http://www.nomos-shop.de/Dudziak-Capacity-We-Trust/productview.aspx?product=13318 Table of Contents Index of tables List of figures List of graphs List of Abbreviations List of Country Abbreviations 8 9 9 11 11 Part I: 13 Introduction and Background 1. Introduction 1.1 Research question 1.2 The research design and outline of the study 13 15 18 Part II: A theoretical framework for the analysis of social capital and compliance 24 2. Beyond state centered theories – Social capital as neglected explanatory variable in the compliance literature 2.1 Introduction 2.2 What is compliance? 2.3 Social capital and non-compliance with European law 2.4 Social capital as a society-centered concept 2.5 Putnam’s way of understanding 2.6 Summary and discussion of the society-centered approach 2.7 Social Capital and the state: The institution-centered approach 2.8 Conclusion 24 24 25 28 29 30 37 40 47 3. What makes state (and non-state) actors comply with EU law? 3.1 Introduction 3.2 What are non-state actors? 3.3 Theories about compliance 3.4 Conclusion 49 49 49 51 66 5 http://www.nomos-shop.de/Dudziak-Capacity-We-Trust/productview.aspx?product=13318 Part III: The empirical analysis of social and political trust as dependent variables 68 4. Operationalization of hypotheses and indicators 4.1 Introduction 4.2 Measuring the society-centered concept 4.3 What comes first? The relationship between networks, norms, and trust 4.4 Institution-centered approach: operationalization of the indicators 4.5 The impact of institutional fairness and effectiveness on political trust 4.6 What is the relationship between social trust and political trust? 4.7 Conclusion 100 105 107 Part IV: Using a combined research design for analysis 109 5. Quantitative analysis: The consequences of social capital for (non)compliance with EU law 5.1 Introduction 5.2 European regulation 5.3 Infringement proceedings as an indicator for non-compliance 5.4 Measuring the dependent variable – infringements of EU law by member states 5.5 Data set 5.6 Non-compliance with EU law across member states 5.7 Quantitative testing of hypotheses 5.8 Conclusion 6. Qualitative analyis: Implementing EU environmental law in Italy 6.1 Introduction 6.2 The choice of policy sector and policy 6.3 Italy and the development of its environmental policy 6.4 The transposition of the habitats directive in Italy 6.5 Assessing non-compliance with the habitats directive in the Italian regions 6.6 The operationalization of the independent variables 6.7 Summary and discussion of findings 6.8 Apulia 6.9 Conclusion 6 68 68 70 80 84 109 109 110 111 112 114 115 117 137 140 140 143 149 154 156 160 170 172 194 http://www.nomos-shop.de/Dudziak-Capacity-We-Trust/productview.aspx?product=13318 Part V: Conclusion 197 7. Summary of findings, conclusions and outlook 7.1 Introduction 7.2 The consequences of social capital on member state compliance: The main findings 7.3 Contribution to the literature on social capital 7.4 Contribution to the compliance literature 7.5 Recommendations for political practice 7.6 The Outlook 197 197 197 202 205 207 207 Appendices 209 Literature 231 7 http://www.nomos-shop.de/Dudziak-Capacity-We-Trust/productview.aspx?product=13318 Part I: Introduction and Background 1. Introduction Research on compliance with European law has become an academic industry1on its own as the increasing number of articles dealing with the topic demonstrate (Giuliani, 2005: 3; cf. Mastenbroek, 2005).2 Most of the research is dominated by theories of international relations and thus focuses on state-centered approaches in order to explain the frequency of non-compliance between member states in the European Union (Haas, 1998; Mbaye, 2001; Tallberg, 2002; Börzel, 2003; Mastenbroek and Kaeding, 2006; Linos, 2007).3 European law formally addresses member states. It affects national regulation and may strengthen the rights of private actors or constrain their behavior (Davies, 2008). Examples range from the right to environmental and consumer protection, to privacy and data protection (Cafaggi and Watt, 2007). Accordingly, state actors are responsible for effectively enforcing the implementation of European policies, oftentimes against domestic opposition. Having an understanding of why non-state actors accept these rules can help to explain how regulators can best achieve voluntary compliance (Murphy, 2004). The latter aspect is particularly important for countries that cannot rely on strong capacity and enforcement power of the state to reach compliance with European law. This study draws on social capital as a different path to explain why some member states comply with European law better than others (Commission of the European Communities, 2007). The study thereby constitutes a first attempt to systematically integrate the concept of social capital into the theoretical and empirical research on compliance with European law. It thus develops an analytical framework through which the analysis and findings can be structured and compared. Social capital has gained popularity in comparative politics4 and has been adopted by different groups of scholars working on collective action problems (Spronk, 2001), while it has been mostly neglected in the compliance literature. The concept of social capital adds important values to compliance research, as it introduces new 1 In his article on compliance studies, Guiliani uses the term “academic growth industries.” The quote stems from Olsen and regards the growing interests of researchers in Europeanization studies (Olsen, 2002: 921). 