INTERGOVERNMENTAL RELATIONS IN THE EARLY 21ST CENTURY: LINGERING IMAGES OF EARLIER PHASES OR EMERGENCE OF A NEW PHASE? J. Edwin Benton Department of Government and International Affairs University of South Florida Tampa, Florida 33620-8100 jbenton@usf.edu Paper prepared for delivery at the 2014 Deil S. Wright Symposium on “Understanding Intergovernmental Relations: Reflections and Directions,” preceding the 2014 ASPA Meeting, Mayflower Hotel, Washington, D.C., March 14, 2014 1 INTRODUCTION In crafting the U.S Constitution and setting into motion what Tocqueville (1999) would call the “novel American Experiment,” the Founding Fathers probably never envisioned the complex system of intergovernmental relations and ubiquitous interactions that would result in the new republic. From the launching of the new democracy in 1789 until the end of the 19th century, the scope of government activity and the impact on governmental decisions were in line with the Jefferson proclamation that “…government that governs best… governs least.” This period of time was marked by Americans embracing the notion of laissez-faire and many of the basic tenets of Social Darwinism, while the dominant political culture could be characterized as a mixture of the traditionalistic and individualistic types (Elazar 1984). With the national government, and even state governments, performing only a limited number of functions and providing a relatively short menu of services, there was little opportunity for these governments, and subsequently, their officials, to come into contract or interact with one another. State-local relations could be characterized by a top-down approach, with states exercising oversight authority over their creations (local governments), while national-state relations could be viewed as “two ships passing in the night,” and each respecting the sphere of authority of the other. That is, these two planes (levels) of government tended to act independently of each another and generally did not encroach on the other (Zimmerman 2008). Therefore, the concept “Dual Federalism” seemed to be an appropriate depiction of the operation of American federalism and subsequent IGR for over 100 years. IGR) were destined to change, however, with the dawning of the twentieth century, as the seeds for change were visible even before 1900 (see O’Toole 2000, 6-7). Deil Wright (1988, 65) explains the coming IGR changes and the reason for them in this way: “It is an accepted fact 2 that since 1900 the U.S. political system has experienced major shifts that represent dramatic, if not evolutionary, upheavals.” He is obviously referring to history-changing events and significant political and public policy decisions that are listed here in abbreviated form and in no particular order: 16th (individual income tax), 17th (direct election of U.S. Senators), 18th (prohibition), 19th (women’s suffrage), 21st (repeal of prohibition), 23rd (right to vote for citizens of the District of Columbia), 24th (prohibition against poll tax), and 26th (lowering of voting age to 18-years-of-age) Amendments to the U.S. Constitution, World War I, Great Depression, World War II, Civil Rights Movement, Congressional enactments and U.S. Supreme Court cases in areas like health care, welfare, housing, labor relations, civil rights and civil liberties, environment, homeland security, immigration, and so forth. To better understand and explain how these events and policy decisions contributed to the evolution of our political system as well as changes in patterns of relations in IGR in the U.S., Wright identified and described seven phases or periods of IGR. The descriptive nature and nuances of each phase crystallized upon Wright’s consideration of the following questions: What underlying forces precipitated the changes? What were the directions and subtle shapes of the shifts? Around what policy issues did the changes revolve, and what were the mechanisms by which the changes implemented? What were the short- and long-term effects of the shift? The resultant seven phases and their approximate periods of prominence are as follows: Conflict (1930s and before), Cooperative (1930s-1950s), Concentrated (1940s-1960s), Creative (1950s-1960s), Competitive (1960s1970s), Calculative (1970s-1980s), and Contractive (1980s-1990s). Over the last twenty-five years, few scholars (including Wright) have either identified or described a new phase of IGR beyond his seventh “Contractive Phase.” Do the principal components associated with the “Contractive Phase” (that is, the main problems or policy issues 3 dominating the public agenda, participants’ perceptions, and IGR mechanisms) still accurately describe and explain the workings of IGR or has a new phase emerged? Given changing citizenry and private sector needs and expectations and profound national and global events, have the basic contours of IGR and roles of various governments and subsequently relations among these governments’ elected and appointed public officials been reshaped and redefined? While it may be the case that remnants of Wright’s seventh phase may still be evident, is it possible that enough has changed in the workings of IGR to suggest the emergence of a new eight phase of IGR? Therefore, the purpose of this paper is to explore the possibility that we have already entered into or about to enter a new eight phase of IGR. Before proceeding to the principal objective of this paper, it is instructive to present a brief synopsis of Wright’s seven phases of IGR. WRIGHT’S SEVEN PHASES OF IGR: AN OVERVIEW Deil Wright’s identification and characterization of seven distinctive periods or phases of U.S. IGR that were evident during the twentieth century has served as an invaluable and insightful guidepost for scholars and practitioners in their desire to better understand and appreciate the dynamic relations and interactions among the national, state, and local governments, but especially, their elected and appointed officials. Hence, it is important that any effort to determine if Wright’s Contractive phase continues to adequately depict IGR in the early part of the twentieth-first century or if a new phase has emerged should start with a review of the significant political and economic happenings and defining moments in IGR that preceded the opening of the new century. A condensed chart of the distinctive features (i.e., main problems, participants’ perceptions, IGR mechanisms, federalism metaphors, and approximate climax period) of each of phase located in Table 1 will assist in this overview. 4 (Table 1 About Here) In the second, third, and fourth columns of the table, three major elements of each of the seven phases are considered. First, what policy issues dominated the public agenda? Second, what dominant perceptions did the chief participants seem to have? In other words, what orientations or mind-sets guided their behavior? Third, what mechanisms and techniques were used to implement governmental actions and objectives? The fifth column of the table provides a metaphorical characterization of each phase (usually a form of federalism), while the sixth column gives the approximate time span of the climax period. For those not familiar with Wright’s phases, two clarifications are in order. First, the descriptors do not include all aspects of intergovernmental interaction during the time period indicated for each phase. For instance, while conflict is the predominant characteristic of the period prior to 1930, it does not preclude the possibility or probability of important cooperative IGR activities. Second, since the dates for each period are approximate and not finite, this means that the phases, in fact, overlap. Therefore, the term “climax period” not only identifies a time of peak prominence but also leaves open the possibility for the continuation of a phase beyond the dates given. For example, even though the conflict phase climaxed before and during the 1930s, the conflict relationship did not end then but often reappears in future periods as a subsidiary theme of the present dominant phase. To repeat, it is noteworthy that none of the seven phases of IGR stops at any particular place and time or actually fade away. That is, phases tend to overlap one another, and elements of them continue on indefinitely. Wright (1988, 66) describes what happens in this manner: “Like successive, somewhat porous strata that have been superimposed on each other (by the interactions and perspectives of public officials), no phase ends at an 5 exact point—nor does it in fact disappear. Each phase is continuously present in greater or lesser measure, bearing the weight, so to speak, of the overlying strata (subsequent phases).” Simply stated, each phase has “carryover effects” much wider than the climax periods indicated in Table 1. In reality, the present state of IGR is the product of manifold overlays of each of the seven phases. Conflicting Phase: 1930s and Before This phrase was characterized by an emphasis on pinpointing the legitimate areas of government authority and jurisdiction and identifying the limits of officials’ actions. This focus was evident at the state and local levels as well as between national and state governments. Dillon’s Rule became synonymous with state supremacy in state-local matters and was relied upon to determine the precise limits of local government authority. The national, state, and local officials who wanted to identify the exact specification of their respective authority believed that their authority would be mutually exclusive. Furthermore, it appears that officials presumed that resistance and antagonism would be part of the usual process of determining who was authorized to do what. Identifying specific government roles and spelling out distinct boundaries (usually through court interpretation of statutes and regulatory authority) were distinguishing attributes of the conflict period. The well-known U.S. Supreme Court case of McCulloch v. Maryland (4 Wheaton 316, 1819), early on, decisively established the conflict-oriented pattern in one very important policy arena with particular relevance for IGR—finances. Although this case is perhaps better remembered for it interpretation of the U.S. Constitution’s Necessary Clause, and especially for upholding the power of the national government to establish a bank, it firmly 6 established the precedent that state laws are null and void if they conflict with the national governments delegated powers, laws enacted by Congress, or federal treaties. But, the Court’s decision in McCulloch did much more than assist and assert national supremacy, for it heralded the beginning of a century and a half of battles between national, state, and local taxing authorities over who could or could not tax what activities of “opposing jurisdictions.” The preoccupation with separating or sorting out powers—however limited or restricted in practice—gave credibility to the metaphor “layer-cake federalism” to describe exclusive or autonomous spheres for national, state, and local governments. Cooperative Phase: 1930s-1950s While the first phase of IGR was mainly characterized by conflict, there nonetheless was some degree of intergovernmental collaboration during the nineteenth and twentieth centuries. However, there was one period of our political history that lasted for approximately two decades (from the 1930s and extending into the 1950s) in which complementary and supportive