IN THE SUPREME COURT OF FLORIDA CASE NUMBER: 65,124 3RD DCA CASE NUMBER: 81-1369 THE CELOTEX CORPORATION, Petitioner, vs. LEE LLOYD COPELAND and VAUDEEN COPELAND, Respondents. BRIEF OF AMICUS CURIAE PITTSBURGH CORNING CORPORATION , STEPHENS, LYNN, CHERNAY, KLEIN & ZUCKERMAN, P.A. One Biscayne Tower, Suite 2400 Miami, Florida 33131 (350) 358-2000 BY: ROBERT M. KLEIN, ESQ. CARON E. SPEAS, ESQ. IN THE SUPREME COURT OF FLORIDA CASE NUMBER: 65,124 3RD DCA CASE NUMBER: 81-1369 THE CELOTEX CORPORATION, Petitioner, vs. LEE LLOYD COPELAND and VAUDEEN COPELAND, Respondents. BRIEF OF AMICUS CURIAE PITTSBURGH CORNING CORPORATION r STEPHENS, LYNN, CHERNAY, KLEIN & ZUCKERMAN, P.A. One Biscayne Tower, Suite 2400 Miami, Florida 33131 (350) 358-2000 BY: ROBERT M. KLEIN, ESQ. CARON E. SPEAS, ESQ. TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction------------------------------------------------1 Statement of the Case and Statement of Facts----------------2 Certified Question------------------------------------------4 Argument----------------------------------------------------5 FLORIDA SHOULD NOT ADOPT THE MARKET SHARE THEORY OF LIABLITY Conclusion--------------------------------------------------35 Certificate of Service--------------------------------------36 • TABLE OF CITATIONS CHENOWITH v. KEMP 396 So.2d 1122 (Fla. 1981) ---------------------------~1 CITY OF NEW SMYRNA BEACH UTILITIES COMPANY v. McWHORTER 418 So.2d 261 (Fla. 1982)-----------------------------~1,12 COLLINS v. ELI LILLY & COMPANY 342 N.W.2d 37 wis. 1984)-------------------------------31 CONE v. INTERCOUNTY TELEPHONE & TELEGRAPH CO. 40 So.2d 148 (Fla. 1949) ------------------------------17,18 GOODING v. UNIVERSITY HOSPITAL BUILDING 445 So.2d 1015 (Fla. 1984)-----------------------------18 GOODYEAR TIRE & RUBBER COMPANY v. HUGHS SUPPLY, INC. 358 so.2d 1339 (Fla. 1978)-----------------------------10,11 HANNON v. WATERMAN STEAMSHIP CORPORATION 567 F.Supp. 90 (E.D.La. )-------------------------------31 HOFFMAN v. JONES 280 So.2d 431 (Fla. 1973)------------------------------5 IN RE RELATED ASBESTOS CASES 543 F.Supp 1152 (N.D.Cal. 1982)-------------------------31 MERTAN v. E.R. SQUIBB & SONS, INC. 190 Cal.Rptr. 349 (App. 1983) -------------------------19,20 MIZELL v. ELI LILLY & COMPANY 526 F.Supp. 589 (D.S.C. 1981)--------------------------31 MORTON v. ALBERT LABORATORIES 538 F.Supp. 593 (S.D.Fla. 1982)------------------------31 MYLES LABORATORIES v. SUPERIOR COURT, etc. 184 Cal.Rptr. 98---------------------------------------19 NAMM v.CHARLES E. FROSST & COMPANY 427 Atl.2d 1121 at 1129 (N.J.App. 1981)----------------34 PATENT v. ADVERT LABORATORIES 437 N.E.2d 171, ~ass. 1982-----------------------------31 RYAN v. ELI LILLY & COMPANY 514 F.Supp. 1004 at 1017 (D.S.C. 1981)-----------------14,31 SINDELL v. ABBOTT LABORATORIES 607 P.2d 904 (Cal. 1980)------------------------------~6,7,9, 10,12,15,14,16,19,21,22, -ii- 23,25 SPEISER v. RANDALL 357 u.S. 513 (1958)------------------------------------13 STARLING v. SEABOARD COASTLINE RAILROAD COKMPANY 533 F.Supp. 183,190 (Ga. 1982)-------------------------5,14,31,34 STATE v. HAYES 333 So.2d 51 (Fla. 1976)-------------------------------5 STUART v. HERTZ 351 So.2d 703 (Fla. 1977)------------------------------~6,27 SUMMERS v. TICE 199 P.2d 1 (Cal. 1948)---------------------------------8,9 THOMPSON v. JOHNS-MANVILLE SALES CORPORATION 714 F.2d 581 (5th Cir. 1983)---------------------------31 WEST v. CATERPILLAR TRACTOR COMPANY INC. 336 So.2d 80 (Fla. 1976)-------------------------------~4,15 YBARRA v. SPANGARD 154 P.2d 687 (1944)-------------------------------------8,9 Miscellaneous Citations: Fischer, Products Liability, An Analysis of Market Share Liability, 34 Vanderbuilt L.Rev. 1623 at 1646 (1981)------------------21 Chase, Market Share Liability: A Plea for Legislative Alternatives, 1982, No.4, V.P., Il1.L.Rev. 1003 (1982)-------------------23,28 Necomb, Market Share Liability for Defective Products: An Ill-Advised Remedy for the Problem of IJentification, 76 N.W.--------23,28 300 U.L.Rev. 1981 Prosser, Law of Torts, §41, (4th Ed., 1971)--------------------------18 Winscott, "Where Have All the Burdens Gone," 8 Western State Law Review, 223 at 230 (1981)------------------------7 -iii- INTRODUCTION Amicus Curiae PITTSBURGH CORNING CORPORATION was a nominal Appellee by operation of the Rules companion COPELAND matter. of Appellate Procedure in the That matter is still pending on rehear- ing before the Third District Court of Appeal. In this instance, PITTSBURGH CORNING CORPORATION has been allowed to file br ief in support of the position of the Peti tioner, an amicus pursuant to an order of this Court which was entered on April 23rd, 1984. Petitioner a Codefendant CORNING in this CORPORATION the companion and VAUDEEN OWENS-CORNING trial and COPELAND the court other matter. COPELAND were the FIBERGLASS action, CORPORATION along with Defendants Respondents Plaintiffs who LEE before are was PITTSBURGH named LLOYD In COPELAND the trial court. In this brief, the parties will be referred to as Petitioners/Defendants and Respondents/Plaintiffs, as well as by name. All emphasis has been indicated to the contrary. -1- supplied by counsel, unless STATEMENT OF THE CASE AND STATEMENT OF FACTS The facts of this case have been adequately summarized decision of the Third District Court of Appeal, which have been submitted Nevertheless, amicus it would appropriate In order be to particularly on behalf of PITTSBURGH CORNING to certain relevant to the petitioning briefly aspects of arguments the the and in the briefs CORPORATION elaborate emphasize the in parties. believes upon those that facts case which will which will be be presented by PITTSBURGH CORNING CORPORATION. In liabili ty, Complaint, negligence dismissed dents' their four and times, Respondents breach and was of pled theories warranty. amended The of strict Complaint was on each occasion. Respon- Complaint was repeatedly dismissed as a result of the COPE- LAND'S failure to specifically identify those products which allegedly caused were used, suggests pated" harm, the or where in by its specif ic manufacturers, they were used. Plaintiffs, they the products Al though the Third District opinion that market the when share liability was did not in fact sent to plead "anticia market share liability theory of recovery. In interrogatories which were Defendant CELOTEX CORPORATION asked MR. product to which he had been exposed. the Plaintiffs, COPELAND to identify each Plaintiff identified products manufactured by JOHNS-MANVILLE CORPORATION and EAGLE-PICHER CORPORATION. In his JOHNS-MANVILLE manufacturers MR. deposition, MR. CORPORATION and of asbestos COPELAND once EAGLE-PICHER products again identified CORPORATION to which he had as the been exposed. COPELAND had no recollection whatsoever of having been exposed -2- « to a CELOTEX product. "I don't remember using any products manufac- tured by (Deposition Thus, it Celotex." aff irmati vely appears of that Copeland, L.L. Plaintiff could Page 255). identify the products of some--but not all--Defendants. In their initial brief, which was filed in the Third District Court of Appeal on September 9th, 1981, Plaintiffs argued that the the dismissal failure MR. trial court had