2 Guiliani refers in his article to research on compliance with law beyond the nation state including research on both compliance with international and European law. 3 Mastenbroek provides an extensive overview on different strands witihin compliance research (Mastenbroek, 2005). 4 See, for example Barrios and Stefes (2006). 13 http://www.nomos-shop.de/Dudziak-Capacity-We-Trust/productview.aspx?product=13318 solutions to the collective action problem oftentimes constituting non-compliance (Scholz, 1998). It illustrates how solidarity and community-oriented thinking generated by social networks and norms facilitates collective action, which in turn enhances compliance (Putnam, Leonardi and Nanetti, 1993; Putnam, 2001). Social capital draws attention to non-state actors and became empirically famous from Robert Putnam’s5 research on civic participation and institutional performance in Italy and America (Putnam, Leonardi et al., 1993; Putnam, 2000). It refers to (a) the norms of reciprocity and (b) networks of civic engagement (Putnam, 2001: 45). Social trust is born from social capital and “therefore could be easily thought of as a proxy” (Putnam, 2001: 45). Embedded in relations of trust and predictability, social capital breeds civic spirit, participation, and respect for law (Diamond, 2003: 5). While different approaches in the literature agree in general that “trust” as a concept amounts to compliance with (domestic) law (Levi, 1988; Braithwaite and Makkai, 1994; Tyler and Degoey, 1995; Scholz, 1998; Putnam, 2001; Kahan, 2002; Murphy, 2004), they focus on different assumptions of the sources that generate it. They can be divided into an institution-centered (a) and a society-centered aproach (b). The latter (b) claims that social capital is produced by factors of civil society (Putnam 1993; 1995; 2000; Kahan 2002). The former (a) intends to link the concept to a set of formal institutions (Evans, Rueschemeyer and Skocpol, 1985; Ostrom, 1995; Levi, 1998; Murphy, 2004; Rothstein and Stolle, 2008: 278). Accordingly, these two approaches claim different causal mechanisms with distinct underlying logics of social action (logic of rational action vs. logic of appropriateness) that either enhance or prevent the effective implementation of European law in the member states. Hence, trust is a central concept upon which this study draws in order to explore its causal relevance for compliance with EU law. The literature distinguishes between different forms and accounts of trust such as strategic or rational accounts of trust and identity – or group-based accounts of trust, moral trust, and trust in the state and political institutions (Stolle, 2002). The different approaches towards trust are distinguished from each other by their assumptions about the definition of trust, sources, and involved actors. Identity-based forms of trust include only people one personally knows, and those individuals who fit into a certain social identity category that one holds: generalized social trust is concerned with individuals’ general trust in others (Stolle, 2002: 409). Moral trust is based on the understanding that people share underlying values (Uslaner, 2002). Some authors distinguish between trust and confidence (cf. Job, 2005: 2). They understand “confidence as a passive emotion” and trust as something which is based upon “beliefs and commitments” (Sztompka, 1999: 27 as referred to in Job 2005: 2). In this study, trust is synony5 Robert D. Putnam is Peter and Isabel Malkin Professor of Public Policy at Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University. 14 http://www.nomos-shop.de/Dudziak-Capacity-We-Trust/productview.aspx?product=13318 mous with the term confidence6 (c.f. Hardin, 2000: 35). In this sense, trust (political and generalized social trust) is a belief or expectation actors have of others (Hardin, 2002; Farrell, 2005: 462). It is beyond the scope of this work to consider the different types of social trust and to explore its empirical relevance for compliance. The focus of this study is placed on the most prominent strand of argumentation on social trust and compliance, as discussed above. 