relationships were most pronounced and had notable political implications. This period was known as the cooperative phase. The principal issues of concern to the country during this period were the alleviation of the widespread economic suffering and distress associated with the Great Depression and responses to international threats such as World War II and the Korean Conflict. Hence, it was reasonable and expected that internal and external challenges to national survival would result in closer contact and cooperation between public officials at all levels of government. This significant increase in the level of cooperation manifested itself in several and varied forms, but especially such innovations as national planning, tax credits, and formula-based grants-in-aid. 7 The principal governmental mechanism as well as the main legacy of the cooperative period was fiscal. Substantial and important financial relations were firmly established and a harbinger of more to come. Subsequently, these relations inspired a new metaphor of intergovernmental patterns—the much-publicized “marble cake” expression that was originated by Joseph McLean (1952) of Princeton University and later popularized and elaborated on by Morton Grodzins—as contrasted with the layer cake conception of the previous period. Grodzins argues that government operations in the U.S were wrongly depicted as a threelayer cake. “A far more accurate image,” Grodzins (19060) said, “is the rainbow of marble cake, characterized by an inseparable mingling of differently colored ingredients, the colors appearing in vertical and diagonal strands and unexpected whirls [sic].” From Grodzins’ perspective, the U.S. system of governance should be viewed as one of shared functions in which “it is difficult to find any governmental activity which does not involve all three of the so-called ‘levels’ of the federal system.” Supportive of these shared functions was an implicit (and sometime explicit) disposition and pattern of behavior among participants that included collaboration, cooperation, and mutual assistance. Concentrated Phase: 1940s-1960s The setting for this period covers the presidencies of Truman, Eisenhower, and Kennedy, where intergovernmental relations became increasingly specific, functional, and highly focused—that is, concentrated. Between 1946 and 1961, twenty-one major new grant-in-aid programs were created, nearly doubling the total enacted in the Great Depression era. With this growth in the number of categorical grant programs, greater increasing attention was paid to service standards. Consequently, administrative rules and regulations as opposed to legislative acts began to govern such thing as award criteria, reporting, and performance requirements. 8 These new grant-in-aid programs focused on two general problem/need areas—(1) capital works, public construction, and physical development; and (2) burgeoning middle class expectations and needs. Examples include airports, hospitals, highways, slum clearance and urban renewal, schools, waste treatment, libraries, and urban planning. Despite the fact that there was a substantial federal involvement in local affairs via such programs, substantial local political control was both encouraged and practiced. In fact, the techniques of grants, service standards, construction projects, and the like were consistent with the local tradition of initiative and voluntary participation. Moreover, IGR techniques were fitted with middle-class values of professionalism, objectivity, and neutrality and therefore gave the appearance that objective program needs rather than politics were being served. That said, it seemed that programs were separated from the sordid side of pork-barrel politics. These key political principles coincided with the reorganization of Congress in 1946 and the establishment of congressional standing committees with specific program emphases. The creation of these committees was to have significant IGR implications. It was not long before these congressional committee patterns quickly became the conduit for access and leverage points for influencing program-specific grants. During this phase, the term or metaphor “water taps” began to be used to describe the intergovernmental relations process that resulted. Due to the flow of influence combined with the concentrated, or focused, flow of funds in this period, the national government had become a heavily-relied upon source of financial resources to which a greatly growing number of water taps were being connected. The flow of funds could be facilitated by those most knowledgeable (the program professionals or specialists) at turning on the numerous “spigots,” and federal funds usually went directly to states that could then turn around and release them in part or in whole to 9 local governments. Cooperation, while prominent during this period, occurred in concentrated and selectively channeled ways. And it was during this phase that the interconnectedness and interdependency of national, state, and local relations were confirmed and solidified. Creative Phase: 1950s-1960s The foundation for the creative phase can be traced back to the cooperative and concentrated periods of IGR. The period was marked by a compelling need for decisiveness in politics and policy and the clear articulation of cohesive national goals. The term “creative” is associated with this period partly because of President Lyndon Johnson’s use of the slogan “creative federalism” and partly because of the many new innovative programs in IGR. Three IGR mechanisms were characteristic of this period—program plans, project grants, and citizen participation. First, comprehensive, area-wide, and statewide plans had to be submitted and approved prior to the receipt of federal grant funds. Second, there was greater use of project grants, whereby grant proposals had to be submitted in a project type format. These kinds of grants not only involve wide-ranging and often detailed proposals or requests but also give much greater latitude to grant administrators than do formula grants, in which statutory or administrative formulas determine recipient entitlements. In addition, public participation was strongly encouraged through the inclusion of the “maximum feasible participation” requirement in legislation. This involvement of clients in program operations and administrative, however, proved to be significant and a troubling component in intergovernmental programs. This period is perhaps best known for the proliferation of the number of grant programs, thus leading to the employment of the metaphor “flowering.” The main policy issues and major themes addressed by this creative activism were two-fold: an urban-metropolitan focus and attention to the disadvantages through antipoverty programs and aid-to-education funds. By 10 1969, there were an estimated 150 major programs, 400 specific legislative authorizations, and 1,300 federal assistance activities (Wright 1988, 78). Of the 400 specific authorizations, 70 involved directly funneled money to local governments, thus bypassing the state governments (Wright 1988, 78). In dollar magnitude, federal grants rose from $4.9 billion to $23.9 billion between 1958 and 1970, while state aid to local governments also increased significantly from $8.0 billion to $28.9 billion (Wright 1988, 78). The significant increase in project grants and the amount of money accompanying them compared to formula grants led to a noticeable change in the attitudes and behavior of IGR participants. Specifically, a grantsmanship perspective grew quickly and extensively, but particularly around poverty and project grant programs. Playing the federal grant “game” became a familiar but time-consuming activity of mayors, local government managers, school officials, governors, and particularly program professionals. Competitive Phase: 1960s-1970s The competitive phase of IGR was distinguished by the escalation of tensions that was fueled by the proliferation of federal grants, the clash between program professionals and participation-minded clients, and the intractability of domestic urban and international problems. Issues related to bureaucratic behavior, administrative competence, and implementation, become dominating concerns. Perhaps one of the most daunting concerns was the lack of coordination among programs and within and among levels of government. Other festering concerns related to program accomplishment, effective service delivery, and citizens access. Subsequently, attention of public officials at levels of government turned to administrative performance or the lack thereof or on organizational structures and relationships that either impeded or improved the delivery of public goods and services. 11 The period was also marked by a sharply different approach with regard to appropriate IGR mechanisms. Pressure mounted to change and even reverse previous grant trends. Suggestions ranged from grant consolidation in the form of block grants to revenue sharing. President Nixon envisioned revenue sharing as a means of improving program effectiveness and strengthening state and local governments, especially elected officials in their competition and disagreements with national bureaucrats. On the national administrative front, efforts were made to encourage metropolitan and regional cooperation (under Office of Management and Budget circular A-95) and reorganize government agencies. The level of disagreement, conflict, tension, rivalry that earned this period the label “competitive intergovernmental relations” meant that there was far too little coordination and cooperation all along the line of administration from top federal policymaker and administrators to state and local professional and elected officials. However, the competition differed in degree, emphasis, and configuration from the inter-level conflict of the older layer cake phase. First, there was competition between professional program specialists or administrators (national, state, and local) and state and local elected and appointed officials. Second, there was competition among several functional program areas (e.g., highways, welfare, education, health, urban renewal, etc.), whereby like-minded program specialists or professionals, regardless of the level of government in which they served, formed rival alliances. These cross-cutting rivalries and fragmentation prompted former North Carolina governor Terry Sanford to suggest the “picketfence” metaphor as descriptive of this period of IGR. Calculative Phase: 1970s-1980s This period was marked by the out-of-control finances and near-bankruptcy of New York City during the mid-1970s. These problems however were not confined to just NYC but rather 12 were reflective of broader societal, economic, and political problems across the nation. The problems included lack of accountability of public officials, bankruptcy and fiscal stress, unwise and heightened dependency on federal aid, perceived overbearing and meddlesome role of federal authorities, and the loss of public confidence in government and government officials generally. While IGR during this period still tended to revolve around federal aid to state and local governments, it was practiced, according to Wright (1988, 98) from a calculative perspective and “contained only the surface trappings of federalism.” State and local governments had the appearance of making important choices, but the