erred in dismissing purportedly been their based upon Complaint the where Plaintiffs' to identify any products manufactured by CELOTEX to which COPELAND had been exposed. Plaintiffs argued that this was error to the extent that there had been testimony which suggested that the Plaintiff had in fact been exposed to CELOTEX products. In court had response, been Defendant correct in CELOTEX dismissing argued the that the Complaint trial because it failed to plead ultim~~e facts as to product identification sufficient to support causes of action for strict liability, negligence or breach of warranty. Thus, according to CELOTEX, MR. COPELAND could not under any circumstances allege or prove any other element of his cause of action simply because he had failed to identify any products manufactured by CELOTEX. It is clear from this brief synopsis that neither the Appellant nor the Appellee below addressed the market share theory of liability. adopted market Nevertheless, share the liability, Third and this Court for resolution. -3- District certified Court the of Appeal question to CERTIFIED QUESTION WHETHER .FLORIDA SHOULD THEORY OF LIABILITY ADOPT -4- THE MARKET SHARE ARGUMENT FLORIDA SHOULD NOT THEORY OF LIABILITY Before policy ln and this wi th venturing practical instance, the Third ADOPT into a THE discussion considerations PITTSBURGH District's MARKET which CORNING suggestion of are would that SHARE the myriad before initially it was the Court take issue "venturing an area not yet explored by the Florida Supreme Court .... " decision, Page 9 at Note 5. from even a on behalf Third of cursory of all District's issues which COPELAND the briefs which will be submitted Petitioner decision have into To the contrary, as will become obvious review of parties of in been fact and the plays thoroughly various havoc amicus, with any "explored"--and resolved--by this Court in prior opinions. the number otherwise Under the circumstances, and particularly in light of the fact that all the circuit courts of this state are currently bound by the Third District's opinion, see STATE v. would have HAYES, respectfully refrained 333 So. 2d submi t from that adopting 51 (Fla. 1976), the Third District should properly this radical See HOFFMAN v. JONES, 280 So.2d 431 (Fla. The cannot importance be overstated. of The PITTSBURGH CORNING this of liability. in this 1973). Court's issues theory decision case presented to the Court by this appeal go beyond the rights and duties existing between the parties. Whether or not the state of Florida recognizes the theory of market share liability may well have a far reaching impact upon the economic system of LINE RAILROAD our entire COMPANY, nation. 533 See F.Supp. -5- STARLING v. 183, 190 (Ga. SEABOARD 1982) COAST wherein the court recognized culpability Pandora's In that product Box liability of . undesirable STARLING court rejected in asbestos "judicial the litigation. policy cases may economic and decisions to result opening in social effects." application of market share See also SINDELL v. expand a The liability ABBOTT LABORATORIES, 607 P.2d 904 (Cal. 1980), dissenting opinion at Page 943. When market the share Third theory of District Court liability supra, interpretation principle an old Appeal introduced Supreme Court in SINDELL, of of by embraced the the California it did not merely endorse a novel of law. To the contrary, it undermined the very foundation of tort liability as it has existed since before the birth of this nation. i ty is an anomaly Anglo-Norman of our means common-law responsibility, the in courts law of "wrong. " fault or fifty torts, For jurisprudence, the of the Indeed, market share liabil- the since the word first time the concept of wrongdoing states. is in "tort" the in history liability without under consideration by That fact alone should be cause for alarm. The defendants in the SINDELL case were several manufacturers of the drug Diethylstilbestrol in the children of widely used from DES was later found to cause 1947 to 1971 to prevent miscarriage. adenocarcinoma (DES), women who had taken the drug. The plaintiff in SINDELL was the daughter of a DES user. Because - DES-related until twenty to twenty-five cancer years does from the not manifest time that itself the drug is ingested, it is difficult to identify the particular manufacturer of the DES which allegedly caused -6- injury. It was purportedly .. for this market the reason share that the liability plaintiff court which, to ,identify in in the SINDELL effect, adopted made it defendant whose the theory unneces sary product caused of for her injuries. Under only show (1) defective or the market that each dangerous; to anyone produced a (2) product; and (4) that theory, marketed the a products plaintiff product of the need that was defendants so that the product could not be attribu- defendant; "substantial liability defendant were identical in formula, table share (3) that percentage" the of defendants the total collectively market for that the plaintiff had suffered damage. that WINSCOTT, "Where Have All the Burdens Gone," 8 West S.L.R., 223 at 230 (1981). Once these share to a burden show the threshold that shifts they Plaintiff's producer questions can to did the not injuries. be held have been individual resolved, named the Thus, possibility liable even though product his market Defendants, manufacture the the which i.e., caused remains product may that not have caused any harm whatsoever to the plaintiff. There are two primary reasons why market share liability is wholly unacceptable of liability is of jurisprudence. as a theory inconsistent with In addition, of recovery. and offensive however, First, to our the basis principles any practical application of the theory would be impossible, uncertain and inequitable. MARKET SHARE LIABILITY IS OFFENSIVE TO OUR FUNDAMENTAL NOTIONS OF JUSTICE AND BASIC TENETS OF FLORIDA JURISPRUDENCE Courts and commentators are once again waging the classic debate over shifting the burden of -7- proof from plaintiff to defen- dant. On instances prior occasions, this where circumstances debate made has it arisen impossible in those for an rare injured plaintiff to obtain relief because he could not identify the culpable the party. In courts have the past, in response cautiously--albeit to such which of recovery essentially such place as the res situations, rarely--shifted of proof from the plaintiff to the defendant. theories rare ipsa burden the burden As a result, limited loquitur upon the are available, defendant to show that he did not cause the plaintiff's injuries. The of the v. TICE, theory alternative of market liability 199 P . 