1.1 Research question When looking at the level of social and political trust of the member states of the European Union (EU) compared with their compliance record, the correlation between these variables is in line with social capital theories (Commission of the European Communities, 1999; World Values, 1999; Commission of the European Communities, 2002; Commission of the European Communities, 2005; Commission of the European Communities, 2007). Countries performing best in complying with EU law present high levels of political and social trust. Those with low levels of trust, fail to comply. The central question of this study therefore asks: how does social capital affect compliance with European law by member states? The independent variable is social capital measured by social and political trust. The dependent variable of this study constitutes compliance with EU law by member states. The majority of the literature adopts the model of social capital as proposed by Putnam to explore its effect on various outcomes, such as economic growth, health or tax evasion (Knack and Keefer, 1997; Van Schaik, 2002; Van der Meer, 2003; Wollebak and Selle, 2003; Sabatini, 2005). A large part of the literature on social capital is concerned with the relationship between social and political trust (Brehm and Rahn, 1997; Van der Meer, 2003; Job, 2005). Few of the studies have attempted to empirically investigate about the impact of institutional performance on trust and compliance. The first researchers to attempt this were first and foremost Levi (1998), Tyler (1990), Braithwaite and Makkai (1994), Rothstein and Stolle (2008). This study asks about the relevance of both social capital research modes - society and institution-centered - to compliance by member states. The purpose of this study is to explore if and how social capital affects compliance by member states. In this study I undertake a systematic application of social capital to compliance research which can serve as a guideline for future research. A second goal of this study is to contribute to both the literature on social capital and compliance beginning with a review of the literature on social capital, from there, developing theoretical arguments about the effects of social capital on com- 6 Institutional trust is applied interchangeably with political trust. 15 http://www.nomos-shop.de/Dudziak-Capacity-We-Trust/productview.aspx?product=13318 pliance. Most compliance research explains the inconsistent rule behavior of state actors and thereby partly considering the role of non-state actors (Lampinen and Uusikylä, 1998; Börzel and Risse, 2000; Mbaye, 2001; Koutalakis, 2004). Oftentimes these studies assign non-state actors a positive role in compliance (Börzel, 2003; Koutalakis, 2004; van der Vleuten, 2005). This study conceptualizes noncompliance with European law by member states as a result of the inconsistent rule behavior of non-state actors. A third goal is to provide empirical and theoretical insights into the effect of social capital and non-state actors on compliance by using quantitative and qualitative research. Most studies conducted on social capital have worked with quantitative methods (Brehm and Rahn, 1997; Knack and Keefer, 1997; Scholz, 1998; Slemrod, 1998; Gabriel, Kunz, Roßteutscher and Van Deth, 2002; Norris, 2002). This study demonstrates a way how qualitative research can be conducted on social capital. It shows to what extent qualitative research adds values to the analysis on social capital and compliance. I shall come back to this point when explaining the research design used in this study. In summary, this work deals with two factors that have been largely ignored in the compliance research: social capital and non-state actors. None of the “three waves of scholarship on EU implementation” (Mastenbroek, 2005) have systematically analysed the role of society, as understood within the social capital paradigm, in compliance with European law. The first wave of EU-related compliance research focused on legal and administrative procedures at the domestic level in order to explain implementation deficits in the member states (Krislov and Ehlermann, 1986; Siedentopf and Ziller, 1988; Demmke, 1994; Ciavarini Azzi, 2000; Demmke, 2001). The analyses cover the transposition, enforcement and application of European law. The variables these studies invoke to explain implementation deficits relate to legal and administrative procedures at the domestic level. This is explained by the academic background of scholars in this field who came either from legal or administrative science (Treib, 2008). The second wave has analysed the degree of fit or misfit between European law and existing domestic legislation (Duina, 1997; Knill and Lenschow, 1998; Börzel, 2003; cf. Kaeding, 2007; cf. Treib, 2008). The central claim is that existing domestic institutional arrangements and regulatory traditions are resistant to change (Kaeding, 2007: 27). If the adaptation of EU law requires significant changes of the regulatory traditions, implementation problems are most likely to occur. I will discuss the misfit hypothesis at length in this study. However, the purpose of this brief review is to underline that the focus was placed on national administrative traditions rather than on (non-state) actor based factors. Later studies find that misfit