choices in reality were few and elusive. The major choice was whether to participate in federal assistance programs. If they decided to take part in these programs, a larger array of more limited options was available. These choices, however, were constrained mainly, if not exclusively, nationally specified rules of the game. This is why “façade federalism” has been chosen as a metaphor characterizing this phase of IGR. The perceptions of IGR participants of this period can be summarized as gamesmanship, fungibility, and overload. Gamesmanship means that IGR players used various strategic games to achieve desired ends. Fungibility refers to the ability of state and local governments to shift or exchange resources received from the federal government for one purpose to accomplish another purpose. Overload denotes the belief that democratic governments have been expected to do more than they are capable of doing in an effective, efficient, and low-cost manner. Several mechanisms were used to implement IGR activities in the calculative phase. One was the channeling of more federal aid on a formula basis as entitlements and in the form of general aid and block grants to states and their local governments. Closely linked to the mechanism of general aid is the practice of bypassing, whereby federal funds would go directly 13 to local governments without having to pass through state treasuries. Loans to governments or individuals (e.g., to New York City or students) constitute a third IGR mechanism. Regulation (in the form of grant guidelines in the Federal Register, grant law, and crosscutting requirements) was a final implementing mechanism. Contractive Phase: 1980s-1990s This most recent period will probably be remembered as one in which federal aid was shrinking, local autonomy was eroding, and court decisions and congressional legislation constricted the range of action of state and local governments, and the increasing tendency of governmental agencies at all levels to enter into contracts for the purchase and delivery of services. Four IGR problems confronted public officials during this period. First, all levels of government have been preoccupied with borrowing and budget balancing as the size and persistence of the federal deficit loomed large and cast a foreboding shadow of the current and long-term IGR fiscal scene. Second, federal deficits and conservative politics resulted in significant cuts and changes in federal aid to state and local governments. Third, the federal court and nonelected officials increasingly directed their attention to detailed, specific, and judgmental policy action of state and local officials (schools, prison, and mental health facilities) and found numerous faults with their actions. Moreover, these nonelected, non-constitutional officials sought to convene, cajole, and convince popularly elected officials into following the “best course of action” in resolving disputes. Fourth, federal mandates in the form of court orders, congressional statues, and administrative regulations abounded and were branded by Zimmerman (1990, 52) as “the principal irritant of American intergovernmental relations.” 14 Contentiousness, disagreement, and even confrontation (that is, between federal and state and local officials) often characterize IGR interaction of this period. Moreover, state and local officials came to the realization that the “good old days” of abundant federal grant money and non-intrusive federal government were over, while they should also be wary of an overbearing federal government. These perceptions produced a sense of defensiveness and distrust on the part of state and local government officials and more litigation. To respond to this deterioration of IGR, President Ronald Reagan was aggressive in efforts to reshape, reform, and restore national-state relations through decentralization (devolution) of the federal system. Three sets of IGR mechanisms (federal statutes/court decisions, information sources, negotiated dispute settlement, and privatization) appeared to be new. The first set of mechanisms represented a partial “rerun” of the conflict phase and evokes a strong sense of “us against them.” Problem solving was revolutionized as a result of changes in computer technology (particularly the sharing of information among like-minded IGR actors) and the development of new social technology (e.g., mediation). Finally, privatization, though the encouragement of competition and innovation, gave especially state and local officials the opportunity to provide services in a more efficient, effective, and less costly manner. The sometimes divergent and even contradictory characterization of the contractive phase meant that was unlikely that a single federalism metaphor satisfactorily described the nature of relations in this period. Therefore, a trio of metaphors (de facto federalism, telescoped federalism, and whiplash federalism) was suggested as reasonable descriptors. IGR SINCE THE LATE 1990s As the preceding review illustrates, IGR in the American federal system of government is subject to major change over time. Unanticipated (or even anticipated) national and international 15 events, public opinion and philosophical shifts, technological and scientific advances, volatile and precarious economic forces, climate and ecological changes, and the advent of a globalized world can serve as underlying causes and catalysts for the development of new patterns in IGR. Have these and other harbingers of change resulted in the emergence of a new or eighth phase of IGR or does the seventh phase persist? Holding Pattern in the Seventh Phase? One of the key observations made by Wright in distinguishing between different phases of IGR is that the emergence of a new period does not necessarily mean the definite end of the previous period or the disappearance of all of the defining characteristics of that phase. That point is emphasized by Wright, when he proposes approximate dates for each phase and allows for the distinct possibility that phases in reality overlap. This perspective on the phases of IGR would suggest that there is the real likelihood of “carryover effects” from one phase to the next. For example, there is no reason to expect that conflict in IGR, to some degree, did not persist beyond the 1930s and into the Cooperative Phase (1930s-1950s) or later periods. Likewise, there is no reason to believe that noteworthy cooperative IGR endeavors or “partnership” efforts did not occur during the Conflict Phase (nineteenth century-1930s). Similarly, it is quite plausible that cooperation and collaboration and mutuality and supportive activity (major hallmarks of the Cooperative Phase) spilled over into the Concentrated, Creative, Competitive, and future phases, for this is the nature of a constantly evolving process of IGR and interactions set in an open system. For certain, new main problems emerge, new participant perceptions arise, and new IGR mechanisms are employed and redefine a new phase of IGR, but remnants of the preceding phase remain and represent subsidiary themes of the current dominant phase. Indeed, the idea of 16 “climax period” is suggestive of the peak prominence of the basic characteristics of a phase, but it does not preclude the continuation of some of the attributes of the previous phase. But before considering whether we have transitioned from the Contractive Phase to a new phase of IGR, it is important to determine if what Wright labeled the Contractive Phase is still a reasonable depiction of IGR from the late 1990s to the present. To facilitate the analysis that follows, it will be useful to examine three distinctive sets of IGR relationships separately. That is, I will initially examine federal-state, federal-local, and federal-state-local relations and then turn my attention to separate analyses of state-local relations and finally interlocal relations. Federal-State, Federal-Local, and Federal-State-Local Relations In the most recent Annual Review of Federalism published in Publius: The Journal of Federalism, the Special Issue guest co-editors report that “the state of American Federalism is arguably more chaotic, complex, and contentious than ever before”(Bowling and Pickerill 2013, 315). This certainly appears to be an accurate characterization of the state of federal-state, federal-local, and federal-state-local relations. Descriptions of federalism and IGR and federalism metaphors like layer cake, marble cake, and picket fence are too one-dimensional to accurately describe the relationships between administrators at the national, state, and local levels of government. Moreover, federalism and IGR is no longer either “cooperative,” “creative,” “coercive,” or “calculative.” Presently, all of these descriptions and approaches, as well as many more, depict the operation and relations of the federal system, even within the same policy area. A good example is the Patent Protection and Affordable Care Act (PPACA), which contains cooperative (grants-in-aid), creative (health exchanges and mandates for individuals), coercive (penalties for citizens and businesses), and calculative (cross-cutting regulations and confrontational politics) elements. In fact, the foregoing description of IGR bears a close 17 resemblance to the depiction of IGR that Wright provided for the “Contractive” phase as he saw it in the 1980s and 1990s, except for the caveat that a new federalism metaphor (fragmentation) should be added to the three suggested by Wright (de facto, telescope, and whiplash). What Remains the Same? In recent years, the President and Congress and both major political parties have been preoccupied with the increasing federal debt, balance of trade deficit, and slow recovery from the Great Recession. No quick solutions have been forthcoming in any of these and other related daunting economic challenges as sharp ideological and partisan differences have brought the federal budgetary process to a virtual standstill and gridlock has taken Washington hostage in what could be called a war of perpetual attrition. Democrats and Republican (and liberals and conservatives) seem content and committed “to slugging it out” until the last man/women falls. In the Publius overview of the Annual Review of Federalism in 2011-12, Gamkhar and Pickerill (212, 359) wrote: “The federal executive branch remained embroiled in political standoffs with Congress on debt and budget issues.” This statement is still the most accurate description of fiscal federalism in 2014. Moreover, since 2013, the federal government has flirted with what would have been a crippling government shutdown, narrowly averted going over the fiscal cliff, and “played chicken” with automatic budget cuts (sequestration) that would have taken $1.2 trillion out of the budget over the next ten years. Ideological and partisan roadblocks not only threaten vital federal programs but also create uncertainty about intergovernmental transfers for state and localities’ budgeting efforts. This is significant because budgetary decisions at the federal level will be pivotal as intergovernmental transfers are a large part of state and local government budgets. 