2d I, ( Ca 1. share theory 1948). liability first 1S a established In that case, variation in SUMMERS two hunters were shooting at quail simultaneously in the direction of the plaintiff. The court held that both hunters were negligent and that each was liable for the plaintiff's injury. EY "The injured party has been placed Defendants in the unfair position of pointing to which was the one that caused the harm. Ordinarily defendants are in a far better position to offer evidence to determine which one caused the injury." From the court context believed of the that it decision, was it is essentially clear that the considering a SUMMERS res ipsa relied upon situation. In YBARRA v. SUMMERS, SPANGARD, the 154 California P.2d 687 Supreme (1944). In Court YBARRA, the court allowed a patient to recover using the theory of res ipsa loquitur, which put the had caused of burden on the defendant the patient's injuries. -8- doctors to establish which It is clear that the court allowed the patient to avail himself of the res ipsa doctrine because the patient had been unconscious at the time of the alleged negligence. If the doctrine is to continue to serve a useful purpose, we should not forget that the particular force and justice of the rule ... consists in the circumstance that the chief evidence of the true cause ... is practically accessible to defendants, but inaccessible to the injured person. Supra at 689. Thus, the be a in SUMMERS better and YBARRA position cases than the require plaintiff that the to offer defendants evidence on the causation issue. It negligent should also be pointed out that all of the allegedly Defendants were YBARRA law sui ts. This before the court, and joined assured (2) as (I) that parties that the each party in the SUMMERS and actual wrongdoer was having the wherewithal to prove causation had the incentive to do so. In contrast, in the DES drug cases like SINDELL, it is actually the plaintiff who is in the best position to determine the identity of the actual The wrongdoer. has had actual contact with the drug, plaintiff's mother and may know where she pur- chased it, or what the packaging or pill looked like. The manufac- turer, on the ultimate users and, the identity of the the other hand, therefore, manufacturer has is of in the had no drug no contact with position to prove which allegedly with equal caused harm to the plaintiff. This cases. rationale applies And more important, force in aSRestos under the SINDELL market share theory, there is no guarantee that the actual wrongdoer is even a defendant -9- in the lawsuit, since the only requirement is that the plainti f f join a "substantial percentage" of the market. In connection Rather, SINDELL, had the of time. to prove nothing failure Given its cannot of plaintiff I s whatsoever that fact, liability say that inability to to do with prove the a causal defendants. proof was merely the result of the passage the defendant is "non-negligence," an alternative one the and theory the of the in no better position rationale which underlies recovery does defendant's not negligence exist, had i.e., anything to do with the fact that the plaintiff is now unable to prove causation or product identity. Nor is the defendant in a better than the plaintiff to carry the burden of proof. position This is in stark contrast to the equitable basis which may otherwise support application in of a those res ipsa instances loquitur one may theory in reasonably any argue given that action, the since plaintiff I s injuries could only have been caused by the defendant's negligence. Further, in those cases, the defendant is truly in a better position to prove otherwise. In INC. , 358 concern the GOODYEAR So.2d for 1339, the principle AND 1341 (Fla. 1978), this gloss" which had "judicial of res ipsa RUBBER COMPANY TIRE loquitur. v. Court been Because of HUGHS expressed developing these is to be utilized unavailable to the of only the injuring IL. i. e., where plaintiff incident." its over concerns, the HUGHS SUPPLY court determined to restore res ipsa to its torically proper balance, SUPPLY "his- the doctrine of res ipsa loquitur "direct evidence due the to Even wi thin -10- of unusual those negligence is circumstances bounds, this Court admonished that res ipsa "is a doctrine of extremely limited applicabili ty," which should only be applied where the plaintiff's injuries could only have been caused by the defendant's negligence. Supra at pages 1341 and 1343. Where a market share theory is applied, it is the evidence of the identity of the wrongdoer which is unavailable to the plaintiff, not evidence therefore, a given lawsuit, it of the most negligence. number of probably market defendants was not that any may be particular they an have been asbestos HUGHS case, SUPPLY), SUPPLY, defined the supra at by (if parameters the the Court will defendant 1342. courts is See not also of of res this pardon the It named in defendant's that the market share liability theory knows no proper limited injury. theory, therefore, the plaintiff's share that unlike the a negligence bounds, caused Under would ipsa loquitur as Truly, in state. the paraphrase "probable actor." CHENOWETH v. seem, KEMP, from HUGHS 396 So.2d 1122 (Fla. 1981). In McWHORTER, position ipsa CITY 418 with loquitur. OF NEW So.2d 261 lower court, a tion of against the (Fla. respect to Once again, an appropriate causal negligence on SMYRNA the BEACH 1982), this parameters the the of plaintiffs link between their the part of UTILITIES named Court COMMISSION reaffirmed liability were unable v. its under res to show injuries and any alleged defendant. In reversing the this -Court repeated its prior concerns over liberalizdoctrine expansion of of res its ipsa loqui tur, intended the plaintiff's plight: -11- and implici ty warned parameters, notwithstanding Certainly, the district court I s desire to provide relief to the McWhorters is understandable. The family's suffering, occasioned by such a disgusting invasion of their horne, would incite the sympathy of any feeling person. But regardless of the magnitude of the McWhorters I misfortune, the facts of this case do not justify the Court's efforts to provide that relief through the invocation of res ipsa loquitur. Supra at 263. Clearly, the McWHORTER court refused to expand an otherwise limited doctrine of proof, plaintiff's notwithstanding the sympathetic in Yet that problem the precise the Third that motivation District I s case. for the decision SINDELL to appears court I s expand nature to have holding, traditional of the been and for theories of liability in wholesale fashion. The shifted is a the burden myth--an established for of SINDELL the "' a of would proof illusion. have from In of generic SINDELL, products. us believe plaintiff fact, the liabi Ii ty which would producers those court in of court absolute favor Justice it merely defendant. SINDELL exceed products dissent to that of This actually liabi Ii ty , the II consumers Richardson, supra at 938. It appears that the decision in SINDELL was principally grounded upon the California Supreme Court's efforts to find someone to II pay for the plaintiff I s somebody must pay. the court's and case some of upon appropr ia te its and a general feeling that This determination rings true notwithstanding II discussion liability, damages, of alternative colorable rule lega 1 of attempt reason precedent. or Yet -12- or to some enterprise base other the theories result logical in of that extension the McWHORTER decision makes it clear that this Court does not feel that it would be appropriate to use sympathy for a particular class of plaintiffs as a grounds for ignoring or otherwise plowing under hundreds of years of legal precedent. wi th Supreme of Court, all due its Florida,which injured proper based upon fails justice and the The cannot