has only limited explanatory power and lacks empirical evidence and conceptual 16 http://www.nomos-shop.de/Dudziak-Capacity-We-Trust/productview.aspx?product=13318 precision (Haverland, 2000; Héritier, Kerwer, Knill, Lehmkuhl, Teutsch and Douillet, 2001; Falkner, Treib, Hartlapp and Leiber, 2005; cf. Kaeding, 2007: 27). The third wave emerged as a result of the theoretical and empirical problems identified in the first and second waves and is eclectic in nature in terms of theory and methods (cf. Treib, 2008). A first attempt was to theorize and research the role of domestic politics in the implementation of European law (Treib, 2003a; 2003b; Mastenbroek, 2005). Scholars in this research field showed that the political preferences of governments influence effective transposition (Treib, 2003a; Treib, 2003b). In this perspective, smooth implementation is not determined by the goodness of fit of European legislation with existing domestic regulatory traditions. The implementation, here the transposition of European law, is successful if the required reforms are in line with the political party preference of government (Treib, 2008). Haverland explains implementation by the role of institutional veto players7 (Haverland, 2000). In the same vein, Lampinen and Uusikylä (1998), Mbaye (2001) and Guiliani (2003) draw attention to the number of institutional veto players and their impact on implementation. Some studies indirectly consider non-state actors who facilitate compliance with European law (Lampinen and Uusikylä, 1998; Mbaye, 2001; Linos, 2007). These authors conceptualize the role of non-state actors, for example, within support for the European integration. Most quantitative studies define non-compliance as a dichotomous variable. State actors do not comply either involuntary or voluntary. The main arguments are developed in the international relations literature and refer to the enforcement (voluntary non-compliance) and management schools (involuntary compliance). This study analyses the impact of enforcement and managerial variables on implementation. I will therefore not explain them at length at this point. Steunenberg introduces a policy-specific model based on rational arguments. In his model, veto players act in policy-specific ways during the decision-making process (Kaeding, 2007: 28). All these studies of the third wave of compliance resesarch, quantitative and qualitative, provide empirically and theoretically strong insights into implementation. As different as they may be from each other, for example, institutionalist arguments vs. actor-centered ones, they all either ignore the role of non-state actors in compliance or consider them to be just one factor among many in explaining non-compliance by member states. Given the lack of a coherent theoretical framework that systematically analysis the role of non-state actors in compliance, this study will fill this gap by providing a comprehensive theoretically informed, empirical analysis of how the two factors - social capital and the role of non-state actors - influence member states’ compliance with European law. The analysis conceptualizes social capital as a variable, 7 The term institutional veto players refers to Tsebelis who calls them this way if veto players are generated by the constitution (Tsebelis, 2002). 17 http://www.nomos-shop.de/Dudziak-Capacity-We-Trust/productview.aspx?product=13318 and identifies the causal mechanisms that link social capital, non-state actors, and member state compliance. I inquire into the role of social capital and non-state actors in compliance by developing hypotheses which can be empirically investigated. The central findings of this study show that low political trust, rather than low social trust, explains the non-compliant behavior non-state actors which in turn lead to non-compliance with European law by member states. A second finding suggests that two factors, fairness (administrative corruption) and state capacity, determine the level of trust in national institutions and state compliance with European law. It thereby confirms other studies which have shown how low state capacity directly accounts for non-compliance by member states (Hille and Knill, 2006; Börzel et al., 2007). The added value of this work to the compliance research is that it empirically traces how limited state capacity also impacts the compliant behavior of non-state actors, leading to compliance failure in member states. In particular, this holds true if non-state actors already possess low capacities. Hence, the occurence of weak states and weak societies goes together (Goetz, 2008; Sissenich, 2010). Weak state capacities impair the capacity-building of non-state actors as it prevents, for example, the sharing of information on compliance requirements. In this analysis I trace how inefficient and ineffective working institutions generate perceptions by non-state actors that state actors are corrupt which in turn determines their feelings of trust in them. The perception of institutions, and their trustworthiness, significantly influences the willingness of non-state actors to comply with rules. In sum, weak state capacity causes both the non-compliant behavior of state and non-state actors, at which one of the two causal mechanisms works through trust in institutions (political trust). Following this, I argue that social capital placed in the realm of society contributes to a strong state. However, the building of social capital requires state infrastructure in the first place which allows groups of individuals to act collectively. 