18 More than in previous decades, states are now in a precarious and vulnerable position. Many of them are just beginning to see noteworthy improvements in their economies. Fortythree states enacted higher spending budgets in FY2013 than in the previous year. And while state revenue collections in FY2013 surpassed pre-Great Recession levels in 2008 (5.7 percent increase), states project that revenues will rise by only 0.8 percent in FY2014 (NASBO 2013a). The ARRA stimulus grants-in-aid helped states to recover from average general fund decreases of 3 percent in FY2009 and 6.5 percent in FY2010 to modest 4 percent increases in FY2011 and FY2012 and a smaller increase of 2 percent in FY2013 (NASBO 2013b). Unfortunately, federal grants to states fell faster than state revenues grew. Although most states enacted higher budgets, the average state budget was authorized to increase by about 2 percent in 2013 (NASBO 2013a). And even though some states were able to partially replenish their fund balances or “rainy day funds,” several finished FY2013 with a zeroed ending balance (NASBO 2013a). Then, only around half of the states predict a fund balance over 5 percent of state expenditures in FY2014, a percentage considered to be insufficient to smooth state expenditures in case of physical or fiscal disaster (NASBO 2013a). Simply put, while a considerable number of states have achieved a degree of stability in their own-source revenues, others are still working on a thin margin. To repeat the obvious, the federal government’s budget has an enormous effect on subnational governments. Federal grant-in-aid programs, both competitive and matching, have increased the dependence of states and their local governments on national funding. In spite of the fact that the number of federal grants has varied over the past half century, overall more state agencies receive federal funding than ever before, with 75 percent of agencies receiving federal monies. In fact, over half of those receiving federal funds are dependent on intergovernmental 19 transfers for more than 25 percent of their overall budgets (U.S. Department of Education 2013). Because of this growing dependence on federal funding since the 1950s, state and local governments will have problems cutting their services in response to reductions in federal grantsin-aids. Just as fiscal federalism continues to define IGR in the early part of the twenty-first century, constitutional federalism also continues to shape federal-state, federal-local, and federalstate-local relations. In the last several years, the U.S. Supreme Court has decided cases with significant federalism consequences. While some of these decisions have provided further protection for sovereign state immunity, others have reasserted the legal authority of the national government to preempt state laws. In perhaps the most celebrated case to be handed down in several decades, the Supreme Court in National Federation of Independent Business v. Sebellius (NFIB) (507 S. Ct. 2566, 2012) ruled on the constitutionality of President Obama’s signature piece of legislation—the PPACA. Writing for the 5-4 majority, Chief Justice John Roberts upheld almost the entire Act, as well as the controversial “individual mandate” that requires individuals to buy health insurance and penalizing those who can afford to purchase insurance but do not. Seen by many, including the media, as a victory for President Obama, the majority opinion was a nuanced one that, while upholding the act under Congress’s taxing power, also established some clear and potentially important limitations on federal power with protections for states. In an odd twist and as a surprise to many Court observers, Roberts reasoned that the individual mandate could not be upheld using the commerce clause but could be upheld under Congress’ power to tax.1 In this respect, the Court’s decision can be viewed as reinforcing and possibly expanding the limitations 20 placed on the commerce clause in two influential decisions of the Rehnquist Court—United States v. Lopez (514 U.S.549, 1995) and United States v. Morrison (529 U.S. 598, 2000). Upon further consideration, this case in the future could serve to limit federal authority in another respect. Since the Court in the end concluded that the individual mandate could stand because the penalty for not purchasing health insurance is really a tax, the inference is that for Congress to enact similar policies in the future, it will have to do so through policy procedures that amount to a tax. Although the Court’s decision would make such policies constitutional in a legal sense, members of Congress might find themselves in a politically untenable or at least unpopular position since they would have to justify such policies as a “tax.” While the NFIB case was the most widely known case pertinent to federalism, the Court handed down other decisions that obviously represent a continuing trend of constitutional protections for state sovereignty over the past two decades. In both Coleman v. Court of Appeals of Maryland (132 S. Ct., 1327, 2012) and Nevada Department of Human Resources v. Hibbs (538 U.S. 721, 2003), the Court provided further protection for states from law suits and reinforced and adhered to the high bar that Rehnquist Court decisions had set for abrogating sovereign immunity. While it can be seen that the Court has taken several opportunities to restrict federal authority and even reaffirm support for state sovereignty, it has also remained active in deciding cases involving federal preemption of state laws. These holdings in these more recent cases have been consistent with earlier Rehnquist Court decisions in siding with the federal government. In in Arizona v. United States (132 S. Ct. 2492, 2012) (cited and discussed in another context later in the paper), the Court held that three of four provisions of an Arizona law (known as SB 1070) intended to discourage and curb illegal immigration into the state was preempted by federal 21 regulation laws. Also, in 2012, the Court decided in Kurns v. Railroad Friction Products Corp. (565 U.S, ___ ) that a federal law (Locomotive Inspection Act) extensively regulated all design aspects of locomotives and preempted state law on any issues involving design effects. What’s New? “Fragmented federalism” is becoming more and more noticeable from the burgeoning patchwork of policies that are popping up across the country. American federalism, by its very nature, produces variation across states; that is, states serve as laboratories of democracy where creative or innovative ideas or policy experimentation are permitted and encouraged. In recent years, however, one sees differentiation occurring not necessarily because of the particularistic needs of the state or its efforts to improve the quality of services or even to enhance servicedelivery efficiency or service effectiveness. Instead, differentiation is driven by at least three other reasons—political polarization, in action of the federal government, and state efforts to cope with federal mandates. Political Polarization Increasing political party polarization continues to have an influence on both short- and long-term governance at all levels of government as well as on IGR. For many observers both inside and outside of government, the distance between the two major political parties has never been greater (see Poole and Rosenthal 2012). Intense partisanship was a distinguishing feature characterizing the conduct and impact of the 2008 and 2012 elections and will likely continue to shape federalism and IGR in the years ahead. Evidence of this lasting effect can be seen from legislative and policy decision-making that occurs within the context of the ongoing ideological divide between the Democratic and Republican parties. According to Bowling and Pickerill, “there is a prominent and prolonged level of heightened partisanship that accompanies seemingly 22 every major policy, budget, and implementation decision at the state and federal levels of government as well as the interactions between them” (2013, 317). Party tensions at the national levels between the two parties have resulted in them being unable to reach compromises on most important policy issues, including the budget. Simply stated, the increasing party polarization coupled with divided party control of the executive and legislative branches has brought “gridlock” to an entirely new level in the past few years. With increasing frequency, one sees political parties (along with factions within the parties, interest groups, and unions) engaging in protracted and passionate battles often depicted as zero-sum games, where there is only a winner or loser and no thought being given to a compromise between divergent views. Unlike the national government which has been embroiled in gridlock, many state governments with conservative Republican governors and Republican-controlled legislatures have been able to make changes to state policy more easily. Specifically, Republicans in these states were able to advance policy agendas on controversial issues like abortion, public sector unionization, gun control, elections, and immigration. Many of these policies, which can be best characterized as extreme policy responses, have resulted in an exaggerated from of “fragmented federalism” or a patchwork of policies across the country created by factions and implemented in fragments. This is perhaps best illustrated by some states’ immigration laws. In a recent study, Schraufnagel and Marquez (2013) report that restrictive immigration policies are positively related to growth in the state’s Hispanic population and Republican control of the legislative and executive branches while negatively related to state legislative professionalism. Extreme partisanship has also been responsible for intense “pushback” scenarios, most notably in the fields of health care, education, and elections. States and local governments have always objected to federal government intrusion into the first of these arenas and have seen 23 federal actions as treading on state sovereignty. With respect to health care and education, state and local governments questions the extent to which the federal government should be involved in the regulation of health care choices and educational goals. Even in the area of elections where the federal government does have the authority to insure against discrimination in both voter registration and the operation of elections, states and local government express a strong dislike for the imposition of “Big Brother” type oversight. The PPACA will probably be remembered as one of the most controversial pieces of legislation to be adopted by the Congress in recent memory. Over the last four years, several parts of the law that are aimed at requiring changes in insurance systems, and thereby regulatory in nature, have already gone into effect. They include requiring insurance companies to provide coverage for adult children (until the age of twenty-six years), requiring coverage of preventative services, limiting the percentage of funds that insurance companies can spend on administration, and prohibiting insurance policies from creating or enforcing yearly or lifetime benefits limits as well as preexisting conditions exclusions. However, a new round of partisan bickering has begun over two larger, and more expensive and expansive, provisions of the law—required Medicaid expansion and the creation of state insurance exchanges. The result has been the creation of pushbacks in two different directions--state governments pushing back against the federal government and the federal government pushing back against the states. On one hand, partisan state pushback