fairness, premise runs individual i. e., be the contrary rights acceptable his inability reconciled market of an collectivist since that the motives SINDELL to provide problem, defendants. simply upon in plaintiff I s SINDELL for decision is SINDELL therefore respect California to and the law freedoms. solution to the to identify all jurisprudence advanced by notions of with share Florida's liability is companies which produce generic predicated items have no property rights, no ownership interests and, indeed, no identity beyond that which makes their collective existence "an industry." Presumably, law in order to causation-in-fact is a requirement of Florida guarantee that a citizen's to due process will not be violated. constitutional right That is, one citizen's proper- ty cannot be taken to pay the liability or debt of another citizen. To hold otherwise is to impair that citizen's fundamental property rights. of the See, SPEISER v. RANDALL, 357 U.S. 513 (1958) for an example due process concerns which may be occasioned where the burden of proof is shifted. With the of court in shocking SINDELL ~isregard suggested for that the joining defendants' a rights, substantial share the DES market as defendants would diminish any injustice that might otherwise result from shifting the burden of proof. -13- SINDELL, supra at 937) In reality, joining a substantial market does not and cannot diminish injustice; an innocent producer I s "damages," to an injured plaintiff. the odds, ignoring i. e., share of the it merely diminishes his financial obligation The California Supreme Court was playing the fact that an individual defendant could be liable even though the odds might be one hundred to one against its liability which the wi t: a the in any courts court to the extent of the products RYAN v. 1981) ; have manufacturer SINDELL ELI so has that case. long this See v. become leap SINDELL 514 one reality, become 1004 COASTLINE to Yet step farther, dissent, F.Supp. SEABOARD a that its products. even manufacturers & COMPANY, STARLING has insurer of quantum others. these circumstances, rejected individual of Under become the takes LILLY accord, given the lnsurers supra at at 1017 942; (D. S.C. RAILROAD COMPANY, 533 F.Supp. 183 at 190 (S.D.Ga. 1982). In this instance, Defendants are strictly Plaintiffs are thus Defendants owed INC., 336 So.2d 80 theory, a a duty COPELANDS for that of MR. (Fla. 1976). that injuries. that the The need not prove that the Defendants were or See, e.g., WEST v. claimed COPELAND I S they care, have the CATERPILLAR TRACTOR COMPANY, Through the use of a market share the Plaintiffs would also be able to avoid having to prove causal Defendants these liable alleging them in fact negligent. the two relationship I products. theories between The would be net MR. COPELAND'S effect to put of the the various injuries conjunctive Defendants and use in the of the position of having to pay damages to the Plaintiffs simply because those defendant were producers of asbestos-related -14- products, and MR. COPELAND has allegedly sustained an asbestos-related injury. PITTSBURGH CORNING would submit that such a result would run contrary this to the Court notions in WEST, of causation which were re-emphasized by ironically at the very moment that the Court was adopting strict liability for application in Florida. In not make effect of WEST, the the Court manufacturer adoption of noted or strict that seller strict an liability insurer." liability was simply "does Rather, the "to remove the burden from the user of proving specif ic acts of neligence." Yet the opinion in WEST was careful to note that adoption of the Restatement rules of rule of strict liability would causation and the defenses not abrogate "ordinary applicable to negligence .... " WEST, supra at 90. In other words strict liability should be imposed only when a product the manufacturer places on the market, knowing that it is to be used without inspection for defects, proves to have a defect that causes injury to a human being .... In order to hold a manufacturer liable on the theory of strict liability in tort, the user must establish the manufacturer's relationship to the product in question, the defect and unreasonably dangerous condition of the product, and the existence of the proximate causal connection between such condition and the user's injuries or damages. Supra at 86-87. Obviously,· adoption of a market share theory of liability would radically alter these standards for recovery. Through the use of a market share theory of liability, a plaintiff would be able to avoid having to prove that any given manufacturer's would not have product to caused actually establish "the injury. manufacturer's -15- The plaintiff relationship to the product "proximate in question," causal manufacturer I s contrary to above, and and Court t s manufacturer I s the would connection" product this and products of between the to in injuries a or to this own Court's all II as was their the particular damages, In short, insurers .of contrary demonstrate defect in WEST. become others, have any "user's mandate would not noted products statement of policy in the WEST case. It allow a is little manufacturer not produce the the plaintiff. comfort that to escape specific The the market liability by asbestos-related Third District has share theory would proving product already that it which did injured acknowledged that such proof is virtually impossible for even the plaintiff to obtain; yet the better plaintiff position, to avoid was not is to certainly identify liability, producing Plaintiff I s a as actual particular asbestos exposure. in at good a tortfeasors. defendant any PITTSBURGH posi tion, time is CORNING Thus, left during if the would to in a order prove years submit not of that it the this alteration of traditional standards of proof would seriously undermine the notion of probability which has been adhered to throughout Florida jurisprudence. For produced of a example, asbestos-related plaintiff I s ducts. It plaintiff However, assume is was twenty that products year according to to the that particular for history possible, "although exposed a only of not at last exposure all particular SINDELL the defendant to few probable, the months similar pro- defendant's rationale, has that the product. improbability of this causal connection does nothing to mitigate the defendant's -16- liabili ty to the plaintiff, since the SINDELL decision makes it clear that a defendant must show the complete absence of a possible nexus between its .product and the plaintiff's injuries. The plaintiff, on the other hand, must only prove that the defendant produced asbestos. of The rest defendant's certainly of plaintiffs' liability, runs contrary is to case, presumed. the including This traditional type the of notions extent presumption of proximate causation which have been espoused by this Court. 