1.2 The research design and outline of the study This study employs both quantitative and qualitative methods in order to empirically test a set of hypotheses derived from the social capital literature related to compliance. The study is divided into five parts. After the introduction, the second part introduces social capital as a neglected variable in the compliance literature. First, it provides an overview on the body of literature that is most relevant to the theoretical, methodological, and empirical focus of this study. I argue that social capital constitutes an important variable that should be considered in the analyses of the compliance literature. Second, the focus of part two moves on to the theo- 18 http://www.nomos-shop.de/Dudziak-Capacity-We-Trust/productview.aspx?product=13318 retical arguments of social capital. It aims to define and conceptualize social capital from above (institution-centered) and below (society-centered) as a variable. Third, I derive hypotheses from competing explanations of the compliance literature that can be tested against social capital variables in subsequent chapters. In sum, the chapter develops and presents a theoretical framework through which we can understand the effects of social capital variables on compliance. The society-centered approach8 derives its logic from game theory. Drawing on the main research on the society-centered approach (Putnam, Leonardi et al., 1993; Brehm and Rahn, 1997; Putnam, 2001; Kahan, 2002; Putnam and Goss, 2002b), I identify three ways through which compliance becomes effective. The first and second mechanisms draw attention to non-state actors through which the compliant behavior of state actors becomes effective. The third effect focuses directly on the compliant behavior of state actors. Following the literature on the institution-centered theory on social capital, I develop two hypotheses driven by the distinct logics of social action (rationality vs. logic of appropriateness). One emphasizes institutional capacity (to sanction law breakers) to promote trust and compliance, and draws as the society-centered approach of game theortical arguments. The second mechanism refers to the moral intention of actors to comply with law. Here the underlying logic of social action is based on the logic of appropriateness than on a rational choice model. The chapter highlights both conceptual weaknesses and strengths of both research modes (bottom-up and tow-down) applied in social capital. It shows how social capital theories fail to define an underlying theory of social action. In this chapter, I argue that the concept of social capital would be strengthened by integrating arguments from the compliance literature. This section underlines the closeness between procedural legitimacy and social capital assumptions. While society-centered approaches fail to define the causal mechanisms of how social trust originates and distributes through society, procedural legitimacy may help to define these by clarifying how social interaction generates both political and social trust (Font and Blanco, 2007). Part Two concludes with a discussion of the most prominent theories about compliance. I first develop hypotheses from the literature and then modify them into more society- than state-centered variables. This allows us to control their impact on compliance against social capital variables. Part Three explores social capital as the dependent variable. First, the chapter presents data that helps us make a systematic, empirical, and analytical study of the factors explaining social and political trust. Social trust appears to be generated by networks and norms. Political trust may be generated by both capacity and fairness. The quantitative analysis confirms the major claims of the social capital lit- 8 Hereafter also called bottom-up approach. 