has resulted where the U.S. Supreme Court in NFIB, nullifying the overly coercive requirement that all states expand Medicaid coverage or face massive losses in federal funding. In essence, expansion decisions are no longer federal mandates but sovereign state choices. On the other hand, pushback by the federal government toward the states has put conservative states in an untenable position with respect to the creation 24 of health exchanges. That is, their choices are either to adopt the minimal undesired standards required by the progressive federal policy or step aside and permit the federal government to operate the health exchanges. While there is speculation as to how states (but especially those where there is intense opposition to the PPACA) will respond to these two provisions of the law (see Bowling and Pickerill 2013; Kaiser Family Foundation 2013; Rigby and Haselswerdt 2013), states’ actions are certain to add complexity to IGR through its diverse and fragmented implementation. In short, shared implementation will leave oversight fragmented. Federal Inaction Variance and fragmentation in federalism and subsequently in IGR is also created by the failure (or perception of failure) of the federal government to act in areas traditionally seen in their domain. Subsequently, a number of states have resisted the federal government or adopted their own laws in immigration policy and regulation of “fracking.” In the area of education, frustrated state and local government officials operate in an environment of uncertainty and must proceed as best they can due to the lack of guidance from the federal government. Historically, citizenship requirements come under the scope of federally-delegated powers and immigration has traditionally has been a national, rather than a state, policy concern. However, numerous failures to enact meaningful immigration reform at the national level have been used as justification for a dramatic increase in states adopting their own legislation in this area. Since 2001, Congress has considered but failed to adopt several pieces of immigration legislation, including the Secure America and Orderly Immigration Act (2005), two Comprehensive Immigration Reform Acts (2006 and 2007), and other pieces of immigration reform legislation under headings like development, relief, and education for alien minors (DREAM Acts). In addition, one DREAM measure did pass the House of Representatives in 25 2010 but the measure failed to get the sixty votes required to invoke cloture and permit a Senate floor vote. In 2012, President Obama weighed in on the subject by issuing an executive order to protect immigrants who would have been eligible for relief under the 2010 Act that granted them work permits and relief from deportation. Also, in 2012 and as mentioned earlier in the paper, the Supreme Court struck down some provisions of Arizona’s controversial immigration law in Arizona v. United States. Yet, the Court left intact a provision authorizing state and local police to investigate the immigration status of individuals they encounter in the course of their duties. On some level, these recent federal action might be interpreted as a reassertion of national government authority in the realm of immigration policy. Nevertheless, there is still no comprehension action on the part of Congress. Since passage of the Elementary and Secondary Education Act (ESEA) in 1962 and creation of the U.S. Department of Education, the federal government has been playing an increasingly important role in education. States and local school districts more than ever look to the federal government for leadership, financial support, and accountability. Yet, in recent years, assistance in these and in other areas has waned. Not only is the federal government unable to act quickly, decisively, and boldly in important educational matters it has also created an environment of uncertainty for state and local governments. At present, four policies are working together to produce uncertainty. First, the No Child Left Behind (NCLB) component of the last reauthorization of the ESEA in 2001 is pushing state governments and the federal government toward an inevitable fiscal showdown. States are facing a 2014 deadline to meet the goal of having 100 percent of students reach proficiency in reading and math. If this target is not met, states stand to lose federal funding. By all accounts, no state will meet this requirement by this year, and one recent report estimates that as many as 26 80 percent of school will be in this situation. The loss of these funds along with the loss of funding most localities suffered during the Great Recession, public education, but particularly in poor districts, would be devastated. Yet, legislative overhaul of NCLB is not imminent. The inability or unwillingness of members of Congress to compromise on issues like the creation of charter schools, state flexibility in the use of federal funds, and teacher accountability has led to a second policy contributing to states’ uncertainty for state and local education systems. Without new congressional legislation, the president and U.S. Secretary of Education have used executive authority to grant waivers to states who would meet certain requirements (e.g., new state standards, new methods of evaluating and aiding low performing schools, new personnel evaluation systems, and streamlining state reporting systems. To date, a significant number of states have applied for and received waivers. However, these states worry about how the reforms they have implemented will fit with federal guidelines when and if ESEA is reauthorized. In any event, uncertainty is made worse by federalism “end-runs” around partisan factions. The third federal policy, which is part of the Obama administration federal stimulus package, is the Race to the Top (RTTT). The RTTT grants have been awarded to states that applied and agreed to meet the criteria of the program, which are comparable to the rules required by NCLB waivers. The most difficult part of RTTT is getting agreement on the use of new performance-based teacher and principal evaluations and pay scales that are tied to increases in students’ test scores. Another complicating factor in implementing these programs is the fact that, while over $4 billion has been granted to state applicants, some states are having difficulty implementing programs because of opposition from teachers’ unions and lobbies. An additional 27 concern is that some states refused to apply for the grants. Thus, uncertainty looms large for states and school districts as they try to follow yet a third set of criteria. A fourth factor creating uncertainty is the rapidly approaching end of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA) stimulus funding. Since 2009, over $100 billion of stimulus funding was allocated to education and about a third of this money was in the form of budget stabilization funds that assisted states and localities avoid some employee layoffs and reduction in services. In spite of the fact that state revenue collections are improving, they are not necessarily growing as quickly as the stimulus funds are being reduced. In some instances, states have been able to make up the difference by shifting funds previously allocated to other program areas. However, if the threats posed by the implementation of federal sequestration materialize after 2014, education funding could be in peril. The case of fracking represents an unusual case of the [un]involvement of the federal government in a newly emerging area. Historically, the federal government has played a primary role in regulatory policy in commence matters by setting broad parameters and state and local governments acting as the principal implementers. But, the case of fracking” is unusual because, unlike a classic federalism problem in which states act in the absence of federal regulation, here the federal government has largely and deliberately cut itself out of the regulatory picture in ways that are seemingly more conducive to the big business interests in the state and the states themselves” (Warner and Shapiro 2013, 474-475). The consequence of what amounts to an abdication of federal regulatory authority has been the development of a fractured and fragmented regulatory policy nationwide, increased court action, and interstate conflict over the transport of fracking waster across state lines (Warner and Shapiro 2023).. 28 Federal Mandates In addition, differentiation and fragmentation in federalism and subsequently IGR is the product of state efforts to cope with federal mandates or satisfy conditions of aid in areas like education, elections, and health care. Federal-state hybrids emerge as states seek to retain elements of their own programs even as mandates, preemptions, and conditions of aid create new processes and dependencies. In the area of education, however, state and local government are hit with a “double whammy.” Federal mandates and conditions of aid not only create uncertainty but also present daunting challenges to state and local governments in their efforts to achieve compliance in the implementation of federal policy. As seen above, states and their local school districts have had to continually requests waivers when compliance with mandates such as those in NCLB and RTTT is not possible. This places not only undue burdens on these governments but also creates a fragmented and disjointed array of different compliance standards and exceptions for different states and areas of the country. This fragmentation is also evident in the elections and health care policy areas (see Shelly 2013: Nussbaumer 2013; Hale and Brown 2013) as sub-national control of the administration of federal elections and the delivery of health care services creates complex networks of dependencies and interdependencies between the national and sub-national governments. Navigating mandates or even conditions for federal aid, as two scholars (Nugent 2009; Shelly 2013) have suggested, has meant that state and local governments increasingly feel the need to engage the federal government over the terms of programs for which they traditionally have had implementation responsibility (e.g., education, elections, and health care). More and more, state and local officials think that they can no longer depend on constitutional protections of their power and federal deference to state supremacy on certain policy issues of vital interest 29 to them and their citizens. Since 1990, waivers have become an important “informal and extraconstitutional safeguard” of state power and one of the most common methods by which federal and state governments have reached accommodation on mandates and conditions for aid that cause dispute (Nugent 2009). Both the federal government and the state governments have numerous reasons to seek flexibility in the implementation of conditions attached to federal grants-in-aid and compliance with federal mandates. For their part, state and local officials governments want to continue to receive federal funding and gain input into the content of the program they will implement, as well as benefit from a reduction in the amount of federal oversight and even be permitted to modify policies to fit specific state needs (Weissert and Weissert 2008). As for federal policy makers who may want to implement bold reforms successfully, they understand that state and local governments have