40 So.2d In CONE v. 148 (Fla. INTERCOUNTY TELEPHONE AND TELEGRAPH COMPANY, 1949), this Court issued what has become the definitive pronouncement in this state on proximate causation. Not every negligent act of ommision or commission gives rise to a cause of action for injuries sustained by another. It is only when injury to a person ... has resulted directly and in ordinary natural sequence from a negligent act without the intervention of any independent efficient cause r or as such as ordinarily and naturally should have been regarded as a probable, not a mere possible, result of the negligent act, that such injured person is entitled to recover damages as compensation for his loss. Conversely, when the loss is not a direct result of the negligent act complained of, or does not follow in natural ordinary sequence from such act but is merely a possible, as distinguished from a natural and probable, result of the negligence, recovery will not be allowed. Supra at 149. Application a of jury verdict, these principles caused the CONE court to reverse since the Court did not feel that the plaintiff s I injuries could be viewed as the probable consequence cf the dant's negligence. The responsibility of a tort-feasor for consequences of his negligent acts must somewhere, and under our legal system -17- the end the defen- liability of the wrongdoer is extended only to the reasonable and probable, not the merely possible, result of a dereliction of duty. CONE, supra at 150. Yet as was liability noted would against above, often result defendant a application of in whose an a market assessment product share theory of money damages possibly--but had of not probably--caused injury to the plaintiff. More recently, in GOODING v. UNIVERSITY HOSPITAL BUILDING, INC., 445 So.2d standing Florida "more from principle has Dean pure best a that than not" Prosser I s not lS a of proving caused enough. Rather, or a in a negligence a defendant's plaintiff's mere or "I the the GOODING, I" action in negligence injuries. possibli ty Citing of matter such causremains probabilities becomes the duty of defendant. long the GOODING court through " I when conjecture, it Court reaffirmed the that the that the this plaintiff stressed evenly balanced, for 1984), treatise on torts, speculation verdict (Fla. burden McDonald ation ' " of the likely Justice 1015 one are at the court to direct supra at 1018, citing to Prosser, Law of Torts, §41 (4th Ed. 1971). In GOODING, the court refused to "approve the substitution of ... an obvious declined to inequity relax for a traditional perceived burdens one," of i. e., proof the merely court because existing causation requirements might ultimately prove too burdensome for those plaintiffs "who the medical malpractice caused could an prove injury but probability of causation .... " GOODING, arly, Court in this instance, the -18- the possibility could not prove the supra at 1019-1020. should that refuse to Simil- judicially negate time worn burdens because some of proof and theories of causation solely plaintiffs may have asbestos-related a difficult every exposed. Adoption of the market share theory would be particularly fied several case, where MR. asbestos-related to which identifying virtually inappropriate in this product time they have been COPELAND has in fact identi- products which he used during his career. Subsequent application of the fornia of v. indefensible basis for liability. SUPERIOR COURT, etc., 184 Cal.Rptr. defendant was form created by the Cali- Supreme Court in SINDELL has demonstrated the limitlessness this the "law" for use able to by women. show 98 that it In MYLES LABORATORIES (App. 1982), for example, never marketed The court ru led that DES the defendant in any could be held liable, since it knew or should have known that pharmacists would DES put share by Such and its acquiescing conduct, spirit that to case if of in a use. "The the drug's is certainly SINDELL decision." true, the wrote such scathing defendant use for opinion gained a market an unintended purpose. actionable The under the dissenting regarding the logic justice direction in the law has taken in the State of California. Similar v. E.R. the evidence that by SQUIBB the Eli DES Lilly & results SONS, are INC., overwhelmingly ingested Squibb. permi tted the 190 under Cal.Rptr. supported the by ··the plaintiff I s Company, Defendant possible On plaintiff the jury appeal, to state a -19- 349 In (App. 1983) defendant's MERTAN where contention mother had been produced returned the SINDELL. court market a verdict ordered share a in favor retrial cause of of and action against Squibb. The appellate court felt that there was at least a possibility that defendant Squibb was the culpable manufacturer. (Eli Lilly action, Company & was inexplicably therefore giving rise to the must pay" no longer a party inference that the to the "somebody mentality was once again a factor.) Market share liability also creates serious equal protec- tion concerns. liability Parties who avail theory (those who themselves cannot of identify the market the share manufacturer) are in a more favorable position than those plaintiffs in asbestos actions who certainly tort Thus, may base in actions, the pick a their more upon favorable e.g., who choose in cannot among standard position plaintiffs plaintiff and claims any tort law. They than plaintiffs medical prove any number of malpractice causation potential are in other lawsuits. whatsoever defendants, thereby increasing his opportunity for recovery. Obviously, of plaintiffs provides identity. the an who unequal are incentive This plaintiff manufacturer is can may protection unable to for plaintiff a particularly readily not be plaintiff's jurisdiction. identify true identify amenable under is to the law specific to a evidence manufacturer insolvent, service favor manufacturers withhold where in of or where process in of whom that the 1 At this point, it is .. worth mentioning that the largest single I / producer of asbestos-related products, JOHNS-MANVILLE, is currently undergoing reorganization. Pursuant to the applicable bankruptcy regulations, all proceedings against MANVILLE in this state have been stayed, although asbestos-related bodily injury claims remain pending as to all other named defendants. -20- Thus, the manufacturer who cannot the plaintiff may be left "holding the bag" escape liability to for another defendant, even though the other defendant's circumstances are not the result of an are is abundance strictly it ducts caution fortuitous. that as collective whole a stances, that a lack of it under liability where a by a to reason prove not make of share of a causal relationship is it makes no Yet "rough that the the sense that a justice" manufacturer who of the keeps should best their pro- circum- are sufficient that not necessary to the nor individualized records market s ens e but may conclusively lack thereof rather theory, a be share plaintiff liability then a valid defense. approach records to If the exis- could not possibly have been exposed to its product. tence but are liable for market manufacturer's manufacturer negligence, doe s defendant manufacturers avoid e. g., or Simi lar ly , fair nevertheless allow of for the mandates longest time will have the best chance of avoiding liability. That was most aptly market share expressed by liability Justice violates Richardson equal in his protection dissenting opinion in SINDELL. A system priding itself on 'equal justice under the law' does not flower when the liabili ty as well as the damage aspect of a tort