19 http://www.nomos-shop.de/Dudziak-Capacity-We-Trust/productview.aspx?product=13318 erature. It first shows that the variables, norms, and networks are significantly correlated with social trust as predicted by the society-centered theory. In contrast to Putnam's theory, norms and networks are not correlated with one another, which is in line with the empirical findings of other studies (cf. Gabriel, Kunz et al., 2002). I then conducted a second analysis of the explanatory variables of political trust. The results support the theoretical predictions of both research modes applied to political trust. Finally, Part Three concludes with an analysis of the relationship between social and political trust. The findings support the assumption as proposed by the literature that both types of trust are closely related to one another (Brehm and Rahn, 1997; Rothstein, 2002). In this chapter I argue that the political trust approach is more precise in its assumptions about how trust is generated by institutions, while the society-centered fails to theoretically define how exactly social trust is generated by networks and norms. Following this, I conclude that the stock of social capital from below (society-centered) requires a minimum of state infrastructure in the first place to prosper. Part Four engages the analysis of social capital and compliance using a combined research design. The purpose of the quantitative analysis is to assess the explanatory power of social capital variables versus state-centered variables suggested by the compliance literature. Moreover, it explores the effect of modified variables derived from compliance theories that aim to directly account for the behavior of nonstate actors. The quantitative analyses explore the correlations of explanatory variables with large-N data sets over time and across countries. It applies multivariate linear regression. The data set this study uses contains over 6,000 cases the Commission opened against the member states for infringing on European law between 1978 and 1999. The data were provided by the research project ‘Compliance with law beyond the nation state’, funded by the German Research Council (DFG) and directed by Prof. Tanja A. Börzel.9 The question of whether these data are outdated or not may appear reasonable to ask. I follow the arguments of other studies that showed that the variation of compliance with European law between member states remains constant over time (Börzel et al., 2007). Member states that performed badly in the early years of European integration continued this performance throughout the period under scrutiny. The results of the quantitative research show that both social and political trust matter for compliance by member states. They highly correlate with the compliance variable, while the results for political trust are more robust than for social trust. Another finding points to the relevance of administrative capacity (the managerial 9 The author participated in this research project, which used this database. The project is aimed at analyzing the conditions under which member states of the EU comply (or not) with EC rules on the basis of the dataset provided by the Commission. For further information on the database, see http://www.fu-berlin.de/polsoz/polwiss/europa/forschung/compliance/index. html. 20 http://www.nomos-shop.de/Dudziak-Capacity-We-Trust/productview.aspx?product=13318 variable) for compliance with European law. Because of the results for social trust revealed by the quantitative analyses, and due to conceptual vagueness implied by the society-centered approach, I do not pursue this line of inquiry. Instead, I focus on the causal relationship between capacity, political trust and compliance, employing qualitative research. The case study focuses on Italy, which has gained notoriety for its poor compliance record with EU law (La Spina and Sciortino, 1993; Pridham and Cini, 1994; Pridham, 1996; Giuliani, 2000; Fabbrini and Doná, 2002; Börzel, 2003: 15; Koutalakis, 2004; Borghetto, Franchino and Giannetti, 2006; Bugdahn, 2006). At the same time, the country suffers from inefficient institutions and low social capital (European Values Study, Putnam, Leonardi et al., 1993; 2000; Mbaye, 2001). Hence the correlations work at the aggregate level in Italy. We can therefore expect to observe the effects of capacity and trust on compliance will most likely occur in this case. The qualitative case analysis is divided into two parts. The first part compares and assesses the implementation of the habitats directive10 in the Italian regions, towards identifying regional patterns of compliance, and controlling for alternative explanations using different indicators than in the quantitative analysis. The purpose is to find out whether we find regional patterns to conduct qualitative analysis on. The findings point out two variables which have explanatory power for compliance: capacity and moreover, institutional fairness (corruption), while political trust is generally low among the regions. Fairness, thus, seems to determine compliance with European law in the Italian regions. Following this is the question whether political trust does really matter for compliance since the findings of the regional comparison underline ‘fairness of institutions’ as the explanatory variable for compliance. I selected a case where high likeliness of observing the effect of fairness on compliance. In other words, I decided against conducting an outlier case study which would have been in line with a mixed-method research design (Mastenbroek, 2005: 1113). The main arguments for not using