considerable experience in certain issues or knowledge of relevant conditions, and this can provide an opportunity to “borrow strength” from the states or create a sense of raison d’etre or legitimacy for federal involvement (see Manna 2006). In addition, Congress and the President may view waivers as an opportunity to push decisions on polarizing topics that could derail legislation onto administrators and to avoid difficult decisions about the nuts and bolts of policy implementation and blame when a policy goes wrong. Waivers in education, health care, and election policy may have other positive governance qualities. For instance, waivers permit states with less developed capacity to still participate in a program and address the issues that gave rise to it. Moreover, those states with more developed capacity may be able to experiment with alternative approaches and may become models for future nationwide reform. With that said, however, the increasing incidence of state and local governments “cutting deals” with federal authorities via waivers ultimately 30 results in a patchwork of implementation policies scattered across the country rather than a uniform set of standards for everyone to follow. Such is the case with regard to federal-state, federal-local, and federal-state-local implementation policies in the areas of education, elections, and health care. In sum, the federal government remains factionalized and fragmented which also characterizes its relationships with both state and local government as well as the relations that the federal, state, and local governments have with one another. State-Local Relations The state of state-local relations, whether it be a snapshot of the present or an assessment over time, must always be considered within the context or knowledge of local governments being creatures of their state. Some have compared the relationship between states and their local government to that of the relations between parents and their children, where states like parents set rules and expectations and local governments like children obey and carry out assigned responsibilities. Therefore, from the outset, state-local relationships were cast in the form of an inferior entity doing the bidding or a superior entity. These early notions about statelocal relations were reinforced when Dillon’s rule was promulgated in what seemed to be a obscure ruling of an Iowa judge in 1868 in the case of City of Clinton v. Cedar Rapids and Missouri Railroad Company (24 Iowa 455). Over time, however, the grant of various degrees of home rule to counties and municipalities has resulted in a moderation in this rather hierarchical, top-down legal arrangement that exists between states and localities. Nonetheless, the presentday legal relationship between states and their local governments, like what was the case a hundred or two hundred years ago, still sets the tone for state-local relations. 31 When functioning as administrative arms (or “branch” or “satellite” offices) of their state government or as semi-autonomous local governments, counties and municipalities (and even townships and school and special districts) are still legally creatures of the state. This arrangement therefore can lead to relations ranging from cooperation to conflict and from harmony to friction. In reality, interactions fitting these descriptions are found in a number of policy areas, but most likely when the issues relate to revenue-raising limits, state mandates, and home rule. In sizing up state-local relations since the approximate beginning of Wright’s contractive phase, it is reasonable to conclude that not much changed. More specifically, local officials complain about overbearing state regulatory oversight, top-down management approach, lack of revenue flexibility, burdensome and costly state mandates, too little shared governance, and insensitivity to or lack of respect for a local government perspective. State officials counter by saying that, given the unitary nature of the legal status of local governments and expectations of citizens that they maintain a vigilant watch for over overzealous, incompetent, or even corrupt local officials, they are simply doing their job. However, both state and local officials are quick to point out that some of the heightened tension found in state-local relations has been exacerbated because Congress has become more polarized, the president and Congress are constantly at loggerheads (i.e., divided government), intense partisanship has become a fixture at the national and state level, and the Great Recession is still causing lingering economic pains. From a macro-level perspective, it is easy to see that local officials are not reticent about pushing back at state officials,2 while a fair amount of state-local negotiation over divisive issues is on the rise. In examining the most likely areas of contention (program cut-backs, revenue 32 inflexibility, state mandates, and home rule), a pattern of fend-for-yourself federalism nonetheless seems like an accurate portrayal of state-local relations since the 1990s. The fend-for-yourself descriptor of state-local relations is most evident with respect to the related issues of state programmatic cut-backs, dwindling state aid, and inflexibility in local revenue options. In the last several decades, state revenues have been erratic and revenue stability has eluded many states due to a number of significant downturns in the economic and changing taxpayer moods, while the effects of the Great Recession have been compared to the cataclysmic era of the Great Depression. Beginning in 2008, state revenues began to decline precipitously and have only begun to show signs of modestly increasing (Bowling and Pickerill 2013; NASBO 2013a). Moreover, most states had exhausted their rainy day funds by 2011 (Prah 2011). State revenue projections for the years ahead, while guardedly optimistic, may languish for some time. This means that state governments, constrained by economic and political resistance to raising taxes as well as constitutional requirements to balance their budgets, have had to make deep cuts in public services. This situation may continue for some time. The service hit the hardest by state cuts has been public education, since it is the largest discretionary budget item in state control; states have also cut higher education funding radically. K-12 education cuts led to the loss of thousands of jobs among teachers and support staff and produced a huge outcry from the public and, of course, from local school districts and employee unions. In response to these cuts, numerous lawsuits were filed. Additional fallout from these funding cuts occurred when local school districts and city and county operated schools fell out of compliance with state education budgeting rules and legislation as well as mandated requirement associated with NCLB and RTTT. 33 Although welfare is not a big budget item for states, welfare programs also were hit hard during the Great Recession, undermining the national social safety net when it is most needed. Nationwide, the welfare cuts affected roughly 700,000 families and 1.3 million children who were dropped from various assistance programs at the height of the crisis in 2011 (Schott and Pavetti 2011). Needless to say, this situation heightened state-local tensions when local officials in major urban centers and large central cities with large dependent populations had to find ways (possibly through reallocation of funds from other programmatic areas) to assist the truly needy. As expected, state budget woes in recent years did not bode well for local governments for other reasons. Specifically, state aid to localities, on average, constitutes from 30 to 40 percent of local revenue—a significant portion of their budgets. Again, the Great Recession has made it necessary for a number of states to drastically cut local aid besides the public school funding cuts. For instance, Ohio cut aid to localities by one-half in one year (2011), while Nebraska cut all state aid to cities and counties entirely in 2001 as well (Gurwitt 2011). The legislators in these states maintained that they would balance the cuts in aid by reforming state laws regarding collective bargaining to reduce costs at the local level and incentivizing cost savings at the local level by starting targeted aid programs (Gamkhar and Pickerill 2012). However, frustrated local officials were hardly placated by these gestures and another “dagger to the heart” of state-local relations had been delivered. One of the most contentious state-local issues has to do with state restrictions of revenueraising abilities. State governments have long imposed controls on nearly all aspects of local financial management—assessment, taxation, indebtedness, budgeting, accounting, auditing, financing, and, of course, revenue sources. In the 1970s, local government stepped up the pace of lobbying state legislatures for greater authority to set reasonable property tax rates (subject 34 citizenry approval) and to tap a larger variety of revenue sources. Fiscal stress has become a common ailment of many local governments over the last four decades and not just an isolated phenomenon. Fiscal stress continues to plague local governments of all sizes and is not a respecter of section of the country or form of government. Yet, state governments have for the most part been very reluctant to acquiesce to pleas to grant greater latitude and flexibility in revenue schemes. In fact, in recent years (even during the midst of the Great Recession), we have seen a wave of new restrictions that have “centered not so much on keeping local governments out of financial trouble as on reducing local governments’ demands of taxpayers” Berman 2005, 51). Other state-imposed limitations on local finances have to do with local borrowing, and this can sometimes encourage localities to bypass limits by creating special districts and authorities. While this may solve one problem, it can also create two other problems—the negative side-effect of producing fragmentation in service delivery and less accountability. Another sore spot in state-local relations is the issue of costly and burdensome mandates, many of which are unfunded. In fact, mandates serve to worsen state-local relations at a time like the Great Recession when revenues are in short supply and state aid is shrinking. This situation has prompted Zimmerman to refer to mandates as “the principal irritants of staterelations” (1987, 78). While some mandates cost relatively little money, their collective effects can have a dramatic impact on local government budgets. In fact, the cumulative effect of bigticket service expenditures in areas like health care, education, land use, judicial and court systems, and environmental protection can overwhelm county and municipal budgets (Berman 2008, 47). Without mandate reimbursement or mandate rollbacks, local governments facing their own financial constraints and fiscal stress are hard put to provide simultaneously mandated 35 services and services identified by constituents as high priorities. Over the years, municipal and county officials who believe that they should not have to both “obey and pay” have lobbied state legislatures basically to no avail in efforts to prevent the enactment of costly mandates or even repeal existing mandates (Benton 2012). A final area of long-standing contentiousness in state-local