action is determined by a defendant I s wealth. The inevitable consequence of such a result is to create and perpetuate two rules of law--one applicable to wealthy defendants, and another standard pertaining to defendant I s who are poor or 'who have modest means. SINDELL at 941. From a historical tort liability perspective, have expanded the to dimensions an -21- alarming and parameters extent. of Judicial rulings which are tacitly based upon a "deep pocket" theory or which are otherwise designed to adjust for problems of proof should be strictly applied within the bounds of constitutional principles. Historically, further," only the courts have to decide years take that next step. has curtai led res ipsa the loquitur, said "we will later of one it alarming trend, such "deep far is but time to this pocket" no Court theory, and has otherwise refused to relax traditional burdens of proof in medical malpractice actions. to take this that perhaps Recognizing this expans ion go This Court refused "that extra step" in the GOODING and HUGHES SUPPLY cases. Adoption of represent a a market major share step beyond liability the theory of recovery lines which were would drawn by the Court in those two cases. PRACTICAL APPLICATION OF MARKET SHARE LIABILITY WOULD BE IMPOSSIBLE, UNCERTAIN AND INEQUITABLE According to the court in SINDELL, the formula for determining the extent of a defendant manufacturer's liability under a market share theory is as follows: (w] e hold it to be reasonable in the present context to measure the likelihood that any of the defendants supplied the product which allegedly injured plaintiff by the percentage which the DES sold by each of them for the purpose of preventing miscarriage bears to the entire production of the drug sold by all for that purpose. Supra at 937. The court further required ··that a "substantial share" of the "appropriate market" be joined as defendants. [This] also provides a ready means to apportion damages among the defendants. Each defen-22- dant will be held liable for the portion of the judgment represented by its share of that market. Supra at 937. PITTSBURGH CORNING would submit that the SINDELL court--in its attempt to "diminish the injustice,"--has provided a formula which is so susceptible to alternate interpretations that it is virtually incapable of practical application. It would tionate share of where liability is otherwise since is based formula, bution, any it in upon "fact" by that defendant's such fault. the mere circumstances of production, share of the market, bears no relationship The determination of a defendant I s the II appropr ia te market" and requires an to "market economic which is only designed to provide a means of risk distrisince true is based upon "measured" the concept of obvious that a defendant 's propor- liability must be capable of precise measurement, liability share" seem rather such a determination would assignation of fault, by have little definition. For to this do with reason, essential that the formula be capable of fair and equitable application between each of the defendant manufacturers. What graphic area, ed, the appropriate or relevant market? Time, geo- the forum in which the defendant's product is market- and the quantity of asbestos in that product are all relevent variables Share U. is affecting Liability: Ill.L.Rev. Defective a defendant's A Plea 1003 Products: for (1982}; An market Chase, share. Legislative Alternatives, Newcomb, Ill-Advised Market Remedy Share for Market 1982, No.4, Liability the Problem for of Identification, 76 N.W. U.L.Rev. 300 (1981) What year constitutes the -23- relevant market? In a DES context, the relevant market in terms of time would when plaintiff's mother ingested the DES. context, be the time However, in an asbestos since exposure is continuous over a period of time, every year, month or day during the years of exposure would be relevant, since arguably it cannot be determined tracted the asbestos-related disease. when It the Plaintiff con- likely that a defen- 1S dant's liability will vary greatly depending upon the year chosen, and in fact it would appear that some kind of formula would have to be worked out so as to include virtually every moment of exposure. Absent some kind of ruling which would require that a the relevant market include the entire period of the plaintiff's exposure to year will asbestos-related determine the products, relevant who market? be dictated by the whim of the plaintiff, have the means of optimizing his were left open to selection, a own is If to the decide which decision is to then the plaintiff will recovery. plaintiff would If this period presumably bring suit against those manufacturers who are best able to pay an award, and who otherwise held the greatest share of the market during the period of exposure. Which asbestos products will be considered in determining the relevant Plaintiff not the Such may others. quanti ties market? have Many products contain to some Moreover, ea9h type of product will contain varying asbestos depending upon nature of equations the product, will be even and the more the asbestos asbestos. exposed of been different manufacturing but formula, identity of the manufacturer. confused by -24- products, the fact that each manufacturer may not have produced specific products during different periods of time. Apportionment is yet another aspect of market share liability upon which the California Supreme Court in SINDELL elected not to elaborate. That is, the Court failed to specify whether or not each defendant's market share is to be determined in proportion to every other defendant's share or in relation to relevant market. This problem is illustrated by th~ the entire following scenario: Assume that plaintiff's damages are $100,000 and he joins enough asbestos manufacturers to represent 60% of the relevant market. Defendant X occupies 20% of the relevant market and 33 and 1/3 % of the market that all joined defendants represent. If each defendant is liable only for the percentage of the judgment that is equivalent to its share of the relevant market, then Defendant X would be liable for 20% of the damages, or $20,000. If defendants are required to pay 100% of the judgment, however, then Defendant X must pay 1/3 of the judgment or $33,333, which is equivalent to 1/3 of the market that all joined defendants represent. In other words, Defendant X would have to pay 67% ($13,333) more than its share of the relevant market. Fischer, Products Liability--An Analysis of Market Share Liability, 34 Vanderbilt L.Rev. 1623 at 1646 (1981). Thus, share it can be seen that the extent to which a defendant's market and the ul timately defendant's depend of the market" upon whether manageable market and method must or are not disproportionate a will "substantial percentage may to is involved in the suit. Assuming- arguendo a liability and the be fair method individual applied that to a court for market calculating shares reality. -25- of This be able both the devine relevant the defendants, would largely that depend upon the continuing existence of is no have guarantee kept volved. may it such If a that each of records over relevent market data. the the various twenty particular