Practice. Basingstoke, Macmillan. Hearne, R. and W. Easter (1997). "The economics and financial gains from water markets in Chile." Agricultural Economics 15(3): 187-199. Hendrischke, H. J. and C. Feng (1999). The Political Economy of China's Provinces: Comparative and Competitive Advantages. London, Routledge. Hoekstra, A. Y. (1998). "Appreciation of water: four perspectives." Water Policy 1(6): 605622. Hu, A., S. Wang, et al. (1995). Report on Regional Disparities in China (zhongguo diqu chaju baogao). Shenyang, Liaoning Renmin Press. Huang, J. and E. Gao (2002). The interpretation of 2002 Water Law. Standing Committee of the National People's Congress and the Ministry of Water Resources. Jaffe, A. B. and R. N. Stavins (1995). "Dynamic incentives of environmental regulation: the effects of alternative policy instruments on technologyl diffusion." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 29(3): S43-S63. Jin, L. and Z. Miao (2005). "Several problems in water abstraction charges collection, management and the reform measures in Liaoning Province " Liaoning Economy 2005(8): 48-49. Jung, C., K. Krutilla, et al. (1996). "Incentives for advanced pollution abatement technology at the industry level: an evaluation of policy alternatives." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 30(1): 95-111. Ke, L. (1998). China's Water Law and Water Management. Beijing, China WaterPower Press. Liu, W., G. Wang, et al. (2003). "Investigation report on water resources fee collection management." China Water Resources 2003(A03): 26-29. 24 Lo, C. W.-H. and G. E. Fryxell (2005). "Governmental and societal support for environmental enforcement in China: an empirical study in Guangzhou." The Journal of Development Studies 41(4): 558-588. Lohmar, B., J. Wang, et al. (2003). "China's agricultural water policy reforms: increasing investment, resolving conflicts, and revising incentives." Agricultural Information Bulletins number 33643. Long, G. and M. K. Ng (2001). "The political economy of intra-provincial disparities in postreform China: a case study of Jiangsu province." Geoforum 32(2001): 215-234. Malueg, D. A. (1989). "Emission credit trading and the incentive to adopt new pollution abatement technology." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 16(1): 52-57. Massarutto, A. (2007). Abstraction charges: how can the theory guide us? OECD Expert Meeting 'Sustainable Financing for Affordable Water Services: From Theory to Practice'. Paris. Milliman, S. R. and R. Prince (1989). "Firm incentives to promote technological change in pollution control." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 17(3): 247-265. O'Connor, D. (1998). "Applying economic instruments in developing countries: from theory to implementation." Environment and Development Economics 4(1998): 91-110. OECD (2007). OECD Environmental Performance Reviews: China. Paris, OECD Publishing. Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the Commons: the Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Pearce, D. and K. Turner (1990). Economics of Natural Resources and the Environment. Baltimore, The Johns Hopkins University Press. Peng, X. and H. Hu (2006). "Evaluation on Allocation System of Available Water or the Yellow River." Yellow River 28(4): 41-43. Pigou, A. (1932). The Economics of Welfare. London, Macmillan & Co. Russell, C. and P. Powell (1996). Choosing Environmental Policy Tools: Theorectical Cautions and Practical Considerations. Washington, D.C., Inter-American Development Bank. 25 Sabatier, P. A. and D. A. Mazmanian (1983). Can Regulation Work? The Implementation of the 1972 California Coastline Initiative. New York, Plenum. Schiffler, M. (1998). The economics of groundwater management in arid countries: theory, international experience and a case study of Jordan. London, Frank Cass Publishers. Schneider, F. G. and J. Volkert (1999). "No chance for incentive-oriented environmental policies in representative democracies? A public choice analysis." Ecological Economics 31(1): 123-138. Scholz, J., J. Twombly, et al. (1991). "Street-level political controls over bureaucracy." American Political Science Review 85: 829-850. Shen, D. (2004). "The 2002 Water Law: its impacts on river basin management in China." Water Policy 6(4): 345-364. Smith, S. (1995). 'Green' taxes and charges: policy and practice in Britain and Germany London, Institute for Fiscal Studies. Stavins, R. N. (2003). Experience with market-based environmental policy instruments. Handbook of Environmental Economics. K.-G. Mäler and J. R. Vincent. Amsterdam, Elsevier Science B.V. 1: 360. Turner, J. L. (2005). "River Basin Governance in China." China Environment Forum 7: 106110. Wang, R. (2007). "Conceptualizing the development of water rights in China." US-China Law Review 4(5): 25-37. Wang, S. (1997). Challenging the Myth of Market: the Role of State in Economic Transition (tiaozhan shichang shenhua: guojia zai shichang zhuanxing zhong de zuoyong). Hong Kong, Oxford University Press. WET (2006). Water Entitlements and Trading Project (WET Phase 1) Final Report, Beijing: Ministry of Water Resources, Canberra: Department of the Environment, Water, Heritage and the Arts. Wu, M. (2003). "Jiangxi water abstraction charge's status quo, existing problems and scientific standards." Prices Monthly 2003(2): 22-24. 26 Wu, q. (2007). "Suggestions on water abstration charge collection in Haozhou city " Jianghuai Water Resources Science and Technology 2007(5): 40-41. Wu, S. (1999). "Thoughts and suggestions on re-enforcing the management of ground water in Liuzhou City." Guangxi Water Resources & Hydropower Engineering(2). Yang, D. (1990). "Patterns of China's regional development strategy." The China Quarterly 122: 230-257. Yang, Z. and J. Wang (2008). "Collecting water abstraction charges: problems and solutions " China Water Transport 8(192-193). Zhang, J. (2001). China's sustainable development strategy research. Beijing, China Agriculture Press. Zhang, Q. and Y. Zhou (2006). Regulation on management of water abstraction licences and water resource charges explanation. Beijing, China WaterPower Press. Zhang, X. and Q. Pan (2006). Yellow River Basin water resource research and evaluation. zhengzhou, Yellow River Zhu, L. (1992). "Ill-balanced regional economic relations: symptons, mechanism and remedy strategy (quyu jingji guanxi shitiao: zhengzhuang, jili he zhengzhi fanglue)." Research on Economics and Management (jingi yu guanli yanjiu) 2(5-9): 50. 27