relations is that of home rule. Again, owing to the fact that local units of governments are creations of their state, local governments have no right to home rule authority. States have advanced slowly and cautiously toward authorizing some type of local home rule, but this progress has done little to change or even challenge fundamental assumptions about the legal status of counties and municipalities. In fact, home rule jurisdictions have few of the protections against capricious state action that private corporations, also chartered by the states, commonly enjoy (Berman 2005). And, although local governments with home rule are usually better off than those that do not have this protection, “local governments, with or without home rule, have limited power to initiate action and spend much time and energy trying to ward off mandates, preemptions, and prohibitions that further limit their authority” (Berman 2005, 46). In sum, state-local relations, while showing some relatively modest signs of moving in a more positive direction over the last forty years, are still basically in a contentious state and fraught with enduring tensions that will not be resolved any time soon. Interlocal Relations For many years, interlocal relations were marred by turf wars, jurisdictional jealousies, and petty rivalries. Common descriptions of local officials by media and state officials was that they were too laid back, lazy, incompetent, intellectually challenged, corrupt, inept, and operate with a backwater mentality. Consequently, state and local textbook and commission report 36 treatments of local governments and their officials often have characterized them in unflattering ways. Moreover, anecdotal stories of urban politics, service delivery, and governance-styles seemed to confirm these characterizations. Most importantly, local governments seemed to follow a “go-it-alone approach in the provision of myriad services (many of which had metropolitan or area-wide implications) and only infrequently communicated with one another about common areas of interest and a broad spectrum of issues where collaboration made a lot of sense intuitively as well as from a practical perspective. Perhaps most unforgiving was the unwillingness to think beyond their borders and explore opportunities for realizing cost savings and efficiencies which collaboration likely could have provided. Not surprisingly, referenda on city-county consolidations (with a handful of some notable exceptions) were rejected by voters after heavy opposition was usually expressed by county and municipal officials. Beginning in the 1980s, local governments and their officials, now feeling the deleterious effects of fiscal stress and retrenchment and the brunt of taxpayer revolts, seemed to be warming up to the idea of pursuing collaborative ventures with other governments. Unlike the relatively few large cities of the mid-1970s that experienced near-fiscal collapse, insolvency, and default of debt, fiscal problems and uncertainly engulfed cities and counties of all sizes and in parts of the country. With encouragement from the federal government and requirements built into the A-95 review process, local governments were also beginning to think regionally in areas like planning and zoning, land use, conservation and environmental protection, water supply, sewage disposal, and solid waste management. But more than anything else, it was the eroding tax base, taxpayer disgruntlement, a faltering economy, and sharp cut-backs in federal grant-in-aid monies (and, in some instances, state aid) that convinced local government officials to put the option of collaborative service provision on the table for serious consideration. Yet, there was still a 37 hesitancy to engage in collaboration when divisive and sticky issues like loss of autonomy and shared governance were likely collaboration tradeoffs. Local officials, while intrigued with the prospects for interlocal collaboration and the benefits of it, proceeded with extreme caution and doubt. In the end, there was only a modest spike in interlocal collaborative ventures. The real push to consider seriously interlocal collaboration however did not occur until the onset of the Great Recession. By all indications, it took a major jolt to the economy similar in magnitude to the Great Depression to persuade local officials to abandon their parochial mentality and get past dislikes for and distrust of jurisdictional neighbors as well other stereotypical views of how local governments ought to operate and seriously consider and pursue interlocal collaborative opportunities. As one local government official in Florida in 2009 candidly admitted when asked why his city had begun to actively study and enter into serious negotiations with neighboring cities and the county to jointly fund and provide services like sewage disposal, solid waste management, vehicle purchasing and maintenance, IT training, roadside mowing, and parks and recreation, “it was like a gun had been put to our head and the option of in-house production and provision was no longer a viable one” (Benton, Aikins, and Miller 2009). In a recent article in a special issue of State and Local Government Review that was devoted to local government collaboration, Carr and Hawkins perhaps sum up the reason why local governments feel compelled more than ever to engage in collaborative efforts. They write that “the fiscal realities many local government face represent a ‘new normal’ in which accountability to the public is a public agenda priority” (2013, 224). This assessment is congruent with the conclusions drawn by others who have also studied interlocal collaboration (Martin, Levey, and Cawley 2012; Elling, Krawczyk, and Carr 2013). For many local governments, delivering high-quality services within the constraints they now encounter is a 38 serious concern. Therefore, these pressures have prompted greater interest than ever before in creating more shared service delivery arrangements and focused attention on the difficulties involved in managing complex relationships among participants in cooperative efforts (Zeemering 2007, 2008; Hawkins 2009; LeRoux, Brandenburger, and Pandey 2010; LeRoux and Carr 2010; Scholz and Feiock 2010). Other evidence exists that there has been a resurgence of interest in collaborative service provision during the Great Recesssion (Perlman and Benton 2012, Benton, Aikins, and Miller 2009). Moreover, a recent survey of local government officials found that collaboration with other local governments “top[ped] the list of trends taking center stage in 2013 (Reach the Public 2013). While organizations like the Interntional City/County Management Association, National League of Cities, and National Association of Counties, as well as “good government” groups and study commissions have endorsed the utilization of collaboration in service delivery and identify them as win-win scenarios, they are actively providing a rich cache of information and a virtual “how to” toolbox or library of guides and instructions via reports, case studies, best cases, webinars, conferences, workshops to walk a local government through the process of planning for, designing, executing, and monitoring collaborative efforts. If this is not incentive enough, some state governments are actively pushing local governments to become more proactive in both the consideration of and participation in collaborative service delivery efforts (Franzel, Newfarmer, and Stenberg 2013). To sum up, collaboration in the provision of local government services is a significant and compelling new and evolving feature and currently defines the state of interlocal relations. 39 Emergence of a New Eighth Phase? In my summary assessment of the state of American federalism and IGR over the last four decades, it does not appear that enough has changed to herald the emergence of a new or eighth phase of IGR. Yet, as history has taught us, American federalism and IGR are not static or in a perfect or perpetual state of equilibrium. Change has occurred, and some of it has been significant and even dramatic. Furthermore, this change has had an obvious and profound impact on the content and tenor of federalism and relations between officials at the federal, state, and local levels of government. These changes, like changes in the past, have been prompted by the necessity to respond to new and extraordinary political, economic, and social problems and to the new realities associated with public opinion, ideology, and partisan shifts. What has been happening in recent years in the federal system and to IGR can be best described as a continuous process of further refining or flushing out the basic contours and boundaries of the contractive phase. At the same time, there has also been an unremitting layering or superimposing of many of the earlier phases of IGR on top of the current contractive phase. With that said, there is clear evidence of two newly evolving patterns in IGR. First, there is the reoccurring picture of increased fragmentation in federal-state, federal-local, and federalstate-local relations, where there is a patchwork of polices across the country. As seen in the summary assessment earlier, one of the elements of “fragmented federalism” is the development of state-specific policy. Many times, these policies are fashioned in response to a perceived need to which the federal government has failed to respond to, even though it may be a purported “national interest.” A second element can be seen in state policies that might be developed in response to federal guidelines, like in the case of education waivers (NCLB) or health insurance/Medicaid (PPACA). Another element can be found in state-specific policies that have 40 high political salience and are motivated at least in part by partisanship (immigration reform, abortion restrictions, right-to work laws, and legalization of same sex marriages and marijuana). In sum, IGR are deeply affected by political factions, and fragmentation continues as state policy development and policy implementation occurs in a piecemeal fashion by the states often driven for all the wrong reasons. A second newly evolving pattern that is evident in the interlocal arena is the increasing incidence of collaboration among local governments. While interlocal collaboration has always been an attractive alternative to in-house provision, it had not been widely utilized until local governments began to experience the pains of severe fiscal stress, beginning in the early 1980s. With the onset of the Great Recession and the prediction that the effects would likely linger for most of the remainder of the second decade of the twentieth century and may be beyond, local governments have recognized the dire necessity of findings ways to cut the cost of service provision. There is a “new normal” in how local governments must operate in the future if they are to survive, and interlocal collaboration is likely to be an integral part of this new way that local governments conduct business in an environment with fewer resources and a public that expects leaner government and cost efficiencies. Therefore, the significance of these developing two patterns may suggest the need to add two new federalism metaphorical descriptors (“fragmented federalism” and “collaborative federalism”) to the three descriptors already identified by Wright. These recommended additional descriptors have been inserted (in italics) in Table 1. In addition to these observations about American federalism and IGR and the conclusion that the contractive phase persists, it is important to consider the need for some qualifications as to how various phases of IGR are depicted and subsequently viewed. First, in examining the 41 scholarly literature and the ongoing intellectual dialogue about IGR, it seems that less consideration is given to interlocal relations in spite of the fact there are more interlocal IGR actors and more governments involved than at the national and state levels. Yet, most characterizations of American federalism IGR (including IGR phases) revolve around what is occurring in the federal-state, federal-local, and federal-state-local arenas. Therefore, should these descriptions of IGR, generally, and IGR phases, specifically, be more balanced in their content, discussion, coverage? Would additional scholarly attention to interlocal policies, politics, and issues assist in shedding more light on the need for a balanced treatment in efforts to accurately and fully depict the substance and nature of IGR? A second qualification would be to view, study, and describe IGR, in general, and IGR phases, in particular, from a “multi-angled” perspective. While efforts to generalize about a subject matter as broad and heterogeneous as IGR have their usefulness, much is lost for the sake of brevity and identifying overall common characteristics. Simply put, the diversity of relations, richness of context, uniqueness of mission and goals, and countless nuances implicit in the various IGR arenas is often lost in attempts to summarize and generalize for the sake of simplification and brevity. Therefore, it may be useful for a better understand the federal system and resulting IGR if one were to view them through a kaleidoscope, as suggest by Zimmerman (2008, 201-202). The utility of this approach is that it may lead to varied and more enlightening assessments and portrayals of American federalism and IGR because it allows for the possibility that IGR participant perceptions and IGR mechanisms may differ noticeably from one arena to another. 42 NOTES 1. As noted below, the Courts decision in NFIB also held that the provisions of the PPACA that required states to accept all the conditions placed on them to continue participating in an expanded Medicaid program or forfeit all federal funding for the program were overly coercive on states and violated principles of state sovereignty. This holding again reinforced key Rehnquist Court precedents on state sovereignty, namely New York v. United States (505 U.S. 144, 1992) and Printz v. United States (521 U.S. 898, 1997). In addition, the Medicaid holding seems to put teeth in the Court’s spending clause jurisdiction articulated in South Dakota v. Dole (483 U.S. 203, 1987). 2. For an excellent discussion of local governments pushing back against state policies, see Riverstone-Newell 2012, 2104. 43 REFERENCES Benton, J. Edwin. 2012. “State-City and State-County Fiscal Relations: A Look at the Past and Present and a Glimpse at the Future.” In Networked Governance: The Future of Intergovernmental Management, edited by Jack W. Meek and Kurt Thurmaier, 39-63. Washington, D.C.: CQ Press. __________. 2013. Local Government Collaboration: Considerations, Issues, and Prospects,” State and Local Government Review, 45 (December): 220-223. Benton, J. Edwin, Stephen Aikins, and Michael J. Miller. 2009. Coping With Dwindling Property Tax Revenues: The Tale of Municipalities and Counties in Florida. Report prepared for the Florida City/County Management Association, Florida League of Cities, Florida Association of Counties, and the Florida Government Finance Officers’ Association, August 24. Berman, David R. 2005. “State-Local Relations: Partnerships, Conflict, and Autonomy,” 2005 Municipal Yearbook. Washington, D.C.: International City/County Management Association. __________. 2008. ”State-Local Relations: Authority and Finances,” 2008 Municipal Yearbook. Washington, D.C.: International City/County Management Association. Bowling, Cynthia J. and Mitchell Pickerill. 2013. “Fragmented Federalism: The State of American Federalism 2012-13,” Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 43 (Summer): 315-342. Carr, Jered B., and Christopher V. Hawkins. 2013. “The Costs of Cooperation: What the Research Tells Us about Managing the Risks of Service Collaboration in the U.S.,” State and Local Government Review, 45 (December): 224-239. 44 de Tocqueville, Alexis. 1999. Democracy in America. New York: Westvaco. Elazar, Daniel J. 1984. American Federalism: A View from the States. New York: Harper and Row. Elling, E.C., K. Krawczyk, and J. Carr. 2013. “What Should We Do? Public Attitudes About How Local Government Officials Should Confront Fiscal Stress,” Local Government Studies. Doi: 10.1080/03003930.823408. Franzel, Joshua, Jerry Newfarmer, and Carl Stenberg. 2013. “Collaborative Service Delivery: How States are Pushing Change.” Presentation at the International City/County Management Association Annual Conference, Boston, MA, September 22-25. Gamkhar, Shama, and J. Mitchell Pickerill. 2012. “The State of American Federalism 20112012: A Fend for Yourself and Activist Form of Bottom-Up Federalism,” Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 42 (Summer): 357-386. Grodzins, Morton. 1960. “The Federal System.” In Goals for Americans: The Report of the President’s Commission and National Goals and Chapters Submitted for Consideration of the Commission. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Gurwitt, Rob. 2011. “As States Cut Aid, Localities Learn To Do Less With Less,” Stateline, October 3. Available at http://www.stateline.org/live/details/story?contentId=603292 (Access March 9, 2014). Hale, Kathleen, and Mitchell Brown. 2013. “Adopting, Adapting, and Opting Out: State Response to Federal Voting System Guidelines,” Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 43 (Summer): 428-451. Hawkins, Christopher V. 2009. “Prospects for and Barriers to Local Government Joint Ventures,” State and Local Government Review, 41 (No. 2): 108-119. 45 Kaiser Family Foundation. 2013. “Health Reform,” Statehealthfacts.org. Available at http://www.statehealthfacts.org/index.jsp (accessed March 2, 2014). LeRoux, Kelly, and Jered B. Carr. 2007. “Explaining Local Government Cooperation in Public Works: Evidence from Michigan,” Public Works Management and Policy, 12: 344-358. LeRoux, Kelly, P. W Brandenburger, and S.K. Pandey. 2010. “Interlocal Service Cooperation in U.S. Cities: A Social Network Explanation,” Public Administration Review, 70 (March/April): 268-278. Manna, Paul. 2006. Schools In: Federalism and the National Education Agenda. Washington, D.C.: Georgetown University Press. Martin, Lawrence L., Richard Levey, and Jenna Cawley. 2012. “The ‘New Normal’ for Local Government,” State and Local Government Review, 44 (December): 17S-28S. Marquez, Timothy, and Scot Schraufnagel. 2013. “Hispanic Population Growth and State Immigration Policy: An Analysis of Restriction (2008-12),” Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 43 (Summer): 315-342. McLean, Joseph E. 1952. “Politics is What You Make It.” (pamphlet) New York: Public Affairs Committee. National Association of State Budget Officers (NASBO). 2013a. Fiscal Survey of the States, Fall 2013. Available at http://www.nasbo.org/sites/default/files.Fall%20201320 Fiscal520Survey.pdf (accessed March 3, 2014). National Association of State Budget Officers (NASBO). 2013b. State Expenditure Report: Examining Fiscal 2011-2013 State Spending. Available at http://www.nasbo.org/sites/ default/files/State%20Expenditure%20Report%20%28Fiscal%202011-2013%20Data %29.pdf (accessed March 3, 2014). 46 Nugent, John Douglas. 2009. Safeguarding Federalism: How States Assert Their Interests in National Policymaking. Norman, OK: University of Oklahoma Press. Nussbaumer, Kirsten. 2013. “The Election Law Connection and U.S. Federalism,” Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 43 (Summer): 392-427. O’Toole, Jr., Lawrence J. 2000. American Intergovernmental Relations, 3rd edition. Washington, D.C.: CQ Press. Perlman, Bruce, and J. Edwin Benton. 2012. “Going It Alone: New Survey Data on Economic Recovery Strategies in Local Government,” State and Local Government Review, 44 (December): 5S-16S. Prah, Pamela M. 2011. “States Balance Budgets with Cuts, Not Taxes,” Stateline, June 15. Available at http://www.stateline.org/live/details/story?/contentId+632583. (Accessed March 9, 2014). Reach the Public. 2013. “Collaboration Is a Hot Trend for State and Local Government” Available at http://www.govdelivery.com/blog/2013/collaboration-is-a-hot-trend-forstate-and-local-governments. (Accessed March 8, 2014). Rigby, Elizabeth, and Jake Haselswerdt. 2013. “Hybrid Federalism, Partisan Politics, and Early Implementation of State Health Insurance Exchanges,” Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 43 (Summer): 368-391. Riverstone-Newell, Lori. 2012. “Bottom-Up Activism: A Local Political Strategy for Higher Policy Change,” Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 42 (Summer): 401-421. __________. 2014. Renegade Cities, Public Policy, and the Dilemmas of Federalism. Boulder, CO: Lynn Rienner Publishers, Inc. 47 Scholz, John, and Richard C. Feiock, eds. 2010. Self-Organizing Federalism: Collaborative Mechanisms to Mitigate Institutional Collective Action Dilemmas. New York: Cambridge University Press. Schott, Liz, and LaDona Pavetti. 2011. “Many States Cutting TANF Benefits Harshly Despite High Unemployment and Unprecedented Need,” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. Available at http://www.cbpp.org/cms/?fa=3498 (Accessed March 9, 2014). Shelly, Bryan. 2013. “The Bigger the Better: Cross-Variation in Federal Education and Medicaid Waivers, 1991-2008,” Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 43 (Summer): 452-473. Voteview.com (Keith Poole). 2012. “The polarization of Congressional Parties.” Available at http://www.voteview.com/political_polarization.asp (accessed March 2, 2014). Warner, Barbara, and Jennifer Shapiro. 2013. “Fractured, Fragmented Federalism: A Study in Franking Regulatory Policy,” Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 43 (Summer): 474496. Weissert, Carol S., and William G.Weissert. 2008. “Medicaid Waivers: License to Shape the Future of Federalism.” In Intergovernmental Management for the Twentieth-First Century, edited by Timonthy J. Conlan, Paul L. Posner, and National Academy of Public Administration, 157-175. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institute Wright, Deil S. 1988. Understanding Intergovernmental Relations, 3rd edition. Belmont, CA: Brooks/Cole Publishing Company. Zeemering, Eric S. 2007. Who Collaborates? Local Decisions About Intergovernmental Relations. Unpublished Dissertation. Indiana University, IN. 48 __________. 2008. “Governing Interlocal Cooperation: City Council Interests and the Implications for Public Management,” Public Administration Review, 68 (July/August) :731-741. Zimmerman, Joseph F. “The State Mandate Problem,” State and Local Government Review, 19 (Spring): 78-79. __________. 1990. “State Mandates and Restraints on Local Discretionary Authority,” Comparative State Politics, 11 (December): 49-56. __________. 2008. Contemporary American Federalism: The Growth of National Power, 2nd edition. Albany, NY: State University Press of New York.