manufacturer escape liability, Yet there defendant manufacturers to forty has not year period kept such in- records, or should the court speculate as to its share of the market? Market well-publicized be forced to in order to share liability asbestos makes manufacturers. easy targets of large, These manufacturers will join as many of the smaller manufacturers as possible spread the losses. (Assuming, of course, that these smaller manufacturers will be amenable to suit in the jurisdiction recognizing tional market share liability.) tort/products This transforms the tradi- lawsuit liability into multi-defendant/multi-district litigation and involves tremendously increased litigation costs. In STUART v. HERTZ, 351 So.2d 703 (Fla. 1977), this Court specifically prohibited a defendant in an automobile accident law sui t a from physician plaintiff in br inging who this third allegedly sustained STUART, a in Court the party had action aggravated original clearly for the indemnity injuries accident. proscribed what which its it characterized To hold otherwise would in effect permit a defendant to determine the time and manner, indeed the appropriateness, of a plaintiff's action for malpractice. This decision eliminates the traditional policy of allowing the plaintiff to chose the time, forum and manner in which to press his claim. A complete outsider, * * and a tort feasor at that, -26- the In as an inappropriate attempt to expand third party practice. * against decision must not be allowed to ... make the plaintiff I s case against the original tortfeasor longer and more complex through the use of a third party practice r ule which was adopted for the purpose of expediting and simpli fying litigation. * * * [A] third party action ... would not only incorrectly expand traditional concepts of indemnity to the point of making it indistinguishable from contribution, but also expand the applicability of the third party rule and make it a tool whereby the tortfeasor is allowed to complicate the issues to be resolved in a personal injury suit and prolong the litigation through the filing of a third-party malpractice action. STUART, supra at 706. Thus, this Court refused to allow the third party indemnity action ln STUART. Notwithstanding these however , it seem where named sui t a would attempts hardly defendant to plead in fair a policy laudable to bar particular market. share a considerations, third party action asbestos-related injury liabili ty in a third party action against manufacturers who had not been named by the plaintiff in the original complaint. would certainly be would undoubtedly could not state This attractive be to appropriate conclusively kind the in that of third smaller any he practice manufact.urers, case had party where only a been and plaintiff exposed to those products which were manufactured by the original defendants. Thus, been exposed a plaintiff solely to one who is virtually product, but who certain is that he honest enough had to concede that he might have worked with the products of other manufacturers, will be put in the unenviable position of being subjected to a massive third party action which was not of his own choosing. -27- This kind of third party practice has other ominous implications the judgment as well. If to the each. defendant's share of an adversarial each the other will be of defendants, position vis defendant share a vis required the defendants each other. to hire is wi 11 In all it own relative be in likelihood, accountants and actuaries for the purpose of determining the extent of its liabil- i ty. the larger If smaller the manufacturers manufacturers same as litigation parties costs as are successful defendant, the the former. in joining latter The total will the have potential cost of such complex litigation is staggering. Furthermore, possible of a to the to product the must into of that is the case, will at 1654. plished is costs bear some Damages in the litigation excess ity these consumer. estimated to pass there hundreds costs which and can be on no guarantee to consumers, rational that it because relationship to the asbestos-related cases of billions the resulting passed on of dollars. figure to. the would be the price its value have been Add that may well consumer. be If in this the risk distribution purposes of market share liabil- be defeated. In addition, where any Newcomb, supra at 316; Fischer, supra risk distribution cannot possibly be accom- number of manufacturers are no longer in the market place, or have otherwise gone out of business. In which of that - regard," there warrant each of more these than a mere considerations are several footnote, would other considerations although warrant a the broadnes s separate brief. For example, where does the liability of wholesalers or distributors -28- ., . .. fit into such the broad entities defective are scheme of liable products., market where pursuant share they to this liability? have passed Court I s Certainly, along otherwise adoption of strict liability. Under liable where the they circumstances, have sold are distributors asbestos-related to be products? held If so, how is a distributor's market share to be determined? While ordinary such sugggestions circumstances, given might a appear distributor's academic under potential cause of action for indemnity against an "actively negligent" manufacturer, the absence of fault in a market share approach should arguably render indemnity questions then the distributor I s in fact, have to a If that is the case, share of the market becomes a factor, in some instances, profited meaningless. and, the largest distributors may actually greater degree from the distribution of asbestos-related materials than did some of the smaller manufacturers. These inquiries alone should be sufficient to call the advisability of adoption of this theory of recovery into question. As can raised be readily' seen above, profit prominence than do tortfeasor is or utilized. that market and share the considerations market share such questions proximate Yet from where CORNING liability will to have assume been greater as the identity of a particular causation PITTSBURGH begin which not a market would serve share theory respectfully submit the purpose for which it was intended. In a traditional product liability jurisdiction, -29- a manu- facturer ordinarily has the incentive to produce a safe product, because the manufacturer is only responsible for its own products. However, where market share liability is implemented, manufacturers will almost certainly be held liable for injuries which were actually caused the by another manufacturer subsidizing the of a manufacturer's relatively manufacturers manufacturer is being of safe held will be for a always defendants, smaller manufacturer to this may for a and the there setting, actually products. liable generic product, In product defective damages caused by a almost product. Thus, percentage be since of all larger manufacturers is really no incentive improve upon its production of that particular generic product. The possibility of being subjected to a product liability suit will only operate as an incentive to an individual manufacturer where potential over which example, liability that where