an outlier case have to do with the reliability of data used in the descriptive analysis of regional comparison. The data used to measure political trust by regions present only crosssectional rather than time-series data, which would compare the level of political trust by region over time. Unfortunately, such data were not available. Hence, we do not know if the values of political trust may vary among the regions over time. The second argument underlines the robust results for the estimated coefficient of political trust presented in the quantitative analysis. I conclude that it is therefore worthwhile to consider these results and proceed with a most likely qualitative case study that would provide evidence of how fairness or corruption accounts for com- 10 The Habitats directive belongs to nature conservation policy. It protects animals, plant species and ‘habitat types‘. 21 http://www.nomos-shop.de/Dudziak-Capacity-We-Trust/productview.aspx?product=13318 pliance as suggested by the descriptive analysis. The analysis thereby also investigates if and how political trust is relevant for effective implementation. The second part of the qualitative analysis is based on a single case study of the implementation of the habitats directive in Apulia. Both the comparison of regional compliance and the single case study conducted in Apulia should help us determine if and how the proposed theoretical model can explain observed variation. A second goal of the qualitative case study is to control for omitted variables. Apulia is an ideal case to trace the effect of low capacity, high corruption and political trust on compliance. The regional capacity of Apulia is comparatively weak and political trust is low, while the data I use point to administrative corruption. Methodologically, I employ/use a backward looking research design, and process tracing, to inquire whether the capacity, fairness and trust variables influence compliance outcomes, or if the absence of one of the explanatory variables increases the likelihood of non-compliance with European law. The empirical findings of the study show that non-state actors can be targeted by European policies. They have to bear potential implementation costs. In this case, state actors depend on the compliant behavior of non-state actors if they in turn want to prevent state compliance deficits. The qualitative case study illustrates how the oppositional behavior of non-state actors may have lead to infringements of EU law in Italy. A second finding of this study points out that fairness and capacity matter for compliance. Fairness, as measured by the degree of corruption, determines the perception individuals have of responsible institutions and therefore influences their trust in them. Several studies have shown how weak state capacities result in poor compliance performance (Mbaye, 2001; Borghetto, Franchino et al., 2006; Hille and Knill, 2006; Kaeding, 2006; Börzel, Hofmann et al., 2007). In this study I show how low state capacity impacts on state non-compliance by affecting the compliant behavior of non-state actors. The qualitative case study provides empirical and theoretical insights into how a weak state or region fails to build the capacity of non-state actors, which is required for compliance. Capacity does not only directly influence the compliant behavior of non-state actors, which in turn determines state compliance both directly and indirectly, as inefficient working administrations are likely to be perceived as corrupt by the public. Part Five synthesizes the findings of the empirical examination. It discusses the general findings and their implications for future research. It highlights the need to obtain data of adequate quality to improve the reliability and validity of quantitative analysis. Furthermore, this final part of the study argues that some points remain unexplained by social capital theories. Here it is argued that the social capital concept could benefit from the integration of sociological theories on social action in order to develop causal mechanisms of the creation of norms. The same accounts for the relationship between social networks and social trust. We still do not know 22 http://www.nomos-shop.de/Dudziak-Capacity-We-Trust/productview.aspx?product=13318 how social networks create and distribute social trust throughout society. Until now, studies on social capital (including my own) could only trace a significant correlation between social networks and trust (Putnam, Leonardi et al., 1993; Putnam, 1995a; Putnam, 1995b; Newton and Norris, 2000; Van der Meer, 2003). Finally, I call for a separation of moral views on compliance from rational choice models. In other words, the integration of non-rational factors into a rational choice model supersedes alternative explanations and fails to explain why in the end most member states comply with European law (Börzel, Hofmann and Panke, 2005; Commission of the European Communities, 2005; Commission of the European Communities, 2007). 23