particular a bears manufacturer manufacturer measures to has remedy any relationship manufacturer has believes exposure to litigation and/or a the some some that it to a product control. may For curtail its judgment by improving its product, additional incentive perceived defect to in his take appropriate product line. On the other hand, where market share liability is implemented, there is the sued. The no limit threat to of number litigation, of times therefore, to the individual manufacturer, has that a company serves as no can real be deterent since that manufacturer's liability no direct correlation with anything over which the individual defendant manufacturer principle of has any control. behavioral science may be, -30- As axiomatic as this it has apparently escaped · ., those who would advocate market share liability. Most courts have rejected market share liability because of the belief that it fails to serve the deterent and risk distribution purposes same are for courts have inherent in attempting to PANY, also the 437 been N.E. the 2nd 37, v. STARLING F.Supp. 183 (S.D.Ga. 538 F.Supp. 593 (M.D.Fla. 543 F.Supp. 1152 567 SALES CORPORATION, cases, rejection determining there has STARLING, supra; 714 has relevant been supra; joint RYAN v. COASTLINE RELATED HANNON 581 ELI LILLY & COM- (5th unanimous 526 ALBERT v. WATERMAN Cir. 1983). because the CASES, STEAMSHIP JOHNS-MANVILLE In asbestos difficulty is particularly exposure to the product. CASES, 589 COMPANY, ASBESTOS THOMPSON v. ASBESTOS F.Supp. LABORATORIES, shares RELATED ADVERT ELI LILLY RAILROAD IN RE v. COLLINS v. v. and CORNING several would liability and finally of acute where See, e.g., supra; liability. practice, which compelled to Aside were point from raised out that the address contribution feasors which will arise should this share which HANNON, THOMPSON, supra. PITTSBURGH of injustices & COMPANY, (E.D.La.); been most of these PATENT MORTON 1982); F.2d RE LILLY 1982); market IN 1984); 1982); continuous 1982; SEABOARD 90 the market. Mass. Wis. (N.D.Cal. F.Supp. about relevent V. However, the difficulties which arise when ELI 533 CORPORATION, concerned 2nd 171, MIZELL 1981); designed. theory and 342 N.W. supra.; (D.S.C. is was determine LABORATORIES, & COMPANY, which the among problem joint tort Court decide to adopt market implications for earlier~ PITTSBURGH a share market -31- third party CORNING feels theory of recovery · " would hopelessly feasors, confuse contribution pursuant to Florida law, actions among joint tort and otherwise render meaningless this state's jurisprudential concept of joint and several liability. For example, would any given defendant in an ongoing asbestos lawsuit have the right to seek contribution from all other manufacturers the (or distributors suit? Would all or wholesalers) defendants be who were jointly and not joined severally in liable, or would each defendant simply be responsible for paying his "share" of the plaintiff's damages? Clearly, his share of the if a defendant damages caused could to only be held the plaintiff liable as among for those defendants who are actually joined in a lawsuit, then that defendant would have the other potential right to file defendant a who third had party not been action named against in the any suit. What will this do to the cost of asbestos litigation, particularly if trial court judges get into the habit of denying leave to file third party complaints, pursuant to this Court's mandate in STUART? These and a plethora of similar questions will arise--and have arisen in California--with the advent of market share liabilIn ity. submit the that final a analysis, plaintiff's therefore, inability to PITTSBURGH identify CORNING would specific tort feasors does not provide a sufficient reason to change fundamental principles of tort law which have evolved over hundreds of years. To PITTSBURGH the contrary" CORNING would respectfully submit that this is the wrong forum for redress of such concerns. If a generic there is a product which sense has of collective responsibility been manufactured on -32- an for industrywide t .. I scale, then imposition of inherently unjust. Our injustices, create since to recognized indi vidual our not that rights courts court And judicial freedoms, with on an individual system was designed them. our and applies liability system the equal while our is to correct courts have designed mandate force to basis which to we defendants, such long protect have as is given well as plaintiffs. It can impose has that is respectfully liability on power and submitted an entire that that only industry. capability. Yet the legislature Only the legislature PITTSBURGH CORNING would suggest that there is a real question as to whether even the legislative branch of any given state would have the authority to legislate the kind of in this instance court liability which solely has wi thin been a created single by state, the lower since this is truly a nation-wide problem. Undoutedly, to pass pay a for law were the which damage would which had legislature of the State of Florida require been a handful caused by of the manufacturers entire to membership of a particular industry, that statute would be subjected to strict judicial scrutiny, ali ty. be no It less is and would otherwise be of doubtful constitution- respectfully repugnant from submitted a that a constitutional simi lar result would standpoint where that result has been achieved through judicial fiat. At than the the .very courts aids legislature on this tional problems, least, action by the efficiency and assures topic will which will preclude uniformity. rather National law" jurisdic- repeatedly, and which "choice of otherwise arise -33- legislature will undoubtedly induce forum-shopping should market share liability be adopted in have urged a tiffs who STARLING and 190; only few states. Many courts and commentators legislative solution for the problems of those plain- are V. a incapable SEABOARD NAMM v. of COAST CHARLES identifying LINE E. RAILROAD FROSST & the proper COMPANY, COMPANY, defendant. supra 427 at Atl.2d 186 1121 at 1129 (N.J.App. 1981). For in this the brief, reasons and for which the have reasons been which set will forth be at length expressed by the other Petitioners and Amicus, PITTSBURGH CORNING would earnestly submi t that this legislature, is indeed a problem which should be left to the and most appropriately for resolution by the Congress of the United States. -34- · ,. CONCLUSION For all of the above cited reasons, Amicus Curiae PITTSBURGH enter of CORNING CORPORATION an order quashing Appeal, and respectfully the otherwise decision of rejecting requests the market this Court to Third District Court share liability as a theory of recovery for plaintiffs in asbestos-related bodily injury actions pending in Florida. Respectfully submitted, ROBERT M. KLEIN CARON E. SPEAS -35- _, I l ) CERTIFICATE OF SERVICE WE foregoing was HEREBY served CERTIFY by mail that a this true and correct 21st day of May, copy of the 1984, to the attached list of addressees. STEPHENS, LYNN, CHERNAY, KLEIN & ZUCKERMAN, P.A. One Biscayne Tower, Suite 2400 Miami, Florida 33131 (305) 358-2000 BY: IN ~ ~ A fv., 6&...-.~- - - - M. - -KLEIN --------ROBERT -36-